market structure, power asymmetries, and credible ... structure, power asymmetries, and credible...

50
Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield Department of Politics Department of Political Science Princeton University University of Pennsylvania Princeton, NJ 08544 Philadelphia, PA 19104 609-258-5831 (phone) 215-898-7657 (phone) 609-258-5349 (fax) 215-573-2073 (fax) [email protected] [email protected]

Upload: phamdiep

Post on 07-Mar-2019

225 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991

Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield Department of Politics Department of Political Science Princeton University University of Pennsylvania Princeton, NJ 08544 Philadelphia, PA 19104 609-258-5831 (phone) 215-898-7657 (phone) 609-258-5349 (fax) 215-573-2073 (fax) [email protected] [email protected]

Page 2: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991

Abstract

In this paper, we examine the political economy of trade flows among major

powers during the twentieth century. In the aftermath of World War II, scale economies

motivated an increasing proportion of trade and the size distribution among the major

powers became severely skewed. As a result, free trade became a risky strategy for

smaller major powers. Reducing this risk required the larger states to make a credible

commitment to keep their markets open. Alliances enabled them to do so. As such,

military coalitions became especially important determinants of trade flows after World

War II.

Our empirical analysis supports this argument. We find that alliances exert a

strong and sizeable effect on trade throughout the twentieth century. Their impact,

however, is larger in the bipolar system than in its multipolar predecessor. Furthermore,

relative to their prewar counterparts, post-World War II alliances exert more powerful

effects on trade between states of disparate size than on trade between more symmetrical

partners. Thus, our empirical analysis suggests that alliances do help resolve the problem

of dynamic inconsistency that power asymmetries and scale economies create.

The argument and evidence we present suggests that the international political

economy resembles other political arenas in which welfare-enhancing outcomes require

the nominally dominant power to tie its own hands. In the international system, we

argue, an alliance can help a large state to do so, just as merchant guilds enabled

medieval rulers to achieve efficient trade levels and a stronger parliament in the

seventeenth century helped the English crown to obtain loans at less than prohibitive

rates.

1

Page 3: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Introduction

Existing studies advance two important arguments about the political foundations

of major-power trade. According to the literature on international regimes, Prisoner’s

Dilemma (PD) preference rankings characterize the trade policy preferences of large

states. Thus, each state’s dominant strategy is to impose tariffs. As is true of PD games

more generally, however, states can achieve the Pareto-optimal free-trade equilibrium if

their interactions continue indefinitely and a credible punishment mechanism anchors

each state’s pledge to keep its markets open (e.g., Axelrod 1984; Keohane 1984;

Yarbrough and Yarbrough 1986).

More recent studies argue that regime theory neglects the impact on major-power

trade of concerns about security produced by the anarchic international system (e.g.,

Gowa 1994; Gowa and Mansfield 1993; Kim 1998; Mansfield and Bronson 1997a,

1997b; Pahre 1999). Some argue, for example, that the “security externalities” of trade

make open markets more likely between allies than between adversaries. Variations in

the expected duration of alliances, they add, make the impact of alliances on trade

stronger in bipolar than in multipolar systems (Gowa and Mansfield 1993; Gowa 1994).

In this paper, we extend the existing research program on the political economy of

trade in two ways. First, we argue that the conditions under which states preferred free

trade shifted after World War II. In the postwar period, scale economies motivated an

increasing proportion of trade and the size distribution among the major powers was

severely skewed. As a result, free trade became a risky strategy for relatively small

major powers. To reduce this risk, larger states had to make a credible commitment to

keep their markets open. It is because alliances allowed the nominally dominant states to

2

Page 4: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

tie its own hands, we argue, that they became especially important determinants of trade

flows after World War II.

Next, we analyze the effects of alliances on major-power trade flows between

1907 and 1991. We do so in two ways. First, recent empirical research has not generated

any consensus on the relationship between alliances and foreign commerce. Because our

study is predicated on the argument that alliances promote open trade, we begin by re-

examining this key issue. Our findings indicate that alliances do exert a large and

statistically significant effect on trade throughout the twentieth century. We also find that

their impact is larger in the bipolar system than in its multipolar predecessor.

Second, we test the particular hypothesis this paper advances about the role that

alliances play when markets are imperfect and a marked size asymmetry exists between

prospective trading partners. The evidence is consistent with our argument. Relative to

their prewar counterparts, post-World War II alliances exert more powerful effects on

trade between states of disparate size than on trade between more symmetrical partners.

Thus, the second part of our empirical analysis suggests that alliances do help states

resolve the problem of dynamic inconsistency that power asymmetries and scale

economies create.

Immediately below, we briefly review the existing literature on the political

foundations of open international trade. Then, we explain why shifts in market structure

and in the distribution of power generate a problem of time inconsistency. Next, we

show how intra-alliance trade can mitigate this problem. Finally, we examine the data

and present our findings.

3

Page 5: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

The Existing Literature

Existing literature about the political determinants of international trade is based

on standard trade theory. Thus, it assumes that a state’s optimal trade policy is a function

only of its world market power—i.e., of its ability to affect the price of its exports relative

to its imports. Whether a country can affect its terms of trade depends upon its relative

size.1 Standard theory defines a country as “small” if its trade policy cannot increase its

terms of trade—i.e., a small country, by definition, faces an infinitely elastic export

supply curve. It is because small countries are price takers that free trade maximizes their

real income regardless of the policies other states adopt.

In contrast, changes in the trade volume of a “large” country can improve its

terms of trade. As a result, its optimal policy depends upon which of three possible

distributions of market power exist. If only one large country exists, its first-best

alternative is an “optimal” tariff—i.e., a tax on trade that maximizes the net gain from the

improved terms of trade and decreased trade volume the tariff generates (Conybeare

1984).2 An optimal tariff remains a large country’s most attractive policy option even if

another relatively large state exists, as long as it has more market power than does its

prospective trading partner.3 For reasons that will become clear below, it is important to

note that a tariff is in either case a Pareto-inferior policy option: the income transfer it

1 Market power can also accrue because a country has a monopoly over the supply of a particular product (e.g., oil). We do not explicitly examine this case, but the argument we advance also applies to this source of market power. 2 Setting the tariff equal to the reciprocal of the elasticity of its trading partner’s export supply curve accomplishes this goal (Ethier 1983, 192). This is the reason that a small country’s welfare-maximizing tariff level is zero. 3 This is so even if a trade war ensues between them. Johnson (1953/54) and Kennan and Riezman (1988) discuss the conditions of power asymmetry under which this conclusion holds.

4

Page 6: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

induces is inefficient, as the large country gains less than the target country loses.4

Finally, a uniform distribution of market power among large countries generates

preference rankings that conform to a PD game.

As such, this third situation is the canonical case of international regime theory

(e.g., Axelrod 1984; Keohane 1982, 1984). Drawing on studies of the PD game,

proponents of regime theory show that free trade can emerge as an equilibrium outcome

of an infinitely repeated game. The game-theoretic set up in this literature assumes that

the conditions of standard trade theory hold. However, asymmetric information exists

about whether states shirk. As a result, decentralized action cannot secure liberal trade. A

regime can do so, however, insofar as it enables its members to detect and punish

attempts to cheat.5

Because regime theory emphasizes the role of market failures, it does not consider

the impact of security concerns on trade. Not surprisingly, studies that take these

concerns explicitly into account generate more qualified predictions about free-trade

prospects. Robert Pahre (1999, 123-48), for example, argues that whether open markets

prevail, even among allies, depends on the distribution of military burdens among them.

His argument assumes that security and trade are public goods, although others maintain

that both can often be privatized (e.g., Conybeare 1984, 1992).

4 That is, the gain to the large country is less than the sum of its loss of consumer surplus and the small country’s loss of producer surplus. A Pareto-superior alternative is free trade plus a side payment from the smaller country to the larger one. This solution is of more interest in theory than in practice, however, given the familiar problems associated with arranging and enforcing side payments. See, e.g., Acemoglu 2002, 3. 5 The regime literature, however, does not identify the mechanism that allows a trade regime to extract information from states with incentives to misrepresent it.

5

Page 7: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Assuming that free trade is excludable, Joanne Gowa and Edward D. Mansfield

(1993; Gowa 1994) contend that regime theory is incomplete. Trade increases a state’s

real income, they argue, bolstering its political-military capacity. Because this “security

externality” is positive in the case of allies and negative in the case of adversaries, allies

have stronger incentives than other states to trade freely with each other.6 As in the case

of regime theory, Gowa and Mansfield assume that the conditions of standard theory

hold.

In the next section of this paper, we discuss the effects of scale economies and

power asymmetries on the incentives of major powers to trade freely with each other.

Doing so makes it clear that PD preference rankings do not always accurately describe

the incentive structures of major powers. This implies that neither repeated interaction

nor monitoring mechanisms will sustain free trade. Imperfect markets and power

asymmetries create a credible-commitment problem. As such, whether the dominant

power is willing and able to tie its own hands determines whether international markets

will be open.

Market Structure and Free Trade

Neoclassical trade theory assumes that differences among countries drive trade.

In its Heckscher-Ohlin variant, differences in relative factor endowments motivate trade.

6 Powell (1999) maintains that concerns about security need not deter trade irrespective of the distribution of the gains that ensue. He acknowledges that a state that receives a disproportionately large share of the gains might attempt to shift the prevailing balance of power in its favor. He argues, however, that its trading partner can neutralize its effort simply by allocating a larger share of its returns to its own military sector. Even under this scenario, however, states are better off trading with their allies than with their adversaries. If the state that receives the larger share of the gains from trade increases its allocation to guns, its ally need not respond in kind. Evidence of free riding among allies suggests the empirical relevance of this argument.

6

Page 8: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

All else equal, gains from trade increase with the disparity between the capital/labor

ratios of trading partners. As such, Heckscher-Ohlin theory generates predictions about

both the direction and composition of international trade. Because relative factor

endowments diverge most sharply between rich and poor countries, neoclassical trade

theory predicts that most trade will occur between them. It also predicts that trade will

take the form of exchanges of perfectly homogenous goods across different industries.

Thus, for example, Germany will export widgets to and import cocoa beans from the

Cote dIvoire.

Different predictions, however, arise from what has come to be called the “new”

trade theory, which accords central roles to product differentiation and scale economies

(e.g., Krugman 1980; Helpman and Krugman 1985; Helpman 1999).7 As their incomes

increase, consumers begin to demand goods that reflect their taste for variety. Hence, if

production exhibits increasing returns to scale (i.e., unit costs that fall as output expands),

an incentive to engage in product differentiation exists. Firms within the same industry

will therefore specialize in the production of differentiated goods—i.e., they will produce

functionally similar goods that differ from each other with respect to quality or style

(Grubel and Lloyd 1975, 95).8 In the presence of scale economies and consumer

demands for variety, the new trade theory predicts that countries with relatively similar

factor endowments will engage in intraindustry trade.

7 It is important to note, however, that some observers dispute the role of scale economies in motivating trade (e.g., Davis and Weinstein 2001). 8 Scale economies can exert large effects on production costs: some studies show that a one percent increase in output leads to 0.15 to 0.20 percent fall in unit production costs (Helpman 1999, 140). As Antweiler and Trefler point out (2002, 107), if costs decrease by 0.13 percent for every one percent increase in output, a firm operating at 10 percent of the output level of a U.S. firm faces 55 percent higher average costs.

7

Page 9: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

In general, existing evidence is consistent with the idea that the foundations of

trade have shifted over time. Kevin H. O’Rourke and Jeffrey G. Williamson (1999a, 7;

see also 1999b), for example, observe that “the correct trade model may vary with the

period being studied.”9 They describe the nineteenth century as the “classic” era of

Heckscher-Ohlin trade (O’Rourke and Williamson 1999a, 4). Trade in that period, as A.

G. Kenwood and A. L. Lougheed (1992, 91) point out, involved the “exchange of

manufactured goods for raw materials and foodstuffs between the rapidly industrializing

countries of Europe and North America and primary producing countries.” The interwar

pattern also conformed to neoclassical trade theory, as manufactures “dominated” the

export shares of the industrialized countries, while the less developed countries exported

primary products (Kenwood and Lougheed 1992, 213-14).

In contrast, post-World War II trade seems to fit the new trade theory more

closely. Intraindustry trade rose steadily from 36 percent of global trade in 1959 to 42

percent in 1964 and 48 percent in 1967 (Grubel and Lloyd 1975, 41). The share of

intraindustry trade in total British trade was about 53 percent in 1970. Ten years later, it

had increased to about 75 percent. By 1990, almost 85 percent of British trade occurred

within rather than across industries. German trade displays a similar pattern: the

corresponding figures are 56 percent in 1970, 57 percent in 1980, and 72 percent in 1990

(Helpman 1998, 581). The British and German data, as Elhanan Helpman (1999, 134)

9 It is important to note that differences in relative factor endowments can also generate intra-industry trade, as factor intensities can vary as much across goods within the same industry as they do in the case of goods that different industries produce. Nonetheless, differences in factor proportions can explain increases in intraindustry trade only if the factor endowments that characterize the principal trading countries have become more disparate across time. This, however, seems to be exactly the opposite of what has occurred in the postwar period (Deardorff 1984, 502).

8

Page 10: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

notes, are consistent with “a general trend of rising shares of intraindustry trade” among

the advanced industrialized countries.

The distribution of trade also reflects the growing importance of trade within

rather than across industries. Thus, an increasing proportion of world trade occurs

between the members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development

(OECD), despite their increasingly similar per capita incomes and factor endowments

(Deardorff 1984, 502). More than half of all merchandise trade now occurs among the

advanced countries, while North-South trade accounts for only about 30 percent of

international trade in goods (Helpman 1998, 573).

Thus, the new trade theory seems to apply with particular force to the post-World

War II period. It is important to note, however, that neither neoclassical nor the new trade

theory alone can explain trade either before or after 1945. Scale economies drove some

trade prior to World War II (e.g., Brown 1995) and differences in factor endowments

continue to motivate a sizeable portion of contemporary world trade. Nonetheless, it

seems clear that scale economies matter a great deal more in the post-1945 period than

they did previously. In the next section of this paper, we examine how changes in the

basis of trade can affect the prospects for open international markets.

Scale Economies, Sunk Costs, and Free Trade

Increasing returns to scale often arise as a consequence of fixed costs—i.e., the

costs that a firm must bear in order to operate and that are independent of its level of

output (Tirole 1988, 307). When production requires the expenditure of fixed costs, entry

9

Page 11: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

is not free and markets will tend to be imperfectly competitive.10 We focus here on the

case in which fixed costs take the form of irreversible investments or sunk costs,

expenditures “that cannot be recouped if the action is reversed at a later date” (Dixit

1992, 108).11

Irreversible investments, as Caroline Freund and John McLaren (1999, 19) note,

are a “routine part of everyday international business.” Standard business manuals, they

observe, contains “long lists of adjustments that must be made in approaching a new

market.” Even Canadian exports to the United States, they point out, require substantial

amounts of legal research. A very familiar example that illustrates the role of sunk costs

in international trade is that of Japanese auto producers. To export to the U.S. market,

these producers had to invest in specialized equipment to meet safety and pollution

standards specific to the United States (Yarbrough and Yarbrough 1992, 71).

It seems clear that overseas trade can create opportunities for profitable

investments in IRS industries that would not otherwise exist. A relatively small country

can exploit scale economies if it invests in the production of goods designed for export to

a larger country. Exercising this option is risky, however. If the small country does so, it

will endow its larger trading partner with the power to appropriate the resulting surplus

ex post (Yarbrough and Yarbrough 1992). As a result, sinking costs into an IRS industry

can leave a relatively small state worse off than it would have been otherwise.

10 Scale economies that are external to the plant but internal to the industry can also exist. In this case, markets remain perfectly competitive. Thus, we limit our analysis to cases in which IRS arise at the firm level. Internal economies of scale give a cost advantage to large firms and create an imperfectly competitive market structure (Krugman and Obstfeld 2000, 122). 11 In practice, the period of time in which costs are sunk varies, so irreversibility endures for the period in “which the cost of being freed from the commitment…is sufficiently high that it does not pay to be freed” (Tirole 1988, 308).

10

Page 12: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Indeed, when exporting requires assets that are specific to the large state’s market,

even the prospect of free-trade negotiations can degrade the welfare of a small state.12

The expectation that the larger country’s market will remain open can stimulate an

allocation of resources within the smaller state that vitiates its bargaining power ex post,

rendering autarky its ex ante welfare-maximizing choice (McLaren 1997).13 Moreover,

as the Japanese auto case suggests, the absolute size of the “small” country can be quite

large by world standards; what matters is the relative size of the two countries’ markets.

As a result, when large disparities in market size exist and markets deviate from

the perfectly competitive structure that standard trade theory assumes, free trade is no

longer a dominant strategy for any state. Small countries that condition their domestic

resource allocation on the presumption that the markets of their larger trading partner will

remain open can endanger rather than enhance their welfare. If imperfect markets and

power asymmetries exist, free trade will maximize the expected national income of the

relatively small state only if the large power is willing and able to make a credible

commitment to keep its markets open.14 We address the implications of this problem of

dynamic inconsistency for liberal international trade next.

12 These investments, of course, can also increase the dependence of the large country on trade. However, the effect on the small country is much greater, because the induced change in its resource allocation is proportionately much larger. In addition, in a trade war, it is in the interest of the large country to impose a tariff, while the small country’s interest dictates adherence to free trade. As a result, increasing trade dependence “improves the trade war outcome for the former and worsens it for the latter,” thereby decreasing the threat point of the smaller state relative to that of its larger counterpart (McLaren 1997, 403, n. 9). 13 This is so as long as the small country’s exports are “poor” substitutes for its imports or if countries do not differ much with respect to labor productivity across sectors (McLaren 1997, 403). 14 See Lapan (1988) for a more general discussion of the time-inconsistency problem in trade.

11

Page 13: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Credible Commitments and Free Trade

Regime theory, as we noted above, assumes that the conditions of standard trade

theory hold and that state preferences conform to those of a PD game. As such, it

assumes that each state can affect its terms of trade. By definition, therefore, it applies

only to the behavior of large states. Studies that focus on the impact of security concerns

on major-power trade are also based on standard trade theory and a PD framework. The

explanatory power of the existing literature, therefore, varies with the foundations of

trade and the extent to which power asymmetries exist among major-power allies. For

reasons we explain below, its explanatory power varies across international systems.

During the multipolar era, relative symmetry prevailed within great-power

alliances. In 1907, for example, the ratio of British to French gross domestic product and

that of Britain to Russian GDP were both about 1.5:1.15 The corresponding French-

Russian ratio stood at 1.03:1. In 1913, the ratio of British to French economic output was

1.40, and the corresponding ratios for Britain and Russia and France and Russia were

0.85 and 0.86, respectively. In 1936, these ratios ranged between 0.39 for France and

Russia to 1.71 for Britain and France. In addition, as we noted above, trade patterns were

consistent with the predictions of the Heckscher-Ohlin model. Thus, major-power trade

during the multipolar era is generally consistent with the iterated PD game that is the

foundation of existing theories about the political economy of trade.

A marked gap between these theories and the real world, however, opens up after

World War II. During the Cold War, the distribution of market power among the major-

power allies was highly skewed. In 1950, U.S. economic output was about eight times as

12

Page 14: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

large as that of Britain and about 10 times as large as that of France. The U.S.-British

ratio remains about 8:1, regardless of whether 1950, 1960, or 1970 data are used to

calculate it. The U.S.-French ratio ranges between about 10:1 in 1950 and 3.5:1 in 1970.

U.S. economic output exceeds that of Germany by a factor of 12 in 1950, 7 in 1960; and

5.5 in 1970. The ratio of U.S. to Japanese economic output ranges between 26:1 in 1950

and 5:1 as of 1970. Thus, marked asymmetries characterize the major powers during the

bipolar period. This period is also one in which, as we noted above, scale economies

motivate a sizeable share of trade among the advanced countries and a disproportionately

large share of world trade occurs among them.

Thus, the straightforward application of existing theories to major-power trade

during the bipolar era seems problematic. Power asymmetries and scale-economy based

trade creates a credible-commitment problem in this period that had not existed

previously. As a result, whether relatively small states choose to assume the risk free

trade creates depends on whether the dominant state is willing to make a credible

commitment to keep its markets open. However, even the willingness of the large state

to tie its own hands may not suffice. The crisis-bargaining literature shows, for example,

that states may not be able to peacefully resolve a dispute even if they are eager to do so.

Because any exogenous shock to the balance of power can generate a demand for future

revisions, no state can credibly commit to adhere to a peace accord (e.g., Fearon 1994).

The same type of problem can impede efforts to conclude a free-trade pact when

the conditions of standard trade theory no longer hold. A large state cannot solve the

problem of time inconsistency with a promise to adhere to free trade, because promising

15 The statistics in this and the next paragraph are calculated using Correlates of War data, described below.

13

Page 15: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

to keep its markets open is in its interest regardless of the strategy it actually intends to

follow. As an announcement does not raise the costs of reneging, it does not affect the

incentive to do so; an announcement is, therefore, “cheap” talk. Consequently, no

prospective trading partner will alter its ex ante beliefs about the large state’s preferences

on the basis of an announcement alone. Instead, the large state must send a “costly”

signal—i.e., it must take an action that is too expensive for its opportunistic counterpart

to mimic.

A political-military alliance can serve as such a signal. This is so even though the

trade signal can be an unintended consequence of alliance formation. Regardless of its

size, a state typically joins an alliance in order to enhance its security. Especially for

small states, any ensuing military force integration allows them to protect themselves

more effectively and more efficiently than if each relied only on its own resources. The

value added of an alliance to a large state more typically lies elsewhere—in, for example,

the access it gains to the territory of its smaller allies or its ability to influence them

(Morrow 1991).

The formation of an alliance can help to secure the large state’s commitment to

keep its markets open for two reasons. First, the decision of the large state to become a

member makes clear its belief that the alliance enhances its welfare. Relative to the

status quo ex ante, therefore, an alliance endows its smaller members with some leverage

over the large state. In addition, the potential military strength of any alliance increases

with the aggregate economic resources of its members.16 As a result, an alliance affects

16 This suggests that it is misleading to represent security concerns as limited to the effects of trade on current military expenditures. The division of the gains from trade also affects security because of its effect on productive capacity in general (cf. Morrow 1997; Powell 1999).

14

Page 16: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

the trade policy incentives of all its members. In the case of the large state, joining an

alliance decreases its incentive to exploit its market power. If its relatively small ally

engages in IRS investments and the large state expropriates the resulting ex post surplus,

the deadweight loss falls on the alliance as a whole. Thus, the large state not only

imposes costs on the small state but also shoots itself in the foot if it does so.17 This, in

turn, makes its smaller members willing to sink costs into the production of exports for

the large country’s markets.

In sum, major-power alliances should exert a positive impact on trade between

their members in both multipolar and bipolar systems. Moreover, as others have argued,

differences in the expected duration of alliances suggest that their effect should be larger

in the more recent period (Gowa and Mansfield 1993; Gowa 1994). The argument we

advance here, however, implies that other sources of cross-systemic variation exist.

When power distributions are skewed and scale economies motivate trade, alliances

should exert particularly powerful effects on trade. An alliance serves as the credible

commitment necessary to induce its smaller members to adopt free-trade strategies.

Thus, bipolar alliances should exert a stronger effect than multipolar alliances on trade

between disparately sized states.

Testing the Argument

To test our argument, we conduct two sets of analyses. Building on recent studies

of the political economy of trade between major powers during the twentieth century, we

17 If the smaller state invests all of its resources in the scale economy sector and the elasticity of substitution between exports and imports is weakly less than one, the resource transfer a tariff induces will be Pareto-optimal, as no consumption distortion occurs in the smaller country. However, complete specialization is specific to the assumption that trade is based only on differences in labor productivity (i.e., on the Ricardian model) (McLaren 1997, 414, n. 41).

15

Page 17: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

estimate the impact of alliances on commerce and assess whether this impact varies

between bipolar and multipolar systems (Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes 1998, 1999).

Next, we examine whether the effect of alliances on trade also depends on market

structure and the distribution of power between economic partners.

In both sets of analyses, we seek to explain bilateral trade flows between states

that were major powers during some part of the twentieth century. We focus on trade

relations between major powers for three reasons. First, our argument applies only if at

least one trading partner can affect its terms of trade. Major powers are more likely than

other states to be able to do so, because both their economies and their trade volumes are

generally sizeable (e.g., Dornbusch 1993). Second, reliable economic data do not exist

for other states, especially before 1945. Finally, since many extant studies of the impact

of alliances on trade include only major powers, analyzing a sample composed of these

states allows us to directly compare our findings with existing results in the literature

(Gowa 1994; Gowa and Mansfield 1993; Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes 1998, 1999).

Further, we analyze aggregate bilateral trade flows. We do so because systematic

data on bilateral tariffs and other trade barriers do not exist for most of the twentieth

century and because an inverse relationship exists between trade barriers and trade flows.

Tariffs raise the price of imports; as such, they typically depress the volume of foreign

commerce.18 In addition, although a conclusive test of our argument requires data on

intraindustry trade and irreversible investments that are not yet available for the countries

and time period in our sample, the model of aggregate bilateral trade flows used in the

following analysis provides a useful first cut at the problem of whether the relationship

18 Of course, trade barriers will not affect trade volumes if demand is completely inelastic.

16

Page 18: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

between alliances and trade varies across systems as well as with market structure and

power distributions.19

To analyze the effects of alliances on bilateral trade flows, we rely on the gravity

model, the workhorse for empirical research on overseas commerce. The gravity model

includes the gross national product (GNP) and population of both the importing and

exporting countries, as well as the geographic distance between them. The theoretical

foundations of the model predict that GNP will be directly related to trade, while both

population and distance will be inversely related to it (Anderson 1979; Bergstrand 1985,

1989; Deardorff 1984, 1998).20 In order to test our theory, we include alliances and the

structure of the international system in the model. As in earlier studies of the political

economy of trade, we also control for regime type, the existence of a military dispute

between states, and the extent to which trading partners have similar foreign policies

(e.g., Bliss and Russett 1998; Duffield 2002; Gowa 1994; Gowa and Mansfield 1993;

Kim 1998, chap. 8; Mansfield, Milner, and Rosendorff 2000; Morrow, Siverson, and

Taberes 1998, 1999).

Since the underlying form of the gravity model is multiplicative, it is estimated

after taking the natural logarithm of each variable.21 Thus, we analyze the following

model:

19 For some recent empirical studies of the role of scale economies in trade, see Antweiler and Trefler (2002) and Everett and Keller (2002). For discussions of the extent to which it is necessary or possible to differentiate between comparative-advantage and scale-economy based trade, see Helpman (1999) and Davis and Weinstein (2001). 20 Anderson (1979), Bergstrand (1985, 1989), and Deardorff (1998) have shown that the gravity model is consistent with a variety of different theories of international trade. 21 The gravity model’s multiplicative form has been justified in a number of ways. One intuitively appealing rationale is that as the national income or population of either i or j approaches zero, so should the amount of trade between them (Deardorff 1998).

17

Page 19: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

logEXPORTij = log β0 + β1logGNPi + β2logGNPj + β3logPOPi +

β4logPOPj + β5logDISTANCEij + β6logBIPOLAR ALLYij +

β7logMULTIPOLAR ALLYij + β8logDISPUTEij + β9logDEMOCRACYij +

β10logSIMILARITYij + β11logWWI + β12logWWII + log εij. (1)

The dependent variable – logEXPORTij – is the natural logarithm of the value of

exports from state i to state j in year t, expressed in constant U.S. dollars.22 The

independent variables include logGNPi and logGNPj, the natural logarithms of the gross

national products of state i and state j, respectively, in year t-1, also expressed in constant

U.S. dollars; logPOPi and logPOPj, the natural logarithms of their respective national

populations in t-1; and logDISTANCEij, the natural logarithm of the shortest geographical

distance between i’s and j’s capital cities.

To assess the effects of alliances, we also include logBIPOLAR ALLYij and

logMULTIPOLAR ALLYij. The former variable indicates whether i and j are political-

military allies during a given year, t-1, in the bipolar era, which began in 1946. The latter

variable indicates whether i and j are allied during a given year, t-1, in the multipolar

period. To code both variables, we use the list of political-military alliances that the

Correlates of War (COW) Project (1993) compiled. We add to that list any states that

fought together in an international war and the Japanese-American Security Agreement,

an issue discussed at greater length below.

22 In light of our argument, it would be useful to exclude trade in military goods. However, data limitations make this impossible. Nonetheless, there are data on the total amount of trade in military goods between most country-pairs in our sample for four periods covered here: 1967-1976, 1976-1980, 1981-1985, and 1987-1991 (United States Arms Control and Development Agency 1983, 1994, 1999). On average, military trade was only about one percent of total dyadic trade during these periods; only rarely did it approach five percent. Thus, little reason exists to believe that trade in military goods accounts for the results reported below.

18

Page 20: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Next, logDISPUTEij indicates whether i and j are engaged in a militarized dispute

(MID) in year t-1. A MID exists when i and/or j threatens, displays, or uses force against

the other. We code disputes using data taken from Daniel M. Jones, Stuart A. Bremer,

and J. David Singer (1996) and from Zeev Maoz (2001). Further, logDEMOCRACYij

indicates whether both i and j are democracies in t-1. States are coded as democratic if

they are assigned a score of 6 or higher on Ted Robert Gurr’s index of institutionalized

democracy, an 11-point scale ranging from 0 (least democratic) to 10 (most democratic)

(Gurr, Jaggers, and Moore 1989; Jaggers and Gurr 1995). Note that each of the four

dummy variables just described takes on values of 1 and 0; in antilogarithmic form they

take on values of e (the base of the natural logarithms) and 1.

As we explain further below, our analysis builds on a recent set of studies in

which James D. Morrow, Randolph M. Siverson, and Tressa Tabares (1998, 1999)

analyze annual trade flows from 1907 to 1990 among France, Germany/West Germany,

Great Britain, Italy, Japan, Russia/Soviet Union, and the United States. As in their work,

we define SIMILARITYij as the taub correlation between the alliance portfolios of states i

and j in year t-1. This variable can range from –1 to 1; but since its lowest observed

value in our data is -0.475, we add 1.475 to SIMILARITYij so that the minimum value of

logSIMILARITYij is 0. Further, Morrow, Siverson, and Tabares (1998, 653) omit from

their sample the periods when World Wars I and II were waged on the grounds that little

trade data are available for these years. However, we have been able to collect a fair

amount of data on major-power trade flows in both periods. We have also collected data

for 1991, the last year of the bipolar era. Consequently, we examine all years (t) from

19

Page 21: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

1907 to 1991.23 To ensure that our findings do not depend on wartime trade, however,

we include one dummy variable for the years when World War I was fought and a second

variable for the years when World War II was underway.

In addition, we make three other changes to the model and data that Morrow,

Siverson, and Tabares use. First, we correct various coding errors in their data set.

Second, where it is possible to do so, we replace missing data with data described in the

appendix to this paper, markedly increasing the number of observations for which

complete information exists. Third, Morrow, Siverson, and Tabares measure both

logEXPORTij and the independent variables described earlier in the same year, t. In

contrast, we measure each independent variable (except logWWI and logWWII) in year t-

1 to reduce the possibility of any simultaneity bias and to take into account the fact that

trade patterns are unlikely to respond immediately to changes in political conditions.

Finally, Morrow, Siverson, and Tabares maintain that the Japanese-American

Security Agreement is a unilateral rather than a mutual security guarantee. Thus, in

contrast to previous work (e.g., Gowa and Mansfield 1993; Gowa 1994), they do not

consider it an alliance. A uniform application of this standard, however, would dictate

the recoding of various other security agreements as well. For example, the North

Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) was, for all practical purposes, a unilateral U.S.

guarantee of European security throughout the Cold War. Therefore, we code the

Japanese-American Security Agreement as an alliance, but we also assess the robustness

of our findings to this coding decision.

23 Note that it is not possible to extend the analysis beyond 1991 because data on both MIDs and the similarity of alliance portfolios are unavailable.

20

Page 22: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

The Statistical Results

As noted earlier, our sample is made up of country-pairs composed of France,

Germany/West Germany, Great Britain, Italy, Japan, Russia/Soviet Union, and the

United States. Each dyad, i and j, is measured twice in every year from 1907 to 1991,

once where exports from i to j are evaluated, the other where exports from j to i are

analyzed. The analysis of time-series cross-sectional data poses various well-known

statistical problems. Particularly important is the danger that the error term (log εij) will

be heteroskedastic as well as serially and contemporaneously correlated. Recent work

suggests that the following procedure can be used to address these problems: estimate the

parameters using ordinary least squares, purge the errors of serial correlation, and

generate “panel-corrected” standard errors that account for any heteroskedasticity and

contemporaneous correlation of the errors across dyads (Beck and Katz 1995).24 Like

Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes (1998, 1999), we use this estimation procedure and

assume that the errors for each dyad follow a first-order autoregressive process common

to all country-pairs in the sample.25

24 Note that the coefficient of variation based on this procedure tends to be much lower than that based on least squares regression. Thus, whereas the adjusted R2 is .61 when our baseline model is estimated using ordinary least squares – a figure that is typical for the gravity model – the adjusted R2s in Tables 1 and 2 are less than half that size. 25 An alternative method to model dynamics in the data is to include a lagged endogenous variable (Beck and Katz 1996). To take into account the concerns expressed by various observers about this method (Achen 2000; Maddala 1998) and to maintain consistency with Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes’s (1998, 1999) study, we model the errors as being serially correlated (AR1). However, we have also examined whether our results are robust to our modeling decision, partly because some previous studies of alliances and trade do include (an instrument for) a lagged endogenous variable (Mansfield and Bronson 1997a). To this end, we created an instrument for the lagged value of trade by regressing logEXPORTij in year t-1 on logGNPi, logGNPj, logPOPi, logPOPj, and logDISTANCEij in year t-2, logWWI, logWWII, and a dummy variable for each country in the sample. When we add to our model the predicted value of logEXPORTij in year t-1, the estimates of the alliance terms are much the same as those shown in

21

Page 23: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

The results, which we present in the first column of Table 1, are consistent with

our argument. The effects of alliances on trade are both positive and statistically

significant, regardless of the structure of the international system. Moreover, alliances do

exert a larger effect on trade when the system is bipolar rather than multipolar. On

average, allies conduct over 60 percent more trade than non-allied countries after World

War II. The corresponding increase during the multipolar era is about 12 percent.26 The

difference between these estimated effects is highly significant (χ2 = 10.88; p = 0.001).

Most of the other variables in our model also exert a strong impact on bilateral

trade flows. As expected, trade is directly related to the national income of both states i

and j; it is inversely related to the distance between them; and each of these relationships

is statistically significant. As in Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes’s (1998, 1999) research,

however, the effect of population on trade is less consistent. Although the estimate of

logPOPj is negative and statistically significant, the estimate of logPOPi is positive and

insignificant.

In addition, we find considerable evidence that military disputes decrease trade,

while democracy and similar alliance portfolios increase it. The estimate of

logDISPUTEij is negative; the estimates of logDEMOCRACYij and logSIMILARITYij are

positive; and all three of them are statistically significant. Finally, and not surprisingly,

Tables 1 and 2. Thus, the effects of alliances do not depend on how we model dynamics in the data. The effects of national income, population, and distance, however, do change in unexpected ways when we include the predicted value of lagged trade. Similar problems have contributed to a general concern about using a lagged endogenous variable to model dynamics (Achen 2000). 26 The quantitative effect of alliance membership in a bipolar system, based on the estimates in the first column of Table 1, is given by eβ6 - 1β6 = e.481 – 1 = .62. The corresponding effect for alliances in a multipolar system is eβ7 - 1β7 = e.114 – 1 = .12.

22

Page 24: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

less trade occurred during the world wars than at other times. The effects of each world

war on trade are negative, quantitatively large, and statistically significant.

It is important, of course, to assess the robustness of these results. First, some

observers argue that China was also a major power during much of the twentieth century.

We did not include China in our sample, because data about its economy and trade

patterns are sparse, especially prior to World War II. However, reliable Chinese

economic data are available for the period since 1960. We use this information to check

whether our findings are robust to the inclusion of China as a major power. As the

second column of Table 1 shows, adding this country to the sample has virtually no effect

on the impact of alliances or any other variable in equation (1).

Second, we address whether our results are robust to the use of a different

measure of foreign-policy similarity. Although Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes rely on

the taub correlation between alliance portfolios to measure SIMILARITYij, an alternative

measure of preference similarity – referred to as “S” – has been used with increasing

regularity in research on international relations (e.g., Gartzke 1998, 2000; Signorino and

Ritter 1999). The third column of Table 1 presents the results when we replace taub with

this index. In general, the results do not depend on which measure is used. It is worth

noting, however, that the estimate of logMULTIPOLAR ALLYij is about three-quarters

larger and much more highly significant in the third column than the first, providing even

stronger evidence that multipolar alliances influence trade flows. Nonetheless, their

impact continues to be significantly smaller than that of bipolar alliances. Since various

studies argue that S is a better index of foreign policy similarity than taub, the fit of our

model improves somewhat when S is used, and S is replacing taub with increasing

23

Page 25: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

frequency in the literature, we will use it in the remaining analyses (Gartzke 1998, 2000;

Signorino and Ritter 1999). Nonetheless, the results rarely depend much on the specific

SIMILARITYij measure.

Third, recall that we added the Japanese-American Security Agreement to the

COW Project’s list of alliances and that we also code states that fought together in a war

as allies. Further analysis provides little indication that these coding decisions have any

substantial effect on the results. As the fourth column of Table 1 shows, the coefficient

of each alliance term remains positive and statistically significant even if we do not code

the U.S.-Japan Agreement as an alliance. In addition, alliances continue to have a larger

effect on trade during the bipolar than the multipolar period, although omitting this

agreement clearly reduces the impact of alliances somewhat in the post-World War II era.

Further, the fifth column of Table 1 indicates that the results are largely unaffected if we

no longer regard states that fought together in a war as allies.

Fourth, we analyze whether the results are robust with respect to the inclusion of a

number of variables that are omitted from equation (1). For example, many preferential

trading arrangements (PTAs) strongly influence trade flows (Frankel 1997; Mansfield

and Bronson 1997a, 1997b). To ensure that the effects of alliances on trade are not

artifacts of PTA membership, we add a dummy variable that indicates if states i and j are

European Community (EC) members in year t-1. The EC is the only PTA relevant to the

states in our sample. Including this variable is also important because its members are

allies. The results in the sixth column of Table 1 indicate that trade between EC

members is significantly greater than trade between other states, but including this

variable does not affect the coefficients of the other variables in the model. Of particular

24

Page 26: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

importance for our purposes is that the effects of bipolar alliances and multipolar

alliances in this specification are virtually identical to those in the third column of Table

1.

We also account for the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), since

it is widely recognized that this institution fostered open trade among its members, many

of which were allied. The seventh column presents the results when a dummy variable

indicating whether states i and j are GATT members in year t-1 is included in the model.

The final column of Table 1 shows the results when we account for the EC and GATT.

The estimates of both variables are positive and statistically significant, indicating that

parties to GATT and the EC conduct more trade than other states. Moreover, the effects

of the remaining variables in the model – including logBIPOLAR ALLYij and

logMULTIPOLAR ALLYij – are quite robust with respect to whether we account for the

influence of these international economic institutions.

Next, it is useful to ensure that the observed relationship between alliances and

trade is not an artifact of any secular trend in both trade flows and the propensity of major

powers to ally with each other. The results provide no evidence that our results are

attributable to the effects of time. Including a trend in the model has very little affect on

signs, sizes, or significance levels of the coefficients in equation (1), and the estimate of

this variable is not statistically significant.

In addition, for each country in our sample, we have included all available data

from 1907 to 1991. However, the COW data set does not code occupied Germany (1946-

1954), Japan (1946-1951), or France (1943) as members of the interstate system (Small

and Singer 1982; Singer and Small 1994). To determine if foreign occupation influences

25

Page 27: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

our results, we introduce a dummy variable that equals 1 if either state i or state j is

occupied in year t, and 0 otherwise. The estimate of this variable is neither statistically

significant nor sizeable. Moreover, including it has no bearing on the other coefficients

in the model.

Finally, it is important to ensure that our results do not reflect the effects of trade

flows on alliances. We therefore estimate a logistic regression in which the observed

value of the dependent variable equals 1 if states i and j are allies in year t, and 0

otherwise. We regress this variable on logEXPORTij, logGNPi, logGNPj, logPOPi,

logPOPj, logDISTANCEij, and logDEMOCRACYij – all of which are measured in year t –

as well as a natural spline function (with three knots) of the length of time since i and j

were last allied to account for any temporal dependence in the data (Beck, Katz, and

Tucker 1998). We then estimate the same model after estimating logEXPORTij in t-1

rather than t. In neither case is the estimate of logEXPORTij statistically significant.

Thus, consistent with the findings of other studies (Mansfield and Bronson 1997a), we

find no evidence that trade flows influence alliances. Consequently, there is little reason

to believe that problems of endogeneity afflict our results.

Scale Economies, Polarity, and Alliances

It seems clear, then, that alliances exert a positive and statistically significant

effect on major-power trade and that their influence is larger during the bipolar era, when

scale-economies motivated trade to a greater extent than during the multipolar era. In

this section, we examine whether the evidence is consistent with our argument that

alliances reduce the risk that a relatively small state confronts in liberalizing trade with a

larger counterpart when markets are imperfect. As we argued above, free trade will

26

Page 28: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

maximize the real income of a small state under these conditions only if its large trading

partner can make a credible commitment to keep its markets open. An alliance enables

the large state to do so by making its adoption of a free-trade strategy incentive

compatible. Empirically, this implies that alliances should exert particularly powerful

effects on foreign commerce when scale economies motivate trade between states of

highly disparate size.

In a preliminary effort to test this argument, we amend equation (1) in the

following way:

logEXPORTij = log β0 + β1logGNPi + β2logGNPj + β3logPOPi +

β4logPOPj + β5logDISTANCEij + β6logALLYij + β7logBIPOLAR +

β8logDISPARITYij + β9(logALLYij × logBIPOLAR) + β10(logALLYij ×

logDISPARITYij) + β11(logBIPOLAR × logDISPARITYij) + β12(logALLYij ×

logBIPOLAR × logDISPARITYij) + β13logDISPUTEij +

β14logDEMOCRACYij + β15logSIMILARITYij + β16logWWI + β17logWWII

+ log εij. (2)

In equation (2), logALLYij is a dummy variable that equals 1 if states i and j are allied in

year t-1 and 0 otherwise. We include logBIPOLAR to capture the fact that scale

economies motivated trade to a greater extent during the period after World War II than

beforehand. It equals 1 during the bipolar period and 0 during the multipolar period.

Further, we include logALLYij × logBIPOLAR to capture the different effects of alliances

on trade in the bipolar and the multipolar eras.

Finally, DISPARITYij is a widely used measure of the relative size of trading

partners (e.g., Egger 2000; Helpman 1987). It is defined as follows:

27

Page 29: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

DISPARITYij = 1 – [GNPi / (GNPi + GNPj)]2 - [GNPj / (GNPi + GNPj)]2

The larger the value of this index, which ranges from 0 to 0.5, the more similar are the

national incomes of states i and j. Our argument about credible commitments implies

that bipolar alliances should exert a particularly powerful effect on trade between states

of markedly different sizes. Hence, we also include the interactions between

logDISPARITYij and logALLYij, logBIPOLAR, and logALLYij × logBIPOLAR,

respectively.

To test this hypothesis, equation (2) is estimated using the same statistical

procedure we employed earlier. The results – which are shown in the first column of

Table 2 – indicate that each variable in the model except logPOPi and logPOPj has a

statistically significant effect on trade. They also provide support for our argument.

Bipolar alliances do exert a larger impact on trade as the distribution of economic power

between trading partners becomes more skewed.

To more fully interpret these results, it is useful to compare the influence of

bipolar alliances on the predicted volume of foreign commerce when states i and j are

about the same size to their influence when the gap between i and j widens. We begin by

expressing equation (2) in antilogarithmic form:

Xij(t) = C × [ALLYij exp(β6 + β9logBIPOLAR + β10logDISPARITYij +

β12(logBIPOLAR × logDISPARITYij))] × [BIPOLAR exp(β7 + β11log

DISPARITYij)] × [DISPARITYij exp(β8)], (3)

where

C=β0GDPiβ1GDPj

β2POPiβ3POPj

β4DISTijβ5DISPUTEij

β13DEMOCRACYijβ14 ×

SIMILARITYijβ15WWIβ16 WWIIβ17εij.

28

Page 30: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

For the purposes of this analysis, C can be treated as a constant. We use equation (3) and

the estimates of β6-β12 in the first column of Table 2 to generate predicted values of Xij(t).

Since our principal interest is in the effect of bipolar alliances on trade as the size

distribution between states i and j becomes more skewed, we start by setting BIPOLAR to

e (and logBIPOLAR to 1). We then compare the effects of a change from the absence to

the presence of alliance on the predicted volume of trade when DISPARITYij at its mean

(.39) to the effects of such a change when the value of this variable is reduced by one

standard deviation (to .28). (Recall that the value of DISPARITYij falls as the trade

partners become increasingly unequal in size.) When DISPARITYij is evaluated at its

mean, an alliance increases the predicted value of exports by about 60 percent. As our

argument predicts, the impact of an alliance rises considerably – yielding more than a 110

percent increases in the predicted volume of trade – when the value of DISPARITYij is

decreased by a standard deviation (i.e., when the difference in the size of the trading

partners increases).

In contrast, multipolar alliances exert a far smaller impact on trade. To address

this issue, we set BIPOLAR to 1 (and logBIPOLAR to 0) and then vary the extent of

disparity in the same way as we did earlier. The results indicate that an alliance increases

the predicted volume of trade by roughly 15 percent when DISPARITYij is evaluated at its

mean, but has virtually no effect on trade when DISPARITYij is reduced by a standard

deviation. Thus, alliances during the bipolar period not only increase trade flows

between their members, but they also do so in a way that suggests that military coalitions

enable large states to tie their own hands with respect to trade policy.

Finally, we analyze whether these results are robust to: (1) the inclusion of

dummy variables for EC and GATT membership, and (2) the use of a modified gravity

model. First, the findings in the second column of Table 2 indicate that accounting for

29

Page 31: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

the EC and GATT has little bearing on the effects of the remaining variables in equation

(2). Moreover, we continue to find that the impact of bipolar alliances on trade increases

as the difference widens between the GNPs of states i and j. During the bipolar era, an

alliance generates an 80 percent increase in the predicted volume of trade when the value

of DISPARITYij is one standard deviation below its mean and only about a 40 percent

increase when DISPARITYij is at its mean.

Second, a number of recent economic studies have modified the standard gravity

model in the following ways (e.g., Egger 2000; Helpman 1987). First, they replace

logGNPi and logGNPj with log(GNPi + GNPj). Second, they replace logPOPi and

logPOPj with a measure of the difference in the relative factor endowments of states i and

j that is expressed as follows:

RFLACij = │log(GNPi/POPi) – log(GNPj/POPj)│

The expectation of this model is that the estimates of log(GNPi + GNPj) and RFLACij will

be positive. Third, these studies include DISPARITYij. Finally, they introduce country-

specific fixed effects into the model. We modify equation (2) in the same way (of course,

DISPARITYij was already in the model) in a final effort to assess the robustness of the

results. We also include the dummy variables for EC and GATT membership since our

earlier analyses indicate that they are strongly related to trade.

The third column of Table 3 displays the results, although we do not report the

country-specific fixed effects (which we include for every state in the sample except the

United States, the country that we arbitrarily designate as the reference category) to

conserve space.27 As expected, the estimates of log(GNPi + GNPj) and RFLACij are

27 Various observers have argued against including fixed effects in models like ours (e.g., Beck and Katz 2001). For that reason and because gravity models rarely include such effects, we have

30

Page 32: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

positive and statistically significant. Moreover, with a few exceptions (specifically,

BIPOLAR and DISPARITYij), the remaining results are quite similar to the previous

findings. Of particular importance is that a bipolar alliance produces about a 40 percent

rise in the predicted volume of exports when the gap in the trade partners’ national

incomes is relatively large and only about a 10 percent increase when the gap narrows.

Although the absolute size of the increases in trade stemming from an alliance is clearly

reduced when we control for the EC and GATT and when the modified gravity model is

analyzed, these results continue to provide strong evidence for our argument that

alliances have a larger influence on trade when markets are imperfect and the distribution

of market power between trade partners is skewed.

Conclusion

The relationship between security and trade has been a longstanding source of

controversy in the field of international relations. In recent years, various studies have

argued that allies trade more freely with each other than do other countries. Some of

these studies maintain that alliance volatility explains the stronger effect of alliances on

trade in bipolar than in multipolar systems. The findings of our empirical analysis of

major-power trade during the twentieth century are consistent with this argument.

However, our analysis also casts new light on the way in which alliances

influence trade. From a theoretical standpoint, we argue that the existing literature on the

not included them thus far. If, however, fixed effects are included in a gravity model, it is preferable to do so on a country-specific rather than a dyad-specific basis (Beck and Katz 2001, 493; Egger 2000; Mansfield and Bronson 1997a). As Antoni Estevadeordal, Brian Frantz, and Alan M. Taylor (2002, 15, n. 37, emphasis original) point out, including dyadic fixed effects to explain bilateral trade leads to the absorption of “any time-invariant pair characteristics,” which represents a “complete rejection of the gravity model framework.” As such, it is “completely detached from any theoretical model of trade.”

31

Page 33: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

political foundations of international trade has been tied for far too long to standard trade

theory.28 Economists have turned to models based on scale economies with increasing

regularity to explain recent trends in both the composition and distribution of trade. It is

time for political scientists to follow suit.

As we show here, doing so can have significant implications with respect to the

analysis of how relatively small states operate in international markets. The literature on

the political economy of international trade has simply assumed that they will adopt free

trade. However, if firms cannot enter and exit markets freely, smaller states will be

unwilling to condition their production on the availability of export markets in the large

state. Inducing them to do so requires the large state to make a credible commitment to

adhere to free trade.

Thus, the international political economy resembles other political arenas in

which marked power asymmetries exist – e.g., cases in which a monopoly of power

threatened efficient trade levels in the medieval era (Greif, Milgrom, and Weingast 1994)

or jeopardized the ability of seventeenth-century monarchs to obtain loans at less than

prohibitive rates (Weingast and North 1988). In each case, the most powerful actor in the

system needed to find a way to tie its own hands. In the international system, we argue,

an alliance can help its dominant member to do so. Moreover, we find that the existing

data support this argument.

28As the references in the text suggest, Yarbrough and Yarbrough (1992) represents an important exception.

32

Page 34: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Appendix

The purpose of this Appendix is to describe the data on trade, national income,

population, and distance used in our analyses. For each of these variables, we began with

Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes’s (1998) data, which are described in the appendix to

their article. We filled in missing trade data using Mitchell (1992, 1995), with the

following exceptions. First, French exports to Japan from 1907-1908 and from 1914-

1921 were taken from Japan (1918, 1924). French exports to Russia during World War I

were taken from France (1919), Nolde (1928), and Clarke and Matko (1983). French

exports to the Soviet Union during World War II were taken from Clarke and Matko

(1983).

Second, German exports to Japan were taken from Japan (1918, 1924,1939) and

Supreme Command for the Allied Powers (1948). German exports to the United States

were taken from the U.S. Department of Commerce, Monthly Summary of Foreign

Commerce of the United States, from 1914-1922 and 1942-1945. Third, Italian exports

to Japan were taken from Japan (1918, 1924, 1939). Italian exports to Russia were taken

from Italy (1916) and from Clarke and Matko (1983). Italian exports to the United States

from 1942-1946 were taken from the U.S. Department of Commerce, Monthly Summary

of Foreign Commerce.

Fourth, Japanese exports not found in Mitchell were taken from Japan (1918,

1924, 1939), Clarke and Matko (1983), U.S. Department of Commerce (1942), and U.S.

Department of Commerce, Monthly Summary of Foreign Commerce of the United

States. Japanese trade data for the period immediately after World War II are taken from

the Supreme Command for the Allied Powers (1948-1953). Fifth, Russian exports to

33

Page 35: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

France in 1914, 1920, and 1921 were taken from France (1919) and Clarke and Matko

(1983). Russian/Soviet exports to Italy were taken from Italy (1916) and Clarke and

Matko (1983). Russian/Soviet exports to Japan were taken from Japan (1918, 1924,

1939), U.S. Department of Commerce (1942), and Clarke and Matko (1983).

Russian/Soviet exports to the U.S. were taken from U.S. Department of Commerce,

Monthly Summary of Foreign Commerce of the United States. Sixth, data on United

States exports were taken from U.S. Department of Commerce, Monthly Summary of the

Foreign Commerce of the United States. Data for China – which we analyze for the

period after 1960 to address the robustness of our results – are taken from the

International Monetary Fund’s Direction of Trade. Finally, for all countries in the sample

except China, missing trade data from 1946 and 1947 were filled in using U.S.

Department of Commerce (1950).

Note that, in cases where exports from state i to state j were not available but j’s

imports from i were available, the latter figure was used. In all cases, trade data

denominated in foreign currencies were first translated into current dollars. The primary

source for exchange rates was the United States Bureau of the Census (1924, 1934,

1947). Most missing values were filled in with data from Bidwell (1970), United Nations

(1951), and Japan (1918). In some remaining cases during World War II, exchange rate

data were unavailable (for example, when the United States government ordered that

currency markets in the New York stop trading the currencies of Axis states during

World War II). In these cases, the final quote available before the war was used. These

cases are as follows. For the ruble in 1939 and 1940, a spot quote in January of 1939

from Bidwell (1970) was used. The 1942 exchange rates for marks were taken from the

34

Page 36: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

last quote in the U.S. Census Bureau (1947) for 1941. For Japan, the exchange rate from

1942 was used for 1943 and 1944. To convert trade in current dollars to constant dollars,

we followed Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes in using data on the Consumer Price Index

drawn from the U.S. Census Bureau (1962, 1996) and Liesner (1989).

To fill in data on national income, we relied primarily on Maddison (1995).

Additional data on Russian/Soviet national income in 1907-1912 and 1914-1927 were

taken from Gregory (1982) and Clarke and Matko (1983). Data on Chinese national

income were taken from the World Bank Development Indicators.

To fill in data on national population, we again relied on Maddison (1995).

However, he does not include data on Soviet population for 1907-1912, 1914-1919, and

1941-1945. For 1907-1912, data were taken from Gregory (1982). For 1914-1919, we

relied on the Correlates of War national material capabilities data set. For 1941-1945,

Soviet population was taken from Clarke and Matko (1983). For a few years

immediately after World War I, Maddison (1991) disagrees with Maddison (1995) on

Germany’s population. In these cases, we rely on the earlier study.

Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes measure the distance between capital cities.

When filling in missing observations, we rely on the values they report, except in the case

of Germany. Berlin was treated as its capital from 1907 to 1948 and from 1990 to 1991.

Bonn was treated as its capital from 1949 to 1989.

Finally, all of the data we added to Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes’s data set on

alliances and the similarity of states’ foreign policy preferences (both taub and S) were

taken from Eugene v2.001 (Bennett and Stam 2000). All of the data we added on

military disputes were taken from Maoz (2001). All additional data on regime type were

35

Page 37: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

taken from the Polity98 data set. Like Morrow, Siverson, and Taberes, we code states for

which data on regime type is missing in a given year as non-democratic.

36

Page 38: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

References

Acemoglu, Daron. 2002. Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 9377.

Achen, Christopher H. 2000. Why Lagged Dependent Variables Can Suppress the

Explanatory Power of Other Independent Variables. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Political Methodology Section of the American Political Science Association, Los Angeles, CA.

Anderson, James E. 1979. A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation. American

Economic Review 69 (1):106-16. Antweiler, Werner, and Daniel Trefler. 2002. Increasing Returns and All That: A View

from Trade. American Economic Review 92 (1):93-119. Axelrod, Robert. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books. Beck, Nathaniel, and Jonathan N. Katz. 1995. What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-

Series-Cross-Section Data in Comparative Politics. American Political Science Review 89 (3):634-47.

_____. 1996. Nuisance vs. Substance: Specifying and Estimating Time-Series-Cross

-Section Models. Political Analysis 6:1-36. _____. 2001. Throwing Out the Baby with the Bath Water: A Comment on Green, Kim,

and Yoon. International Organization 55 (2):487-95. Beck, Nathaniel, Jonathan N. Katz, and Richard Tucker. 1998. Taking Time Seriously:

Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable. American Journal of Political Science 42 (4):1260-88.

Bennett, D. Scott, and Allan Stam. 2000. EUGene: A Conceptual Manual. International

Interactions 26 (1):179-204. Bergstrand, Jeffrey H. 1985. The Gravity Equation in International Trade: Some

Microeconomic Foundations and Empirical Evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics 67 (3):474-81.

_____. 1989. The Generalized Gravity Equation, Monopolistic Competition, and Factor-

Proportions Theory in International Trade. Review of Economics and Statistics 71 (1):153-63.

Bidwell, R. L. 1970. Currency Conversion Tables: A Hundred Years of Change. London: Rex Collings.

37

Page 39: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Bliss, Harry, and Bruce Russett. 1998. Democratic Trade Partners: The Liberal Connection. Journal of Politics 60 (4):1126-47.

Brown, John C. 1995. Imperfect Competition and Anglo-German Trade Rivalry:

Markets for Cotton Textiles before 1914. The Journal of Economic History 55 (3):494-527.

Clarke, Roger A., and Dubravko J. I. Matko. 1983. Soviet Economic Facts, 1917-1981.

2d ed. New York: St. Martin’s. Conybeare, John A.C. 1984. Public Goods, Prisoner’s Dilemmas, and the International

Political Economy. International Studies Quarterly 28 (1):5-22.

_____. 1992. A Portfolio Diversification Model of Alliances: The Triple Alliance and the Triple Entente, 1879-1914. Journal of Conflict Resolution 36 (1):52-85.

Correlates of War Project. 1993. Alliances Data. Unpublished data set, University of

Michigan. Davis, Donald R., and David E. Weinstein. 2001. What Role for Empirics in International

Trade? Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 8543.

Deardorff, Alan V. 1984. Testing Trade Theories and Predicting Trade Flows. In

Handbook of International Economics, edited by Ronald W. Jones and Peter B. Kenen. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

_____. 1998. Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical

World? In The Regionalization of the World Economy, edited by Jeffrey A. Frankel. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Dixit, Avinash. 1992. Investment and Hysteresis. The Journal of Economic Perspectives

6 (1):107-32. Dornbusch, Rudiger W. 1993. The Case for Bilateralism. In Protectionism and World

Welfare, edited by Dominick Salvatore. New York: Cambridge University Press. Duffield, John S. 2002. International Institutions and Interstate Trade: Reassessing the

Effects of Alliances and Preferential Trading Arrangements. International Politics 39 (3):271-91.

Egger, Peter. 2000. A Note on the Proper Specification of the Gravity Equation.

Economic Letters 66 (1):25-31.

38

Page 40: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Estevadeordal, Antoni, Brian Frantz, and Alan M. Taylor. 2002. The Rise and Fall of World Trade, 1870-1939. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 9318.

Ethier, Wilfred. 1983. Modern International Economics. New York: W.W. Norton. Everett, Simon J., and Wolfgang Keller. 2002. On Theories Explaining the Success of the

Gravity Equation. Journal of Political Economy 110 (2):281-317. Fearon, James D. 1994. Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International

Disputes. American Political Science Review 88 (3):577-92. France. 1919, 1924. Statistique Generale de La France, Annuaire Statistique. Paris:

Imprimerie Nationale. Frankel, Jeffrey. 1997. Regional Trading Blocs. Washington, DC: Institute for

International Economics. Freund, Caroline, and John McLaren. 1999. On the Dynamics of Trade Diversion:

Evidence from Four Trade Blocs. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Paper no. 637.

Gartzke, Erik. 1998. Kant We All Just Get Along? Opportunity, Willingness, and the

Origins of the Democratic Peace. American Journal of Political Science 42 (1):1-27.

_____. 2000. Preferences and the Democratic Peace. International Studies Quarterly 44 (2):191-212. Gowa, Joanne. 1994. Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Gowa, Joanne, and Edward D. Mansfield. 1993. Power Politics and International Trade.

American Political Science Review 87 (2):408-20. Gregory, Paul R. 1982. Russian National Income, 1885-1913. New York: Cambridge

University Press. Greif, Avner, Paul Milgrom, and Barry R. Weingast. 1994. Coordination, Commitment,

and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild. Journal of Political Economy 102 (4):745-76.

Grubel, Herbert G., and P. J. Lloyd. 1975. Intra-Industry Trade: The Theory and Measurement of International Trade in Differentiated Products. New York: Wiley.

39

Page 41: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Gurr, Ted Robert, Keith Jaggers, and Will H. Moore. 1989. Polity II: Political Structures and Regime Change, 1800-1986. Study no. 9263. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research.

Helpman, Elhanan. 1987. Imperfect Competition and International Trade: Evidence from

Fourteen Industrial Countries. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 1 (1):62-81.

_____. 1998. The Structure of Foreign Trade. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of

Economic Research Working Paper no. 6752. _____. 1999. The Structure of Foreign Trade. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 13

(2):121-44. Helpman, Elhanan, and Paul R. Krugman. 1985. Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition, and the International Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Italy. 1916. Annuario Statistico Italiano, Seconda Serie. Vol. VI. Roma: Tip. Elzeviriana. Jaggers, Keith, and Ted Robert Gurr. 1995. Tracking Democracy’s Third Wave with the

Polity III Data. Journal of Peace Research 32 (4):469-82. Japan, Department of Finance. 1918, 1920, 1926, 1939. Financial and Economic Annual

of Japan. Tokyo: Government Printing Office. Johnson, Harry. 1953/54. Optimum Tariffs and Retaliation. Review of Economic Studies

22 (1):142-53. Jones, Daniel M., Stuart A. Bremer, and J. David Singer. 1996. Militarized Interstate

Disputes, 1816-1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns. Conflict Management and Peace Science 15 (2):163-213.

Keohane, Robert O. 1982. The Demand for International Regimes. International Organization 36 (2):325-55. _____. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political

Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Kennan, John, and Raymond Reizman. 1988. Do Big Countries Win Tariff Wars?

International Economic Review 29 (1):81-85.

Kenwood, A. G., and A. L. Lougheed 1992. The Growth of the International Economy, 1820-1990. 3rd ed. New York: Routledge.

Kim, Soo Yeon. 1998. Ties that Bind: The Role of Trade in International Conflict

40

Page 42: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Processes, 1950-1992. Ph.D. diss. Yale University. Krugman, Paul. 1980. Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of

Trade. The American Economic Review 70 (5):950-59.

Krugman, Paul, and Maurice Obstfeld. 2000. International Economics: Theory and Policy. 5th ed. Reading, MA: Addison Wesley.

Lapan, Harvey E. 1988. The Optimal Tariff, Production Lags, and Time Consistency.

American Economic Review 78 (3):395-401. Liesner, Thelma. 1989. One Hundred Years of Economic Statistics. New York: The

Economist. Maddala, G. S. 1998. Recent Developments in Dynamic Econometric Modelling: A

Personal Viewpoint. Political Analysis 7:59-87. Maddison, Angus. 1991. Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development: A Long-Run

Comparativist View. Oxford: Oxford University Press. _____. 1995. Monitoring the World Economy, 1820-1992. Paris: Organization for

Economic Cooperation and Development. Mansfield, Edward D., and Rachel Bronson. 1997a. Alliances, Preferential Trading

Arrangements, and International Trade. American Political Science Review 91 (1):97-104.

_____. 1997b. The Political Economy of Major-Power Trade Flows. In The Political

Economy of Regionalism, edited by Edward D. Mansfield and Helen V. Milner. New York: Columbia University Press.

Mansfield, Edward D., Helen V. Milner, and B. Peter Rosendorff. 2000. Free to Trade:

Democracies, Autocracies, and International Trade. American Political Science Review 94 (2):305-21.

Maoz, Zeev. 2001. Dyadic Militarized Interstate Disputes (DYMID 1.1) Data Set.

Available at http://spirit.tau.ac.il/~zeevmaoz/. McLaren, John. 1997. Size, Sunk Costs, and Judge Bowker’s Objection to Free Trade. American Economic Review 87 (3):400-20. Mitchell, Brian R. 1992. International Historical Statistics: Europe, 1750-1988. 3rd ed.

New York: Stockton Press.

_____. 1995. International Historical Statistics: Africa, Asia, and Oceania, 1750-1988. 2d ed. New York: Stockton Press.

41

Page 43: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Morrow, James D. 1991. Alliances and Asymmetry: An Alternative to the Capability Aggregation Model of Alliances. American Journal of Political Science 35 (4): 904-33.

. 1997. When Do “Relative Gains” Impede Trade? Journal of Conflict Resolution 41 (1):12-37.

Morrow, James D., Randolph M. Siverson, and Tressa E. Taberes. 1998. The Political

Determinants of International Trade: The Major Powers, 1907-1990. American Political Science Review 92 (3):649-61.

_____. 1999. Correction to “The Political Determinants of International Trade.”

American Political Science Review 93:931-33. Nolde, Baron Boris E. 1928. Russia in the Great Economic War. New Haven, CT: Yale

University Press. North, Douglass C., and Barry R. Weingast. 1988. Constitutions and Commitments: The

Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in 17th Century England. The Journal of Economic History 49 (4):803-32.

O’Rourke, Kevin H., and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 1999a. The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Between 1400 and 2000: When It Explained Price Convergence, When It Did Not, and Why. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 7411.

_____. 1999b. Globalization and History: The Evolution of a 19th Century Atlantic

Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Pahre, Robert. 1999. Leading Questions: How Hegemony Affects the International

Political Economy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Powell, Robert. 1999. In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategies in International Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Signorino, Curtis S., and Jeffrey M. Ritter. 1999. Tau-b or Not Tau-b: Measuring the

Similarity of Foreign Policy Positions. International Studies Quarterly 43 (1):115-44.

Singer, J. David, and Melvin Small. 1993. National Material Capabilities Dataset. Study

no. 9903. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research.

_____. 1994. Correlates of War Project: International and Civil War Data, 1816-1992.

Study no. 9905. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research.

Siverson, Randolph, and Harvey Starr. 1991. Diffusion of War: A Study of Opportunity

42

Page 44: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

and Willingness. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Small, Melvin, and J. David Singer. 1969. Formal Alliances, 1816-1965: An Extension of

the Basic Data. Journal of Peace Research 6 (3):257-82. _____. 1982. Resort to Arms: International and Civil Wars, 1816-1980. Beverly Hills,

CA: Sage. Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston. 1988. A New Set of International Comparisons of

Real Product and Price Estimates for 130 Countries, 1950-1985. Review of Income and Wealth 34 (1):1-26.

_____. 1991. The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International

Comparisons. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2):327-68. Supreme Commander for the Allied Powers. Various years. Economic Statistics. Tokyo:

Economic Planning Agency, Japanese Government. Tirole, Jean. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. United States Arms Control and Development Agency. 1983, 1994, 1999. World Military

Expenditures and Arms Transfers. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. United States Bureau of the Census. 1921, 1928, 1934, 1947, 1962, 1965, 1996.

StatisticalAbstracts of the United States. Washingon, DC: Government Printing Office.

United States Department of Commerce. 1942. Foreign Commerce Yearbook, 1939.

Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. _____. 1950. Foreign Commerce Yearbook, 1948. Washington, DC: Government

Printing Office. _____. Various years. Monthly Summary of Foreign Commerce of the United States.

Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. United Nations. 1951. Yearbook of International Trade Statistics, 1950. New York:

Statistical Office of the United Nations. Yarbrough, Beth V., and Robert M. Yarbrough. 1986. Reciprocity, Bilateralism, and

Economic Hostages: Self-Enforcing Agreements in International Trade. International Studies Quarterly 30 (1):7-22.

______. 1992. Cooperation and Governance in International Trade: The Strategic

Organizational Approach. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

43

Page 45: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Table 1. Estimated Effects of Gross National Product, Population, Distance, Alliances, Military Disputes, Regime Type, Similarity of Relations, World War, the EC, and GATT on Trade Flows Between Major Powers, 1907-1991. Variable Model 1.1 Model 1.2a Model 1.3 INTERCEPT -2.140** -2.608** -3.457**

(.737) (.629) (.727) GNPi .533** .538** .513**

(.056) (.038) (.053) GNPj .401** .369** .374**

(.046) (.032) (.043) DISTANCE -.396** -.436** -.418**

(.041) (.022) (.041) POPi .027 .079 .139 (.128) (.051) (.128) POPj -.210* -.019 -.089

(.110) (.073) (.107) BIPOLAR ALLY .481** .465** .531**

(.100) (.075) (.097) MULTIPOLAR ALLY .114* .100** .189**

(.068) (.054) (.059) DISPUTE -.315** -.307** -.295** (.043) (.032) (.041) DEMOCRACY .740** .759** .858**

(.089) (.075) (.096) SIMILARITY (TAU) .408** .478**

(.151) (.123) SIMILARITY (S) 1.555** (.230) WWI -.823** -.820** -.763**

(.140) (.122) (.131) WWII -.997** -1.004** -.809** (.144) (.110) (.140) N 3346 3774 3209 R2 .20 .20 .23

44

Page 46: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Table 1 – continued Variable Model 1.4b Model 1.5c Model 1.6 INTERCEPT -3.813** -3.331** -3.739**

(.725) (.728) (.749) GNPi .536** .514** .500**

(.053) (.053) (.053) GNPj .397** .375** .360**

(.043) (.043) (.043) DISTANCE -.435** -.416** -.384**

(.040) (.041) (.041) POPi .139 .129 .177 (.128) (.128) (.130) POPj -.086 -.098 -.050

(.108) (.108) (.109) BIPOLAR ALLY .325** .534** .475**

(.092) (.097) (.097) MULTIPOLAR ALLY .203** .191** .192**

(.060) (.072) (.058) DISPUTE -.301** -.303** -.296** (.042) (.041) (.041) DEMOCRACY .915** .857** .848**

(.098) (.097) (.095) SIMILARITY (S) 1.585** 1.456** 1.511**

(.237) (.245) (.229) WWI -.771** -.757** -.760**

(.132) (.131) (.130) WWII -.841** -.796** -.809** (.141) (.140) (.139) EC .401** (.120) N 3209 3209 3209 R2 .23 .23 .23

45

Page 47: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Table 1 – continued Variable Model 1.7 Model 1.8 INTERCEPT -3.248** -3.849**

(.711) (.741) GNPi .490** .482**

(.053) (.053) GNPj .348** .340**

(.046) (.045) DISTANCE -.431** -.403**

(.040) (.040) POPi .179 .202 (.126) (.128) POPj -.042 -.018

(.111) (.113) BIPOLAR ALLY .406** .372**

(.094) (.095) MULTIPOLAR ALLY .191** .194**

(.060) (.059) DISPUTE -.302** -.303** (.041) (.041) DEMOCRACY .762** .762**

(.092) (.092) SIMILARITY (S) 1.581** 1.547**

(.231) (.230) WWI -.753** -.751**

(.134) (.133) WWII -.827** -.827** (.140) (.139) EC .305** (.117) GATT .408** .376** (.114) (.113) N 3209 3209 R2 .25 .25

46

Page 48: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Table 1 – continued Note: Entries are Prais-Winsten regression estimates, with panel corrected standard errors in parentheses. a Results are generated after including dyads involving China for the period 1960-1991. b Estimates are generated after excluding the Japanese-American Security Agreement from the list of alliances. c States that fought together in a war but did not have a formal alliance are excluded from the list of alliances. ** p < .01; * p < .05. One-tailed tests of statistical significance are conducted for the estimates of GNPi, GNPj, DISTANCE, POPi, POPj, BIPOLAR ALLY, and MULTIPOLAR ALLY since their signs are specified by the gravity model and by our theory, respectively. Two-tailed tests are conducted for the remaining estimates.

47

Page 49: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Table 2. Estimated Effects of Alliances, Polarity, and the Similarity of Economic Size on Trade Flows Between Major Powers, 1907-1991. Variable Model 2.1 Model 2.2 Model 2.3a INTERCEPT -4.936** -5.095** -.522

(.769) (.779) (1.277) GNPi .577** .545** (.056) (.056) GNPj .435** .401**

(.046) (.048)

GNPi + GNPj .972** (.089) DISTANCE -.525** -.531** -.732**

(.039) (.039) (.049) POPi .151 .262

(.125) (.128) POPj -.067 .047

(.103) (.112)

RFLAC .369** (.080) ALLY .618** .603** .622**

(.124) (.123) (.121) BIPOLAR .757** .522 1.031**

(.272) (.271) (.290) DISPARITY -.838** -.822** .341**

(.116) (.114) (.165) ALLY × BIPOLAR -.790** -.973** -1.232** (.232) (.235) (.230) ALLY × DISPARITY .502** .503** .374** (.108) (.107) (.100) BIPOLAR × DISPARITY 1.242** 1.160** 1.116** (.186) (.183) (.181) ALLY × BIPOLAR × -1.229** -1.258** -1.109** DISPARITY (.204) (.203) (.190) DISPUTE -.294** -.293** -.332** (.043) (.042) (.041) DEMOCRACY .975** .871** .531**

(.097) (.093) (.094)

48

Page 50: Market Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible ... Structure, Power Asymmetries, and Credible Commitments: Alliances and Major-Power Trade, 1907-1991 Joanne Gowa Edward D. Mansfield

Table 2 – continued Variable Model 2.1 Model 2.2 Model 2.3a SIMILARITY (S) 1.750** 1.709** 1.792** (.228) (.224) (.223) WWI -.715** -.711** -.817**

(.127) (.125) (.122) WWII -1.024** -1.071** -1.074** (.157) (.154) (.157) EC .347** .310* (.120) (.127) GATT .460** .273* (.116) (.112) N 3209 3209 3209 R2 .27 .27 .32 Note: Entries are Prais-Winsten regression estimates, with panel corrected standard errors in parentheses. a Results are generated after including country-specific fixed effects. **p < .01; * p < .05. One-tailed tests of statistical significance are conducted for the estimates of GNPi, GNPj, DISTANCE, POPi, POPj, GNPi + GNPj, and RFLAC since their signs are specified by the gravity model. Two-tailed tests are conducted for the remaining estimates.

49