optimal dividend and financing control problem in the risk … · 2020. 4. 20. · optimal dividend...

7
International Journal of Science and Research (IJSR) ISSN (Online): 2319-7064 Index Copernicus Value (2013): 6.14 | Impact Factor (2015): 6.391 Volume 5 Issue 6, June 2016 www.ijsr.net Licensed Under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY Optimal Dividend and Financing Control Problem in The Risk Model with Non-Cheap Proportional Reinsurance Ye Liu 1 , Danfeng Zhao 2 1 Hebei University of Technology, School of Sciences, Beichen district, Tianjin 300401, China 2 School of Sciences, Hebei University of Technology, Beichen district, Tianjin 300401, China Abstract: In this paper, we consider the optimal dividend and financing control problem in the risk model with non-cheap proportional reinsurance and two kinds of transaction costs. The company control its reserves by paying dividends, issuing equity and taking reinsurance. In our model, the objective is to find the strategy which maximizes the expected present value of the dividends payout minus the equity issuance until the time of ruin. We solve the optimal control problem and identify the optimal strategy by constructing two categories of suboptimal control problems, one is the classical model without equity issuance,the other never goes bankrupt by equity issuance. Keywords: dividend, equity issuance, non-cheap proportional reinsurance, HJB equation, optimal strategy 1. Introduction Optimal dividend strategy, as one major public concern to assess the stability of companies that take on risks, has become an increasingly popular topic in actuarial research. Its origin can be traced as early as the work of De Finetti [1], which introduced a discrete-time model for optimal dividend. De Finetti showed that the optimal strategy is a barrier strategy and determined the optimal level of the barrier by maximizing the expected discounted dividends paid to shareholders. Since then the optimal dividend strategy has been studied extensively. Some recent works include Højgaard and Taksar [2], Gerber and Shiu [3], Cadenillas et al.[4], Avanzi et al.[5]and so on. Meanwhile, in the real financial market, equity issuance is an important approach for the insurance company to earn profit and reduce risk. Both equity issuance and dividend are important issues in modeling insurance risk. Sethi and Taksar [6] recently considered the model for the company that controls its risk exposure by issuing new equity and paying dividends to shareholders and discussed the problem using singular and impulse controls. Løkka and Zervos [7] studied the combined optimal dividend and equity issuance problem by taking into account the possibility of bankruptcy. The aforementioned authors mainly focused on developing optimal dividend and equity issuance strategies. They did not consider reinsurance. Reinsurance plays a significant role in both theory and practice of insurance risk modeling. It is a means by which a direct insurance company can transfer the risks from their liabilities to a second insurance carrier. The three popular types of reinsurance strategies are stop-loss reinsurance, proportional reinsurance and excess-of-loss reinsurance. The academia and practitioners have paid more attention to the proportional reinsurance and excess-of-loss reinsurance. Some works on the excess-of-loss reinsurance are Asmussen et al.[8], Choulli et al.[9], Centeno [10] and so on. Some literature on the proportional reinsurance includes He and Liang [11], [12] and so on. He and Liang [11], [12]incorporated the proportional reinsurance strategy in the combined dividend and equity issuance problem using both singular and mixed singular-impulse controls. Motivated by these works, we consider the optimal dividend and financing control problem of an insurance company. We assume that the company can control its reserves by paying dividends, issuing equity and taking non-cheap proportional reinsurance. Moreover, there exists a minimal reserve requirement. And some costs will be incurred: reinsurance company will need more premium for the risk ceded by the insurer; fixed cost is generated by advisory and consulting fees when payingdividends; proportional transaction costs are generated by the tax. In this paper, we consider the dividends payout and the equity issuance as the reflecting and absorbing boundaries of the reserve process, respectively. Firstly, we study the solutions of two models: one is diffusion control model without equity issuance, the other stands for the model with equity issuance to meet the minimal reserve requirement, so it never goes bankrupt. Our objective is to maximize the expected present value of the dividends payout minus the equity issuance until the time of ruin. Then we prove that the value functions and the optimal strategies are the solutions of the two control problems. We provide a rigorous and detailed mathematical analysis for the combined effect of the optimal dividend, equity issuance and non-cheap proportional reinsurance strategies. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the control model of an insurance company with non-cheap proportional reinsurance. In Section 3, we present two lemmas for proving the main results of this paper. In Section 4, we construct solutions of two categories of suboptimal models. In Section 5, we verify the value function and the optimal strategy with the corresponding solution in Paper ID: NOV164089 http://dx.doi.org/10.21275/v5i6.NOV164089 563

Upload: others

Post on 22-Oct-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • International Journal of Science and Research (IJSR) ISSN (Online): 2319-7064

    Index Copernicus Value (2013): 6.14 | Impact Factor (2015): 6.391

    Volume 5 Issue 6, June 2016

    www.ijsr.net Licensed Under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY

    Optimal Dividend and Financing Control Problem in

    The Risk Model with Non-Cheap Proportional

    Reinsurance

    Ye Liu1, Danfeng Zhao

    2

    1Hebei University of Technology, School of Sciences, Beichen district, Tianjin 300401, China

    2School of Sciences, Hebei University of Technology, Beichen district, Tianjin 300401, China

    Abstract: In this paper, we consider the optimal dividend and financing control problem in the risk model with non-cheap proportional reinsurance and two kinds of transaction costs. The company control its reserves by paying dividends, issuing equity and taking

    reinsurance. In our model, the objective is to find the strategy which maximizes the expected present value of the dividends payout minus

    the equity issuance until the time of ruin. We solve the optimal control problem and identify the optimal strategy by constructing two

    categories of suboptimal control problems, one is the classical model without equity issuance,the other never goes bankrupt by equity

    issuance.

    Keywords: dividend, equity issuance, non-cheap proportional reinsurance, HJB equation, optimal strategy

    1. Introduction

    Optimal dividend strategy, as one major public concern to

    assess the stability of companies that take on risks, has become

    an increasingly popular topic in actuarial research. Its origin

    can be traced as early as the work of De Finetti [1], which

    introduced a discrete-time model for optimal dividend. De

    Finetti showed that the optimal strategy is a barrier strategy

    and determined the optimal level of the barrier by maximizing

    the expected discounted dividends paid to shareholders. Since

    then the optimal dividend strategy has been studied

    extensively. Some recent works include Højgaard and Taksar

    [2], Gerber and Shiu [3], Cadenillas et al.[4], Avanzi et

    al.[5]and so on.

    Meanwhile, in the real financial market, equity issuance is an

    important approach for the insurance company to earn profit

    and reduce risk. Both equity issuance and dividend are

    important issues in modeling insurance risk. Sethi and Taksar

    [6] recently considered the model for the company that

    controls its risk exposure by issuing new equity and paying

    dividends to shareholders and discussed the problem using

    singular and impulse controls. Løkka and Zervos [7] studied

    the combined optimal dividend and equity issuance problem

    by taking into account the possibility of bankruptcy. The

    aforementioned authors mainly focused on developing optimal

    dividend and equity issuance strategies. They did not consider

    reinsurance.

    Reinsurance plays a significant role in both theory and practice

    of insurance risk modeling. It is a means by which a direct

    insurance company can transfer the risks from their liabilities

    to a second insurance carrier. The three popular types of

    reinsurance strategies are stop-loss reinsurance, proportional

    reinsurance and excess-of-loss reinsurance. The academia and

    practitioners have paid more attention to the proportional

    reinsurance and excess-of-loss reinsurance. Some works on

    the excess-of-loss reinsurance are Asmussen et al.[8], Choulli

    et al.[9], Centeno [10] and so on. Some literature on the

    proportional reinsurance includes He and Liang [11], [12] and

    so on. He and Liang [11], [12]incorporated the proportional

    reinsurance strategy in the combined dividend and equity

    issuance problem using both singular and mixed

    singular-impulse controls.

    Motivated by these works, we consider the optimal dividend

    and financing control problem of an insurance company. We

    assume that the company can control its reserves by paying

    dividends, issuing equity and taking non-cheap proportional

    reinsurance. Moreover, there exists a minimal reserve

    requirement. And some costs will be incurred: reinsurance

    company will need more premium for the risk ceded by the

    insurer; fixed cost is generated by advisory and consulting fees

    when payingdividends; proportional transaction costs are

    generated by the tax. In this paper, we consider the dividends

    payout and the equity issuance as the reflecting and absorbing

    boundaries of the reserve process, respectively. Firstly, we

    study the solutions of two models: one is diffusion control

    model without equity issuance, the other stands for the model

    with equity issuance to meet the minimal reserve requirement,

    so it never goes bankrupt. Our objective is to maximize the

    expected present value of the dividends payout minus the

    equity issuance until the time of ruin. Then we prove that the

    value functions and the optimal strategies are the solutions of

    the two control problems. We provide a rigorous and detailed

    mathematical analysis for the combined effect of the optimal

    dividend, equity issuance and non-cheap proportional

    reinsurance strategies.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we

    introduce the control model of an insurance company with

    non-cheap proportional reinsurance. In Section 3, we present

    two lemmas for proving the main results of this paper. In

    Section 4, we construct solutions of two categories of

    suboptimal models. In Section 5, we verify the value function

    and the optimal strategy with the corresponding solution in

    Paper ID: NOV164089 http://dx.doi.org/10.21275/v5i6.NOV164089 563

  • International Journal of Science and Research (IJSR) ISSN (Online): 2319-7064

    Index Copernicus Value (2013): 6.14 | Impact Factor (2015): 6.391

    Volume 5 Issue 6, June 2016

    www.ijsr.net Licensed Under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY

    either category of suboptimal models, tightly connecting with

    the relationships among the parameters.

    The Model

    Let 0( , ,{ } , )t t P F F be a filtered probability space and

    tB is a standard Brownian motion on this probability space,

    where tF represents the information available at time t and

    any decision made up to time t is based on this information. To pay dividends to the share holders, the insurance company

    has to determine the times and amounts of dividend payments.

    A dividend stream is defined by

    ……,21,|iξ,τ ii :L ,where ii ξ,τ are the time and

    amount of the i th dividend payment, respectively. We assume that ……,21,|i,τi is a sequence of increasing stopping times and ……,21,|i,ξi is a sequence of

    non-negative,i.i.d random variables.Let tL denote the total

    amount of dividends paid until time t . Then we can define

    1i

    tt IL iτ ξ: i, where

    EI is the indicator function of the event

    E . We suppose the liquid reserves of the insurance company must satisfy some minimal reserve requirement. In this case,

    we assume that the company needs to keep its reserves above

    m , 0m is the minimal reserve requirement. The company is considered bankrupt as soon as the reserves fall below m . However, to avoid bankruptcy, the company should issue

    some equity. We denote tG as the total amount raised by

    issuing equity from time 0 to t . We assume that the process 0tGt , is 0t t adapted F , increasing, right-continuous

    with left limits and 0)(0 G . By the reinsurance strategy

    10,ta (the proportional retention level), the amount of dividend

    tL and equity issuance tG , the liquid reserve of the

    insurance company evolves according to the stochastic

    equation,

    iτ0 01

    λ- λ-μ ξ ,i

    t t

    t s s s s ttn

    R x a d a dB I G

    (2.1)

    where x is the initial reserve, 0 is the relative safety

    loading of the insurer and is the relative safety loading of the

    reinsurer.

    The proportional reinsurance is cheap when . We

    consider the case of which is called non-cheap

    proportional reinsurance.

    We will define an admissible strategy as follows.

    A strategy G;……,ξ,ξ;……,τ,τ;, 21210 tat is said to be admissible if

    (i) }{ ta is an 0t t adapted F process and 10 ])1,[( taP for

    any 0t .

    (ii)For each ,……1,2,i tFt }{τi and

    ii τξ F .

    (iii) }{ tL is 0 progressivet t ly F measurable, increasing and

    cádlág, 0tGt , is 0t t adapted F , increasing, cádlág

    and mRi

    τiξ.

    (iv) 0.,)τlimP( i

    tti

    (v) t tL G 0, here ,t t t tt tL L L G G G

    .

    We write x for the space of these admissible policies. For each x , we write }0|t{ tRR : for the surplus

    progress of the company associated with . The surplus progress is written as follows,

    i{τ }0 01

    λ- λ-μ ξ .i

    t t

    t s s s s ttn

    R x a d a dB I G

    (2.2)

    The ruin time correspond to is defined as:

    }:0{inf:τ mRt t and τ is an t F stopping time. For

    each dividend payment, we have to pay a fixed set-up cost

    ),(0 K , which is independent of the amount of the payment.

    Let 11 be a positive number. Then 11 is the tax rate if

    the dividend is taxed. Consequently, the amount of the money

    that the shareholder receives is ξiK 1 if the amount ξ i

    of

    the liquid assets is distribute. In the meanwhile, the

    shareholders must pay out 122 g to meet the amount of

    g as new equity of the company. 2 is the proportional

    transaction cost generated by the issuance of equity.

    So our optimal control problem is to maximize the expected

    present value of the dividends payout minus the equity

    issuance before bankruptcy, i.e. we need to find maximizing the following performance function as

    τ - s 2{τ τ } 0, ( ξ ) e .i

    ii s

    i

    V x E e K I dG

    11

    (2.3)

    The optimal value function is defined as

    ).,(sup)(

    xVxV

    (2.4)

    In addition, the minimal reserve requirement asks for 0)( xV ,

    for mx . To solve the optimization problem, our must

    determine the value function )(xV and the optimal strategy

    satisfies ),()( xVxV .

    Next, we will divide into two parts: 2 and

    2 .

    (I) We discuss the case of 2 . It includes two

    situations: (i) 01 xdx and (ii) 00 xd , where

    ,,, 0-)y

    2(

    -y

    2

    -2

    02

    20

    udyuGGx

    u

    d is a nonnegative constant.

    First, we consider the situation (i):

    Paper ID: NOV164089 http://dx.doi.org/10.21275/v5i6.NOV164089 564

  • International Journal of Science and Research (IJSR) ISSN (Online): 2319-7064

    Index Copernicus Value (2013): 6.14 | Impact Factor (2015): 6.391

    Volume 5 Issue 6, June 2016

    www.ijsr.net Licensed Under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY

    ((i) will be discussed in Section 3 and Theorem 4.1 and

    Theorem 4.2. (ii) and (II): 2 will be discussed after

    that.)

    3. Two Primary Lemmas

    In this section we give two main lemmas before proving the

    Theorems in Section 4.

    Lemma 3.1.

    There exists a unique mKxx

    ,,,, 111 satisfying the

    following equation in 1x ,

    ,01211

    212

    11

    121

    21

    xmbxmbe

    bbb

    be

    bbb

    b (3.1)

    where 2

    22

    22

    22

    1

    2,

    2

    bb .

    Proof. Denote the left-hand side of (3.1)by )( 1xk .

    Differentiating )( 1xk with respect t 1x ,we have

    0' 121112

    11

    12

    211

    xmbxmbe

    bb

    be

    bb

    bxk

    .

    Then )( 1xk is a strictly decreasing function of 1x . )( 1xk

    reaches its maximum at m on ,m .We deduce ,)( 1 xk as 1x and

    0)(212

    11

    121

    21

    bbb

    b

    bbb

    bmk

    ,

    thus (3.1) has a unique solution 1

    x and mx 1

    .

    Lemma 3.2

    There exists a unique mxx 2111

    ,,,, satisfying

    the following equation in 1x ,

    ,221

    11

    12

    21 1211

    xmbxmbe

    bb

    be

    bb

    b (3.2)

    where 21, bb are the same as in Lemma 3.1.

    Proof. Denote the left-hand side of (3.2) by )( 1xh .

    Differentiating )( 1xh with respect to 1x , we have

    0)(' 1211

    21

    211

    12

    1211

    xmbxmbe

    bb

    bbe

    bb

    bbxh

    .

    Then )( 1xh is a strictly increasing function of 1x . )( 1xh

    reaches its minimum at m on ,m . We deduce )( 1xh , as 1x , and

    21

    21

    11

    12

    21)(

    bb

    b

    bb

    bmh

    , thus (3.2) has a unique solution

    1x and mx

    1.

    4. Two categories of suboptimal solutions

    In this section, we consider two categories of suboptimal

    control problems.

    Let 0,, AAA La be the control process for the company

    in which equity issuance is not permitted.We define the

    associated optimal value function as

    ),(sup)( AA xVxVA

    , for mx .

    Let BG,, BBB La be the control process for the company with equity issuance procedures. In this case, the

    insurance company will never go bankrupt. The associated

    optimal value function is ),(sup)( BB xVxVB

    , mx .

    According to (2.4), it follows that )(,)(max)( xVxVxV BA

    for mx .

    The two suboptimal solutions will play a key role in

    constructing the optimal policy . Thus we will first study

    the solutions to the two suboptimal control problems.

    4.1 The solution to the problem without equity issuance

    In this subsection, our objective is to maximize the expected

    discounted dividends payout.

    Theorem 4.1. We assume

    11 xx , where

    1x and

    1x are defined in Lemmas 3.1. and 3.2. Then the

    function f defined by

    ,

    ),()()(

    ,

    ,)()()(

    )(

    1

    11112

    1

    )(

    2

    )(

    11

    xx

    xfxxxf

    xxm

    exCexCxf

    xf

    xdxbxdxb

    0201

    11

    (4.1.1)

    satisfies the following HJB equation and the boundary

    conditions for mx ,

    )(4.1.2

    ),(',)()(')-()(''2

    1maxmax

    0,)()(

    1

    22

    10,

    xfxf

    xfxfxfaxfaa

    0.)( mf (4.1.3)

    Moreover, for mx ,

    ,)(' 2xf (4.1.4)

    where21, bb are the same as in Lemma 3.1, )(,)( 1211 xCxC

    are

    defined by

    ;)(e

    )(,)(e

    )(212

    )(

    1112

    121

    )(

    2111

    012011 bbb

    bxC

    bbb

    bxC

    dxxbdxxb

    .)()(sup)( 1 yfyxKxfxym

    Proof. By the standard theory of optimal control, we use the

    same method as in Wendell and Fleming [13] and Højgaard

    and Taksar [2] to get a function f satisfying the following

    HJB equations,

    )(4.1.5

    .0,)(''

    ,,)('

    ,

    0,)()(')-()(''2

    1max

    1

    11

    1

    22

    10,

    xxxf

    xxxf

    xxm

    xfxfaxfaa

    Then differentiating w.r.t a for the first equation of (4.1.5), we can find

    )(''

    )(')(

    2 xf

    xfxa

    .

    Since )(xa belongs to 10, , putting the expression )(xa

    Paper ID: NOV164089 http://dx.doi.org/10.21275/v5i6.NOV164089 565

  • International Journal of Science and Research (IJSR) ISSN (Online): 2319-7064

    Index Copernicus Value (2013): 6.14 | Impact Factor (2015): 6.391

    Volume 5 Issue 6, June 2016

    www.ijsr.net Licensed Under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY

    into the first equation of (4.1.5), we get

    0)-()('

    )(

    )(''2

    )('2

    2

    xf

    xfc

    xf

    xf .

    Denoting )('

    )()(

    xf

    xfxp

    , we get that

    .,)(

    )()2

    (c

    )('2

    2

    mxxcp

    xp

    xp

    By a simple calculation, we find that there exists a nonnegative

    constant d such that 1( )( ) ( ), ,

    '( )

    f xp x G x d x m

    f x

    where )(1G denote the inverse function of G .

    We have

    )(2

    )( dxcGxa 1 .

    Since ][0,1)( xa , we have

    2c

    20

    Gxdx . The above

    expression requires 0xd and 2 .Therefore, we need to

    consider two cases: 2 and 2 .

    First we suppose 01 xdx under the case of 2 .

    Since )(xa is an increasing function, we know 1)( xa on

    1, xm , which implies that the first equation of (4.1.5) becomes

    )(4.1.7,0,)()(')-()(''2

    11

    22 xmxxfxfaxfa

    Therefore

    ;,)()()( 1)(

    2

    )(

    11 xmxexCexCxfxdxbxdxb

    ,0201 11

    111112 ),()()( xxxfxxxf .

    Due to the continuity of the function )(' xf and )('' xf at point

    1x , we can derive that

    0,)()()(''

    ,)()()('

    )(2

    22

    )(2

    111

    1

    )(

    22

    )(

    111

    0201

    0201

    11

    11

    xdxbxdxb

    xdxbxdxb

    ebxCebxCxf

    ebxCebxCxf i.e.

    )(e)(,

    )(e)(

    212

    )(

    1112

    121

    )(

    2111

    012011 bbb

    bxC

    bbb

    bxC

    dxxbdxxb

    .

    From 0)( mf , we have

    0)()()()(

    2

    )(

    11 0201

    11

    xdmbxdmbexCexCmf ,

    which implies that 1x is a solution of (3.1). Using Lemma 3.1,

    we have

    11 xx . Similarly, if 11 xx, then 0)( mf . So

    110)( xxmf .

    We will prove that f satisfies (4.1.2)-(4.1.4). Noticing that

    11, 21 , it suffices to prove the following:

    )(4.1.8

    .

    0,)()(')-()(''2

    1max

    ;,)(',)('

    0,)()(')-()(''2

    1max

    1

    22

    10,

    121

    22

    10,

    xx

    xfxfaxfa

    xxmxfxf

    xfxfaxfa

    a

    a

    The proof is as follows: for

    1xx ,

    )()()( 11112 xfxxxf , we have 0)( 111 xf

    .

    Therefore

    0)()(

    )()(')-(max

    )()(')-()(''2

    1max

    11111

    2210,

    222

    22

    10,

    xxxf

    xfxfa

    xfxfaxfa

    a

    a

    Using the same way as in Højgaard and Taksar [2], it is easy to

    prove that

    0)()(')-()(''2

    1max 111

    22

    10,

    xfxfaxfaa

    holds for

    1xxm .

    Since 0)(' )()(12

    2111

    1211

    xmbxmb

    eebb

    bbxf

    ,

    then )(' xf is a decreasing function on ],[ 1xm. Moreover,

    11 )(' xf and

    1)(' xf are obvious.

    The problem remaining is to prove that the solution f satisfies

    )()()()()( 1 xfKyxyfxfxf :

    x

    m

    x

    yKdfKdf 0))('())('( 11

    . The proof of

    (4.1.4) is as follows.

    Since

    111

    21

    11

    12

    21 ,) ()(' 1211 xxxhebb

    be

    bb

    bmf

    xmbxmb and

    )(xh is a strictly increasing function, we have

    211 ) () ()(' xhxhmfby Lemma 3.2.

    4.2. The solution to the problem with equity issuance

    In this subsection, our aim is to maximize the expected

    discounted dividends payout minus the expected discounted

    equity issuance over all reinsurance, dividends payout and

    equity issuance strategies. This kind of insurance companies

    will never go bankrupt.

    Theorem 4.2. Assume that

    11 xx , where 1x and

    1x are

    defined in Lemmas 3.1 and 3.2. Then the function g defined

    by

    )(4.2.1

    ,

    ),()()(

    ,

    ,)()()(

    )(

    1

    11112

    1

    )(

    2

    )(

    11

    xx

    xgxxxg

    xxm

    exCexCxg

    xg

    xdxbxdxb

    0201

    11

    satisfies the following HJB equation and the boundary

    conditions:

    )(4.2.20,)('),()( 2

    1

    22

    10,),(',)()(')-()(''

    2

    1maxmax

    xgxgxg

    xfxgxgaxgaa

    0)(' mg (4.2.3)

    where 21, bb are the same as in Lemma 3.1, )(),( 1111 xCxC

    are

    defined as same as in Theorem 4.1 by replacing 1

    x with 1

    x .

    Proof. Considering the time value of money leads us to the

    conclusion that it is optimal to postpone the new equity

    issuance as long as possible. If we issue equity at the reserve

    n prior to m , 2)(' ng and )(' xg is a decreasing function,

    so )('' ng must be 0 to meet the requirement2)(' xg .But it

    is not compatible with 10,a . Thus we know that it is optimal to issue equity only when the reserves become m .

    Paper ID: NOV164089 http://dx.doi.org/10.21275/v5i6.NOV164089 566

  • International Journal of Science and Research (IJSR) ISSN (Online): 2319-7064

    Index Copernicus Value (2013): 6.14 | Impact Factor (2015): 6.391

    Volume 5 Issue 6, June 2016

    www.ijsr.net Licensed Under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY

    By the same argument as in Theorem 4.1, we know the

    function g should be characterized by

    )(4.2.4)(' 2mg

    )(4.2.5

    .0,)(''

    ,,)('

    ,

    0,)()(')-()(''2

    1max

    1

    11

    1

    22

    10,

    xxxg

    xxxg

    xxm

    xgxgaxgaa

    Doing the same procedures as in proof of Theorem 4.1, we can

    prove the function )(xg of (4.2.4) and (4.2.5) has the same

    form as )(xf , and 1x satisfies the following equation

    .2

    21

    11

    12

    21 1211

    xmbxmbe

    bb

    be

    bb

    b

    By Lemma 3.2, we have

    11 xx and .1 mx

    We will prove that the solution g satisfies the conditions

    mentioned in Theorem 4.2. It suffices to prove the following:

    )(4.2.6

    ,

    0,)()(')-()(''2

    1max

    ;,)(',)('

    0,)()(')-()(''2

    1max

    1

    22

    10,

    121

    22

    10,

    xx

    xgxgaxga

    xxmxgxg

    xgxgaxga

    a

    a

    and )()( xgxg .

    Using the similar procedures as in Section 4.1, we can prove

    the above affirms.

    We will verify 0)( mg , i.e.

    .

    )()(

    )(

    1211

    1211

    212

    11

    121

    21

    11

    212

    11

    121

    21

    xmbxmb

    xmbxmb

    ebbb

    be

    bbb

    b

    xkxk

    ebbb

    be

    bbb

    bmg

    (ii) 00 xd .

    By the same argument as in (i), we can get the Lemmas and

    Theorems that are similar to Lemma 3.1, Lemma 3.2 and

    Theorem 4.1,Theorem 4.2, where )(xf and )(xg are defined

    as follow. The corresponding value functions are defined by

    )(1

    xVA and )(1 xVB, respectively.

    ,1

    12113

    10

    )(

    12

    )(

    112

    0

    )(G

    1

    12111

    ),()()(

    ,

    ,)()()(

    ,

    ,)()()(

    )(

    0

    1-

    xx

    xfxxxf

    xxdx

    exCexCxf

    dxxm

    exCxCxf

    xfxdxbxdxb

    dydy

    dx

    x

    0201

    where

    ;)(e

    )(,)(e

    )(

    212

    )(

    11

    12

    121

    )(

    21

    11 012011 bbb

    bxC

    bbb

    bxC

    dxxbdxxb

    ,1

    12113

    10

    )(

    12

    )(

    112

    0

    )(G

    1

    12111

    ),()()(

    ,

    ,)()()(

    ,

    ,)()()(

    )(

    0

    1-

    xx

    xgxxxg

    xxdx

    exCexCxg

    dxxm

    exCxCxg

    xgxdxbxdxb

    dydy

    dx

    x

    0201

    where

    .)(e

    )(,)(e

    )(

    212

    )(

    11

    12

    121

    )(

    21

    11 012011 bbb

    bxC

    bbb

    bxC

    dxxbdxxb

    (II) 2 .

    In this case, the company does not need to reinsure, i.e.

    1)( xa for all mx . By the same argument as in (i), we can

    get the Lemmas and Theorems that are similar to Lemma 3.1,

    Lemma 3.2 and Theorem 4.1, Theorem 4.2, where )(~

    xf and

    )(~ xg are defined as follow. The corresponding value functions

    are defined by )(2

    xVA and )(2 xVB, respectively.

    ,),(~

    )()(~

    ;,)()()(~

    )(~

    111112

    1

    )(

    21

    )(

    111

    xxxfxxxf

    xxmexCexCxfxf

    dxbdxb

    21

    11

    where .

    )(e)(,

    )(e)(

    212

    )(

    11121

    121

    )(

    21111

    1211 bbb

    bxC

    bbb

    bxC

    dxbdxb

    ,),(~)()(~

    ;,)()()(~

    )(~

    111112

    1

    )(

    21

    )(

    111

    xxxgxxxg

    xxmexCexCxgxg

    dxbdxb

    21

    11

    where

    .)(e

    )(,)(e

    )(212

    )(

    11121

    121

    )(

    21111

    1211 bbb

    bxC

    bbb

    bxC

    dxbdxb

    5. The Solution to the General Problem

    We now study the optimal control problem without any

    restriction on the issuance of equity.

    Theorem 5.1. Let concave function 2)( Cx satisfy the

    following HJB equation and boundary condition : for mx ,

    )(5.10,)('),()( 2

    1

    22

    10,),(',)()(')-()(''

    2

    1maxmax

    xxx

    xxxaxaa

    (5.2)0.)('),(max 2 mm

    Then ),()( xVx for any admissible policy .

    Proof. Since )(x is a concave, increasing and continuous

    function on ,m . From )()( xx , we know (5.3)0.ξ,ξ,)()ξ( 1 mxKxx

    For a policy , we note ,,: 21 ss LLs and

    ss GGs :'

    .

    tss

    t

    c

    t GG,'

    ss

    , )G(G is the continuous part of

    tG .

    By Itô formula,

    tss

    s

    c

    s

    ts

    t

    s

    s

    ts

    t

    t

    e

    dGe

    dBsae

    dsexe

    ,'ss

    ,

    s0

    s0

    s0

    )(

    )(R)(R

    )(R'

    )(R'

    )(R)()(R

    Paper ID: NOV164089 http://dx.doi.org/10.21275/v5i6.NOV164089 567

  • International Journal of Science and Research (IJSR) ISSN (Online): 2319-7064

    Index Copernicus Value (2013): 6.14 | Impact Factor (2015): 6.391

    Volume 5 Issue 6, June 2016

    www.ijsr.net Licensed Under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY

    where ,)()(')-()(''2

    1)( 22 xxaxax

    .)ξ(-K

    )G(G

    )(R)(R

    )(R)(R)(R)(R

    }{1

    1

    ,'ss2

    ,'ss

    ,ss

    ,'ss

    ti

    i

    tss

    s

    tss

    s

    tss

    s

    tss

    s

    i

    i Ie

    e

    e

    ee

    By substituting this inequality into the above equation and

    taking expectation on both sides, we obtain

    .)ξ(-K

    )()(R

    }{1

    1

    20

    )(

    ti

    i

    s

    ts

    t

    t

    i

    i IeE

    dGeExeE

    By the definition of and 21 )(' x , it is

    easy to prove that

    0.)(Rinflim)()(Rinflim)(

    IeImee tt

    tt

    t

    t

    So we deduce that

    iτ - s{τ τ } 0

    , ( ξ ) e ( ).i

    i s

    i

    V x E e K I dG x

    1 21

    The main results of this paper are the following.

    Theorem 5.2. (I) 2 .

    (i) 01 xdx .

    1x ,

    1x are given in Lemmas, )(),( xfxV and )(xg are

    defined by (2.4), (4.1.1) and (4.2.1) respectively. )(xVA and

    )(xVB are defined in Section 4.

    If

    11 xx , then )()()( xVxfxV A . The optimal

    policy ),,(

    GLa

    satisfies the following

    )(5.4

    0,

    0,)(

    ,

    ,ξμ-λ-λ

    0 :

    1

    1

    i

    t

    txRt

    t

    nt

    t

    sss

    t

    st

    G

    dLtI

    xR

    IdBadaxR

    t

    100

    where )(

    tt Raa .

    If

    11 xx , then )()()( xVxfxV B . The optimal

    policy ),,(

    GLa satisfies the following

    )(5.5

    0,)(

    0,)(

    ,

    ,ξμ-λ-λ

    0 }:{

    0 }:{

    1

    i}{τ

    1

    i

    tmRt

    txRt

    t

    t

    nt

    t

    sss

    t

    t

    dGtI

    dLtI

    xRm

    GIdBadaxR

    t

    t

    100

    where )(

    tt Raa .

    According to Lions and Sznitman [14] we know that the

    processes ),,(

    GLa and ),,(

    GLa

    are uniquely determined by (5.4) and (5.5).

    (ii) 00 xd .

    All the results are similar to 01 xdx .

    (II) 2 .

    All the results are same to the case 01 xdx . In this case,

    the insurance company doesn't need to reinsure.

    Proof. (I) If

    11 xx , the function )(xf satisfies the HJB

    equation and boundary conditions. And )(xf also satisfies

    conditions (5.1) and (5.2) in Theorem 5.1. So

    )()()( xVxVxf A by Theorem 5.1. We will prove

    )()( xVxf corresponding to . Applying generalized Itô

    formula, we obtain 0)(R

    tf and

    )(5.6.)ξ(-K

    )(R')(R)()(R

    }{1

    1

    0

    )(

    ti

    i

    ss

    t

    t

    s

    t

    t

    i

    i Ie

    dBfaexffe

    where }:0{inf mRt t . Because

    0)()(Rinflim )(

    mfefet

    t

    t

    , taking expectation

    at both sides of (5.6), we get

    ).,()ξ()(}τ{τ

    τ

    i

    i

    xVIKeExfi

    i

    11

    So )(xf is the value function corresponding to , and

    )()( xVxf A . Using the results )()()( xVxVxf A , we have

    )()()( xVxVxf A .

    If

    11 xx , )(xg defined in (4.2.1) satisfies the HJB equation

    and boundary conditions. Thus )(xg satisfies conditions (5.1)

    and (5.2) in Theorem 5.1. So )()()( xVxVxg B by Theorem

    5.1. We will prove )()( xVxg corresponding to .

    Applying generalized Itô formula, we obtain 0)(R

    tf

    and

    )(5.7,)ξ(-K

    )(R')(R

    )()(R

    }{1

    1

    0

    20

    )(

    ti

    i

    ss

    t

    t

    s

    s

    ts

    t

    t

    i

    i Ie

    dBfae

    dGexgge

    where }:0{inf mRt t . Since

    0)(Rinflim )(

    t

    t

    t

    ge , by taking expectation

    at both sides of (5.7), we get

    .),(

    e)ξ()(0

    s-

    }τ{τi

    τ

    i

    i

    xV

    dGIKeExgi

    s

    121

    So )(xg is the value function corresponding to ,and

    )()( xVxg B . Using the results )()()( xVxVxg B , we have

    )()()( xVxVxg B . The proof of (ii) and (II) is similar to (i),

    so we omit it here.

    6. Conclusion

    In this paper, we consider the optimal dividend and financing

    control problem in the risk model with non-cheap proportional

    reinsurance. The management of the company controls the

    reinsurance rate, dividends payout and the equity issuance to

    maximize the expected present value of the dividends payout

    minus the equity issuance until the ruin time. To be more

    Paper ID: NOV164089 http://dx.doi.org/10.21275/v5i6.NOV164089 568

  • International Journal of Science and Research (IJSR) ISSN (Online): 2319-7064

    Index Copernicus Value (2013): 6.14 | Impact Factor (2015): 6.391

    Volume 5 Issue 6, June 2016

    www.ijsr.net Licensed Under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY

    realistic, we assume the minimal reserve restrictions and

    consider the fixed and proportional transaction costs. The

    former cost is generated by the advisory and consulting as well

    as the latter is generated by the tax. It is the first time to study

    non-cheap proportional reinsurance in an insurance model

    with this method to solve the optimal control problem, which

    construct two categories of suboptimal control problems, one

    is the classical model without equity issuance, the other never

    goes bankrupt by equity issuance. We verify the optimal

    strategy and the value function with the corresponding

    solution in either category of suboptimal models, tightly

    connecting with the relationships among the parameters.

    7. Acknowledgements

    We are very gratrful to the careful reading of the manuscript,

    correction of errors, valuable suggestions which improved this

    paper very much.

    References

    [1] De Finetti, B., “ Su un'impostazione alternativa dell teoria

    collettiva del rischio,” Transactions of the XVth

    International Congress of Actuaries, Vol.2, pp. 433-443,

    1957.

    [2] Højgaard, B., Taksar, M., “Controlling risk exposure and

    dividnds payout schemes: Insurance company example,”

    Math. Finance, 9(2), pp. 153-182, 1999.

    [3] Gerber, Hans U., Shiu, Elias S.W., “ Optimal dividends:

    analysis with Brownian motion,” N. Am. Actuar. J., 8(1),

    pp. 1-20, 2004.

    [4] Cadenillas, A., Choulli, T., Taksar. M., Zhang, L.,

    “ Classical and impulse stochastic control for the

    optimization of the divideng ang risk policies of an

    insurance firm,” Math. Finance, 16(1), pp.181-202,

    2006.

    [5] Avanzi, B., Gerber, H.U., Shiu, E.S.W.,“Optimal

    dividends in the dual model,” Insur. Math. Econ., 41(1),

    pp. 111-123, 2007.

    [6] Sethi, S.P., Taksar, M., “ Optimal financing of a

    corporation subject to random returns,” Math. Finance, 12(2), pp.155-172, 2002.

    [7] Løkka, A., Zervos, M., “Optimal dividend and issuance of equity policies in the presence of proportional costs,”

    Insur. Math. Econ., 42(3), pp. 954-961, 2008.

    [8] Asmussen, S., Højgaard, B., Taksar, M., “Optimal risk

    control and dividend distribution policies: example of

    excess-of-loss reinsurance for an insurance corporation,”

    Finance Stochast., 4(3), pp. 299-324, 2000.

    [9] Choulli, T., Taksar, M., Zhou, X.Y., “Excess-of-loss

    reinsurance for acompany with debt liability and

    constraints on risk reduction,” Quant.Finance, 1, pp.

    573-596, 2001.

    [10] Centeno, M., “ Dependent risks and excess of loss

    reinsurance,” Insur.Math. Econ., 37(2), pp.229-238,

    2005.

    [11] He, L., Liang, Z.X., “ Optimal financing and dividend

    control of the insurance company with fixed and

    proportional transaction costs,” Insur. Math. Econ., 42, pp.

    976-983, 2008.

    [12] He, L., Liang, Z.X., “ Optimal financing and dividend

    control of the insurance company with fixed and

    proportional transaction costs,” Insur. Math. Econ., 44(1),

    pp. 88-94, 2009.

    [13] Wendell, H., Fleming, H. Mete Soner., “ Controlled

    Markov Processes and Viscosity Solutions,” Springer-

    Verllag, New York, 1993.

    [14] Lions, P.-L., Sznitman, A.S., “ Stochastic dierential

    equations with reflecting boundary conditions,” Comm.

    Pur. Appl. Math., 37, pp.511-537, 1984.

    Author Profile

    Ye Liu received the B.S. degree in Mathematics and

    Applied Mathematics from Handan College in 2014 ,

    and now studying in the graduate school of Hebei

    university of technology, China.

    Danfeng Zhao received the B.S. degree in Mathematics and

    Applied Mathematics from Xingtai College in 2014 , and now

    studying in the graduate school of Hebei university of technology,

    China.

    Paper ID: NOV164089 http://dx.doi.org/10.21275/v5i6.NOV164089 569