lea schneider matriculation no: 307041 price

125
Lea Schneider Matriculation no: 307041 Price differentiation An empirical analysis of the potential of dynamic pricing strategies

Upload: others

Post on 27-Jan-2022

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Lea Schneider

Matriculation no: 307041

Price differentiation – An empirical analysis

of the potential of dynamic pricing strategies

Lea Schneider Königsberger Str. 1

Matriculation no: 307041 79346 Endingen a. K.

[email protected] Abgabe: 18.04.2016

Price differentiation –

An empirical analysis of the potential of

dynamic pricing strategies

Bachelor dissertation

Presented to gain admission to

Bachelor of Science degree at Pforzheim University

Supervisor: Prof. Dr. Nadine Walter

Second Marker: Prof. Dr. Thomas Cleff

Declaration

I hereby declare that this Bachelor dissertation is all my own work. I have only used the

sources or resources I have explicitly referenced. I have attributed all direct and indirect

quotations.

Berlin, 18.04.2016

Table of Contents

List of abbreviations ....................................................................................................... 1

List of tables and figures ................................................................................................ 1

List of appendices ............................................................................................................ 1

Introduction to the topic ................................................................................................. 2

1.1 Motivation ......................................................................................................... 2

1.2 Objectives and goals ......................................................................................... 2

1.3 Structure ............................................................................................................ 3

2 Definition of price differentiation .......................................................................... 4

2.1 The fundamentals for the definition .................................................................. 4

2.2 Legal definition of price differentiation ............................................................ 6

2.3 Economic definitions ........................................................................................ 7

2.3.1 Economic definition without the consideration for cost differences ............ 7

2.3.2 Economic definition with the consideration of cost differences ................... 8

2.4 A marketing definition ...................................................................................... 9

3 Types of price differentiation............................................................................... 10

4 Requirements for price differentiation ............................................................... 13

5 Effects of price differentiation ............................................................................. 15

6 The concepts behind willingness to pay .............................................................. 15

6.1 The concept of reference prices ...................................................................... 15

6.1.1 Introduction to reference prices .................................................................. 15

6.1.2 Internal reference price ............................................................................... 16

6.1.3 The external and advertised reference price ............................................... 17

6.1.4 Reference prices in different channels ........................................................ 17

6.2 The concept of price fairness .......................................................................... 18

6.2.1 The concepts of equity theory and dual entitlement ................................... 18

6.2.2 Procedural and Distributive Fairness .......................................................... 19

7 The role of the internet ......................................................................................... 20

7.1 Price and cost transparency ............................................................................. 20

7.2 Collection of consumer information ............................................................... 22

8 Dynamic pricing .................................................................................................... 23

8.1 The concept of dynamic pricing ..................................................................... 23

8.2 Dynamic posted prices .................................................................................... 25

8.2.1 Dynamic price updating .............................................................................. 25

8.2.2 Dynamic E-coupons .................................................................................... 26

8.3 Discovery price ............................................................................................... 27

8.3.1 Auctions ...................................................................................................... 27

8.3.2 Reverse Auctions ........................................................................................ 28

8.3.3 Exchanges ................................................................................................... 29

8.4 Bundling .......................................................................................................... 29

9 Hypotheses ............................................................................................................. 30

10 Methodology .......................................................................................................... 37

11 Findings .................................................................................................................. 40

12 Conclusions ............................................................................................................ 70

13 Limitations ............................................................................................................. 71

14 Recommendations for actions .............................................................................. 73

Appendices ..................................................................................................................... 82

Publication bibliography ............................................................................................ 113

1

List of abbreviations

ARP – advertised reference price

B2B – business to business

B2C – business to consumer

ERP – external reference price

IRP – internal reference price

NYOP – Name-Your-Own-Price

USP – unique selling proposition

WOM – word-of-mouth

List of tables and figures

Table 1: Definitions for price discrimination .......................................................... 5

Figure 1: Classifications of dynamic pricing by Kannan and Kopalle ................. 25

List of appendices

Appendix 1: Thesis Questionnaire......................................................................... 82

Appendix 2: Thesis Fragebogen ............................................................................ 84

Appendix 3: Interview Daniel Korany .................................................................. 86

Appendix 4: Interview Norbert Weisshaar ............................................................ 89

Appendix 5: Interview Jochen Gönsch .................................................................. 92

Appendix 6: Interview Werner Tauss .................................................................... 97

Appendix 7: Interview Tim Brzoska ................................................................... 100

Appendix 8: Interview Irene van der Wal ........................................................... 103

Appendix 9: Interview José Francisco Guzmán Tanikawa ................................. 105

Appendix 10: Interview Wolfgang Sessler .......................................................... 110

2

Introduction to the topic

1.1 Motivation

Pricing is the biggest profit lever. A one percent increase in price leads to more

than eleven percent increase in profit. This also holds true the other way around: a

one percent decrease will cause high profit losses (Marn & Rosiello, 1992, p. 84).

Even though companies should invest in better pricing schemes, pricing from a

marketing viewpoint is still a vastly underestimated business topic. Most of

today’s companies have not yet mastered the importance and complexity of the

price effect and subsequently miss out on important profits. Other companies

already understand the interaction of consumer and product. They are able to

adapt and apply their knowledge to improve their strategies.

The early 21st century is shaped by technological advances which have greatly

influenced the way to conduct business. Clearly, both companies and consumers

have more possibilities to connect with marketplaces and gather knowledge on

products and services. Bringing the topics of pricing and internet together holds a

lot of potential. It is not a new idea to price differentiate. Marketers have long

understood that charging different prices to different customers helps to increase

profits. Although this pricing technique has existed for such a long time, changes

in the way consumers behave in the purchase situation and the possibilities arising

with technological advances bring to question what possibilities for price

differentiation lie ahead.

With this background in mind, the motivation of this thesis is to take a look into

today’s price discrimination and discover new opportunities to implement this

kind of pricing strategy by using the advantages of better and faster technology.

1.2 Objectives and goals

The leading question for this thesis is based on how companies should implement

price differentiation. The focus on dynamic pricing techniques tries to combine

the traditional logic of price differentiation with current technological advances.

The goal is to offer a thorough analysis on how and why price differentiation

works and how dynamic pricing strategies can be included in companies. The

3

focus is to give tangible recommendations to facilitate the implementation of

related strategies.

Several questions lead toward the objective:

How does price differentiation work?

What are the boundaries of price differentiation, considering the

consumers notion?

How do companies need to use the internet to take advantage of pricing

opportunities and avoid drawbacks?

How important is dynamic pricing?

Is dynamic pricing applicable to any company, product or service?

By answering these questions throughout the theoretical analysis and the expert

interviews, this thesis will lead over to practical recommendations. Those can be

accomplished with the specific results from the interviews and knowledge from

other marketing fields, which should be considered in setting up a price setting

process.

Finally, paving the way for the use of dynamic pricing as a regular price

differentiation scheme is one of the ideal outcomes of this thesis.

1.3 Structure

This thesis consists of a theoretical research part and an empirical study with

expert interviews.

The theory aims at giving an understanding about the idea of price differentiation

as one very commonly used pricing technique. It will give a clear picture of the

aspects of price differentiation and the requirements on how it can be

implemented. A single chapter on the economic effects of price differentiation

will give insights into the profitability of the respective types of differentiation.

Since the matching price of a product refers to the consumer alone, further

chapters of this thesis will shed light on psychological aspects of reference prices

and the underlying concept of fairness. Understanding these concepts is one key

in finding the right pricing strategy for any company. Continuing on, the next part

of the thesis will discuss dynamic pricing strategies in detail. The emphasis on this

4

part is to present the existing types of dynamic pricing strategies and their

applications.

Following the theoretical frame, several hypotheses will lead over to the empirical

part of this bachelor thesis. One aim of the hypotheses is to secure the findings

from research. More importantly, the hypotheses are supposed to create a

transition into the practical application of these strategies and their business value.

Any real-life examples add transparency to the applicability of dynamic pricing

and help to endorse the recommendations, which will complete this thesis. These

recommendations give direct aid to marketers at different stages of the strategic

pricing process.

2 Definition of price differentiation

2.1 The fundamentals for the definition

Since the first mentioning of modern price discrimination by Pigou (1920), there

have been new approaches and empirical researches in various directions,

especially concerning the exact definition of price discrimination. Many authors

agree to the aspects “the more one thinks about price discrimination, the harder it

is to define” (Phlips, 1983, p. 5) and “it is difficult to offer an all-encompassing

definition” (Tirole, 1988, p. 134).

Primarily, taking a closer look at the general meaning of the term discrimination

provides a first indication to the possible characterization of price discrimination.

One general approach for a definition points out “direct discrimination shall be

taken to occur when a person is treated less favourably than another person would

be” (Federal Anti-Discrimination Agency, 2006).

Taking into account this definition in combination with pricing, it can be derived

that price discrimination suggests unfavourable behaviour in pricing strategies. On

this basis, Table 1 shows the different existing definitions of price discrimination

in thematic and chronological order, which will be analysed and compared in

order to conclude the fundamentals of this thesis.

5

Table 1: Definitions for price discrimination

Author Definition Main

Characteristics

Robinson Patman

Act

(1936)

“It shall be unlawful […] to

discriminate in price between

different purchasers of

commodities of like grade and

quality […].

[…] only due allowance for

differences in the cost of

manufacture, sale, or delivery

resulting from the differing

methods or quantities […].”

Legal definition,

different focus as

the economic

definitions

Machlup

(1955, p. 397)

“Price discrimination is […] the

practice of a firm selling a

homogeneous commodity at the

same time to different purchasers

at different prices.”

No cost

consideration;

homogeneous

products with

slight differences

Robinson

(1969, p. 179)

“the act of selling the same article

produced under a single control,

at different prices to different

buyers”

No cost

consideration,

identical products

Bloomsbury

Business &

Management

Dictionary

(2007, p. 5859)

“The practice of selling the same

product to different buyers at

different prices.”

No cost

consideration,

identical products

Landsburg

(2010, p. 334)

“Charging different prices for

identical items.”

No cost

consideration,

identical products

6

Nicholson/Snyder

(2010, p. 355)

“Selling identical units of output

at different prices.”

No cost

consideration,

identical products

Masterson/Pickton

(2010, p. 375)

“Price discriminators charge

different prices for the same

products to different market

segments.”

No cost

consideration,

focus on market

segments

Elegido

(2011, p. 633)

“Price discrimination is the

practice of charging different

customers different prices for the

same product.”

No cost

consideration,

identical products

Stigler

(1987, p. 210)

“by defining discrimination as the

sale of two or more similar goods

at prices that are in different ratios

to marginal cost”

Marginal cost

differences matter

Shepherd/Shepherd

(2004, p. 205)

“If the ratios of price to cost are

different among buyer, then it is

price discrimination.”

Cost differences

matter

Miller

(2012, p. 544)

“Selling a given product at more

than one price, with the price

difference being unrelated to

differences in marginal cost.”

Marginal cost

differences matter

McConnell et al.

(2012, p. 207)

“The practice of selling a specific

product at more than one price

when the price differences are not

justified by cost differences.”

Cost differences

matter

Source: Own selected depiction of cited authors

2.2 Legal definition of price differentiation

The legal definition of the Robinson-Patman-Act is exclusively dealing with price

differences. It takes no interest in the relation to cost differences, stressing its

main concern: stating that price discrimination reduces competition. Furthermore,

the legal definition focuses on companies in direct competition with each other

7

and does often not regard geographical discrimination. When products are of alike

grade or quality and a definite disturbance of competition with the outcome of a

monopoly can be determined, price discrimination takes place. Under certain

circumstances the law allows price discrimination to prevail, for instance when

price differences are necessary to meet competition. To conclude, the legal

definition of price discriminatory practices may strongly vary from the economic

standpoint (Schneidau & Knutson, 1969, p. 1144).

2.3 Economic definitions

2.3.1 Economic definition without the consideration for cost differences

The ultimate basic definition for price discrimination goes back to various authors

with slightly altered phrasing but the same components: Elegido (2011, p. 633),

Landsburg (2010, p. 334), Nicholson and Snyder (2010, p. 355) as well as the

dictionary definition (Bloomsbury Business Library,, 2007, p. 5859). All these

authors state price discrimination to be the practice of selling the same good to

different customers at different prices. Machlup (1955, p. 397), using the same

basic definition, implies that price discrimination does not only work with

identical commodities but rather with homogeneous ones, which differ slightly

from each other. In fact, he determines homogeneous commodities being in fact

essential for certain types of price discrimination (Machlup, 1955, p. 397). By

adding this specificity to his definition, the former restriction of the term “same”

is being evaded. Machlup goes into more detail by determining the meaning and

implications of each term in his definition, which most other researchers have

neglected to do. Some might be neglecting detail due to a different focus in their

work, where such a detailed definition is not a necessity. Meanwhile, Philips

(1983, pp. 5–7) and Tirole (1988, p. 3) confirm the former distinction of Machlup

by determining that discrimination can take place with differentiated products as a

way to segment customers according to their preference for different attributes of

the same basic commodity.

Although this definitional attempt at first glance seems logical and to provide the

necessary details to understand price discrimination, several economists have

uttered criticism about this definition. They argue that this definition leads to

8

mischaracterizations of price discriminatory techniques, where some pricing

techniques might be mistaken as discriminatory, although differences in prices

could actually be the result of cost differences. Milgrom (1987, p. 365) argues,

that the traditional definition is indeed too broad in terms of categorizing price

discrimination.

2.3.2 Economic definition with the consideration of cost differences

In order to avoid those misinterpretations, the theoretical scope has been increased

by adding the factor of cost differences. Consequently, economists define price

discrimination to exist when differences in price cannot be explained by

differences in costs – more specifically differences in marginal costs (Stigler,

1987, p. 210; Shepherd & Shepherd, 2004, p. 205; Miller, 2012, p. 544;

McConnell et al., 2012, p. 207). These economists also argue that once a price

difference cannot be explained by existing cost-differences, the price is

discriminatory. Philips (1983, p. 6) claims that price discrimination exists as long

as price-cost margins are unequal for differentiated products. In this case absolute

differences between price and marginal costs are studied. On the other hand,

Stigler (1987, p. 4) proposes an analysis based on price-cost mark-ups. This way,

relative cost differences in the ratios between prices and costs for several products

are considered. Clerides (2004, p. 403) suggests the choice of interpretation as

critical, since one definition might indicate price discrimination while the other

does not. Furthermore, the margin definition is more likely to indicate price

discrimination, so both methods hold potential for error.

Even though this classification minimizes the problems of the first definition, it

still does not convey sufficient information on the unspecified details like the

actual similarity of the commodities. Clerides states that “in fact there is no single,

widely accepted definition of price discrimination” (Clerides, 2004, p. 402). Still,

this second classification is most accurate for the economical perspective and

offers marketers a specific framework.

9

2.4 A marketing definition

Of the researched definitions, the one most focused on the marketing perspective

is set up by Masterson and Pickton (2010, p. 375). They define price

discrimination as a strategy to “charge different prices for the same product to

different market segments” (Masterson & Pickton, 2010, p. 375). Whereas

economists and law representatives simply determine different people as

recipients of the pricing technique, this definition already indicates how to

determine which kind of consumer should be charged differently. Considering

this, it is more practically oriented. But this definition has its shortcomings. As

discussed before, focusing on identical products narrows the scope of

consideration and ought to be evaded. Instead, using the distinction of

“homogeneous but not necessarily identical commodity”, allows the definition to

grasp a wider array of possible price discriminatory practices. Looking at market

segments alone is another restriction. Thoroughly discussed in the following

chapter, market segments represent only one specific kind or price discrimination

and could therefore falsely narrow the scope. Instead, “based on segmentation

criteria” can be interpreted to hold true for all kinds of price discrimination,

depending on whether the interpretation is more strict or loose. Considering this,

an alternative less confining definition for marketers might be: “Price

discrimination is the practice of charging different prices for a homogeneous, but

not necessarily identical commodity to different customers based on different

segmentation criteria.” For this paper, this is the most useful kind of definition, as

the marketing aspects of price differentiation shall be discussed, with the

knowledge that the economic aspects of this particular pricing technique have to

be thoroughly considered before implementation.

For this paper, the terms price discrimination and price differentiation will be used

interchangeably and will presume the same meaning. This assumption has been

found to not hold true for all other research on the topic, as some authors

differentiate strongly between the different terms, as illustrated by Elegido (2011,

p. 633). In case of this thesis, both terms will be used with the above expressed

definition.

10

Knowing the different definitions of price discrimination helps marketers

understand how price discrimination works, especially when determining

differential pricing and its monetary results. In case of this thesis, keeping in mind

the differences of the definitions helps to better understand their concept and some

implications for marketers. The foremost interest is to gather qualitative

information on the implementation of price discrimination techniques. In this

paper the exact mathematical implications which arise with economic theories can

therefore be ignored.

3 Types of price differentiation

Various categorization methods for price differentiation have been shown in

literature. Arthur Cecil Pigou (1920) has been the first to introduce the

terminology of three degrees of price discrimination, which is a common basic

reference in other literature (Holmes, 1989; Varian, 1992; Dastidar, 2006;

McAfee, 2008).

First-degree price discrimination focuses on catching the individual willingness to

pay of each consumer and represents the perfect price discrimination with

individual prices based on the consumer’s identity. Unlike the other two degrees

of differentiation, real-world applications have been mainly theoretical and

literature on the topic remained scarce (Encaoua & Hollander, 2007, p. 1). Still,

some traditional uses have been discussed by Machlup (1955, pp. 401–403). One

of the functioning applications is bargaining for cheaper prices, which often takes

place in unorganized and imperfect markets and leaves the consumer at the

advantage to use the non-transparency in his favour. Another, rather insignificant

personal discrimination is to charge hand-picked customers a higher price with the

knowledge that they have no interest or incentive to switch. The “size-up-his-

income” discrimination generally makes sense for services provided by lawyers or

doctors. This includes charging higher prices to upper-class customers and

showing generosity towards poorer customers, therefore focusing on providing

service to everyone and using the differences in price-sensitivity to increase

profits (Machlup, 1955, pp. 401–403).

11

In the traditional theory of Pigou (1920), second-degree price discrimination was

an approximation of first-degree price discrimination and rarely functional in

reality (Stole, 2007, p. 2227). Modern research, among others McAfee (2008,

p. 473) and Tirole (1988, p. 135) redefined this degree to include self-selection of

consumers. With this degree of price discrimination, distinct consumer groups

cannot be predicted. Instead, buyers are offered several options on price and

quantity and self-select according to their willingness to pay. By offering different

versions or quantities of a product, customers chose the option they find most

attractive (McAfee, 2008, p. 473). With regards to McAfee (2008, pp. 473–476),

second-degree price discrimination with volume discounts is regularly used, but

specifically vulnerable towards arbitrage as long as the potential reselling prices

are higher than the unit price after discounts. The use of coupons is based on the

individual’s value of time and price sensitivity, which indicates that a good

coupon addresses consumers with a low value of time and high price sensitivity.

Bundling goods together offers a way of indirect price discrimination, which

relies, just like any other form of indirect discrimination, on the price sensitivity

of the consumer and the overall attractiveness of the offer. Performance-based

discrimination is widely used in the electronics industry by offering two different

versions of a product and letting the consumer decide on their preferred price-

performance ratio (McAfee, 2008, pp. 473–476).

Much research and focus has been dedicated to third-degree price discrimination

as the most common type out of the three degrees of price differentiation (Varian,

1992, p. 248). Third-degree price discrimination occurs when companies use

additional information on consumers to charge them different prices, as long as

those prices remain the same for all amounts of units purchased (Dastidar, 2006,

p. 231). Machlup (1955, pp. 403f.) shows the different applications by

distinguishing consumers considering their geographical location, age, sex,

membership and life stage. Further classifications include the loyalty status of the

consumer and the use and purpose of the product. In all cases, third-degree

discrimination relies on the existence of variations in customer groups, especially

to “exploit differences in the ‘squeezability’ of the separate groups” (Machlup,

1955, p. 403).

12

In contrast to the traditional classification by Pigou, Machlup (1955, p. 400) used

a distinction between personal, group and product discrimination to classify the

different ways of price differentiation, with his literature based on former findings

by Cassady (1946; cited by Machlup, 1955, p. 400). With regards to the degrees

of price discrimination, personal discrimination represents the first-degree, group

discrimination involves similar methods to what Pigou defined as the third degree

and product discrimination comprehends the differences that arise with different

product versions respectively what is defined as the second degree of price

discrimination (Machlup, 1955, p. 400). The advantage of this classification is the

obvious relationship the category names share with the characteristics of this

group of price differentiation. Simultaneously, this classification has only been

rarely used and has mostly been mentioned as a comparison to Pigou.

Stole (2007, p. 2227) and McAfee (2008, pp. 468f.) suggest yet another

categorization for the different types of price discrimination. According to their

research, first and third-degree discrimination can be categorized as direct price

discrimination, because companies can directly group customers according to

their different characteristics and charge them differently. Following this logic

path, second-degree price differentiation, where the consumer self-selects his ideal

price level, is called indirect price discrimination. In this case, companies

indirectly offer the discriminatory prices to consumers without influencing which

consumers are taking advantage of the price discrimination (Stole, 2007, p. 2227;

McAfee, 2008, pp. 468f.).

Evidently, all three classifications show a thorough understanding of the topic and

represent the different emphasis and preferences of the respective authors.

Understanding these classifications allows to get an understanding about the

different approaches on the subject and the subjectivity of the research. In this

thesis, understanding these different classifications is another important step

towards the immersion of the issue.

13

4 Requirements for price differentiation

Carroll and Coates (1999, pp. 470f.) but also Varian (1989, p. 599) and Landsburg

(2010, p. 335) agree on three general conditions for a successful implementation

of price differentiation.

First of all, Carroll and Coates assume that companies need to have some market

power to be able to influence the prices paid by the consumer. Market power1 can

stem from advantages in quality, service and other factors to distinguish a

company on the market. Hence, price discrimination can happen in pure

monopolies, monopolistic competition and oligopolies. Since the demand curve in

case of market power has a downward slope, the surplus for consumers’ increases.

Price discrimination offers a way to capture some of that surplus for the company

(Carroll & Coates, 1999, pp. 470f.).

Secondly, the company has to hold control over the sale of the product in order to

limit the options of arbitrage in the market. In a situation of arbitrage, a consumer

who is offered a lower price for a good will purchase a large quantity of that good

and then resell this good to consumers who do not have access to the lower price

of the offer. Perfect arbitrage describes a situation in which the company is forced

to sell all the output at the lowest price when otherwise consumers would resell to

other consumers. Arbitrage causes the company to charge one single price

(McAfee, 2008, pp. 467f.). Only when consumers are unable to move between

different segments, price discrimination is successful (Masterson & Pickton, 2010,

p. 375).

There are several conditions under which arbitrage is difficult or even impossible.

Services often represent an easy way of price differentiation, as they are

perishable and are normally impossible to resell. Moreover, high transportation

costs for goods make arbitrage unfavourable, since the additional costs would

diminish the price difference between the lowest selling price of one consumer

and the higher price offered in resale to another consumer. Furthermore, when

goods are customized and individually produced, the option of resale becomes

1 Market power is defined as “the degree to which a firm exercises influence over the price and

output of a market” (Bannock et al., 1992, p. 274).

14

more difficult. Legal restrictions on resale and thin markets2 put a direct stop on

the options of arbitrage and work in favour for companies. Likewise, special

contracts or warranties that cannot be forwarded plus information and

transparency problems all stop arbitrage from occurring (McAfee, 2008, pp.

467f.).

To avoid conflict with arbitrage, companies should implement certain controls

over the consumers by implementing licensing agreements, reselling prohibitions

or quantity limitations (Carroll & Coates, 1999, p. 471).

Although preventing the risk or arbitrage in offline channels is generally not a big

problem, the increasing possibilities of the internet with resale and price

comparison platforms have a certain impact on the importance of the issue and the

efforts needed to counteract arbitrage (Varian, 1992, p. 241).

The third condition for price discrimination is for consumers to have different

price elasticities in demand3 for a commodity. The degrees of price discrimination

which are applicable to the consumer depend on the extent of information on the

differences of consumers’ willingness to pay. Knowing each individual

willingness to pay will allow a perfect first-degree discrimination. Having enough

information to distinguish two groups of people, one with a high willingness to

pay and the other with a substantially lower willingness to pay, indicates it is ideal

to use second- degree price discrimination and letting each consumer self-select

their choice. Finally, if the company can correlate the differences in elasticities to

certain group characteristics, third-degree price discrimination becomes a

possibility (Carroll & Coates, 1999, p. 471).

Although researchers agree on these requirements for price differentiation, the

effort associated with the implementation of the pricing strategy and the

implications for marketing will be studied in more detail in the empirical analysis

of this thesis.

2 A thin market is a market with few buyers and sellers, where a product is customized or where

there is low demand for the product (McAfee, 2008, p. 468). 3 Price elasticity of demand is “a measure of how much the quantity demanded of a good responds

to a change in the price of the good” (Mankiw, 2008, p. 90).

15

5 Effects of price differentiation

Generally speaking, Carroll and Coates (1999, pp. 471f.) purport how price

discrimination affects distribution and efficiency, although the specific economic

effects depend on the exact types of discrimination and are linked to the available

information. Even so, price discrimination is still a profitable practice to engage

in. The profits result from the consumer surplus collected by having a certain

market power and control over prices. If engaging in first-degree price

discrimination, due to the idea of perfect information on individual customers, the

whole consumer surplus can be collected. As long as prices are equal to or higher

than marginal costs, profits can be generated. For third-degree price

discrimination, not all of the consumer surplus can be extracted, since the

individual willingness to pay is not known and consumers can only be charged in

segments. Economic literature calculates the exact efficiency outcome of third-

degree price differentiation from the slope of the demand and cost curves (Carroll

& Coates, 1999, pp. 471f.).

Economic literature by Schmalensee (1981) and Varian (1985) shows by means of

price-sensitive customers, that price discrimination leads to an increase in welfare

compared to uniform pricing, provided that the output sold increases in

comparison to the uniform price situation (Elegido, 2011, p. 638).

These effects help a company to understand the potential success of a strategy, but

it is at least as important to understand what drives the success or failure of a

strategy. The following part of this thesis will analyse the psychological ideas

behind reference prices and fairness perception.

6 The concepts behind willingness to pay

6.1 The concept of reference prices

6.1.1 Introduction to reference prices

The reference price is defined as “[…] an internal standard against which

observed prices are compared” (Kalyanaram & Winer, 1995, p. 161).

16

It is generally accepted that reference prices are used to judge the purchase price

of a product (Monroe, 1973, p. 76). In traditional microeconomics, a consumer

makes his decision based on actual prices and income. With the concept of

reference prices, decisions are based not only on actual, but also on perceived

prices (Kalyanaram & Winer, 1995, p. 162).

6.1.2 Internal reference price

The internal reference price is based on the individual memory of the consumer

on the perception of prices. For the internal reference price, Briesch et al. (1997,

pp. 202f.) determine three main conceptualizations of how the IRP works. A

majority of researchers (Lattin & Bucklin, 1989, p. 300; Mayhew & Winer, 1992,

p. 63; Kalyanaram & Little, 1994, p. 415) model reference price with the

assumption of consumers remembering past prices, which then influence the

reference price. In this scenario, recent experiences have more importance and

weight than distant ones. Furthermore, the share of past promotions have a direct

effect on the IRP, as continuous promotions lower the reference price for the

consumer to an overall lower level. (Janiszewski & Lichtenstein, 1999, pp. 353–

355).

Advocates of the second concept (Winer, 1986, p. 251; Kalwani et al., 1990,

p. 251) do only take past prices into account, but also consider contextual factors

such as general price trends or the selling frequency of the brand.

Another movement (Hardie et al., 1993, pp. 379f.; Rajendran & Tellis, 1994,

p. 30) argues that consumers are not able to memorize past prices and therefore

use current prices of certain brands at the time of the purchase. On the other hand,

the study of Briesch et al. (1997, p. 213) indicates, that many consumers do in fact

remember past prices quite accurately. Moreover, research proposes that even if

consumers are not able to recall the exact prices, they still have a vague idea

whether the price they are facing is justified (Monroe & Lee, 1999, p. 208).

There is not only single true approach on how to determine internal reference

prices. Different research and different survey outcomes have indicated various

aspects and led to different approaches. Importantly to understand is that

17

consumers use the internal reference price to judge prices of products and services

(Wolk & Spann, p. 15).

6.1.3 The external and advertised reference price

The external reference price is based on observations of stimuli in a purchase

situation, such as prices for products in the same category (Mayhew & Winer,

1992, p. 62). External reference prices can be provided through catalogues, price

lists and other price cues for similar products. The advertised reference price is a

good way for companies to influence the perception of the consumer. In this case,

the advertised reference price is either compared to a former price, the suggested

retail price or to competitors (Biswas & Blair, 1991, pp. 1f.).

The effectiveness to influence a consumer’s internal reference price with

advertisement strongly depends on contextual factors, such as the placement and

size of the price advertisement, the feeling towards the brand and the price

reputation of the company (Biswas & Blair, 1991, p. 2).

The advertised reference price has proven to be especially effective in offline

channels. Indeed, for posted prices, the ARP has shown to decrease external

search costs and increase the buying intentions. Furthermore, the authors argue

that the ARP in a situation of an auction might even decrease purchase intention

because online channels have increased the amount of price information available.

Consequently, the IRP and ERP are much more influential factors (Wolk &

Spann, p. 16). The theory of reference prices does in fact have value when

estimating consumer demand. It is an important tool in order to set price

discriminatory techniques since the segmentation for differentiated pricing is

solely based on the willingness to pay of the consumer (Monroe & Lee, 1999,

p. 208).

6.1.4 Reference prices in different channels

The rise of the internet has created three types of retailers: pure offline retailers,

pure online retailers and those using both channels. The reference price for

different channels vary, seeing as many consumers expect lower prices on the

internet (Zettelmeyer, 2000, p. 304). This is the result of the belief, that overhead

18

costs4 of online retailers are lower and these should lead to accordingly lower

prices for the end-consumer (Hardesty & Suter, 2005). This is consistent with

studies showing that pure Internet e-tailers indeed offer lower prices than offline

retailers or multichannel retailers, who use both traditional and online retailing

(Brynjolfsson & Smith, 2000, pp. 564f.; Tang & Xing, 2001, p. 329).

This chapter helps to understand how reference prices are developed. The

following chapter about the concept of price fairness will give an indication about

what happens when a discrepancy between the expected price and the real price

exists.

6.2 The concept of price fairness

6.2.1 The concepts of equity theory and dual entitlement

Price fairness can be defined as “a consumer’s assessment and associated

emotions of whether the difference between a seller’s price and the price of a

comparative other party is reasonable, acceptable, or justifiable” (Xia et al., 2004,

p. 3). According to equity theory (Adams, 1965, p. 280), people are comparing

their contributions with the outcome of an exchange. They are not concerned with

the absolute level of prices, but the fairness of an outcome in comparison to the

outcome for other people. If a purchase situation is unfair, dissatisfaction ensues

and the consumer will try to restore equity by changing or ending the exchange

(Cox, 2001, p. 266).

Dual entitlement builds on equity theory and suggests that fairness perceptions

rely on the belief of consumers that they are entitled to a reference price and

companies to a reference profit respectively (Kahneman et al., 1986, p. 729).

Notably, the entitlement of the seller has precedence over the buyer in case of a

conflict. Accordingly, buyers understand, that higher costs can be passed on by

increased prices (Vaidyanathan & Aggarwal, 2003, p. 454). According to Bolton

et al. (2003, p. 474), giving cost information may help to weaken the effects of

price increases. Still, consumers do not always take into account all cost factors or

4 Overhead costs, also called indirect costs are part of different cost objectives but cannot be tied to

any single one directly, for example administrative costs (Synder & Davenport, 1997, p. 159).

19

give less weight to certain factors by underestimating their cost effect (Bolton et

al., 2003, p. 474).

When these findings are combined with the research from reference prices, it hints

at the fact that fairness also differs between channels and that companies have to

take specific care of each of their channels.

6.2.2 Procedural and Distributive Fairness

Procedural fairness is based on the company’s price setting process and

distributive fairness is focused the outcome of this process, the actual price the

consumer has to pay (Maxwell, 2008, pp. 74f.).

Campbell (1999, p. 188) proposes that a company’s’ motive for a price strategy as

well as their prior reputation does have influence on the perception of price

fairness. Research states that consumers sometimes predict companies behaviour

based on their past motives. A good reputation will increase the likelihood of a

positive association and positive motives, which then also has an effect on how

the consumer evaluates a firms pricing strategy (Campbell, 1999, p. 188). By

building goodwill, a company earns lenience in their actions. A lack of positive

reputation and goodwill leads to mistrust (Shapiro, 1983, pp. 659f.). If prices are

perceived as unfair by the consumer, possible reactions have been found in

customer dissatisfaction, discarded purchase intentions as well as negative word-

of-mouth (Huppertz et al., 1978; Campbell, 1999). When facing large inequalities

and unfairness, buyers might even be tempted to cope with the situation by

seeking monetary compensation, although that depends on the efforts involved

and the likelihood of success (Xia et al., 2004, p. 7).

One way to circumvent the negative reactions is using yield management, which

uses seemingly similar products that differ by additional benefits or restrictions.

Consequently, product differentiation helps avoid unfairness perceptions. In the

case of price discrimination, different researchers have studied various situations

(Xia et al., 2004, p. 8).

Generally, when comparing uniform and differential pricing, customers perceive

differential pricing as unfair and uniform prices as fair. Research by Huang et al.

20

(2005, pp. 355–360) suggests that random price discrimination is perceived as

unfair by the majority of the respondents. Furthermore, geographic discrimination

as well as charging differently between existing and new customers was perceived

as highly unfair. Generally, paying the same price in online channels as in offline

channels is considered unfair, since customers – as established before – assume

costs to be lower in online channel and expect a matching lower price. On the

other hand, research suggest that pricing models like auctions, group-buying

discounts and the Priceline model5 are accepted by the consumer (Huang et al.,

2005, pp. 355–360).

This chapter was supposed to help understand what influences fairness. Knowing

the psychological aspects beneath customer behavior is essential when thinking

about pricing strategies. Accordingly, this part of the thesis is very important in

order to target customers with particular pricing strategies and the corresponding

marketing strategies.

7 The role of the internet

7.1 Price and cost transparency

Advances in technology such as increased data storage and the ability to share

information across user networks is destined to have an effect on consumer

behaviour. Garbarino and Lee agree that “information flows more freely on the

internet than traditional environments” (Garbarino & Lee, 2003, p. 497). The

result of the growth in technology and its importance are electronic marketplaces6,

which help to bring together buyers and sellers and increase the efficiency of

information distribution (Bakos, 1997, p. 1678).

Search costs7 are lower in online channels (Granados et al., 2006, p. 149) for both

price and non-price attributes (Degeratu et al., 2000, p. 56). One of the general

5 A reverse auction platform, where consumers can make a single bid. The focus of this model is

on price-sensitive customers (Kannan & Kopalle, 2001, p. 74) . 6 An electronic marketplace is defined as an “interorganizational information system that allows

the participating buyers and sellers in some market to exchange information about prices and

product offerings” (Bakos, 1997, p. 1676). 7 The common economic definition of search costs is “the costs incurred by the buyer to find an

appropriate seller and purchase the product, which includes opportunity costs of the time spend

searching as well as additional expenditures” (Bakos, 1997, p. 1677).

21

rules of search theory states that decreasing search costs will lead to an increase of

time spend looking for information (Bakos, 1991, p. 297). Consequently, the

options to search the internet for information in the search phase of the purchasing

process are increasingly used by buyers (Henry, 2005, p. 345). Henry argues that

the already existing information overload cannot be processed and that consumers

actually use less information with increasing information complexity (Henry,

2005, pp. 349f.). This is a clear indicator that information overload should be

avoided.

One driver of low search costs are shopbots8, which typically list product

information in comparable tables, allowing the consumer to choose the most

attractive price offerings and being directly redirected to the retailers’ websites

(Smith, 2002, p. 446). By using one of many price comparison websites,

consumers can easily navigate through a vast amount of products and their

respective prices (Sinha, 2000, p. 44). Every time a cheaper price results from

these comparisons, consumers change their perception of cost and price for a

product, which means that the new external reference price is influencing the

willingness to pay. By gaining new information, buyers are able to actively drive

prices, simply by knowing the costs of a commodity and hence being able to

judge the fairness of a price (Sinha, 2000, p. 44).

In case of high search costs, the benefits of the additional information do not

cover the costs, which will lead to less or even no search during the purchasing

process. In turn, this allows companies to set higher prices because those might be

more easily accepted (Henry, 2005, pp. 349f.).

Logically, the quantity of information available has influence on how useful the

information is. Furthermore, it is also important how the information online is

displayed and how the layout of the information can help or keep a customer from

gaining knowledge (Granados et al., 2010). Even if there is a large amount of

information available online: If this information is not easy to analyse, then

transparency is low. Simple layouts provide the highest transparency and are

preferable to the consumer (Galitz, 2008, p. 50).

8 Shopbots or shopping robots are automated tools which allow to compare and search for price

and product information of online retailers (Smith, 2002, p. 442).

22

7.2 Collection of consumer information

Technological developments have driven the possibilities of new innovative

pricing techniques (Terwiesch et al., p. 339). The seemingly endless amount of

big data9 provides insights on efficiency and new business capabilities. (Fulgoni,

2014, p. 373).

The internet has not only increased price transparency for consumers, but also

facilitated the information flow for sellers. Market transparency can be defined as

“the level of availability and accessibility of information about products and

market prices” (Granados et al., 2008). Information transparency is defined as

“the degree of visibility and accessibility of information” (Zhu, 2002, p. 93). Both

definitions indicate the availability of information about markets, market

participants and products on the internet.

Companies benefit from information on consumer preferences and their price

sensitivity. Traditionally, sellers used zip codes to differentiate consumers. With

the internet, the ability to individually track site visits and activity has increased

(Garbarino & Maxwell, 2010, p. 1066), especially with the continuing

development of processing power and data storage. Especially e-commerce

developments fuel the options to strategise based on market information

(Granados et al., 2010, p. 208). Sellers are increasingly capable of influencing the

information provided to the consumer by revealing, concealing or distorting

market information by strictly following a predetermined transparency strategy

(Granados et al., 2008, p. 730). When companies frequently change their prices

and achieve advanced seller coordination, buyers do have a difficult time

estimating the true price of a product because transparency decreases (Oh &

Lucas, 2006, p. 757).

The internet has brought many opportunities and advantages to companies. The

higher transparency for consumers has a huge impact on pricing. After

researching the basics of how to use price differentiation and its effects, chapters

on reference prices and fairness helped to understand how consumers understand

and judge prices. With the knowledge on internet transparency for both companies

9 “Big data refers to datasets whose size is beyond the ability of typical database software tools to

capture, store, manage, and analyze” (Manyika et al., 2011, p. 1).

23

and consumers, it will be easier to dive into the issue of dynamic pricing, which

combines the idea of price differentiation with the abilities gained from

technology.

8 Dynamic pricing

8.1 The concept of dynamic pricing

Dynamic Pricing is broadly defined as “as the buying and selling of goods and

services in markets where prices are free to adjust in response to supply and

demand conditions at the individual transaction level” (Garbarino & Lee, 2003,

p. 496). Or more practically speaking: “a pricing strategy in which prices change

either over time, across consumers, or across product / service bundles” (Kannan

& Kopalle, 2001, p. 63).

New possibilities of forming markets on the internet, the possibility of adjusting

prices in short amounts of time and the effectiveness in measuring demand and

analysing competitive prices have helped to develop dynamic pricing strategies on

the internet (Jayaraman & Baker, 2003, pp. 470f.). Kannan and Kopalle (2001,

p. 63) state, that the internet has offered new pricing possibilities, although they

mainly refer to the use of existing strategies for new product or service categories.

Here, dynamic posted-prices and the increase of new product categories in online

auctions are part of this development.

Dynamic pricing has proven to be most efficient with products that are either

perishable, time-sensitive or have a depreciating value (Jayaraman & Baker, 2003,

p. 470). The early applications of dynamic pricing have in fact taken place with

products of limited capacity. Often known as revenue or yield management, the

main emphasis with this technique is the allocation of capacity to different

demand segments (Elmaghraby & Keskinocak, 2003, p. 1288). Over time, as

predicted by Kannan and Kopalle (2001, p. 72), dynamic pricing has also been

adopted to other industries.

Certainly, different products and industries require different approaches to

dynamic pricing. Elmaghraby and Keskinocak (2003, pp. 1289f.) have determined

24

three different criteria of the market environment influencing dynamic pricing

strategy. The first criterion is whether or not inventory replenishment is possible.

This determines whether inventory decisions have to be made at the beginning of

the product’s life-cycle or if there is access to additional units during the season.

The second aspect considers if demand is dependent or independent over time.

Demand is independent over time for most necessities and non-durable products.

On the other hand, when the durability of a product is high, price changes matter

because they affect the overall performance more directly, especially when

knowledge structures influence willingness to pay.

The last criterion of this research is about myopic and strategic consumers.

Myopic consumers act irrationally and buy a commodity as soon as the price is

lower than their reference price, without the consideration of future prices. On the

other hand, strategic consumers always consider how prices might develop over

the life-cycle. When companies face this kind of customer, dynamic pricing is

more complex because more aspects and consumer reactions have to be

considered (Elmaghraby & Keskinocak, 2003, pp. 1289f.).

In order to determine the right price for the consumer, a company needs a vast

amount of information at its disposal. Knowing their operating costs and supply,

as well as future demand predictions, the value of the commodity for the

consumer and the resulting willingness to pay helps determine prices, while low

costs for setting and adjusting prices is another reason why dynamic pricing is

even possible (Elmaghraby & Keskinocak, 2003, p. 1287).

The advantage of dynamic pricing enables companies to increase margins and

collect more consumer surplus. Dynamic pricing has become a critical component

for e-commerce, fuelling the growth of new business ideas and electronic

marketplaces (Jayaraman & Baker, 2003, p. 476).

On the other hand, one reason for not pursuing a dynamic pricing strategy is the

fear of consumer backlash and negative publicity (Hinz et al., 2011).

There are several dynamic pricing methods, generally two broad categories can be

determined (Elmaghraby & Keskinocak, 2003): the posted-price and the

discovery-price mechanisms. With a posted price mechanism, the seller offers

25

commodities at a certain fixed price for buyers to take-it-or-leave-it. In price-

discovery mechanisms or auction pricing, buyers have influence on prices via

bidding processes. Kannan and Kopalle add the dimension of bundle pricing,

where consumers self-select a bundle according to their needs and willingness to

pay. In Figure 1, discovery-price is referred to as auction pricing and all three

types of dynamic pricing are displayed.

Figure 1: Classifications of dynamic pricing by Kannan and Kopalle

Source: Kannan & Kopalle, 2001, p. 66

8.2 Dynamic posted prices

8.2.1 Dynamic price updating

Most medium-value consumer goods which are sold at posted prices in offline

channels are also sold at posted prices online. Still, prices are changing much

more frequently online than in conventional channels (Kannan & Kopalle, 2001,

p. 64). The information efficiency of the internet drives down menu costs10 and

fast-processing of consumer data allows companies to dynamically change posted

prices, often at least once a day (Kannan & Kopalle, 2001, p. 64), sometimes once

an hour or even more often (Elmaghraby & Keskinocak, 2003, p. 288).

In the past, posted prices were static and rarely changed, often only over the

course of weeks or months. With dynamic posted-prices, companies change prices

over time according to information on demand, supply and time of sale. They can

price discriminate, especially consumers purchasing in infrequent patterns, who

10 All costs associated with a change in price (Levy et al., 1997, p. 791)

26

are often not aware that they are being price discriminated (Kannan & Kopalle,

2001, p. 71). Posted prices are the most practical pricing strategy for large

quantities of consumer goods, as the transaction process is very fast. Indeed, many

transactions can be fulfilled in short amounts of time (Kannan & Kopalle, 2001,

p. 68).

8.2.2 Dynamic E-coupons

According to Kannan and Kopalle (2001, p. 66), another opportunity arising with

the internet development is the possibility to target promotions individually, using

mass customization in form of dynamic coupons. Dynamic coupons are electronic

coupons who have different values across time and customer characteristics.

Although posted prices stay the same, each customer pays a different price

according to the individual coupons they receive. Depending on their browsing

behaviour and engagement, consumers can receive coupons of varying values.

Dynamic coupons can be set up to reach the right consumer at the right time

(Kannan & Kopalle, 2001, p. 65).

The concept of dynamic coupons can be related to the concept of personalisation

(Wierich & Zielke, 2014, p. 702). The impact of personalisation is based on the

self-reference effect, which indicates that addressing a person’s self-concept

increases their ability of information processing (Burnkrant & Unnava, 1995,

p. 17). Studies have also shown that personalisation generates positive emotions

towards the stimulus (Debevec & Romeo, 1992, p. 97). This indicates that

dynamic coupons can have a potentially higher redemption rate than traditional

coupons.

One of many ways to target consumers at differently effective prices is price

matching. When using this approach, the e-tailer provides a consumer with the

option to price-compare and the subsequent promise to match the lowest price

being offered anywhere else. Only consumers who chose to take advantage of the

price-comparison have the opportunity to decrease the price, similarly to

consumers who chose to use traditional coupons (Kannan & Kopalle, 2001, p. 65).

27

While posted prices give the consumer some chance to influence the price by

using coupons or buying a product when the price is at its lowest, discovery-price

mechanisms are mainly steered by the consumer himself.

8.3 Discovery price

8.3.1 Auctions

Auctions comprise the second part of dynamic pricing strategies. They are a

common approach used on the internet, where sellers have access to a large

amount of buyers. In B2B markets, auctions are a common practice. On the other

hand, they are mainly used in B2C markets to sell collectibles, rare items and used

merchandise (Kannan & Kopalle, 2001, p. 66). For common products, auctions

are often not pursued, seeing as the cost of participating in that kind of auction

often exceed the expected savings (Jayaraman & Baker, 2003, p. 473). With the

big uncertainties about auction type, duration and bidding tactics, there are many

questions remaining for the optimal method of auctions.

One of the most important decisions of the seller is to set a minimum threshold

price for the auction (Sinha & Greenleaf, 2000, p. 245), which holds as a

reference price for bidders and gives an indication for the value of the product

(Chernev, 2003, p. 51). Sinha and Greenleaf (2000, p. 245) discuss the specific

strategies for sellers depending on the rules of the auction model.

An often used auction model is the open English auction, where bidders raise each

other’s bid until only the highest one is left. In theory, even the smallest of price

increases are allowed, but most practices, especially online auctions, have

established a certain minimum increase of the bid (Sinha & Greenleaf, 2000,

p. 245). Other auction types are the Dutch auction11, the first-price sealed-bid

11 In the Dutch auction, the auctioneer calls offers in descending order; auction ends when a buyer

accepts one of the price offers (Vickrey, 1961, p. 14).

28

auction12 and the Vickrey auction13, but those are not as relevant for the internet

background.

8.3.2 Reverse Auctions

In reverse auctions, commonly known as Name-Your-Own-Price models, a

consumer places a bid on a commodity according to his willingness to pay. If the

bid exceeds the unrevealed price threshold of the buyer, the bid is accepted and

the product is sold at the price of the bid. With limited supply, the first to bid

above the threshold receives the product (Spann & Tellis, 2006, p. 65). Literature

by Spann and Tellis (2006) distinguishes between two classical types of reverse

auctions. Some platforms14 restrict consumers from making more than one bid,

however others allow repeated bidding, therefore giving the consumer a change to

adjust to the invisible threshold. Though the restriction from more than one bid

eliminates the consumers’ possibility to bidding up to the threshold price, which

would eliminate potential profits, it also means that the company might lose

revenue if a consumer might be willing to pay more but is not able to place a

higher bid (Spann et al., 2004).

Unlike classical auctions, a Name-Your-Own-Price company faces consumers

irregularly and has to decide on the acceptance of a bid without observing all

possible bids (Fay, 2004, p. 407). Compared to other pricing strategies, the buyer

in an auction does not have any specific reference point of the price. Since NYOP

strategies are mainly used to sell commodities with no apparent product scarcity,

the consumers do not bid against each other as in normal auctions but against the

sellers’ threshold prices. Furthermore, compared to classical auctions which often

involve scarce products, buyers are not depending on reverse auctions and have

the option of purchasing the product elsewhere (Chernev, 2003, p. 51).

12 In this auction form, the sealed bids are submitted, with the highest bid receiving the object

while paying the amount of this bid (Maskin & Riley, 1984, p. 1482). 13 The Vickrey auctions also works with sealed bids, but instead of his own bid, the highest bidder

has to pay the price submitted by the second-highest bid (Milgrom & Weber, 1982, p. 1090). 14 An example would be Priceline, which only allows for one bid, which is in turn binding if

accepted. Priceline gives pointers indicating the chances of winning the bid at three to four

different price levels (Kannan & Kopalle, 2001).

29

When consumers are able to select their own prices, they are more flexible to

express their willingness to pay than in a scenario with set prices, as they have

unlimited options of suggesting a price instead of just accepting the restriction of

a given price (Chernev, 2003, p. 52). This suggests that generally speaking, a

NYOP strategy is more desirable than an established price situation. Yet, Chernev

(2003, p. 52) also argues that ultimately, the preference of one strategy over the

other depends on the specific context of the situation and whether or not the

bidder has a predetermined reference price and clear expectations. If a reference

price is not available, a reverse auction is more likely to be associated with

uncertainty and risk, which often makes it inferior compared to a posted price.

8.3.3 Exchanges

Exchanges are transactions of goods or services between several buyers and

sellers. They connect buyers and sellers in real-time without being expensive. The

link is established by middlemen that charge a commission or fee for their service

of linking people based on their market knowledge. Exchanges work for a variety

of different industries, but the low entry costs and potential profits have caused an

oversupply. Products sold on exchanges are typically sold and bought in large or

smaller quantities with great time specificity (Jayaraman & Baker, 2003, p. 473).

8.4 Bundling

A bundling strategy involves the collection of goods into a package and selling

them at a discounted bundle price (Bitran & Ferrer, p. 93). There are two types of

variations in bundles. The first type of bundle offers a larger amount of a single

item with a quantity discount. The second type of bundle is when a single good is

included in a bundle with other goods, where the price of the bundle depends on

the specific bundle (Kannan & Kopalle, 2001, p. 67).

The first type of bundle is typically priced lower than the single components, but

the second type of bundles can sometimes be priced higher than the single

components in combination. This may occur with “complementary bundles”,

which is a pre-designed combination designed to operate together. This happens

with products who need complementary products to work. By forming a bundle,

30

the consumer avoids additional efforts in putting together the different single

components (Heeler et al., 2007, p. 493). Research also indicates, that bundle

offers increase purchases, because consumers assume a good bargain and higher

convenience and are indeed more likely to purchase the bundle than the individual

goods (Nguyen et al., 2009, p. 224).

After compiling all relevant information of price differentiation and in particular

all available dynamic pricing strategies, it is time to pursue the next part of this

thesis’ objective. The following hypotheses are based on the theoretical research

but intent to apply the topics into a more practical setting. Especially discussions

on controversial hypotheses and examples will enrich the empirical part. In turn,

the results from the expert interviews will be used to formulate detailed

recommendations on how to use price differentiation.

9 Hypotheses

In order to create an empirical part for this bachelor thesis, the collected theory

was used to induce several hypotheses. These hypotheses aim to substantiate the

theoretical implications of price differentiation in light of business practices and

various products and services, which have been known to be associated to this

pricing technique.

H1: The internet offers new ways of price discrimination.

The first hypothesis is destined to create access to the topic of the bachelor thesis

for the interview participants. It is a basic hypothesis, which will create a base for

the further investigation of the topic and convey a first impression on the

knowledge and emphasis of the different interviewees. Meanwhile, it also

connects the broad topic of price discrimination in relation to the internet, which

will then be further explored.

31

H2: Consumer reference prices differ between offline and online channels.

Going more into detail of one of the aspects regarding price discrimination, this

hypothesis is based on the theoretical assumption that prices should be lower in

online channels than they are in offline channels. Since the theory shows some

ambiguity concerning this assumption, the interview experts are expected to

deliver their opinion on whether or not this holds truth in reality.

H3: Consumer reference prices differ between cultures and countries.

Another assumption concerning reference prices is the difference between price

expectations of different cultures and countries, which has been indirectly

mentioned in the theoretical research. Although literature mainly refers to

differences in actual prices, the idea can also be transferred to reference prices.

This hypothesis is important, since markets are becoming more and more

integrated and companies increasingly operate on a global level, where differences

in cultures do affect all kinds of marketing activities.

H4: With more online transparency people spend more time looking for price

information.

All literature agrees that transparency has increased with the help of internet

technologies. At the same time, studies have revealed very different results on

whether or not the increased transparency leads to an actual increase in search. Of

course, at least being able to estimate the ramifications of transparency gives an

indication for marketers on how to handle the transparency and its results.

Collecting the expert opinions on this hypothesis will allow more specific

recommendations to the marketing practice.

H5: More transparency influences perception of fairness for the consumer.

The perception of fairness is driven by comparing the price and its mechanism

with that for other consumers. Since more transparency facilitates the search for

32

information and the ability to compare, logical conclusion suggests that internet

transparency of costs and prices influences the consumer’s perception the fairness

of a price. By adding this hypothesis to the expert interview, the applicability of

this statement will be tested with regards to different industries and practices.

H6: Price and cost transparency have direct influence on the willingness to pay.

Similarly as in the hypothesis before, willingness to pay - or the reference price -

is also part of the equation with transparency and price fairness. Again, knowing

the structure of costs and prices through increased transparency is allowing the

consumer a better judgement of realistic prices. Accordingly, it can be assumed

that transparency is influencing the development and formulation of both external

and internal reference prices, which ultimately results in willingness to pay.

Verifying this hypothesis allows the better understanding of other influential

factors and how these factors can be positively influenced.

H7: For companies the main advantages of internet transparency are new pricing

possibilities with regards to more specific segmentation and a better

understanding of the consumer with new possibilities of market research and data

collection.

With this hypothesis, the focus moves to the company side, trying to distinguish

how they benefit from increased market and information transparency. As

research shows, technological advances have created new chances for pricing and

access to a large amount of information. While this is endorsed by the theory, the

main aim of this hypothesis is to confirm the theory and find other advantages for

companies that have not been discussed in the summary of the theoretical

background.

33

H8: The main disadvantages are increased transparency of costs and prices plus

the danger of arbitrage.

Focusing on the disadvantages of transparency, deduction from the theory

concedes the formulation of this hypothesis. Although companies have the ability

to collect more information, consumers also have more knowledge, which leads to

increased competition. Exclusion of arbitrage has often been stated in the theory

as one of the requirements for price discrimination. It is also the sole requirement

most affected by the advance of technologies, although a logical assumption

would be to see the danger of arbitrage as one of the main disadvantages. As this

has been mainly derived from a combination of different theoretical aspects and

has no actual literature as backup, the answers for this hypothesis will potentially

diverge in each expert interview. Only by knowing the disadvantages of

transparency for companies can solutions be found to improve those conditions.

H9: For companies the advantages gained from increased transparency are more

substantial than the disadvantages.

Through working on the theoretical part of this bachelor thesis, the advantages

gained from transparency are assumed to be of higher substance than

disadvantages. Reviewing this hypothesis sums up this set of questions and

possibly confirms the usefulness of the internet advance, which then can be used

to show companies how to improve their strategies regarding their online presence

and use.

H10: The internet has increased the risks and options of arbitrage.

As discussed in theory, the internet connects markets and increases the

interactions between buyers and sellers. Differences in prices can be exploited by

reselling via online channels. Since prohibiting arbitrage has been found to be one

of the requirements for price differentiation, it is important to collect opinions on

the actual danger of arbitrage through technological advances and possible

solutions to improve a companies’ position.

34

H11: For international PD, arbitrage costs are decreasing because of easier

access to markets, decreasing transportation costs and free trade zones.

Arbitrage is anticipated to have become easier in recent years, because markets

are connected through trade zones and lower transportation costs and generally

easier access to globally scattered markets. These developments lead to the

assumption that arbitrage costs are decreasing for resellers, so the benefits

increase and arbitrage might generally be more attractive. Analysing the results

for this hypothesis could help with the risk assessment for arbitrage and determine

which companies and products are particularly vulnerable. From this risk

assessment, strategies to conquer arbitrage might be a further result from this

empirical analysis.

H12: Dynamic Pricing is more accepted with perishable goods and services

compared to non-perishable categories.

Dynamic pricing in literature is mainly researched in the areas of perishable

products and services or in cases where supply is limited. This is conclusive in all

theoretical approaches, since price differences for perishable commodities and

services are evident. The key to acceptance is explaining and understanding the

reasons behind the strategy. It seems quite obvious that this works better when

something is perishable, inseparable, intangible or lacks homogeneity. This

hypothesis might also shed some light on other categories with effectively

dynamic pricing.

H13: Dynamic pricing can only be realized on the internet as costs of

implementation are too high in offline channels.

The costs of changing a price includes the physical work of actually changing the

price plus the costs of making a pricing strategy. The costs of formulating a

strategy normally not necessarily change in between channels, implementing the

price does indeed show differences in prices, as offline channels need more

35

personnel and time to actually change each physically existing product price.

Online channels just use software to quickly change pricing schemes. The

difference concerning the costs are assumed to be substantial. Charging dynamic

prices based on time of purchase and consumer characteristics does simply not

seem beneficial in offline channels. By checking this specific hypothesis, the

theory of prices in different channels and the concrete application for dynamic

pricing strategies becomes more obvious.

H14: Dynamic Pricing is considered an unfair pricing technique and will cause

the consumer to stray from the brand.

Considering the thoroughly discussed topic of fairness in relation to dynamic

pricing, the indications gathered from fairness theory indicate that price

differences not explained by cost differences are often considered unfair. Some

pricing strategies, including traditional price differentiation, have indeed been

accepted. But the general idea of discriminatory pricing is not easily accepted by

the consumer. Since this hypothesis is based on the consumers’ view on price

differentiation, theoretical approaches can only go so far. Above all it is helpful to

know the different evaluations of this statement by experts in this certain field, let

alone their long-term experiences with consumer research and their applications

of different strategies.

H15: Name-your-own-price (NYOP) transactions are the easiest way to capture

the consumers’ willingness to pay.

NYOP as one alternative of dynamic pricing techniques is a reverse auction,

where consumers bid without any reference point, solely based on their

willingness to pay or at least their assumption of product value. In comparison to

other dynamic pricing alternatives, the consumers can only rely on their internal

reference price. Furthermore, whereas other dynamic pricing strategies might aim

at individual pricing, NYOP does not require any substantial market research or

consumer knowledge for individual consumers. The hypothesis represents the

36

idea, that this strategy is the easiest way for a company, to skim consumer surplus

and subsequently increase profits.

If this hypothesis is confirmed, it would indicate that many more companies

should adapt this strategy. In any case, a thorough discussion on this hypothesis

will give valuable insights into the different options to capture willingness to pay.

H16: Most consumers don’t take advantage of price discrimination in form of

coupons.

Coupons are part of self-selection second-degree price discrimination. In dynamic

pricing, dynamic coupons have emerged and are used on an increasingly regular

basis. Since many companies are still using traditional coupons, which are

distributed to a large potential customer base, the actual impact of these coupons

is questioned though this hypothesis. Is will be assumed that the large amount of

coupons and the effort associated with selecting the right coupon at the right time

causes many consumers to avoid these efforts and pass on coupons’ benefit.

Whether this means that companies should only use dynamic coupons or no

coupons at all, and whether this hypothesis is even true, will be researched with

the help of the expert interviews.

37

10 Methodology

In order to allow for a practical approach of the intensively discussed theoretical

background, the following part consists of expert interviews. These interviews

aim at discussing and deepening the application of several derived hypotheses.

The empirical part of this thesis consists of expert interviews, which were

preferred over other empirical methods as this is a qualitative and rather

explorative setting, where the recommendations of the topic of price

discrimination and specifically dynamic pricing are desired outcomes. Since this

paper focuses on the possibilities and challenges in this particular pricing area,

conducting expert interviews with different insights into the implementation and

importance of these strategies seemed to lead to the best results.

The objective was to find someone with a theoretical or practical knowledge about

price differentiation and ideally also in dynamic pricing strategies, as those

interviewees were most promising for the thorough analysis of the topic.

In order to find suitable interview partners, contact was made to different

marketing and pricing consultants in Germany, preferably those with a B2C

background, as they fit the criteria for the interview better. Furthermore, contact

was made with professors from German institutions, based on their fields of

expertise and publications in the area of price discrimination, revenue

management and dynamic pricing. Further opportunities arose by using personal

connections through the “Tandem” mentoring program of Pforzheim Business

School, which created the contact to a marketing consultant as well as an

employee of Hewlett Packard, who both were very helpful in gathering qualitative

data. As the only international interview partner, contact was established towards

the partner university TEC de Monterrey, where the professor for our pricing

course in fourth semester was asked to complete the questionnaire.

In total, contact was made with around 35 different potential pricing experts,

although most did not reply to the initial e-mail. Of those who replied, some were

too busy with their working schedules to work out a matching date, while others

were surprisingly flexible in their schedules and had both time and interest in

participating in this bachelors thesis. Some of the interviewees asked to receive

the bachelor thesis upon completion.

38

The expert interviews were conducted with eight different experts in the area of

marketing, pricing, e-commerce and operations research. The idea was to collect

as many different perspectives as possible while asking the same hypotheses and

supporting questions. Expert interviews were chosen as a means to empirically

investigate the topic beyond the theory, as these experts all have experience in

pricing practices and can best determine if and how price differentiation,

especially dynamic pricing in the sense of individual differentiation, can be

applied in different industries and with varying products.

The questions were aimed to answer the several hypotheses, as well as go into

detail on examples, insights and opinions of the respective experts. Together with

the theoretical analysis of the topic, the interview results will be the base for the

recommendation section.

The following interviewees helped to complete this thesis with their

knowledgeable input.

The first interview was with Daniel Korany, who works as a project manager in a

pricing consultancy, mainly focusing on the B2B area. As a former student of the

“International Marketing” programme at Pforzheim University, contact was

established through Professor Walter.

Norbert Weisshaar, a partner of the mentoring program “Tandem” at Pforzheim

University is the mentor of a classmate and a pricing consultant, who also

specializes in price negotiation and sales.

Jochen Gönsch is chair holder for the chair of business administration, particularly

for service operations at Mercator School of Management at the University

Duisburg-Essen. He has several publications on the topic of dynamic pricing and

revenue management with his focus on operations management.

Werner Tauss owns his own consultancy for pricing and yield management. He

shared a lot of his experiences with the pricing of airlines and cruise ships and

offered great examples of how pricing in these industries work.

Tim Brzoska, a pricing consultant at Simon-Kucher & Partners, the world’s

leading consultancy for pricing, works for both B2C and B2B projects. In this

39

interview, due to time constraints, some questions were left out in order to put

focus on the rest of the questions and gain insightful knowledge on those.

Irene van der Wal works as product manager at Hewlett Packard. As a colleague

of the “Tandem” mentor Jeannette Weisschuh, she offered her knowledge on the

pricing topic. With her financial and marketing background, she was a very

knowledgeable candidate for the interview.

José Francisco Guzmán Tanikawa works as a professor at Instituto Tecnológico y

de Estudios Superiores de Monterrey, at Campus Monterrey in Mexico. He was

the pricing professor who initiated my interest for the area of pricing. He is also

the director of marketing at EGADE business school, the graduate school of TEC

de Monterrey. He answered the interview in writing, mainly due to the time zone

differences and his busy schedule.

One interview was conducted personally during an internship at Daimler AG with

the expert on price perception at Mercedes-Benz Vans Wolfgang Sessler. Since

automotive pricing does not include dynamic pricing strategies today, the

interview was not strictly focused on the thesis questionnaire. Instead, Mr Sessler

explained the pricing system of his expertise and only answered some of the given

questions.

Many of the questions were not answered directly enough to draw a strong

conclusion about the opinion. Not wanting to misinterpret the answers, they were

categorized as neutral and will be listed with the affirmations and the refusals in

order to discuss why exactly the opinion was not stated more precisely.

All interviews had a duration of 40 to 60 minutes, depending on the number of

questions asked and the elaborateness of the answers.

40

11 Findings

The internet offers new ways of price discrimination.

This was a very openly stated question to ease into the topic, which led the

interviewees to talk about various aspects of internet pricing. Four out of seven

answers confirmed the hypothesis, while three remained neutral, not showing a

clear tendency for or against the statement.

Concerning general changes which have derived from technological advances,

“the internet offers flexible possibilities to show offers”15, which according to Mr

Tauss has great impact on how pricing has to be done. Mr Gönsch gives credit to

new possibilities of individual customization by mentioning that “[…] on the

internet, a product can be freely configured, without the restrictions in a shop

[…].”16 Likewise, Mr Brzoska sees great potential on the internet as “technically

there are more ways to target the consumer, because you have specific

information and it is easier to change prices.”17

Focusing more on the specific changes for pricing, Mr Weisshaar explained, that

“the dominance of the price factor has increased”18, indicating that pricing has

become a more important topic. Likewise, Mr Guzmán agrees that “people can

check prices easily, so markets are more sensible to prices”.

Moving even closer to the main topic of the hypothesis, there has also been

developments for price differentiation with the rise of technological advances.

According to Mr Gönsch, the internet has increased flexibility in many ways:

“Interesting are companies which go towards first degree price discrimination,

with the use of coupons, with which you try to reach individual customers.”19

15 „Im Internet sind die Möglichkeiten viel flexibler, Angebote anzuzeigen.“ (Werner Tauss) 16 „Bei Dienstleistungen kann man über das Internet mehr Konfiguration beim Produkt vornehmen

als im Ladengeschäft, egal welches Produkt denn es braucht nicht die Zeit des Verkäufers.“

(Jochen Gönsch) 17 „Ja, rein technisch gesehen hat man viel mehr Möglichkeiten, den Kunden gezielter

anzusprechen, weil man gezieltere Informationen über den Kunden hat und es technisch besser

funktioniert, Preise zu ändern.“ (Tim Brzoska) 18 „Dominanz des Preises hat zugenommen.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 19 „Interessant sind Unternehmen, die in Werbeaussagen und Pressemeldungen in Richtung ersten

Grades diskriminieren.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

41

With this, he already mentions some aspects for upcoming hypotheses and

demonstrates his expertise on the topic.

He also demonstrates his knowledge by giving examples of particular pricing

mechanisms. Mr Gönsch introduces an example of a pricing strategy which has

evolved through technological advances. He talks about blind booking, a

particular concept for airline pricing: “Blind booking has a fixed price but at the

time of booking, the customer does not know where the journey will go. The more

destinations you delete, the more expensive, but the consumer is able to influence

the outcome to match his needs.”20 This particular example is a great illustration

of second-degree price differentiation, where consumers choose how much

convenience they want and how much they are willing to pay for it.

Although all these statements clearly illustrate the advantages of the internet, the

interviewees have also discovered disadvantages. For one, Mr Brzoska does not

believe that it is as easy to charge different prices in different channels: “It

becomes increasingly difficult to price differentiate between channels.”21At the

same time, he knows that not only has transparency increased for companies, but

more and more “the challenge is higher transparency for consumers.”22

Corresponding to this, Mr Korany explains how “companies have an interest in

having satisfied customers”23 but he also realizes “how consumer have more

power in the purchasing process.”24 With these challenges, companies need to be

smart on how to do their pricing.

Being experts in pricing also lead the experts to give indicators how to act as a

company. For one, Mr Weisshaar is convinced that “sellers have to tell their value

story and have to be smart with the target group.”25 Furthermore, in order to be

able to satisfy customers and use the increased transparency on the internet, Mr

Tauss indicates that “the company has to find out what the consumer wants.

20 „Blind Booking bei Germanwings: Flug buchen aber bei der Buchung ist es unklar, wohin man

fliegt. Je mehr Ziele man ausschließt, desto teurer aber desto klarer beeinflussbar, wohin die Reise

geht.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 21 „Es wird immer schwieriger, Preisdifferenzierung über Kanäle zu betreiben.“ (Tim Brzoska) 22 „Die Herausforderung ist, dass auch mehr Transparenz herrscht.“ (Tim Brzoska) 23 „Unternehmen haben Interesse, Konsumenten zufrieden zu stellen.“ (Daniel Korany) 24 „Die Hauptänderung ist, dass der Konsument einen stärkeren Einfluss hat.“ (Daniel Korany) 25 „Verkäufer müssen ihre Value Story erzählen und in den Zielgruppen intelligenter arbeiten.“

(Norbert Weisshaar)

42

Market research can lead to surprising results.”26 If there were any doubts as to

why companies should invest in this, Mr Weisshaar clearly knows the answer. He

uses a statistic to demonstrate the power of pricing, as “the price lever. With a one

percent price change comes more than twelve percent change in profits.”27

Overall, the experts have shown that the internet has indeed changed the way of

how business and pricing in particular works. Technological advances are

responsible for many new possibilities in the pricing area, but there are also new

challenges und obstacles because the consumer suddenly also has more prospects.

Some more of these particular developments are targeted in the rest of the

hypotheses and will be focused on.

Consumer reference prices differ between offline and online channels.

On the topic of reference prices and their differences between channels, the

experts were not in agreement. In fact, while three did not see differences between

channels, four other experts supported the hypothesis.

Arguing for differences between channels, Mr Brzoska illustrates: “I believe that

the expectation of lower prices online has been established. You expect that. But I

think that the added value online is much higher, because convenience is

higher.”28 Mr Brzoska also has an idea about why prices online are lower than in

traditional offline channels. He states that “online channels could always offer

lower prices because of their cost structure. The companies did not realize the

value of the online channel for the consumer.”29 Since theory has shown that the

internal reference price can be based on past prices, it is not surprising that there

might be differences between channels. After talking about reference prices in

online channels, with the advantage for consumers to quickly compare prices, Mr

Gönsch does not see the same possibilities for offline channels as “offline you

26 „Das Unternehmen muss herausfinden, was der Kunde will. Dabei kann man ganz schöne

Überraschungen in der Marktforschung erleben.“ (Werner Tauss) 27 „Hebel des Preises. 1% Preisänderungen bedeuten 12,5% mehr Erträge.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 28 „Ich glaube schon, dass sich mittlerweile der Gedanke verfestigt hat, dass man es online

günstiger bekommt. Man erwartet das ein bisschen. Obwohl ich glaube, der Mehrwert online ist

größer als in Läden, weil die convenience größer ist.“ (Tim Brzoska) 29 „Online konnte man immer günstiger anbieten, weil sie geringere Kostenstrukturen haben. Die

haben verpasst zu erkennen, dass ihr Kanal mehr Wert für den Kunden darstellt.“ (Tim Brzoska)

43

have more of a feeling what a product should cost, no direct comparison.”30 In the

meantime, Mr Weisshaar offers some substantial reasons as to why prices offline

are expected and accepted to be higher, “because you have the experience; the

nice salesperson who can communicate the price much better.”31 With these

background of offline channels, it makes sense to have differences in reference

prices.

Several of the interviewees believe that these differences in reference prices can

be attributed to the fact that it is much easier to get actual price information

online. First of all, Mr Gönsch points out that “in online channels, you can form a

reference price, which represents the actual price”32. According to Mr Gönsch,

that can be attributed to the fact that “in online channels, you can make price

comparisons quickly“33. In line with this reasoning, Mr Guzmán agrees: “You can

easily have a reference price, just by using another website of a different store or

provider.” Because of how easy price comparison online has become, Mr Korany

established another finding on reference prices: “The ERP has lost some of its

strength. The suggested retail price does not play a big role in online channels,

because you are quick to get other references to judge fairness.”34 While the

theory already dedicated much influence to the internal reference price, this

indicates that it might indeed be more difficult to influence reference prices

online.

Concluding the overall results for this topic, the interviews in most cases

supported the theoretical research on reference prices between channels. Due to

more information online, reference prices are supposedly more accurate and lower

due to the fact that the cost structure online is lower than in traditional offline

channels.

30 „Im Laden hat man eher ein Gefühl was das gut kosten sollte, aber da steckt kein direkter

Preisvergleich dahinter.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 31 „Viele machen keinen Unterschied mehr, aber grundsätzlich höherer Referenzpreis da man das

Erlebnis hat, einen netten Verkäufer, hier kann die Kommunikation zum Preis besser aufgebaut

werden.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 32 „Online hat man eher einen Referenzpreis, der eine reale Preis ist zu dem ich das gut auch

bestellen kann.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 33 „Ja ich glaube als Kunde ist man im online Kanal sehr schnell Vergleichspreise besorgen kann.“

(Jochen Gönsch) 34 „Der ERP hat online ein bisschen an Stärke verloren. Die unverbindliche Preisempfehlung spielt

online weniger eine Rolle, da man schnell andere Referenzen einholen kann um die Fairness zu

beurteilen.“ (Daniel Korany)

44

Consumer reference prices differ between cultures and countries.

With many companies acting on an international level, it becomes more and more

important to know about the difference in behavior and expectations between the

countries. All eight pricing experts answered this questions, six were clearly in

favour of this hypothesis and two more reserved on a neutral standpoint.

First of all, we have the argument in favour of this hypothesis, with Mr Gönsch

stating that, “the actual price is surely different. The goods in the different

markets are objectively also differently priced.”35 While Mr Korany agrees with

the general notion of the text, he also points out that these differences between

countries become smaller. He declares that “prices for a product in different

countries become more similar and so the reference prices become more similar as

well.”36 While he sees some differences between countries, Mr Guzmán remains

sceptical concerning the hypothesis: “I don’t think that the culture by itself could

be significant.” Because Mr Guzmán did not completely deny a relevance, he was

considered in a neutral perspective. Also not completely satisfied with the

wording of the hypothesis is Mr Gönsch, who emphasizes that „surely there are

already differences in a country between different age groups and depending on

the product.”37

After talking about the difference in reference prices, the experts help to

understand what influences reference prices. Mr Tauss gives his opinion on the

main influence on reference prices, which are “definitely the product elements.”38

Meanwhile, Mr Weisshaar finds other factors which influence reference prices:

“Competitors’ behaviour, transparency between channels and to lower one’s

sights in terms of service or availability.”39 These influencing factors are

35 „Grundsätzlich ist der konkrete Preis sehr sicher immer unterschiedlich. Die Sachen sind in

verschiedenen Marlten objektiv auch unterschiedlich teuer.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 36 „Preise werden ähnlicher zwischen verschiedenen Ländern und damit werden auch die

Referenzpreise ähnlicher.“ (Daniel Korany) 37 „Sicher unterscheidet sich auch die Art, wie sich der Referenzpreis bildet, selbst schon innerhalb

eines Landes je nach Alter und Produktgruppe.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 38 „Mit Sicherheit die Produktelemente.” (Werner Tauss) 39 „Wettbewerbsverhalten, Transparenz dass es beim Onlineshop das Produkt günstiger gibt und

Abstriche machen z.B. bei Service oder Verfügbarkeit.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

45

important to understand and it is any company’s responsibility to target these

factors and try to influence them.

Even with all the information on how reference prices vary, Mr Gönsch gives an

example of a situation, where the reference prices wouldn’t influence purchase

behaviour. He claims that “when people are thirsty, they buy something to drink,

even if it is more expensive.”40

With the findings from this hypothesis, it can be concluded that there are some

differences between price levels and reference prices between countries, although

experts might argue that they become smaller with the increase of

internationalisation. Important to know is that these differences between prices

can affect arbitrage and that pricing one product in different countries requires

research on the perception of value in order to price it right.

With more online transparency people spend more time looking for price

information.

The fact that transparency has increased has been established through research.

Whether an increase leads to more search time will now also be assessed by

analysing the opinions of the interviewees. Five of seven experts clearly affirmed

the hypothesis, while two gave answers which could not clearly be assigned as yes

or no.

Going into detail on why this statement holds true, Mr Korany offers an

explanation as to why consumers spend more time looking for information: „The

purchasing process becomes more complicated. There are more options, more

products and different prices. That’s why the consumer needs more time.”41 By

adding the word “complicated”, Mr Korany already indicates which kind of

product needs the most information search. Irene van der Wal agrees: “I do

believe that people spend more time to find a good price for them online, but

mainly for products that do not belong to your daily needs.” In the meantime, Mr

40 „Wenn sie unterwegs sind und Durst haben dann kaufen Sie etwas, auch wenn es teuer ist.“

(Jochen Gönsch)

41 „Die Kaufentscheidung wird schwieriger, Mehr Optionen, mehr Produkte, verschiedene Preise,

deshalb braucht er mehr Zeit.“ (Daniel Korany)

46

Guzmán does not point out the product characteristics, but rather the consumers’

characteristics: “It depends how important the decision it is to you. The

involvement in the decision is crucial in order to know the amount of information

the customer is willing to have.”

Mr Brzoska offers several criteria, which influence the length of the search: “It

strongly depends on the product. There are several dimensions with influence.

How much do I invest, how emotionally involved am I, how important is the

product? How many people are involved in the buying process?”42 All these

questions influence how important the search for information is for the consumer

and how much time and detail he will put into accumulating information. Mr

Guzmán gives specific examples on the differences in search volume. He thinks

that “if you have a low involvement product like a soap, consumers are not

willing to handle a lot of information but for an insurance or a car, they will be.”

Mrs van der Wal adds another potentially important aspect: “Also, exclusivity of a

product can have an influence.”

After learning about these basic criteria for search behavior, Mr Guzmán voices

an interesting opinion about online behaviour as part of a generation issue: “A

millennial will be much more willing to invest time looking on the internet than a

baby boomer.” With his perception of the differences between generations he

indicates an interesting concept, which could ultimately affect how information is

distributed.

Of course, there have also been opposite opinions on the actual transparency of

the internet. Mr Sessler points out the differences with cars, where „the internet

does not offer an objective price comparison, because you will only see list prices,

while all cars get dealer discounts up to thirty percent.”43 Similarly critical is Mrs

van der Wal, who doesn’t think that “pricing online is at all transparent. Prices

changes depend on time or even sometimes on your profile or internet

buying/searching behavior.” It is important to keep in mind that these statement

42 „Das hängt stark von dem Produkt ab. Da gibt es verschiedene Dimensionen, die das

beeinflussen. Wie viel investiere ich, wie stark bin ich emotional involviert – wie wichtig ist das

Produkt. Wie viele Entscheider sind involviert, das beeinflusst die Suche ebenfalls. Es kommt

natürlich auch darauf an, wie oft man ein Produkt kauft.“ (Tim Brzoska) 43 „Internet bietet keinen objektiven Preisvergleich, weil nur Listenpreise vergleichbar sind, dabei

sind alle Preise nachlassbehaftet, bis zu 30%.“ (Wolfgang Sessler)

47

do not criticise the hypothesis itself, but rather doubt the transparency underlying

the increased online search. As such, they should be kept in mind as an indicator

that consumers might not always believe the price information they find online.

Summing up, the experts shed some more light on the theoretical approaches to

the topic by giving differences in generations, customer segments, industries and

the type of product in question. Overall they show support for the hypothesis,

while pointing out some problems and areas for improvement. Still, the results

from the analysis is that it can be said that the internet has offered more ways of

search which are used to find information for certain products and that internet

search has mostly increased. For companies this could indicate that internet

presence is more important than ever and that whatever information is put on the

internet, is also immediately available to potential customers.

More transparency influences perception of fairness for the consumer as

knowledge structures can be built.

The expert interviews have shown that customers most probably spend more time

searching for price information with the increasing possibilities of the internet.

The corresponding transparency allows customers to have a better picture of the

market. How the experts consider this transparency to affect fairness is reflected

in their answers. Out of seven answers to this question, five experts confirmed the

statement, one remained neutral and one did not agree with the hypothesis.

As one of the experts who approves of this hypothesis, Mr Korany believes that

fairness can be judged much more accurately with the help of online information.

He knows that “yes, we can now have a much better picture about the fairness of a

price. We have transparency of prices and quality.”44 Especially having

transparency on both aspects should make it easier for customers to judge the

price-performance ratio. As shown in prior hypotheses, by making price

information available, reference prices are easily formed. Mr Sessler offers his

opinion for the automotive industry by adding to the existing arguments: “If one

44 „Ja, wir können uns jetzt ein besseres Bild über Fairness des Preises machen. Wir haben

Transparenz über die Qualität und die Preise.“ (Daniel Korany)

48

gets a five percent discount and the other gets thirty percent discount, of course

that is a reason to be upset.”45 To sum up this line of reasoning, Mr Gönsch states

that “price transparency gives the feeling of a reference price and if a price is

much higher than the market price, without understanding the reason why, I will

consider it unfair.”46

Although transparency seems to generally influence the perception of fairness, Mr

Korany, who has experience with B2B and B2C states: “In B2B the effect of price

fairness transfers to the whole relationship and has lasting influence. Even if at

one point the price is not as low as the client would like, if he was treated fairly in

the past he would still consider it fair now.”47 On the other hand, “With B2C, the

effect is not so strong; you don’t bond over fair prices but loyalty programs.”48

With these differences in the discussion, it would make sense to conduct market

research on the particular target group with the particular product or service. Since

these statements might vary and could indicate different approaches, it seems to

be quite dependent on the product.

Overall, the pricing experts have established that fairness is indeed a very

important factor in the relationship between company and customer. Mr

Weisshaar thinks that the feeling of unfairness might cause “a negative image due

to negative WOM”49. Mr Gönsch voices the worst potential effect of unfairness:

“If I feel treated unfairly, I would no longer want a relationship to the

company.”50 Mr Guzmán has a similar opinion: “if a loyal consumer feels an

unfair relation with the company, their reaction will be stronger”. Obviously,

treating a customer fairly is very important and any pricing strategy should

incorporate that.

45 „Wenn der eine 5% Nachlass bekommen hat und der Andere 30%, dann ist das natürlich ein

Grund sich zu echauffieren.“ (Wolfgang Sessler) 46 „Aus Preistransparenz ergibt sich dann ein Gefühl was der Marktpreis sein soll und wenn ein

Preis extrem über dem Marktpreis ist, ohne dass ich verstehe warum, dann empfinde ich das als

unfair.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 47 „Im B2B: Peak Experiences, Effekt von Preis Fairness würde man auf die ganze Beziehung

transferieren, langfristiger Einfluss auf die Kundenbeziehung. Auch wenn spätere Preise nicht

ganz so niedrig wären wie erwünscht, würde der Kunde es als fair ansehen.“ (Daniel Korany) 48„Bei Konsumenten ist der Effekt meiner Meinung nach nicht so stark, man bindet nicht über

faire Preise sondern über Loyalty Programme, Effekt eher kurzfristig.“ (Daniel Korany) 49 „Negatives Image durch negatives WOM.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 50 „Wenn ich das Gefühl habe, jemand macht mir einen unfairen Preis würde ich keine weitere

Beziehung zu dem Unternehmen mehr wünschen.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

49

Mr Weisshaar gives pointers as to how companies can influence the perception of

fairness. He states that you need “transparency about the additional value of a

higher price. You need to teach this to the consumer and the employees. The value

story is more than product and price, it’s about the whole marketing mix.”51

Therefore he suggests that “you have to explain your prices”.52 Mr Gönsch also

thinks that if you explain prices properly, “the costumer will then hopefully see

why the price is expensive and decide for the product”.53 Mr Weisshaar also

knows that “for products or services with good reviews, the consumer has a higher

willingness to pay”.54 Being open about the advantages of your product and the

additional value obviously improves willingness to pay.

The pricing experts have overall agreed with the theory on how fairness is

expected and how it is rewarded. The interviews have proven how important it is

to be fair and how a company can influence price changes in order to adhere their

positive customer relationships. Again, it is important to understand the

motivation of the customer and how he perveices prices. With the results,

appropriate actions can be taken when undergoing a change in pricing strategy or

when trying to improve the current one.

Price and cost transparency have direct influence on the willingness to pay.

Since transparency online has increased, the research has shown that through price

comparisons and a vast amount of information, theoretically, the willingness to

pay should be influenced. With six out of seven positive affirmations and only one

rejection of the hypothesis, the majority of the pricing experts seem to agree with

the theory.

51 „Transparenz über den Mehrwert, um den Preis zu rechtfertigen, wie setzt sich der Preis

zusammen. Mehr aufklären, sowohl Verkäufer als auch Kunde; Value Story ist mehr als Produkt

und Preis, sondern gesamter Marketing Mix.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 52 „Man muss den Preis erklären.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 53 „Dann sieht der Kunde hoffentlich ein, warum der Preis teurer ist und entscheidet sich dafür.“

(Jochen Gönsch) 54 „Ja, bei guten Bewertungen von Produkten und Services ist der Konsument eher bereit was zu

bezahlen.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

50

Indeed, Mr Gönsch acknowledges this hypothesis as „the more transparent the

market, the more do I have a reference price in mind”55, which has also been

confirmed in the prior hypotheses for reference prices. Mr Brzoska knows, that

there is not only transparency for prices. He claims that “price transparency often

indicates more transparency on quality. If a product is of good quality, I am

willing to pay more.”56 As already established, it is important to explain prices

and transparency on quality could be part of such an explanation.

With this in mind, a general recommendation from Mr Weisshaar would be “[…]

to speak the language of the target group and meet their expectations. Have clear

messages for the consumer.”57 With this, it is much easier to achieve success. It

also emphasizes how important it is to know the consumer.

Apart from transparency, the questionnaire aimed at understanding the other

influencing factors, which change willingness to pay. The interviewees point out

that there are indeed several factors which have influence on the consumer’s

willingness to pay. Mr Korany knows several factors which change the purchase

situation: “Is it a present or for myself? My willingness to pay will be higher for

presents.”58 He also names “customer reviews, the speed of transaction”59 as well

as “how fast do I need the product?”60 as important factors. Indeed, according to

Mr Guzmán, even the weather counts: “you are more willing to pay a higher price

for a coffee when it is cold than when it is hot.” All of these factors influence the

perception of prices, which clearly shows that convenience has great value as well

as the purpose of the purchase.

On the other hand, when it comes to factors which might not have an influence,

there is some controversy. Mr Korany mentions the hypothesis, that “hard factors,

such as income, have a small influence.”61 While this is indeed an interesting

55 „Je transparenter der Markt, je mehr habe ich einen Referenzpreis im Kopf.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 56 „Transparenz auf der Preisseite bedeutet oft auch mehr Transparenz auf der Qualitätsseite.

Wenn ein Produkt gut ist, bin ich auch bereit mehr zu zahlen.“ (Tim Brzoska) 57 „Ja, man muss die Sprache der Zielgruppe sprechen und Erwartungshaltungen erfüllen, Angebot

nicht in Technoquatsch formulieren sondern klare Botschaften für die gewünschten Zielgruppen.“

(Norbert Weisshaar) 58 „Geschenk oder für mich selbst? Die Zahlungsbereitschaft für ein Geschenk wäre größer.“

(Daniel Korany) 59 „Käuferbewertungen, Geschwindigkeit der Abwicklung.“ (Daniel Korany) 60 „“Wie schnell brauche ich das Produkt?“ (Daniel Korany) 61 „Harte Faktoren wie Einkommen spielen einen kleineren Einfluss.“ (Daniel Korany)

51

hypothesis, Mr Gönsch is of different opinion and points out the opposite: „Surely

the financial possibilities. There are product categories for which I find the price

appropriate but I won’t buy because it’s not within my financial possibilities.”62

This interesting contradiction indicates that there might be potential for further

research on the influential factors and that although there is much unison on the

influences of willingness to pay, there is also no clear findings on how influential

the income factor is.

The goal for this statement was to understand if the pricing experts with their

practical experience agree with the theory and what other aspects they might

discuss. The discussion has shown that even with such an nearly unanimous

distribution, there are still varying opinions on basic influences of willingness to

pay, which indicates that not only there is room for further research on the

specific topics but also that there is no single true answer to the questions in this

context.

For companies the main advantages of internet transparency are new pricing

possibilities with regards to more specific segmentation and a better

understanding of the consumer with new possibilities of market research and data

collection.

After establishing the effects of the internet on prices, this hypothesis considers

the advantages of internet transparency. The question received different responses,

with three out of seven answering in the affirmative, three not really giving a clear

statement and one denying the proposition.

For Mr Tauss, the internet gives the advantage of the „speed of doing things,

either price changes or other rule changes”63. While this statement concerns the

implementation of prices on the internet, Mr Tauss also know that the internet

allows companies “to be flexible and understand consumer behavior”64. Mr

62 „Sicherlich auch die eigenen Möglichkeiten. Es gibt Produktkategorien, bei denen ich den Preis

für angemessen halte, die ich aber trotzdem nicht kaufe weil es über meinen finanziellen

Möglichkeiten liegt.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 63 „Die Geschwindigkeit mit der ich Dinge in den Markt stellen kann, seien es Preisveränderungen

oder andere Spielregeln.“ (Werner Tauss) 64 „Außerdem ist man sehr flexibel und kann sehr gut das Kundenverhalten nachvollziehen.“

(Werner Tauss)

52

Brzoska agrees and states that „if I have consumers, I know much more about

them”65, clearly indicating that the knowledge about the consumer is increased,

which can help in the process of finding the ideal pricing strategy. What adds to

this process of finding a strategy is the collection of consumer data, because

according to Mr Tauss, that can show “at what point of the sales funnel/buying

process does the consumer leave.”66 Gathering such insights is particularly

important, because it shows where the problems are and why the customer might

not buy the product. Once the point of exit is determined, further research can

help to avoid similar exists in the future. Besides being able to have the

knowledge on the consumer and indicators for pricing strategies and their

implementation, Mr Brzoska adds that “Obviously, the advantage is to focus on a

much bigger customer group.”67 Clearly, the internationalisation of the internet

gives access to target groups all around the world, which can be focused on by

knowing their differences. As indicated with the differences in reference prices,

different customers in different countries have to face different pricing strategies.

Overall, the interviewees generally agreed with the hypotheses, but also

emphasized how this depends on the specific situations. The knowledge

avaiblable online and the potential of new consumer groups and markets has high

potential but can also be a great challenge for companies.

The main disadvantages are increased transparency of costs and prices plus the

danger of arbitrage.

Knowing the business world inside out, the pricing experts have all agreed that

besides the advantages there are also disadvantages and threats associated with

increased transparency. Seven answers to this hypothesis were collected and five

clearly agreed with the statement. Two of the pricing experts gave no clear answer

but instead explained what they consider to be most disadvantageous.

65 „Ansonsten, wenn ich Kunden habe, dann weiß ich viel mehr über sie.“ (Tim Brzoska) 66 „Bis zu welchem Schritt des Kaufprozesses geht der Kunde und wann steigt er aus.“ (Werner

Tauss) 67 „Der Vorteil ist natürlich, dass ich eine viel größere Kundengruppe ansprechen kann.“ (Tim

Brzoska)

53

Mr Brzoska wholeheartedly agrees with the hypothesis: “This is a huge

problem.”68 He is not alone, as Mr Guzmán agrees that “arbitrage and cannibalism

are always risks in these strategies” because, as Mr Tauss points out, “the

consumer has the same information”69. The problem of internet transparency

indeed seems to be higher knowledge for the consumer, which can lead to

arbitrage. As someone who has worked on various projects in his position as a

consultant, Mr Korany claims that arbitrage “is a huge problem in the

pharmaceutical industry.”70 Despite this example, his overall evaluation states that

he “[…] didn’t perceive the risk to be great.”71 One explanation Mr Korany offers

for his assessment is that “the price range between different countries becomes

smaller and prices become more and more similar.”72 With small price gaps,

arbitrage often does not make sense anymore, that’s why the theory also suggest

for companies facing arbitrage problems to keep price gaps small.

Apart from the notion that arbitrage can be a risk in some industries, the experts

were able to distinguish further disadvantages of internet transparency. Mr

Gönsch explains how “transparency can be a disadvantage because it puts prices

under pressure.”73 Similarly, Mrs van der Wal recognizes danger for prices as

transparency increases: “For a manufacturer anther disadvantage I see is price

erosion.” Apart from the price issues, another disadvantage revealed by Mr

Gönsch is the fact that “a company has a certain pressure for innovations.”74 Price

pressure is especially dangerous, as it could lead to price wars and downward

price spirals. Although pressure for innovations can also be disadvantageous,

innovations are one great way of differentiation and keeping a company away

from price pressure. Mr Weisshaar recommends „to react flexible and fast to

changes and use innovations to make prices matter less”75, basically agreeing to

the general threats of transparency and pointing out the importance of properly

reacting to them.

68 „Das ist ein Riesenproblem.” (Tim Brzoska) 69 „Eben, er hat die gleichen Informationen.“ (Werner Tauss) 70 „Das kriege ich immer als großes Problem der Pharmabranche.“ (Daniel Korany) 71 „Das habe ich gar nicht als stark wahrgenommen.“ (Daniel Korany) 72 „Preisspanne zwischen Ländern nimmt ab, Preise werden insgesamt ähnlicher.“ (Daniel Korany) 73 „Transparenz kann man aus als Nachteil sehen weil Preise unter Druck geraten.“ (Jochen

Gönsch) 74 „Ein Unternehmen hat auch einen gewissen Innovationsdruck.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 75 „Flexibler reagieren und rasch auf Änderungen einstellen, mit Innovationen punkten, dann wird

der Preis nur noch sekundär sein.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

54

This hypothesis has shown that there are indeed drawbacks to internet

transparency, especially the pressure on prices and the need to always find new

innovative ways to differentiate a company. The disadvantage of arbitrage should

be taken into account if the risks are unknown, since this could be a huge problem

for some industries, while for many others it might not be a huge issue. Since this

issue cannot be answered generally, every company should research their market

and know its strength and weaknesses.

For companies the advantages gained from increased transparency are more

substantial than the disadvantages.

Of course, after establishing the interviewees’ opinion on advantages and

disadvantages, their opinion on whether – despite all disadvantages – the positive

aspects prevail is questioned. Only two out of six answers approved that

advantages are greater than disadvantages. The rest of the experts somehow

approved but did not want to make an all-encompassing statement and provided

information that it most likely depended on the specific company and situation.

Primarily, Mr Weisshaar attests that, “transparency which shows value is a huge

advantage I can use.”76 Since it was established before, that price transparency

often comes with quality transparency, Mr Weisshaar seems to take this as one

way to use transparency in a company’s favour.

In a more neutral position, Mr Gönsch claims that this hypothesis “depends on the

company and industry.”77 Equally, Mrs van der Wal states that it “depends also if

you are manufacturer or supplier/reseller and where you are in the distribution

chain… it for sure is much more complex…” As mentioned, these differences in

industries and companies require a thorough analysis of the environment.

Although Mr Guzmán is not against the statement of the hypothesis, he also

knows that things can easily go wrong. He argues that “if you are careless with the

execution of the strategy and you don’t create barriers or controls to mitigate or

76 „Eine Transparenz, die Leistung verdeutlicht ist ein großer Vorteil, daraus kann ich was

machen.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 77 „Ich glaube das kommt auf das Unternehmen und die Branche an.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

55

decrease the arbitrage, the loss could be more than the gain.” All these opinions,

despite being so different, make a good point. Mr Gönsch has an example to

emphasize that even in the right industry, a company can do things wrong: “Do

you know the mail-order company Quelle? It’s not clear if it was just the internet,

but it did have an influence – for Quelle, the disadvantages outbalanced the

advantages although a mail-order company is predestined for the internet.”78

Summing up the results from the interview findings combined with the research, it

cannot be said whether or not advantages or disadvantages outweigh the other.

Many factors have influence on successfully using online channels. It’s obvious

that knowing the risks and preparing properly for online strategies is essential

business and even if all odds are in favour of a company, the wrong

implementation can easily lead to irreparable damages.

The internet has increased the risks and options of arbitrage.

Arbitrage has already been discussed as a topic when talking about the

disadvantages of technological advances. The already mixed results from those

hypotheses also shine through with this question. Out of all experts, six answered

the question to this hypothesis. Five agreed with the hypothesis that arbitrage

indeed increases, while one expert contradicted the statement. Since many

opinions on arbitrage have already been discussed before, the analysis of this

hypothesis will not repeat already established quotes.

Mr Brzoska has an explanation as to why arbitrage has increased: “The internet

makes it easier to order online. That’s why the risk of arbitrage is greater than in

the past.”79 With these increased risks, Mr Weisshaar claims that “yes, you need

to be able to determine whether supply and demand in the different markets are

changing and react appropriately.”80

78 „Kennen Sie das Versandhaus Quelle? Man weiß nicht ob es nur am Internet lag, aber es hatte

einen großen Einfluss – für Quelle haben die Nachteile die Vorteile überwogen obwohl ein

Versandhaus prädestiniert für das Internet wäre.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

79 „Das Internet macht es einfacher, Produkte im Ausland zu bestellen. Daher ist das Risiko

größer als in der Vergangenheit.“ (Tim Brzoska)

80 „Ja, deshalb flexibel auf dem Schirm haben wie sich Angebot und Nachfrage in den

verschiedenen Märkten verhält und dann reagieren.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

56

Mr Korany mentions an example, where arbitrage has proven to be a problem:

„Swiss automobile dealers buy cars in Germany because of the exchange rate,

even with customs it’s still cheaper.”81 Stating the complete opposite, Mr Sessler,

with his expertise from Mercedes Benz, has a different take on arbitrage when

talking about the automotive industry. “We have very different national customer

retention, which doesn’t make it easy to buy in other countries.”82 With just this

one example, the two experts show that they have made quite different

experiences with arbitrage in the same industry. This points out how arbitrage can

be a very individual problem for individual countries or companies.

With more information on arbitrage already disclosed in the hypothesis about

advantages of internet transparency, it can be emphasized that although a

company should know about the risks of arbitrage in their industry and for their

product, it is not something that should keep companies from pursuing differential

pricing.

For international PD, arbitrage costs are decreasing because of easier access to

markets, decreasing transportation costs and free trade zones.

Since the theory has pointed out that arbitrage costs strongly influence how much

arbitrage is possible, finding the determinants from an expert point of view can

help to further distinguish the topic. Out of six answers, two thirds were positive

affirmations, two gave no clear answer.

Starting off with the affirmation of the hypothesis, Mr Gönsch claims that “when

markets grow together, transportation costs often decrease.”83 Furthermore, he

also substantiates his opinion by saying that “it’s easier to order in Europe.”84

Having established that arbitrage can indeed still be a risk to some industries, the

experts also offer ways to circumvent the dangers of resale. Starting off, Mr

Guzmán believes that if companies want to avoid arbitrage, it is important “not to

81 „Schweizer Automobilhändler gehen wegen dem Wechselkurs gerne nach Deutschland um

Autos zu kaufen, auch mit Zoll ist es günstiger.“ (Daniel Korany)

82 „Wir haben sehr unterschiedliche nationale Kundenbindung, die es nicht einfach macht, in

anderen Ländern zu kaufen.“ (Wolfgang Sessler) 83 „Gerade wenn Märkte zusammenwachsen sinken häufig die Transportkosten.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 84 „In Europa ist es einfacher zu bestellen.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

57

create a price gap so big, that it would motivate arbitrage.” Additionally, Mr

Weisshaar sees potential in avoiding arbitrage by doing “a thorough segmentation

and set new price points.”85 He also believes it important to “focus on the target

group and pass on some customers who do not bring profits.”86 Finally, another

helpful advice from Mr Guzmán points out, that to avoid arbitrage, companies

have to “sell the same product in different markets, but with different brands that

have and strong local brand equity.”

Thanks to the interviewees, several practices to avoid arbitrage have come up and

can be used as a foundation for pricing strategies. These strategies are especially

important for the industry which discover problems with arbitrage. With these

recommendation on how to conquer the arbitrage problem, every company should

be able to decrease the risk by using one or more of these solutions.

Dynamic Pricing is considered an unfair pricing technique and will cause the

consumer to stray from the brand.

When it comes to a certain pricing strategy, it is always about whether or not the

consumer will accept this particular approach. Considering the unfairness of

dynamic pricing, the interviewees did not clearly agree on this hypothesis. Out of

the six interviewees who were asked this questions, one disagreed with the

hypothesis and the other five did not clearly state their opinion on the hypothesis,

but rather made it dependent on the circumstances and type of discrimination.

When asked about some famous examples of personalized dynamic pricing,

which did not succeed, Mr Gönsch knows that the most famous example of how

individual price discrimination can go wrong, was “10 or 15 years ago, Amazon

charged different people different prices. That was a huge scandal. For years,

nobody dared to approach the topic.”87 In the case of Amazon, Mr Gönsch

remembers how “[…] the assumption was, that regular customers have to pay

85 „Man muss Kunden immer mehr segmentieren und neue Preispunkte setzen.“ (Norbert

Weisshaar) 86 „Zielkundengerecht setzen und auf den ein oder anderen Kunden verzichten der keine Margen

mehr nennt.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 87 „Es gab mal vor 10-15 Jahren als Amazon unterschiedlichen Deutschen unterschiedliche Preise

angeboten hat. Das war ein Riesenskandal und 10 Jahre hat sich niemand mehr an dieses Thema

ran getraut.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

58

higher prices than first-time customers. Something like that is easily seen as

unfair.”88 As indicated, the way of personal discrimination was not taken lightly

and negatively influenced all strategies related to personalize pricing for many

years. Mr Brzoska also remembers an example of how dynamic pricing can go

wrong: „There was a soda machine, where the price was regulated by the outdoor

temperature. The hotter the weather, the more expensive the beverages. That was

not popular.”89 Again, this example shows that differentiating on such

circumstances can have the opposite effect of the desired outcome.

To collect the general problems with dynamic pricing mechanisms, Mr Brzoska

knows that there are specific problems when discriminating on personal

characteristics: “If I get price differentiated because of personal characteristics,

whether or not I use an iPad or another type of tablet, I would be unhappy.”90

Mentioning another aspect, Mr Gönsch argues that „if you use a segment-oriented

differentiation […] I think that can be considered unfair.”91 Mr Gönsch already

offers a preferable alternative, stating that “[…] when consumers can select

themselves, it works better.”92 In theory, this self-selection has also shown to be

the most accepted method of differentiation.

Moving from the general view to some detailed aspects, Mr Brzoska explains that

there are differences between channels: “On the internet, it can happened that

prices are different in the morning and in the evening. It doesn’t feel unfair

because you know it’s dynamic.”93 In this case, temporal dynamic pricing on the

internet has become known and consumers have adapted this as a familiar

occurrence. Mr Guzmán claims that the fairness concept depends of which

consumer segment is buying the product since “perception of value could change

88 „Man konnte da auch nichts dagegen machen und die Vermutung war, dass Stammkunden

teurere Preise kriegen als Erstkunden und sowas wird schnell als unfair gesehen.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

89 „Es gab mal Getränkeautomaten, bei denen war die Preissteuerung über die Außentemperatur

gesteuert. Je wärmer es wurde, desto teurer wurden die Getränke. Das kam nicht gut an.“ (Tim

Brzoska)

90 „Wenn man aufgrund persönlicher Eigenschaften, zum Beispiel ob ich ein iPad oder ein

anderes Tablet benutze, im Preis differenziert wäre, dann wäre ich zickig.“ (Tim Brzoska) 91 „Wenn man eine segmentorientierte Preisdifferenzierung hat und Kunden auf Grund

Eigenschaften einordnet, Seniorenrabatt und sowas, das glaube ich kann als unfair empfunden

werden.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

92 „Wenn man dagegen Preisdifferenzierung hat, die nicht auf Segmenten ansetzt sondern wo die

Kunden sich selbst einordnen, ist es besser.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 93 „Im Internet kann es schon mal passieren dass morgens und abends die Preise unterschiedlich

sind. Das wirkt nicht so unfair, denn man ist gewohnt, dass es dynamisch ist.“ (Tim Brzoska)

59

from one day to another in the same segment”, states Mr Guzmán.

He also explains how “the main goal of dynamic pricing is the same as revenue

management; to take out more value from the market, but if you don’t identify the

variables that can trigger the different behaviour and value from the market, you

might decrease the revenue or the profits of a company.” Mr Guzmán understands

the risks of a dynamic pricing strategy and how important it is to understand all

factors.

While it has become clear that there is much to do wrong with dynamic pricing

strategies, there are also experts, who do not see this as a problem. As the one

expert, who clearly disapproved of the hypothesis, Mr Weisshaar does not believe

that “the consumer even realizes it.”94 Mr Tauss is not convinced by the

hypothesis either: “From my experiences with the airline and cruise ship industry

I know that dynamic pricing is not used regularly yet. I wouldn’t know that this

already exists in detail. People don’t know why you charge different prices

because it’s not expensive to do it right.”95 The scepticism relies on the fact that

the consumer does not understand the price system. With increased transparency

and interaction between customers, it is not wise to rely on the fact that people

might not understand the price because if they find out that there has been an

unjustified pricing mechanism in place who differentiated in a way, which is not

accepted, the potential backlash could be huge.

In order to avoid such a situation, the experts make aware of what you should do.

As Mr Brzoska points out, it is most important to be able to give a satisfactory

explanation of prices: “If you don’t have an explanation, it is bad.”96 This has

already been strongly discussed in the hypothesis on transparency and its

influence on fairness and willingness to pay. Additionally, Mr Gönsch expresses

that “as a company you have to change the products.”97 By changing products,

changes in price can be explained and justified.

94 „Nein glaube ich nicht, da der Konsument es gar nicht mitbekommt.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

95 „Aus eigener Erfahrung mit den Branchen mit denen ich arbeite (Kreuzfahrten, Luftfahrt), wird

das noch nicht sonderlich genutzt. Ich wüsste nicht, dass es das bereits in großem Detailgrad gibt.

Warum verschiedene Preis verlangt werden, das weiß man ja nicht. denn es kostet ja nicht viel, das

richtig zu machen.“ (Werner Tauss) 96 „Wenn es dann keine Erklärung gibt, dann ist es schlecht.“ (Tim Brzoska) 97 „Da muss man dann als Unternehmen die Produkte verändern.“ (Jochen Gönsch)

60

This introductory hypothesis on dynamic pricing ought to bring together the

topics of fairness which have already been discussed in a general setting and

combining them with the specifics of dynamic pricing. It is interesting to see how

such a pricing strategy affects fairness and that it all comes down to explanation

of prices. In the end, the overall learning shows that as long as you can explain the

prices successfully to the customer, a pricing mechanism can work, no matter

what it is. The following hypotheses will aim at bringing more information on

how dynamic pricing works and what opportunities exist which have so far not

been utilized.

Price differentiation and dynamic pricing are more accepted with perishable goods

compared to non-perishable categories.

In order to determine the possibilities of dynamic pricing strategies, it is important

to align the expertise of the theoretical research with the one of the pricing

experts. All eight experts answered this questions and they all agreed with the

hypothesis, although, as it will be shown, this does not mean that price

differentiation and especially dynamic pricing are not possible or desirable for

non-perishable goods.

When talking about when and why dynamic pricing is successful, Mr Gönsch

knows that it works “because people get used to it with time.”98 Mr Guzmán

agrees and adds that “human beings like habits, and habits and patterns are

difficult to modify, but not impossible”. He shows his optimism, that certain

pricing strategies can be taught to be accepted as long as they are made into

habits. Mr Weisshaar adds another component to the acceptance of dynamic

pricing with perishable goods. He states that dynamic pricing with these products

works “because you can argue logically.”99 In this case, it is not about teaching

the consumer to accept a certain strategy, but to argue logically why prices are

different by appealing to human reasoning.

98 „Ich glaube es liegt daran, dass sich die Leute daran gewöhnen mit der Zeit.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 99 „Man kann es inhaltlich argumentieren.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

61

While it has become clear how dynamic pricing can be accepted, there are certain

things, for which acceptance has already been established. Mr Brzoska considers

limited capacity to be one great factor to explain changing prices, since “the

consumer understands that scarce products get more expensive. It’s easy to

explain. The consumer understands certain mechanisms.”100 Indeed this seems to

hold true, as Mr Korany also thinks that “capacities are an important factor”.101 In

addition to that, Mr Brzoska adds another type of product for which dynamic

pricing supposedly works: “Definitely works with scarcity. It also works with

products with high fix costs and low variable costs.”102 Apart from that, Mr Tauss

also knows in which purchase situation dynamic pricing might work. For him it’s

all about timing: “Yes. If it doesn’t matter whether I buy a product today or next

week, dynamic pricing won’t work.”103

All these characteristics are most likely to exist with perishable products. Mr

Gönsch does in fact not see the possibilities with non-perishable goods: „When

Amazon shows you an expensive price, you will feel discriminated.”104

On the other hand, this is not the only opinion on the matter and Mr Guzmán does

not think that dynamic pricing is solely possible for perishable goods and claims

that for them “dynamic pricing could be better, but is not a rule.” Although

dynamic pricing might be better to explain for perishable products or products

with limited capacity, it all depends on what to explain to the consumer.

One idea how dynamic pricing could be used for a product, which does not have

the ideal characteristics for this type of strategy, was named by Mr Korany: „With

perfume you can differentiate with loyalty systems. You can use a membership,

where you can pay 100 Euros per year and you receive twenty percent discount on

every perfume bought, similar to what the ‘Deutsche Bahn’ is doing.”105 This

100 „Aus Konsumentensicht versteht jeder, dass bei Knappheit ein Produkt teurer wird. Das kann

man erklären. Bestimmte Mechanismen sind vom Konsumenten erlernt.“ (Tim Brzoska) 101 „Kapazitäten spielen dabei einen wichtigen Faktor.“ (Daniel Korany) 102 „Auf jeden Fall bei Knappheit. Das funktioniert aber auch bei Produkten mit hohen Fixkosten

und geringen Variablen Kosten.“ (Tim Brzoska) 103„Ja. Wenn ich ein Produkt sehe bei dem es egal ist ob ich es heute kaufe oder nächste Woche,

dann funktioniert das nicht.” (Werner Tauss) 104 „Wenn Ihnen Amazon den teureren Preis anzeigt, dann fühlt man sich schnell diskriminiert.“

(Jochen Gönsch)

105 „Bei Parfüms kann man auch differenzieren mit einem Treuesystem. Man kann eine

Mitgliedschaft einführen. Man zahlt 100 Euro im Jahr und bekommt 20% Rabatt auf jedes Parfüm,

ähnlich wie bei der Deutschen Bahn.“ (Daniel Korany)

62

example shows that although it might have to be packaged differently, doesn’t

mean that you can’t charge different prices for non-perishable goods.

In the end, Mr Gönsch gives a great indication as to why it makes sense to

consider dynamic pricing for a company, because “compared to static pricing, a

company which uses dynamic pricing successfully gets higher profits and has

good chances of utilizing maximum capacity.”106

To conclude this hypothesis, it can be said that there are generally more ways to

explain to the consumer that persishable goods and services are dynamically

priced. Some habits and pricing mechanisms have been learned and accepted and

can be used without any implications. At the same time, when it is possible to

explain dynamic pricing logically, the consumer should not feel treated unfairly. It

is therefore up to the company itself to distinguish their pricing strategy and

communicate how that strategy works.

Dynamic pricing can only be realized on the internet as costs of implementation

are too high in offline channels.

This hypothesis tries to determine the possibilities of dynamic pricing strategies

for companies and whether it would make sense to use such a strategy offline. Out

of seven answers, three were affirmative, three denying and one neutral, showing

that the interviewees had several points for and against this statement.

First of all, the experts should give an indication to what degree this hypothesis

holds true. Mr Tauss expands the criteria why dynamic pricing works better

online beyond the cost factor: “It’s about the costs, but it‘s also about speed.”107

He indicates that there are several aspects to consider which could be quite

difficult for offline channels. When talking about the actual costs for the

implementation of dynamic pricing strategies, Mr Gönsch points out, that it “[…]

depends how often you change prices.”108 Mr Guzmán also apprehends that the”

106 „Gegenüber statischem pricing hat das Unternehmen, das sinnvoll dynamic pricing einsetzt

einen höheren Erlös und es hat häufig bessere Chancen seine Kapazität vollständig auszulasten.“

(Jochen Gönsch) 107 Es sind einmal die Kosten und zum anderen die Geschwindigkeit.“ (Werner Tauss) 108 „Es kommt drauf an wie Sie das dynamic pricing machen und wie oft man die Preise ändert.“

(Jochen Gönsch)

63

costs related with implementation in offline channels could overshadow the

benefits of it.” Clearly there are more costs associated with offline channels. But

this does, according to Mr Korany, not exclude offline channels from using

dynamic pricing strategies: “Offline is always more expensive but offline auctions

by airlines are managed through software, to avoid additional costs.”109 Since

there might be ways to use both types of channels, the interviewees have some

input about how to do that.

When asked about the challenges of implementing such a strategy, Mr Tauss

knows the important thing about implementing this type of pricing: “If I don’t

know what the customer wants or the competitors do, I can lose money really fast.

The willingness to pay is very important. You have to concentrate in

communicating the strengths and advantages of the brand.”110 As another

important thing to consider before implementation, Mr Korany adds “It’s

important to associate feelings of unfairness with something positive. You can tie

it to a product upgrade or to promotions.”111 Obviously, again it’s about offering

value to the customer and making him understand where the price is coming from.

On the question whether the experts would recommend dynamic pricing to

companies, Mr Weisshaar confirmed that „if product portfolio and industry allow

it. Dynamic pricing has always existed – just slower. With the internet, price

changes are faster and more precise.”112 As indicated, if the circumstances allow

for it, companies should pursue dynamic pricing.

Although dynamic pricing seems to be viable for both channels, it is clearly more

costly offline. Additionally, the possibilities in online channels are greater because

companies are more flexible to react to changes and have more technology to help

in the implementation of these pricing strategies. Still, for some companies, using

109 „Offline immer teurer, aber bei dem Beispiel der Fluggesellschafts Auktionen wird das auch

durch Software geregelt, dass keine Mehrkosten entstehen.“ (Daniel Korany) 110 „Wenn ich nicht weiß was der Kunde will oder der Wettbewerber macht, dann kann ich schnell

Geld verlieren. Die Zahlungsbereitschaft der Kunden zu kennen ist sehr wichtig. Man muss sich

darauf konzentrieren, die Stärke und Vorteile der Marke zu kommunizieren.“ (Werner Tauss) 111 „Dann ist auch wichtig, unfaire Gefühle mit etwas angenehmem zu verbinden. Man kann ein

Produkt Upgrade machen, es könnte mit Promotions verknüpft werden.“ (Daniel Korany) 112 „Ja wenn es das Produktportfolio und die Branche zulassen; Dynamic Pricing wird schon

immer gemacht, nur langsamer; jetzt eben besser durchs Internet, Preise wurden schon immer

justiert, heute schneller und präziser.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

64

offline channels can make just as much sense, especially if they are offline

retailers only.

Name-your-own-price transactions are the easiest way to capture the consumers’

willingness to pay.

One very specific dynamic pricing strategy is the reverse auction, which has been

described in detail in the theoretical part of this thesis. As one specific type of

reverse auctions, the NYOP model has been chosen to focus on in the expert

interviews and the results will be discussed accordingly. The opinions on this

hypothesis varied, since out of the seven answers, two denied the hypothesis, one

stays neutral without clear position and four approved of the assumption.

The supporters of the statement, such as Mr Guzmán, consider NYOP transaction

to have potential: “If you remove the brand equity factor… yes, because it will

only measure the price sensitivity towards the product.” Likewise, Mr Tauss

endorses the hypothesis: “One of many ways to determine willingness to pay. If

there is transparency and customers realize a difference in prices, they will not

feel treated unfairly because they have determined the price themselves.”113 At

first glance, this type of strategy seems to be a great way to capture willingness to

pay.

Some of the experts are not fully convinced though. Mr Korany, while not

completely dismissing NYOP strategies, offers alternatives: „It’s a good but not

ideal mechanism. Yield Management is better to skim profits.”114 Meanwhile, Mr

Weisshaar thinks that “it depends on the consumer to show ambition to bid. Do I

want to afford the product or not? NYOP is only one part of pricing, with certain

product groups.”115 He indicates that this only works for some product groups,

similar to what the overall opinion was on the applicability of dynamic pricing to

113„ Eine von vielen Varianten, wie man eine Preisbereitschaft ermitteln kann. Wenn Transparenz

herrscht und Kunden die Unterschiede in den Preisen finden, dann gibt es keinen Ärger, weil der

Konsument den Preis selbst bestimmt und sich nicht beschweren kann.“ (Werner Tauss) 114 „Guter aber kein optimaler Mechanismus, Yield Management ist besser um Profite

abzuschöpfen.“ (Daniel Korany) 115 „Hier kommt es auf die Bereitschaft des Konsumenten an, sportlicher Ehrgeiz des Mitbietens.

Will ich mir das Produkt leisten oder nicht? NYOP nur als Teil der gesamten Preispolitik, nur mit

bestimmten Produktgruppen.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

65

perishable or non-perishable goods. When going more into detail on whether this

is a good pricing strategy or not, Mr Gönsch critically argues that “if it was such a

great way, it would have more significance.”116 While Mr Gönsch does not go

into more detail, Mr Brzoska has an idea on why it is not such a good system. He

believes that „it doesn’t work without peer pressure and a clear cost structure.”117

He also knows that there is one specific problem with this pricing strategy: “The

consumer has too few price anchors.”118 According to his statement, without an

indication of the value of a product, an auction bid does not come easy.

To conclude, the interview experts have varying opinions on the usefulness of

NYOP models, which shows that although it has proven successful for its

inventors, this type of dynamic pricing strategy also has its weaknesses, which

should be considered before implementing such a strategy.

NYOP is successful because the consumer determines the price himself and

therefore feels a higher sense of fairness.

In the case of Priceline, the research showed that the NYOP strategy works rather

well. This hypothesis was used to find out whether the interviewees agree and

whether they attribute this to psychological factors. Out of the six answers to this

statement, four clearly agreed with the idea of the hypothesis, while two

positioned themselves vaguely.

First of all, thinking about the advantages of a NYOP strategy, Mr Tauss believes

that NYOP offers advantages to all parties. He says that „it has several

components. As a company you learn about willingness to pay. As a consumer

you feel fairness, because you have made a deliberate choice.”119 Mr Weisschuh

agrees and states „Yes, it is a good feeling but in the end, nobody gives away

116 „Ich glaube, wenn das so ein super Weg wäre hätte es eine größere Bedeutung.“ (Jochen

Gönsch) 117 „Ohne Peer Pressure und ein klares Bild zur Kostensituation funktioniert es nicht.“ (Tim

Brzoska) 118 „Die Leute haben zu wenige Preisanker.“ (Tim Brzoska) 119 „Ja und das hat verschiedene Komponente. Ich als Unternehmen lerne die Preisbereitschaft aber

das andere ist die Fairness, denn als Kunde hat man sich bewusst entschieden.“ (Werner Tauss)

66

anything.”120 Though the use of a NYOP strategy can bring advantages to both

parties, it is still about making the best deal possible for both sides.

Although Mr Korany generally agrees with the hypothesis, he points out that „it

doesn’t work with necessities. If you have to fly from A to B on a business trip,

you will pay a high price. But you won’t need a business class ticket.” 121 It makes

sense to point out these weaknesses of such a strategy. Obviously, as discussed

before, for some situations the general rules don’t apply. So far, the interviewees

have seen potential for all the situations, in which it is about leisure and

enjoyment, without the strict restrictions of a need behind it.

As a matter of fact, Mr Gönsch seems to have found another potential obstacle

which he imagines for the NYOP strategy: “You might still be unsatisfied,

because you might think you could have paid even less.”122 Obviously, without

any indication to the value of a purchase, it is difficult to estimate if the successful

deal was a preferable deal or not. Mr Gönsch offers another argument to add to

this line of thought: “maybe the consumer considers it complicated to think about

the price.”123 When reference prices are not clear, a decision making process

could take up a lot of time and become less desirable. But there are also options to

improve this kind of situation.

In this context, when considering pricing psychology, Mr Korany knows how to

influence the consumer using anchors: „The impact of anchors is irrational. With

overall higher numbers, the consumer will automatically chose a higher

number.”124 If this holds true in all cases, it could make sense to offer price

anchors in order to push higher prices, although this could also easily be

considered manipulative. Anchors would help companies to achieve profit goals,

but they might not be a trustworthy source for customer. Still, offering anchors as

orientation could help to simplify the process of reverse auctions. As another

120 „Ja, es gibt ein gutes Gefühl aber letztendlich verschenkt niemand was.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 121„ Ja, aber es klappt nicht wenn eine Notwendigkeit besteht, z.B. muss man von A nach B fliegen

aber Business Class braucht man nicht.“ (Daniel Korany) 122 „Bei diesem NYOP, wenn ich vielleicht einen Preis gezahlt habe, der niedriger ist als

woanders, bin ich vielleicht immer noch unzufrieden, weil man sich denkt, man hätte noch

weniger bezahlen können.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 123 „Weil der Kunde es vielleicht auch als kompliziert empfindet, sich den Preis zu überlegen.“

(Jochen Gönsch) 124 „Ankerwirkung ist irrational, bei höheren Zahlen wird automatisch auch eine höhere Zahl

genannt.“ (Daniel Korany)

67

effect auctions can have on the consumer, Mr Gönsch mentions one interesting

example: „There is a phenomenon on Ebay, where a lot of things are sold more

expensively than with price comparison searches because once consumers start

bidding they want to win the auction and get the product.”125 Although this does

not work for reverse auctions, it proves that bidding includes involvement, maybe

because it gives the consumer the feeling of already owning something, even

before it is officially bought. Using such psychological phenomena could offer

potential in this area of pricing.

To conclude, the pricing experts have demonstrated ways why NYOP strategies

work and how they could be advantageous. At the same time, they name

limitations for this strategy and possible ways to overcome them by leading the

customer in the right direction. In the end, the success can be attributed to the

power the customer has but that this might also be the greatest challenge.

Most consumers don’t take advantage of price differentiation in the form or

coupons.

The final hypothesis surrounds the topic of coupons as a measure of second-

degree price discrimination. In this case, not one of the seven answers was

positive, with four being neutral and three saying no to the question. During the

interviews, it became clear that this type of question couldn’t be answered

affirmatively as it asked about a topic where most of the experts had no deeper

knowledge and therefore did not want to approve solely based on their personal

experience. At the same time, most interviewees shared that they themselves were

not using coupons on a regular basis.

Even without being able to tell details, Mr Weisshaar said that “there was once a

big hype.”126 As part of this hype, due to the vast amount of coupons Mr Korany

points out that “the effect of coupons disappears really fast.”127 Corresponding

with that comment, Mr Brzoska, out of experience, states that coupons have “low

125 „Es gibt auch bei Ebay das Phänomen, dass viele Sachen teurer verkauft werden als über eine

Preissuchmaschine, weil wenn die Leute mal mitsteigern, dann wollen die Leuten auch die

Auktion gewinnen und das Produkt haben.“ (Jochen Gönsch) 126 „Es gab mal einen großen Hype.“ (Norbert Weisshaar) 127 „Effekt von Coupons verpufft ziemlich schnell.“ (Daniel Korany)

68

redemption rates, which does not mean people do not use it. Sometimes you are

simply overwhelmed by coupons.”128 With the sheer amount of coupons on the

market, consumers might just lose focus. In order to improve the use of coupons,

Mr Guzmán claims that “many companies have created mechanisms to make

coupon redemption a little higher, but sometimes that causes consumers that were

willing to pay full price, to receive a discount even if they didn’t want it.” Of

course, while higher redemption is a wanted effect, coupons should ideally only

benefit those customers, who were highly price sensitive, the ones who would not

have bought the product without a coupon.

On the other hand, coupons can also have the opposite effect of people buying

things they wouldn’t actually need. Mr Tauss knows that “There are not many

products or services, for which there is no coupon. There are people who make a

sport out of it.”129 And he adds that this might even lead to a situation where „the

consumer buys things he doesn’t need, but because he had a coupon for it.”130

When discussing which type of consumer would behave in such a pattern, Mr

Guzmán claims that the “consumers with high price sensitivity are more willing to

use them.” It makes sense that consumer who are very price sensitive would

invest more time and efforts into getting a better price. Mr Korany also points out,

that there could be one other type of situation, which increases the usage of

coupons: „To overcome the system is more motivation than the actual monetary

savings.”131

After discovering how coupons are used and that there is a real overflow of

coupons in the market, it makes sense for Mr Korany to say that “it’s a problem

because coupons hurt the image and you don’t make good business but destroy

brand value.”132 Of course this makes sense when talking about all those

customers, who do no longer buy without a coupon and who learn to wait in order

to take advantage of a better price. Therefore it might be harmful to give coupons

128 „Sehr geringe Einlösquoten. Das muss nicht allgemein heißen, dass wenig genutzt wird, man

wird oft einfach überschüttet.“ (Tim Brzoska) 129 „Man wird zugeschüttet und es gibt kaum etwas, bei dem es keinen Coupon gibt. Es gibt Leute,

die machen einen Sport daraus.” (Werner Tauss) 130 „Er kauft auch Dinge, die er nicht braucht, aber er hatte einen Coupon dafür.“ (Werner Tauss) 131 „Das System überführt zu haben ist größerer Antrieb als tatsächliche Kostenersparnis.“ (Daniel

Korany) 132 „Eher problematisch da Coupons für ein Ramsch-Image sorgen, man macht weniger

Schnäppchen sondern zerstört eher an Wert.“ (Daniel Korany)

69

to everyone. As researched throughout the theoretical part, dynamic coupons can

be targeted according to past purchase behaviour in a way which can be less

harmful towards the brand. When considering whether dynamic coupons would

be a better alternative, Mr Brzoska confirms: “Yes, absolutely. Dynamic coupons

help to address the needs of the customer.”133 Similarly, Mr Weisshaar supports

“dynamic coupons are generally better than normal ones.”134

Clearly there is potential for coupons when they are personalised, because while

posted prices stay the same and appear to be the same to everyone, coupons can

change these prices and skim different customers with their different willingness

to pay. If a company wants to try coupons, they should always do it dynamically

in order to protect their brand.

133 „Ja absolut. Damit kann man die Bedürfnisse des Kunden besser ansprechen.“ (Tim Brzoska) 134 „Dynamische Coupons sind grundsätzlich besser als normale Coupons.“ (Norbert Weisshaar)

70

12 Conclusions

The interviews have shown that the existing research already covers most of the

issues and challenges of the hypotheses. In the end, the greatest learning is that

there is not one universal solution and answer to pricing topics. Indeed, as with

many business decisions, it all depends on the industry, the company and the

product in question. Generally, there are many opportunities and challenges in

online channels, especially with increased transparency for consumers. Prices

have become an important purchase factor and they are easily compared.

Therefore, companies need to explain prices and add value to their products or

services to be noticed. This influences how prices are perceived and how much

customers are willing to pay. Although this transparency can be a threat, it can

also be turned into an opportunity by using the transparency to communicate

advantages. The interviews have also confirmed that fairness and trust are indeed

important concepts for pricing strategies and companies should know their value

and always act with the consumer in mind. While for many companies the

advantages of increased transparency can be greater than disadvantages, it mostly

depends on how communication with consumers works and whether the consumer

finds positive reinforcement for the brand online or whether he find out about

some unfairness or manipulation. A great danger of online transparency is

pressure of prices which is a result of consumers being able to easily compare

prices online. This price pressure might be avoided by being flexible, investing in

innovations and improving brand value in order to justify a certain price level.

The conclusions for the topic of dynamic pricing is that generally, dynamic

pricing has been accepted for certain industries, where capacities are limited and

perishable. The experts agree that it works better for these goods and services, but

that it is generally a thing of explanation. If a company is able to properly explain

a pricing strategy in a way that can be accepted by the consumer, dynamic pricing

is possible. That also goes for the differences in channels. There are more

possibilities online, but offline channels can use dynamic pricing as well, even if

they might not be able to change prices as fast and flexible as it is possible online.

Generally, this indicates that dynamic pricing is potentially possible for every type

of product as long as these conditions are fulfilled. With NYOP as one focus of

dynamic pricing strategies, the experts were more sceptical. Although a reverse

71

auction works in certain settings, it is again very much depening on the situation

and the product. The positive thing is that it catches willingness to pay, but the

interviews have also demonstrated that there might be more potential with

strategies where the consumer gets incentives to choose a profitable price,

possibily by using anchors or other psychological price points.

The success of coupons is doubted, as they do more harm than good to a brand.

Dynamic coupons on the other hand could be a much better way to target price

sensitive customers without losing surplus on those who are willing to pay full

price.

The learnings from this thesis have nicely complemented the theoretical part.

These learnigns will now be part of the upcoming recommendations for action,

which will also include outside knowledge on marketing and pricing and combine

these two fields in order to give indicators for companies on how pricing should

be done.

13 Limitations

As in any empirical analysis, the research also has its limitations. In case of the

expert interviews, several limitations could be noted.

First of all, there were only eight interviews in total with very different opinions,

which already shows that there is much to be discussed about the topic and that

interviewing eight experts is not representative enough to draw definite

conclusions. By conducting more interviews, it could have been possible to find

more opinions, but also to find an inclination towards one line of thought.

Secondly, while all experts worked in the field of pricing, there was not much

specialized knowledge to this relatively modern pricing strategy. This made it

difficult to find convincing statements. With more resources it might have been

possible to talk directly to some of the pricing experts who specialize in this field

but due to their busy schedules they did not replay or were generally not available

for an unpaid interview.

72

Lastly, after already conducting several interviews, it came to attention that the

questions were sometimes too complex or specific and not easy to understand.

This sometimes required more explanation for the question and caused the

interviewees to be less sure about their answers. By doing a focused test-run

before starting with the interviews and reviewing each question on its complexity

and applicability could avoid such problems for future reference.

73

14 Recommendations for actions

The findings from research, the discussion of the interviews and other background

marketing knowledge will be used to put forth the following recommendations for

actions any company should consider when facing their pricing strategy. In order

for companies to stay competitive, pricing has to be taken seriously and time and

money should be invested in order to find the perfect strategy for a firm’s

portfolio. While many companies still neglect the effects of doing the wrong

pricing strategy, other have invested resources and have been able to transform

their business to the better.

The organisation of pricing

In many cases, the prices are determined by the controlling department of a

company. Since they have a very analytical background with the exact

calculations of production costs and profit margins, they seem to be the logical

choice for many companies. With marketing knowledge and the indications from

this thesis and other research, the only logical result is to have pricing experts in

the marketing department, who create the price with their knowledge on consumer

psychology and value creation. Although controlling should be closely involved

in the calculation of profits and give their agreement, the creation of price

strategies and their implementation should be left to the marketing department,

simply because they understand the consumer best and in today’s globalised

world, pricing focused on the consumer is a necessity. Therefore it would be a

great idea to build a pricing team, which comes from both the marketing and

controlling background and is hierarchically beneath the marketing department.

This way, value pricing and ideal strategies which combine both pricing and other

marketing aspects would build a strong brand and increase consistency. Most

importantly, the executive level has to understand and support the importance of

such an expert pricing department and ideally, even push forward into new pricing

possibilities. This way, pricing strategies which are customized for the company,

product or service and the target groups can be created.

74

Profit Growth

One of the main goals of companies is to improve profits. There are generally two

ways to do that. Either a company cuts costs or they increase prices. Cutting costs

can be the less transparent strategy, but it can also lead to lower quality or other

unwanted social consequences such as a large number of employee resignations.

A company should closely monitor the usefulness of cutting costs, because it

normally always comes with a price, be it the brand image, the company

reputation or product quality. With the increase of value pricing strategies, many

have understood that it makes much more sense to do top line growth.

Instead of trying to achieve certain volume targets and cutting the price in the

process, profit targets help to have sustainable growth. It also helps to strengthen

the brand instead of risking brand equity by decreasing prices to a level they can’t

come back from. Increasing brand value drives pricing power and studies have

shown that companies should focus on innovations and marketing as a unit to

improve the value of a brand. Therefore pricing has more than just influence on

profits, it also strongly drives brand value and image of a company.

With the matter of innovations, there should be a development team constantly

working on new product ideas and innovations. These innovations should then be

checked against their profitability and acceptance in the market and unprofitable

ideas should be cut by the department itself. Most importantly, the innovation

should be based on some need or benefit for the target group. Many companies

just focus on their internal ideas and inspirations without knowing anything about

what the consumer might think about it. Innovation is key, but only when it

focuses on the customer.

Creating a new pricing plan

The following steps show how a company can find out if their ideal pricing

strategy lies within the possibilities of dynamic pricing, price differentiation or

other value pricing strategies. These steps should all take place in a pricing

strategy to ensure optimized success.

75

Objective

The final step of building a better pricing strategy is the analysis of success.

Without tracking the results of a new pricing strategy, a company will not know if

they are on the right track. Accordingly, the first step has to set the goals and

measurements for the upcoming strategy. Then, using key performance indicators

to track established goals, the consequences of new pricing techniques should be

closely monitored. These goals and KPIs are directly linked to the pricing strategy

established in the process. While there are general KPIs, others have to be

specifically matched to the needs and characteristics of the individual situation.

Obviously, since dynamic pricing and price differentiation in general aim at

improving profits, a higher profit goal could be measures by using KPI’s such as

daily sales, average price, average profit margins, online conversion rates and

others. For e-commerce, tracking an increased conversion rate could use the

shopping cart abandonment rate, click-through rates, website traffic and bounce

rates. These can be easily tracked with tools such as Google analytics.

Tracking the success of dynamic coupons online also works accurately. When the

goal is to increase the retention rate of coupons, it is easy to measure the average

retention rate, the type of product or service for which the coupon is used and the

average amount spend on the purchase.

If coupons are distributed by multiple online channels, a company should go as far

as to implement individual tracking links into the different websites in order to be

able to determine where the consumer began his journey and where he found the

coupons. This being said, performance reports are important for all areas of

marketing and should be used to gather further insights on the customer journey

and behaviour. This way, future strategies can benefit from the findings.

Market Research

Company, customer, competitor. At the beginning of all marketing strategies is

the analysis of the internal and external environment. The theory and expert

interviews have shown that it is always most important to know how the

consumer thinks and acts. This also holds true for pricing strategies. One part of

this process is to know the consumers preferences and especially their willingness

76

to pay. Thorough market research needs to establish customer profiles and

characteristics, price sensitivities and the true value of a product or service from

the customers’ point of view. Only then can marketers use segmentation to target

specific customer groups with pricing strategies and promotions. As theory has

indicated, knowing the reference prices and therefore being able to influence them

through techniques like anchors or fencing will ultimately make a pricing strategy

work. For reference prices, quantitative marketing research could deliver average

price expectations and value perceptions, while new pricing strategies could be

tested in qualitative settings such as focus groups or mystery shopping to

determine whether the explanation of prices is properly mediated.

But even if marketing research has been successfully conducted it is very

important to continuously validate these results in order to find changes in trends,

consumer behaviour or value perception. There is no clear timeline on how often

market research should be conducted, as it often depends on the type of product

and its life-cycle. For electronics, trends and consumer price sensitivities change

more rapidly than for products with less innovative changes and longer life-

cycles. Still, even for less innovative products, pricing can offer many ways of

generating profits and research should be considered of utmost priority. Therefore

marketing research is always a good investment and builds the foundation of any

successful marketing or pricing strategy.

This also goes for market research focused on innovations. Only when companies

understand what the consumer wants and needs do they have a chance to bring

value to the consumer and find a unique selling proposition.

Segmentation

Segmentation is not only important for marketing in general, but especially to

create segments with different price sensitivities and therefore being able to

charge different prices. The smaller these segments, the more consumer surplus

can be absorbed and the more profitable a business becomes. Although micro

segmentation appears quite lucrative, it is also very costly and requires a lot of

effort. Still, by calculating the additional benefits and costs of micro segmentation

and finding the ideal degree of segmentation, companies can assure they are using

the most profitable strategy for their products. These segments will also later be

77

used to target promotions and other marketing measures. If a company wants to

implement price differentiation for segments, then market research with focus on

willingness to pay is most important to do the segmentation.

Unique selling proposition

Another important aspect, not only for pricing but also for marketing in general, is

the unique selling proposition of a product. A USP helps to differentiate a product

and adds to the value story, which in turn helps to justify price strategies. For

some products, the USP could be a characteristic of the product, a technological

advantages, a design or brand value or part of customer service. For a company to

improve their success and stay competitive, it is essential to understand the value

of ones’ product and advocate it against competitors. While the USP can be used

for promotions and in communications, it also helps to convey price strategies. At

this point of the price strategy process, a company needs to determine their USP

and build their strategies around it.

Transparency strategy

Going back to the online area of pricing, the theory has shown that transparency is

a double-edged sword, which can deeply influence not only the fairness

perceptions of price, but also the overall relationship between the consumer and

the company. Researchers have shown that companies should pursue certain

transparency strategies to overcome the problems of transparency and stimulate a

positive customer response. At the same time, companies should stay truthful,

since negative backlash can easily arise from deception and manipulation

attempts. Here, pricing and branding have to be considered together. By

increasing the goodwill of a company and therefore creating a positive and

trustworthy image, the consumer is less likely to doubt a company’s intention and

complain about their prices. In order to create such a relationship, companies have

to be aware of the needs of the consumer and make it their goal to satisfy those

needs. Goodwill also closely connects with transparency, because being open with

customers builds a strong relationship of trust. A company should also be

consistent in order to improve the relationship to the customer. Delivering a clear

message and a consistent brand and attitude increases reliability. In the end, it’s

also about having satisfied customers, because if the customer is happy with a

78

company, in the end he will be more willing to invest to keep such the

relationship. Therefore transparency about prices and quality, as seen in theory

and in the empirical analysis have indeed a strong influence on customers.

Therefore companies should at least question if their current standing on

transparency is enough to stimulate customer trust.

Pricing strategy

Finally it’s all about how the pricing should be made in the future. The learnings

from this thesis can help to establish certain possibilities in price discrimination

and dynamic pricing. If all prior steps of this model were successfully handled,

the results should already indicate which pricing strategy would make the most

sense. Again, this is all about knowing the consumer. With the results from

research, the segmentation and the value of the unique selling proposition, the

company should spend time to develop the potential strategy. It’s absolutely

necessary to be sure that the consumer will be able to understand how the strategy

works and that these strategies are based on market research findings. It’s even

possible to conduct further research in trial runs to test a new strategy.

Price differentiation is something that can be done for any kind of product which

attracts different customer segments. The easiest versions would be student

discounts, senior discounts and group discounts. These are easily done by

checking identification and can be implemented by most stores and online shops.

For products which can be delivered in different versions with varying values,

second-degree price differentiation can be implemented. An example could be a

limited access to a gym only at special times for a lower price than an all-access

card. It also includes the storage space on a smartpone or a limited edition colour

which is more expensive than the regular model. In the end, it’s about determining

the different values for the segments and skimming them with the right price. If

anything, companies should move away from a cost-plus pricing.

Dynamic pricing is more specific and has been proven very effective in many

channels. Changing prices over time is also a mostly accepted pricing technique,

especially for airlines, hotels, cruise ships and other forms of touristic activities.

Even for products in traditional channels, more and more opportunities of

dynamic pricing have arisen in the past. Electronic price tags, where price changes

79

are as simple as on the internet have the ability to change the face of offline

pricing. This way, costs in offline channels can be kept to a minimum and price

changes are done easily. This could make sense for electronics or department

stores, which are much more frequented in the evening and on weekends.

In order to truly grasp willingness to pay, companies should try to personalize

pricing, although as seen throughout this thesis, if it cannot be explained and

properly communicated, it might have negative repercussions. A good way to

avoid any negative backlash are dynamic coupons as part of loyalty programmes

based on prior buying patterns and behaviour. These coupons are especially easy

to use for e-commerce, where past purchase data can be stores and cookies help to

track online activities. Using e-mail or pop-ups at the end of the purchase to

deliver certain coupons is a relatively easy task. Another option is to give discount

on the next purchase, which rewards loyal customers and gives an incentive to

shop again.

There are many possibilities to implement pricing strategies. Marketers should

also implement loyalty programs and improve customer service and experience to

tie the consumer to their brand. Examples of loyalty programs could be a point

system, where collecting points gives the customer the opportunity of a discount

or special customer treatment. These point systems should be clear and concise

and ultimately very simple to understand. Another possibility would be to

implement tiered systems, where the reward increases with loyalty, as done with

airline mile clubs. There are many possibilities with loyalty programmes. The

most important point is to keep existing customers happy and give them a reason

to purchase again.

In the end, anything where the consumer can chose between different values

offers a way to perfectly attract different price sensitivities and maximize sales

and profits. If companies do not have enough expertise in pricing and have not yet

been able to put together a pricing team, they can use consultancies to develop the

strategies and help with the implementation.

80

Implementation

Even with the best strategy, the implementation of a pricing strategy should be as

meticulously planned as the strategy behind it.

If the previous steps of the model have shown that the company should indeed

pursue a dynamic pricing strategy, they have increasing opportunities to use

professional tools. Because the topic of dynamic pricing in e-commerce has

gained more importance, online service contractors have appeared, who specialize

in processing the massive amount of data and give automated recommendations.

One such service contractor in the German area is “metoda”, which focuses on

offering companies a Another alternative provider is ActivePivot, which

consolidates data from catalogues, inventory applications, web analytics systems

and online competitor pricing to give meaningful price indicators which allow to

respond to market changes and opportunities. Since it takes a lot of time, effort

and money to collect findings personally and process big data, for many

companies a good alternative can be to choose such a provider to outsource.

Although this kind of financial investment seems to be targeted at large e-

commerce companies, smaller companies also have chances to use dynamic

pricing and even offline channels have certain tools at hand. With electronic shelf

labels, brick and mortar retailers also have increasing power over immediate price

changes.

Obviously, dynamic pricing is not suitable for all companies and products equally.

If the first steps have shown that other price differentiation strategies or even

other forms of value pricing make more sense, they can keep the following in

mind.

Especially when using a direct price discriminatory technique by putting

consumers together in a segment, communication is key. Teaching the value story

and the reasons for the price change to employees can help to satisfy curious

customers, and will slowly lead to an overall higher acceptance of a new pricing

strategy. Most importantly, a company should not just implement a pricing

strategy without thoroughly following the first steps. If so, it could turn out that

the value was over- or underestimated and wrongly priced, which could not only

cause a consumer to avoid a product or company in the future, it could in the

81

worst case also tarnish the brand image and have long-term consequences on

brand equity. New pricing strategies should not be forced out too early on, but a

company should rather take its time and if in doubt use small trial runs to test

prices and market research to confirm price sensitivities and willingness to pay.

The perfect pricing strategy takes time and effort and is not done overnight. But

when looking at the effect of an improved pricing strategy on profits, it has a great

impact on margins and on the brand, which can be strengthened. In the end, it is

definitiely worth it to invest in the right price.

82

Appendices

Appendix 1 - Thesis Questionnaire

What are the major changes that occurred in pricing over recent years?

In general, what kind of pricing should companies do?

Do you think the internet actually offers new ways of price discrimination?

What kind of new methods do you know about? Which kind of price discrimination would you

recommend for to a company?

Reference Prices:

Do you believe that reference prices differ between offline and online channels?

Do you believe that reference prices differ between different cultures? Why do you think that

is the case?

Which other factors have influence on reference prices? Does this, in your opinion, hold for all

kinds of products?

Can you imagine a situation where the reference price of a product has no influence on the

decision process?

What ways of influence does a company have on the reference price?

Transparency:

Do you believe that more online transparency influences people to spend more time looking

for price information?

What are the main changes that arise with the internet for consumers?

What are the consequences of higher transparency?

For which kind of product do people spend more time looking on the internet? Do only certain

kind of people look for information?

Do you believe that transparency influences the perception of fairness because consumers

can build up their knowledge and experience?

How does the consumer react to transparency?

What other factors have influence on fairness perception?

Which consequences does the feeling of fairness or unfairness have for the customer/company

relationship?

How can a company influence the fairness perception of a consumer?

Does transparency have an influence on the willingness to pay?

What other factors have influence on willingness to pay?

Does this apply to all consumers or are there differences?

How can companies use price transparency to their advantage?

What are the advantages of internet transparency for companies? Do you see new pricing

possibilities and better consumer knowledge as the main advantages? If not, what are the most

important advantages?

Do you believe that the main disadvantages are the increased transparency, especially in

terms of arbitrage risks? What other disadvantages can you imagine? Do these differ with

industries?

Do you think that the overall advantages are greater than the disadvantages? Do you know of

any situation where this might not be the case? Industries, products? Give an example.

How can companies use transparency to their advantage?

83

Arbitrage:

Do you think the internet has actively increased the risk of arbitrage?

Which other effect does the internet have on arbitrage?

Are there certain products for which arbitrage is more likely than for others? Which industries are

more affected than others?

In your opinion, do access to markets, decreasing transportation costs and growing free

trade zones decrease the cost of arbitrage?

Can you think of any other factors that have a higher or equal influence on arbitrage?

How do companies protect themselves from arbitrage? How can marketing work against arbitrage?

Dynamic pricing:

Do you think that dynamic pricing is generally considered an unfair pricing technique by the

consumer? What is the most likely reaction of the consumer?

What are possible consequences of dynamic pricing? How would you go to avert the

risks/negative consequences or change the consumers mind?

Do you know of famous examples of dynamic pricing that may or may not have been successful?

Why?

Can you imagine any products where individual prices are accepted by the consumer?

Do you think that dynamic pricing works rather with perishable goods than non-perishable

goods? Why does it work with these products but not with others?

Can you imagine other industries where individual pricing could be an option?

How can a company take advantage of dynamic pricing?

Do you consider dynamic pricing to be important for the future or is it merely a trend?

Do you think that consumers change enough for more individual pricing techniques to become

possible? In which way would a consumer have to change in order for dynamic pricing to work?

Can Companies influence the consumer enough for such a change?

Do you think that individual pricing can only be realized in online channels because

implementation in offline channels is too costly?

What are the main cost factors that cause the differences in costs?

What are the greatest challenges for companies concerning the implementation of dynamic

pricing?

Would you recommend a company to pursue dynamic pricing? What would dynamic pricing

indicate for marketing in general? What other marketing measures would have to be implemented?

NYOP:

Do you believe that NYOP transactions are the easiest way to capture the consumers’

willingness to pay?

With which kind of products does NYOP work?

What is the first thing that comes to your mind about NYOP transactions (products, platforms,

industries, cases, etc.)? Can you think of any other techniques that work similarly?

Is NYOP successful because the consumer determines the price himself and therefore feels a

higher sense of fairness?

Does this work with all products? How can a company positively influence this process?

Promotions:

Do you believe that the majority of consumers takes advantage of coupons?

What influences a consumer to pursue coupons?

Which kind of consumer pursues coupons etc.? Are there products where more consumers try to

find a cheaper price and others where they don’t care?

84

How can a company use this knowledge to implement coupons? (Dynamic coupons?)

Appendix 2 - Thesis Fragebogen

Was hat sich in der Preispolitik der letzten Jahre geändert?

Welche Art von Pricing sollte ein Unternehmen implementieren?

Glauben Sie, dass uns das Internet neue Möglichkeiten der Preis- Differenzierung bietet? Kennen Sie ein Beispiel? Welcher Form der Preis- Diskriminierung hat Ihrer Meinung nach die

größte Relevanz? Nach welchen Kriterien würden Sie Preis diskriminieren?

Referenzpreise:

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis eines Konsumenten in offline und online Kanälen

unterscheidet? Auf welche Art unterscheidet sich der Referenzpreis?

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis zwischen verschiedenen Kulturen oder Ländern

unterscheidet? Welche Gründe gibt es dafür?

Welche anderen Faktoren können Einfluss auf den Referenzpreis haben? Gibt es dabei

Unterschiede bei verschiedenen Produkten?

Gibt es eine Kaufsituation bei der der Referenzpreis keinen Einfluss auf die Entscheidung hat?

Wie kann ein Unternehmen den Referenzpreis beeinflussen?

Transparenz:

Was waren die bedeutendsten Veränderungen die das Internet für den Konsumenten gebracht hat?

/ Was sind die Konsequenzen von höherer Transparenz?

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass eine höhere Online Transparenz dazu führt, dass Konsumenten

mehr Zeit mit der Suche nach Preis-Informationen verbringen?

Für welche Art von Produkt wird die meiste Suche nach Informationen verbracht? Wie würden Sie

den Konsumenten beschreiben, der intensiv und häufig nach Informationen sucht?

Hat Transparenz einen Einfluss auf die Wahrnehmung von Fairness eines Konsumenten?

Welche weiteren Faktoren haben Einfluss auf das Gefühl von Fairness?

Und welche Konsequenzen hat (Un-) Fairness für die Beziehung zwischen Kunde und

Unternehmen?

Wie kann ein Unternehmen Fairness beeinflussen?

Haben Kosten- und Preistransparenz einen direkten Einfluss auf die willingness-to-pay eines

Konsumenten? In welchem Ausmaß?

Welche weiteren Faktoren haben Ihrer Meinung nach einen Einfluss auf die willingness-to-pay?

Gilt dies für alle Konsumenten gleichermaßen oder sehen Sie Unterschiede?

Wie kann ein Unternehmen Transparenz als Vorteil nutzen?

Denken Sie dass die größten Vorteile von Transparenz die neuen Möglichkeiten der

Preispolitik und Marktforschung/Big Data sind? Falls nein, was halten Sie für am wichtigsten?

Sind Sie der Meinung dass die größten Nachteile die erhöhte Transparenz für Kunden und

die Gefahr von Arbitrage sind? Welche anderen Nachteile sehen Sie? Unterscheiden sich die

Vor- und Nachteile in verschiedenen Industrien/Branchen?

Glauben Sie, dass die Vorteile von Transparenz die Nachteile überwiegen? Für welche

Situation/Industrie/Produkt könnte dies nicht der Fall sein?

Arbitrage:

Hat das Internet das Risiko und die Möglichkeiten zu Arbitrage vergrößert?

85

Gibt es spezifische Produkte für die eher zutrifft als für andere? Welche Industrien leiden am

meisten unter dem Einfluss von Arbitrage?

Glauben Sie, dass hauptsächlich der erleichterte Zugang zu Märkten, geringere

Transportkosten und Freihandelszonen die Arbitrage Kosten verringern?

Welche anderen Faktoren spielen hierbei eine Rolle?

Wie kann Marketing im Allgemeinen Arbitrage entgegen wirken?

Dynamic Pricing:

Wird dynamic pricing im Allgemeinen als unfair angesehen?

Welche Art dynamic pricings kennen Sie? Wie reagiert der Konsument auf dynamic pricing?

Gibt es Möglichkeiten negative Konsequenzen zu umgehen – wenn ja, wie?

Kennen sie bekannte Beispiele von dynamic pricing, die erfolgreich waren oder gescheitert sind?

Haben Sie eine Erklärung warum?

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass dynamic pricing eher bei vergänglichen Produkten/Services

funktioniert?

Für welche weitere Art Produkt funktioniert dynamic pricing? Warum funktioniert es mit diesen

aber nicht mit anderen Produkten?

Welche Vorteile hat das Unternehmen durch dynamic pricing?

Ist dynamic pricing die Zukunft der Preispolitik?

Glauben Sie, dass der Konsument insoweit beeinflusst werden kann, dass es mehr Möglichkeiten

für dynamic pricing geben könnte?

Wie kann ein Unternehmen den Konsumenten beeinflussen?

Stimmen Sie zu, dass dynamic pricing nur über Online Kanäle möglich ist, da die Kosten bei

Offline Kanälen zu hoch sind?

Was bewirkt den Unterschied in den Kosten?

Welche Herausforderungen bestehen bei der Implementierung von dynamic pricing?

Welche Auswirkungen hat diese Art von Pricing auf das Marketing im Allgemeinen?

Sollte jedes Unternehmen danach streben, dynamic pricing zu nutzen? Was wäre eine Alternative?

Wie kann ein Unternehmen dynamic pricing zu seinem Vorteil nutzen?

NYOP:

Was ist das erste, an das Sie bei NYOP Transaktionen denken? (Produkte, Industrien,

Plattformen?)

Ist NYOP der einfachste Weg, um willingness to pay einzufangen?

Kennen Sie eine andere Preisstrategie, die ähnlich funktioniert?

Glauben Sie der Erfolg von NYOP liegt daran, dass Konsumenten den Preis selbst

bestimmen dürfen und nicht an die Angaben eines Unternehmens gebunden sind?

Funktioniert dieses Prinzip mit jedem Produkt?

Wie kann ein Unternehmen einen positiven Einfluss auf den Konsumenten ausüben?

Coupons:

Glauben Sie, dass der Großteil der Konsumenten die Vorteile von Coupons nutzt?

Welche Art von Konsument nutzt die Vorteile von Coupons bewusst?

Gibt es Produkte bei denen generell eine höhere Prozentzahl von Coupons benutzt wird? Wie kann

ein Unternehmen dieses Wissen nutzen? – Wie können sie effektiv Coupons einsetzen?

Sind dynamische Coupons die bessere Alternative? Was würden Sie einem Unternehmen raten?

86

Appendix 3 - Interview Daniel Korany

Was hat sich in der Preispolitik der letzten Jahre geändert?

Die Hauptänderung ist, dass der Konsument einen stärkeren Einfluss hat. Durch Transparenz von

Preis und Qualität, haben Konsumenten eine größere Auswahl von Anbietern und Produkten.

Unternehmen haben keine räumliche Differenzierung mehr möglich durch die Transparenz.

Unternehmen haben Interesse, Konsumenten zufrieden zu stellen durch Bewertungen.

Bewertungen sind sehr Einflussreich und entstehen durch die Transparenz von Preis und Qualität.

Was für eine Art Pricing sollte ein Unternehmen heutzutage implementieren?

So differenziert wie möglich, Kanal- und Kundenspezifisch. In B2B geht das sehr gut, bei B2C ist

es durch die Transparenz schwieriger aber Zwischen Kanälen kann man differenzieren.

Mehrwertorientiert, wenn ich super Bewertungen habe oder Wettbewerbsvorteile können sich im

Preis widerspiegeln. Unternehmen haben oft Angst davor das zu nutzen. Transparenz das können

Unternehmen zu ihrem Vorteil nutzen. Qualität sollte Transparenz sein um Preis zu rechtfertigen.

Preis soll im Verhältnis zum Wert stehen. Im Mediengeschäft ist der Price per Klick

wertorientierter als eine Printanzeige. Hier sind genauere Messungen möglich. Mit dem

Preisniedrigmodell kann man gut machen.

Glauben Sie, dass uns das Internet neue Möglichkeiten der Preis- Differenzierung bietet?

Ja

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis eines Konsumenten in offline und online Kanälen

unterscheidet? Gute Frage, ich glaube der ERP hat online ein bisschen an Stärke verloren oder ist neu definiert.

Die Unverbindliche Preisempfehlung spielt online weniger eine Rolle, da man sehr schnell andere

Referenzen einholen kann und so die Fairness beurteilen kann.

Erwartet der Konsument andere Preise online?

Nein das glaube ich nicht

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis zwischen verschiedenen Kulturen oder Ländern

unterscheidet?

Wir launchen eine Kosmetiklinie in Deutschland und den UK, die Preise werden ähnlicher

zwischen verschiedenen Ländern und damit werden auch die Referenzpreise ähnlicher. Schwer zu

sagen.

Welche anderen Faktoren können Einfluss auf den Referenzpreis haben?

Was für eine Art Produkt ist das. Bei Nischenprodukten ist Transparenz nicht so wichtig, je

weniger Angebot es gibt und je weniger es im Kopf ist desto mehr kann das Unternehmen den

Referenzpreis steuern. Gutes Beispiel ist Amazon: Wird als sehr günstig wahr genommen, sind

aber tatsächlich eine der teuersten Anbieter; sie konzentrieren sich auf die meist gesuchtesten

Produkte mit sehr günstigen Preisen, aber das sind nur die Top 10% der Produkte und der Rest ist

sehr teuer.

Unternehmen muss sein Portfolio segmentieren und differenzieren um herauszufinden, in welchem

Bereich sie einen großen Einfluss auf den Referenzpreis haben könnten und das sind sicherlich

nicht die meistgesuchtesten Produkte.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass eine höhere Online Transparenz dazu führt, dass Konsumenten

mehr Zeit mit der Suche nach Preis-Informationen verbringen?

Ja davon würde ich ausgehen.

Was waren die bedeutendsten Veränderungen die das Internet für den Konsumenten

gebracht hat?

Die Kaufentscheidung wird schwieriger. Klar, es gibt mehr Optionen, mehr Produkte,

verschiedene Preise, deshalb braucht er mehr Zeit aber ich glaube das Konsumenten besser Deals

bekommen.

Gibt es dabei Unterschiede bei verschiedenen Produkten?

Bei Industriegütern besteht auch eine gewisse Transparenz, Alibaba verkauft beispielsweise

Zement. Bei Konsumgütern würde ich sagen je komplexer das Produkt, desto länger und

87

schwieriger die Suche.

Versicherungen wäre ein solch komplexes Produkt. Hier könnte man zwei Hypothesen aufstellen:

ist die Suche schon so kompliziert, dass man am Ende doch das Erstbeste nimmt, aber aus privater

Erfahrung eher die zweite Hypothese dass man mehr Zeit damit verbringt weil es einfach zu

komplex ist, man braucht einfach ewig.

Hat Transparenz einen Einfluss auf die Wahrnehmung von Fairness eines Konsumenten?

Ja, wir können uns jetzt ein besseres Bild über Fairness des Preises machen. Wir haben

Transparenz über die Qualität und die Preise. Das hatten wir früher nicht. Die unverbindliche

Preisempfehlung war eine künstliche Transparenz, da Preise immer darunter lagen. Jetzt können

wir uns viel schneller ein Bild machen.

Und welche Konsequenzen hat (Un-) Fairness für die Beziehung zwischen Kunde und

Unternehmen?

Im B2B spreche ich oft von Peak Experiences, ein Moment bei dem man denkt, das war super fair.

Ein Effekt von Preis Fairness würde man auf die ganze Beziehung transferieren, das hat

langfristigen Einfluss auf die Kundenbeziehung. Auch wenn spätere Preise nicht ganz so niedrig

wären wie erwünscht, würde der Kunde es als fair ansehen. Bei Konsumenten ist der Effekt meiner

Meinung nach nicht so stark, man bindet nicht über faire Preise sondern über Loyalty Programme.

Ansonsten müsste man immer den fairen Preis haben, der Effekt ist eher kurzfristig.

Haben Kosten- und Preistransparenz einen direkten Einfluss auf die willingness to pay eines

Konsumenten? Ja

Welche weiteren Faktoren haben Ihrer Meinung nach einen Einfluss auf die willingness to

pay?

Rieseneinfluss haben die Käuferbewertungen, die Geschwindigkeit der Abwicklung, dann meine

persönliche Situation: wie schnell brauche ich das Produkt, Geschenk oder Für mich selbst,

Zahlungsbereitschaft für Geschenk wäre größer. Ansonsten die klassischen Produktfaktoren.

Ich würde die Hypothese aufstellen: Harte Faktoren wie Einkommen haben keinen starken

Einfluss auf die Zahlungsbereitschaft. In B2B wären das eher die erwarteten Einsparungen.

Denken Sie dass die größten Vorteile von Transparenz die neuen Möglichkeiten der

Preispolitik und Marktforschung/Big Data sind?

Genau, was auch wichtig ist sind die besseren Upsell Möglichkeiten. Da ist Amazon der Meister

mit „Kunden kaufen auch“. Ich weiß, dass viele Online Retailer die meisten Profite mit Upselling

machen und den Warenkorb maximieren. Das ist viel einfacher geworden für Unternehmen.

Hat das Internet das Risiko und die Möglichkeiten zu Arbitrage vergrößert?

Das habe ich gar nicht als stark wahrgenommen. Das kriege ich immer als großes Problem der

Pharmabranche. Manche kleineren Produkte werden dann vielleicht im Ausland gekauft

beispielsweise Kosmetikprodukte werden in England gekauft aufgrund des Wechselkurses. Die

Preisspanne zwischen Ländern nimmt ab, Preise werden insgesamt ähnlicher.

Welche Industrien leiden am meisten unter dem Einfluss von Arbitrage?

Mit Sicherheit gibt es da Unterschiede, bei Pharma ist Arbitrage ein riesen Thema. Bei Software

Projekten ist das gar kein Thema. Automobilbranche ist noch ein großes Thema. Schweizer

Automobilhändler gehen wegen dem Wechselkurs gerne nach Deutschland um Autos zu kaufen,

auch mit Zoll ist es noch günstiger. Ob das onlinespezifisch ist... ja online befeuert Arbitrage durch

Transparenz.

Glauben Sie, dass die Vorteile von Transparenz die Nachteile überwiegen?

Für Konsumenten und Unternehmen überwiegen die Vorteile. Es ist aber wichtig, dass die

Unternehmen müssen ihre Organisation umstellen und nicht hängen bleiben. Das ist die

Schwierigkeit, weil sie sich nicht anpassen können, wenn man mit Konkurrenz nicht umgehen

kann dann ist man nicht wettbewerbsfähig genug.

Glauben Sie, dass hauptsächlich der erleichterte Zugang zu Märkten, geringere

Transportkosten und Freihandelszonen die Arbitrage Kosten verringern? Ja, sehr einleuchtend.

Wie kann Marketing im Allgemeinen Arbitrage entgegen wirken?

88

Man sollte die Preisspanne klein halten. Man kann mit Transportrichtlinien spielen und die

Lieferungen auf bestimmte Länder begrenzt. Man kann auch sagen, ich führe verschiedene

Marken oder neue Abpackungsgrößen ein, das verhindert Produkttransparenz, dass es im Ausland

günstiger sein könnte zu kaufen.

Wird dynamic pricing im Allgemeinen als unfair angesehen?

Die Regel in B2B ist, keiner bezahlt für sein Kilo Stahl gleich viel, auch bei Software gibt es

Preislisten und man bekommt 60-80% Rabatt, hier sind die Branchen daran gewohnt aber nutzen

Informationen von besseren Deals um zu verhandeln. In B2C funktioniert das, solange es nicht

willkürlich ist. Der Differentiator ist der Zeitpunkt des Kaufs, so lässt sich das erklären. Bei einer

Auktion ist es der Unterschied wer am Ende bietet. Auf Basis von Big Data behaupte ich,

funktioniert das nicht. Es muss erklärt werden können. Dann klappt das gut. Da ist auch ein

Lerneffekt der Konsumenten dabei. Man hat gelernt, dass keiner das gleiche für ein Flugticket

zahlt.

Glauben Sie, dass der Konsument insoweit beeinflusst werden kann, dass es mehr

Möglichkeiten für dynamic pricing geben könnte?

Das geht schon, bei Kinos könnte man dynamic Pricing machen. Sorgt immer für Widerstand zu

Beginn, aber mit Erklärung und gutem Kommunikationsmaterial kann sich der Konsument daran

gewöhnen.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass dynamic pricing eher bei vergänglichen Produkten/Services

funktioniert?

Ja, Kapazitäten spielen dabei einen wichtigen Faktor. Das geht nicht für andere Produkte. Bei

Parfüms kann man auch differenzieren mit einem Treuesystem. Man kann eine Mitgliedschaft

einführen. Man zahlt 100 Euro im Jahr und bekommt 20% Rabatt auf jedes Parfüm, ähnlich wie

bei der Deutschen Bahn.

Stimmen Sie zu, dass dynamic pricing nur über Online Kanäle möglich ist, da die Kosten bei

Offline Kanälen zu hoch sind?

Es gibt’s im Offline Kanal. Bei Fluggesellschaft am Flughafen wenn man ein Upgrade auf

Business möchte. Das bieten Airlines aus dem Nahen Osten an, man kann sagen wie viel ist man

bereit zu zahlen? Beim Einstieg wird gesagt ob du den Business Platz bekommst. Bei Ebay

Auktionen feuert man sich gegenseitig an, das treibt den Preis. Wenn man hier einen Anker

einbaut, dann würde das gut funktionieren.

Offline immer teurer, aber bei dem Beispiel der Fluggesellschafts Auktionen wird das auch durch

Software geregelt, dass keine Mehrkosten entstehen. Kostendifferenz durch Personal,

Gebäudekosten etc.

Welche Herausforderungen bestehen bei der Implementierung von dynamic pricing?

Die Schwierigkeit ist das Problem des shitstorms. Wenn jemand rausfindet es ist unfair, meldet

sich an andere Kunden im B2B Bereich und verbreitet das Wort. Das ist gefährlich. Negative

WOM, Konsumenten können sich gegenseitig anstacheln, die Produkte nicht mehr zu kaufen und

machen es sich zur Mission, das Unternehmen schlecht zu machen. Die Hater im Netz sind eine

Gefahr.

Sollte jedes Unternehmen danach streben, dynamic pricing zu nutzen?

Ja ich würde das empfehlen, aber man muss einen guten Roll-out plan haben und sollte nichts über

Nacht erzwingen. Man kann mit einigen Kundensegmente starten, mit einer kleinen

Differenzierungsspanne starten und dann nach und nach erweitern.

Man kann eine Konditionale Roadmap erstellen und KPI festlegen z.B. Um wie viel Prozent

können die Bewertungen schlechter werden.

Welche Auswirkungen hat diese Art von Pricing auf das Marketing im Allgemeinen?

Marktforschung ist sehr wichtig um richtig zu differenzieren, Unternehmen vernachlässigen das

manchmal. Dann ist auch wichtig, unfaire Gefühle mit etwas angenehmem zu verbinden. Man

kann ein Produkt Upgrade machen, es könnte mit Promotions verknüpft werden. Verknüpfung mit

positivem Marketing um Preiserhöhung besser umzusetzen.

Was ist das erste, an das Sie bei NYOP Transaktionen denken?

89

Das ist schwer für Verhandlungen, weil man als Unternehmen den Anker selbst als Referenz

setzen möchte. Ich würde das gar nicht als NYOP einstufen, eher als Auktion weil der Preis

letztendlich durch den Mechanismus gesteuert wird. Ich kenne das von Cafés oder bei Trinkgeld,

da bin ich skeptisch. Es muss sozial erwünscht sein, viel Geld da zu lassen. Bei Trinkgeld ist es

nicht immer erwünscht, kulturelle Unterschiede aber es gibt keinen richtigen, höchstens einen

kulturellen Anker (Trinkgeld bei uns: 5-10%). Da kann ein Unternehmen mehr rausholen, wenn

man einen Anker setzt. Ein gutes Beispiel ist Taxifahren in den USA. Man wird gefragt wie viel

Trinkgeld möchten sie geben? Möchten sie überhaupt was geben? 20, 25 oder 30% Trinkgeld?

Wenn man da sieht, bei diesem Anker traut sich kein Mensch unter 10% zu geben. Das würde

auch beim Restaurant gehen. Bezahl was du willst, im Durchschnitt wird so und so viel bezahlt.

Bei Museen geht es nicht um Profite, sondern ein kulturelles Angebot, das ist sozial erwünscht,

große Zahlungen werden als Spende gesehen. Das macht Sinn.

Ist NYOP der einfachste Weg, um willingness to pay einzufangen?

Ja, aber es gibt auch andere Wege. Man hat nicht immer die Option eine Auktion zu machen,

macht nur Sinn bei einem begrenzten Angebot. Willingness to pay kann verloren gehen wenn es

um Notwendigkeit geht. Guter aber kein optimaler Mechanismus, Yield Management ist besser

um Profite abzuschöpfen. Ich erinnere mich an die Olympischen Spiele. Beim Ticketgeschäft gibt

es soziale Anforderungen bestimmte Segmente zu bedienen, Interesse low oder mid segment zu

bedienen. Diese Leute werden durch Auktionen ausgeschlossen.

Glauben Sie der Erfolg von NYOP liegt daran, dass Konsumenten den Preis selbst

bestimmen dürfen und nicht an die Angaben eines Unternehmens gebunden sind?

Ja, aber es klappt nicht wenn eine Notwendigkeit besteht, z.B. muss man von A nach B fliegen

aber Business Class braucht man nicht. Für manche Dinge gibt es eine unbegrenzte

Preisbereitschaft, daher klappt das eher bei „nice to have“ Produkten. Dann ist das ein super

Mechanismus.

Wie kann ein Unternehmen einen positiven Einfluss auf den Konsumenten ausüben?

Alle meine Überlegungen gehen zum Anker. Ankerwirkung ist irrational, wenn man hohe Zahlen

genannt bekommt, wird man automatisch auch eine höhere Zahl nennen. Der Durchschnittliche

Flugpreis kann angegeben werden um eine Preisvorstellung zu vermitteln. Außerdem kann man

die Vorteile des Produkts auszuzeichnen, um wahrgenommenen Wert zu erhöhen.

Glauben Sie, dass der Großteil der Konsumenten die Vorteile von Coupons nutzt?

Ich würde behaupten, der Effekt von Coupons verpufft ziemlich schnell. Man wird überflutet von

Coupons. Ich finde die eher problematisch da Coupons für ein Ramsch-Image sorgen, man macht

weniger Schnäppchen sondern zerstört eher an Wert.

Welche Art von Konsument nutzt die Vorteile von Coupons bewusst?

Der klassische Schnäppchenjäger, muss nicht Arm sein, aber Gerechtigkeit ist wichtig, er mochte

nicht verarscht werden. Es gibt das Gefühl „Das System überführt zu haben“, ich glaube das ist der

größere Antrieb als tatsächliche Kostenersparnis

Was würden Sie einem Unternehmen raten?

Kommt darauf an, aber grundsätzlich eher kein gutes Tool. Unternehmen machen teilweise viele

Verluste durch Coupons. Es gibt ein großes Risiko und ist sehr spekulativ. Promotion bei der man

klar sahen muss Ziel ist, Awareness in einem bestimmten Gebiet(regional) aber Ziel ist nicht

Umsatz oder Profit.

Appendix 4 - Interview Norbert Weisshaar

Was hat sich in der Preispolitik der letzten Jahre geändert?

In Deutschland dominiert der Preis, durch das Nachkriegs-Geschäftsmodell. Beispiel niedrige

Lebensmittelpreise z.B. Aldi; aufgrund der Rabattforderungen muss auf Qualität verzichtet werden

daher die künstliche Aromen in Kuchen. Schnäppchenjagd und Preiskampf wird stärker, Hebel des

Preises 1% Preisänderungen, 12,5% mehr Erträge. Die Dominanz des Preises hat zugenommen,

Geiz ist geil und Aldi-infiziert.

Preisvergleich nur noch einen Klick entfernt, Verkäufer verlieren ihre Verkaufsargumente,

90

Verkäufer müssen ihre Value Story erzählen und in den Zielgruppen intelligenter arbeiten. Nur

Produkt und Preis interessiert, Service ist nicht mehr so relevant.

Glauben Sie, dass uns das Internet neue Möglichkeiten der Preis- Differenzierung bietet?

Ja, man kann sich jetzt richtig positionieren. VW hat 12 Marken unter einem Dach, alle Marken

funktionieren. Preisdifferenzierung deutlich im Bereich des Tourismus.

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis eines Konsumenten in offline und online Kanälen

unterscheidet?

Viele machen keinen Unterschied mehr, aber grundsätzlich höherer Referenzpreis da man das

Erlebnis hat, einen netten Verkäufer, hier kann die Kommunikation zum Preis besser aufgebaut

werden. Bei Produkten für Leidenschaft, Hobby achten wir weniger auf den Preis und damit eine

höhere Zahlungsbereitschaft, Situation: Entspannt, Urlaub, in der Not gibt man mehr aus. Wieso

habe ich mehr bezahlt im offline Kanal? Netter Verkäufer, gute Beratung erhöht die

Zahlungsbereitschaft

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis zwischen verschiedenen Kulturen oder Ländern

unterscheidet?

Ja, Nahrungsmittel in den verschiedenen Ländern, Frankreich oder Italien gibt viel mehr aus als

die Deutschen, dafür ist in Deutschland ein dickes Auto vor der Tür, Werte die nach außen wirken.

Die soziale Schere geht weiter auseinander, Kultur und Kaufkraft zwingen die Menschen zu Aldi

und Lidl, da nicht mehr Geld – aus reinem Sachzwang.

Welche anderen Faktoren können Einfluss auf den Referenzpreis haben?

Wettbewerbsverhalten, Transparenz dass es beim Onlineshop das Produkt günstiger gibt;

Abstriche/Abschlag machen z.B. bei Service, Verfügbarkeit, Schnäppchenmentalität nicht nur

günstig zu kaufen sondern Verwandten und Bekannten zeigen zu können : „ich habe ein

Schnäppchen gemacht“

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass eine höhere Online Transparenz dazu führt, dass Konsumenten

mehr Zeit mit der Suche nach Preis-Informationen verbringen? Ja

Für welche Art von Produkt wird die meiste Suche nach Informationen verbracht?

Manche suchen zuerst nach Preis, während andere auch nach Bewertungen suchen auf Blogs etc.

Käuferverhalten das auf Beschreibungen und Bewertungen achtet

Hat Transparenz einen Einfluss auf die Wahrnehmung von Fairness eines Konsumenten?

Ja, bei guten Bewertungen von Produkten und Services ist der Konsument eher bereit was zu

bezahlen; bei Hobbys ist man bereit mehr zu bezahlen; was heißt fair? Premiumauto Porsche

Cayenne ist keine Design-Offenbarung aber der Konsument will dieses Label haben, keine

Verhandlungen möglich mit Verkäufern

Transparenz ist ein Indikator für Marktpreis und konkurrenzfähiger Preis, aber fairer Preis ist

schwer zu definieren, welche Erwartungen und Kaufmotive habe ich? Mit einem Porsche will ich

angeben und bin dementsprechend bereit mehr zu bezahlen

Und welche Konsequenzen hat (Un-) Fairness für die Beziehung zwischen Kunde und

Unternehmen?

Verschiedene Möglichkeiten des Feedbacks, im Restaurant habe ich hohe Erwartungen und meine

Erwartungen wurden nicht getroffen – fatale Folgen wie ein Kieselstein den man ins Wasser wirft.

Negatives Image durch negatives WOM, Feedback über Blogs und Plattformen,

Gefahr da es sehr subjektiv ist und es immer auf die einzelnen Feedbacks ankommt

Wie kann ein Unternehmen Fairness beeinflussen?

Transparenz über den Mehrwert, um Preis zu rechtfertigen, Man muss den Preis erklären. Mehr

aufklären, sowohl Verkäufer als auch Kunde. Value Story ist mehr als Produkt und Preis, sondern

gesamter Marketing mix. Segmentierter transportieren, für einen reinen Preiskäufer machen

Mehrwerte keinen Sinn, er achtet nicht auf Zusatzinformationen; Leistung muss klar

Zielgruppenmäßig transportiert werden; mehr Preis für wahrgenommene Mehrleistung: weiche

Faktoren: Freundlichkeit, Service, oder animiert dargestellt auf einer Website.

Haben Kosten- und Preistransparenz einen direkten Einfluss auf die willingness to pay eines

Konsumenten?

91

Ja, wenn transparent gemacht wird was den Preis ausmacht durch z.B. Zusatznutzen, Verkäufer

kann auf Bedürfnislage eingehen, Botschaften warum es kein Discountpreis ist; Beispiel Taschen-

Label mit handgefertigten marokkanischen Taschen, nicht billig aber Gründerin erklärt dass 50%

in Schulprojekte in Beduinenbereichen eingesetzt wird, erhöhter Zahlungsbereitschaft wegen

gutem Gewissen. Viele Unternehmen machen Cost Plus, aber viele haben den Mut nicht sich im

hochqualitativen Preis aufzuhalten. Premium Parkett Hersteller gibt zu schnell nach in den Preisen;

die haben beim Endkonsumenten festgestellt, dass Bereitschaft bei 30% über dem aktuellen Preis

liegt; Rausfinden welcher Preis der Endkonsument bezahlen will. Swarovski Chef hat eine Kette

von exklusiven Rosengeschäften aufgemacht, welches Preissystem? Value Pricing, Umfrage bei

Kunden um den Preis herauszufinden

Wie kann ein Unternehmen Transparenz als Vorteil nutzen?

Ja, man muss die Sprache der Zielgruppe sprechen und Erwartungshaltungen erfüllen, Angebot

nicht in Technoquatsch formulieren sondern klare Botschaften für die gewünschten Zielgruppen;

viele Informieren sich vorher und gehen dann in den Laden oder man bekommt im Laden das

Produkt dreidimensional präsentiert aber man lässt es sich nach Hause liefern

Denken Sie dass die größten Vorteile von Transparenz die neuen Möglichkeiten der

Preispolitik und Marktforschung/Big Data sind? Ja natürlich, Big Data blickt keiner mehr

durch; soll man auf Print oder Media setzen. Herausforderung diese Möglichkeiten auf das

Geschäftsmodell zu übertragen.

Man sollte herausfinden welche Motive steuern den Konsumenten, die Zielgruppe, denn das ist

wichtig für die Preissetzung.

Sind Sie der Meinung dass die größten Nachteile die erhöhte Transparenz für Kunden und

die Gefahr von Arbitrage sind?

Ja, die Unternehmen müssen sich darauf einstellen, weg von Produkt Lebenszyklus und

Preiszyklus, flexibler reagieren und rasch auf Änderungen einstellen, mit Innovationen punkten,

dann wird der Preis nur noch sekundär sein, wichtig ist auch Spezifikationen einzuhalten, Qualität

gleich bleibend; wenn ein Produkt ein Versprechen hat und bei billigen Komponenten floppt das

Produkt, kann sich ein Unternehmen nicht leisten; Termintreue und wettbewerbsfähige Preise.

Glauben Sie, dass die Vorteile von Transparenz die Nachteile überwiegen?

Eine Transparenz, die Leistung verdeutlicht ist ein großer Vorteil, daraus kann ich was machen;

viele haben Angst davor dass Informationen der Kalkulation offen liegen; Value Story auf den

Punkt bringen ob über Wort und Bild oder im Verkaufsgespräch

Transparenz funktioniert für viele Premiumprodukte z.B. Hermes und Kelly Tasche

Menschen wollen sich differenzieren von anderen, Prestige Thema bedienen und dafür wird ein

bestimmter Preis bezahlt

Es gibt ein Delta, bei dem man den Preis akzeptiert. Tankstelle 1 3 Cent billiger aber t2 immer

besonders freundlich, deshalb geht man dahin; falls 4 Cent teurer dann t1.

Hat das Internet das Risiko und die Möglichkeiten zu Arbitrage vergrößert?

Ja, deshalb flexibel auf dem Schirm haben wie sich Angebot und Nachfrage in den verschiedenen

Märkten verhält und dann reagieren

Glauben Sie, dass hauptsächlich der erleichterte Zugang zu Märkten, geringere

Transportkosten und Freihandelszonen die Arbitrage Kosten verringern? Ja

Welche anderen Faktoren spielen hierbei eine Rolle? Schnelligkeit

Wie kann Marketing im Allgemeinen Arbitrage entgegen wirken?

Man muss Kunden immer mehr segmentieren und neue Preispunkte setzen; Zielkundengerecht

setzen und auf den ein oder anderen Kunden verzichten der keine Margen mehr nennt.

Wird dynamic pricing im Allgemeinen als unfair angesehen?

Nein glaube ich nicht, da der Konsument es gar nicht mitbekommt; Media Markt je nach Frequenz

wird der Preis z.B. der Waschmaschine geändert, morgens billiger, abends teurer; gar keinen

Überblick ob Fair oder nicht.

Für bestimmte Produkte hat man klare Preispunkte z.B. für Butter für andere nicht.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass dynamic pricing eher bei vergänglichen Produkten/Services

funktioniert?

92

Ja ganz klar, weil man kann es inhaltlich argumentieren, beispielsweise „die Bananen müssen

raus“. Funktioniert auch für Saisongeschäft z.B. Grill ist im Herbst Winter billiger

Welche Vorteile hat das Unternehmen durch dynamic pricing?

Letztendlich ist es ein Margenspiel, dynamic pricing richtig gemacht und angepasst kann zum

Margenstabilisator werden; Nachlässe sind schlecht, bei nur 5% Rabatt muss man 27,5% mehr

Menge verkaufen, diesen Hebel kennen viele nicht und denken sie können es „über die Masse

wieder machen.“

Ist dynamic pricing die Zukunft der Preispolitik?

Ich glaube schon dass es eine stabile Größe sein wird.

Glauben Sie, dass der Konsument insoweit beeinflusst werden kann, dass es mehr

Möglichkeiten zur individuellen Diskriminierung geben könnte?

Obwohl der Preis dominant ist glaube ich dass wir so reizüberflutet sind, dass der Effekt nicht

lange anhält; heute so morgen so. Lidl hat einen Skandal nach dem anderen aber es wird weiterhin

gekauft. Die größte Macht hat der Verbraucher aber dem Großteil geht es nicht um moralische

oder ethische Geschichten, nicht nachhaltig, morgen ist alles wieder vergessen

Stimmen Sie zu, dass dynamic pricing nur über Online Kanäle möglich ist, da die Kosten bei

Offline Kanälen zu hoch sind?

Ganz eindeutig; wenn ein internationales Unternehmen z.B. Adidas dynamic pricing in Russland

machen will sind die Kosten zu hoch in traditionellen Kanälen, dauert im Face to Face zu lange,

dynamic pricing und Internet bedingt sich.

Sollte jedes Unternehmen danach streben, dynamic pricing zu nutzen?

Ja wenn es das Produktportfolio und die Branche zulassen; dynamic pricing wird schon immer

gemacht, nur langsamer; jetzt eben besser durchs Internet, Preise wurden schon immer justiert,

heute schneller und präziser.

Was ist das erste, an das Sie bei NYOP Transaktionen denken? (Produkte, Industrien,

Plattformen?) Ebay

Ist NYOP der einfachste Weg, um willingness to pay einzufangen?

Hier kommt es auf die Bereitschaft des Konsumenten an, sportlicher Ehrgeiz des Mitbietens, will

ich mir das Produkt leisten oder nicht, NYOP nur als Teil der gesamten Preispolitik, nur mit

bestimmten Produktgruppen, ich glaube nicht ich mache alles auf Auktionen

Glauben Sie der Erfolg von NYOP liegt daran, dass Konsumenten den Preis selbst

bestimmen dürfen und nicht an die Angaben eines Unternehmens gebunden sind?

Ja, es gibt ein gutes Gefühl aber letztendlich verschenkt niemand was; psychologische

Komponente.

Glauben Sie, dass der Großteil der Konsumenten die Vorteile von Coupons nutzt?

Es gab mal einen großen Hype. Dynamische Coupons sind grundsätzlich besser als normale

Coupons.

Appendix 5 - Interview Jochen Gönsch

Was hat sich in der Preispolitik der letzten Jahre geändert?

Die Leute machen sich zunehmend mehr Gedanken um Preise, wir haben den Eindruck dass es

immer noch viele Unternehmen gibt, die es einfach irgendwie machen, aus dem Bauch heraus,

aber zunehmend gibt es dass man Marktforschung macht, zum anderen aber auch mit gesundem

Menschenverstand ran geht. Es gibt es häufig, dass man gewachste Preis-Strukturen im

Unternehmen hat. Wir hatten mal einen Bauchmaschinenverleih, da konnte man Bagger, Gerüste

zu vermieten: die hatten es so dass je länger man mietet, desto günstiger wird der Preis pro Tag,

man konnte 7 Tage mieten. Ein Tag war teurer als nur 5 Tage nutzen und musste dann nur 5/7

bezahlen, es war dermaßen besser länger zu mieten. Solche Strukturen gibt es häufig und es ist

mein Eindruck dass sich Unternehmen immer mehr daran machen, solche Probleme zu vermeiden.

Autovermieter: One Way Miete teurer als wenn man das Auto zur gleichen Station zurückbrachte.

One Way Miete war es bei der Abholung zu sagen. Wenn sie das Auto einfach woanders

93

abgegeben haben, dann war es trotzdem der günstigere Preis. Unternehmen versuchen jetzt, solche

Inkonsistenzen zu vermeiden.

Glauben Sie, dass uns das Internet neue Möglichkeiten der Preis- Differenzierung bietet?

Ja bestimmt, das hängt immer vom gut ab. Bei Dienstleistungen kann man über das Internet mehr

Konfiguration beim Produkt vornehmen als im Ladengeschäft, egal welches Produkt denn es

braucht nicht die Zeit des Verkäufers. Beispiel: Gravur iPhone.

Blind Booking bei Germanwings: Flug buchen aber bei der Buchung ist es unklar, wohin man

fliegt. Je mehr Ziele man ausschließt, desto teurer aber desto klarer beeinflussbar, wohin die Reise

geht.

Nach welchen Kriterien würden Sie Preis diskriminieren?

Das hängt vom Produkt ab und wie man es vertreibt. Es gibt die üblichen Sachen aus der Literatur,

zweiten oder dritten Grades. Interessant sind Unternehmen, die in Werbeaussagen und

Pressemeldungen die in Richtung ersten Grades diskriminieren, mit Nutzung von

Gutscheinaktionen und Coupons, bei denen man versucht Kunden über individuelle Kundenkarten

Dinge zu geben

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis eines Konsumenten in offline und online Kanälen

unterscheidet?

Ja ich glaube als Kunde ist man im online Kanal sehr schnell Vergleichspreise besorgen kann.

Wenn man nicht nur bei Amazon bestellt und es etwas Teureres ist bei dem man sich mehr Zeit

lässt, dann kann man sehr schnell bei einer Preissuchmaschine und einem anderen Anbieter einen

Vergleichspreis bekommen wenn es ein standardisiertes Produkt ist. Im Laden ist es nicht ganz so

einfach, da muss man aufs Handy schauen um vielleicht noch einen Versandpreis zu finden.

Online hat man eher einen Referenzpreis, der eine reale Preis ist zu dem ich das gut auch bestellen

kann. Im Laden hat man eher ein Gefühl was das gut kosten sollte, aber da steckt kein direkter

Preisvergleich dahinter.

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis zwischen verschiedenen Kulturen oder Ländern

unterscheidet?

Grundsätzlich ist der konkrete Preis sehr sicher immer unterschiedlich. Die Sachen sind in

verschiedenen Marlten objektiv auch unterschiedlich teuer. Sicher unterscheidet sich auch die Art,

wie sich der Referenzpreis bildet, selbst schon innerhalb eines Landes je nach Alter und

Produktgruppe.

Gibt es eine Kaufsituation bei der der Referenzpreis keinen Einfluss auf die Entscheidung

hat?

Ja bestimmt, bei Produkten die man schnell haben will oder die günstiger sind. Wenn sie

unterwegs sind und Durst haben dann kaufen Sie etwas, auch wenn es teuer ist. In dem Fall spielt

der Referenzpreis für die Kaufentscheidung keine Rolle. Man versucht den Referenzpreis durch

Marketing zu beeinflussen, in dem man das Produkt als hochwertig präsentiert; auch durch die

Verpackung. Es gibt einen Ansatz: wenn man eine Zeitschrift kaufen will für 6 Monate kostet es

30€ und für 12 Monate kostet es nur 40€ und das Abo für zwei Jahre kostet nur 75€. Daraufhin

kaufen die Leute das Jahres Abo weil es super günstig wirkt. Man setzt alternative Angebote, die

dann den Referenzpreis beeinflussen mit Angeboten die letztlich keiner kauft.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass eine höhere Online Transparenz dazu führt, dass Konsumenten

mehr Zeit mit der Suche nach Preis-Informationen verbringen?

Die Preistransparenz hat sicherlich zugenommen, vielleicht in wenigen Bereichen nicht aber bei

normalen Produkten schon. Ja ich glaube schon, dass Kunden mehr Zeit mit Informationssuche

verbringen. Früher sind Kunden schneller zum Laden gegangen und haben das Produkt gekauft

aber mit mehr Informationen und Preisen wird länger gesucht.

Für welche Art von Produkt wird die meiste Suche nach Informationen verbracht?

Naja gut, es gibt Recherche in innerlichen Aspekten z.B. wenn man einen neuen Computer kauft.

Gut vergleichbare Produkte würde ich eher Preise vergleichen. Bei Kleidung finde ich es

schwierig. Myhammer Plattform bei dem man eine Kleinanzeige macht, welche Handwerkliche

Leistung man benötigt und dann werden Angebote abgegeben, aber die Angebote liegen bis zu

100% auseinander; zuvor gab es in diesem Bereich keine Transparenz. Früher hat man maximal

zwei Maler angerufen, jetzt kann man viele Angebote einholen.

94

Hat Transparenz einen Einfluss auf die Wahrnehmung von Fairness eines Konsumenten?

Ja, in der Erfahrung der Maler den dreifachen Preis zu bieten. Alles was 50 oder 100% teurer ist

als ein anderer Preis ist sogar ein Verstoß gegen die guten Sitten. Aus Preistransparenz ergibt sich

dann ein Gefühl was der Marktpreis sein soll und wenn ein Preis extrem über dem Marktpreis ist,

ohne dass ich verstehe warum, dann empfinde ich das als unfair.

Und welche Konsequenzen hat (Un-) Fairness für die Beziehung zwischen Kunde und

Unternehmen?

Wenn ich das Gefühl habe, jemand macht mir einen unfairen Preis würde ich keine weitere

Beziehung zu dem Unternehmen mehr wünschen.

Wie kann ein Unternehmen Fairness beeinflussen?

Man muss seinen Preis erklären; man muss dafür sorgen, dass der Kunde versteht warum der Preis

so ist wie er ist. Dann sieht der Kunde hoffentlich ein, warum der Preis teurer ist und entscheidet

sich dafür. Qualitätsgründe spielen rein. Beim Strompreis ist es vielleicht auch wichtig 100%

Ökostrom zu nehmen, anstatt den wichtigsten Preis.

Haben Kosten- und Preistransparenz einen direkten Einfluss auf die willingness to pay eines

Konsumenten?

Je transparenter der Markt, je mehr habe ich einen Referenzpreis im Kopf. Wenn ich das nicht

habe, bin ich eher bereit den erstbesten Preis zu bezahlen.

Welche weiteren Faktoren haben Ihrer Meinung nach einen Einfluss auf die willingness to

pay?

Sicherlich auch die eigenen Möglichkeiten. Es gibt Produktkategorien, bei denen ich den Preis für

angemessen halte, die ich aber trotzdem nicht kaufe weil es über meinen finanziellen

Möglichkeiten liegt.

Wie kann ein Unternehmen Transparenz als Vorteil nutzen?

Für diejenigen, die neu in den Markt gehen und günstige Preise haben ist das sicher ein Vorteil.

Gerade bei Marktplätzen wie „Myhammer“ ist man nicht nur darauf angewiesen, empfohlen zu

werden sondern kann auch mit dem Preis Kunden erreichen.

Denken Sie dass die größten Vorteile von Transparenz die neuen Möglichkeiten der

Preispolitik und Marktforschung/Big Data sind?

In Bezug auf die Transparenz habe ich nie darüber nachgedacht, ob es Vorteile zu Big Data gibt.

Natürlich sind Unternehmen dabei, sich ein Bild über die Preise zu machen und haben die Vorgabe

wir sind 5% billiger wie der Wettbewerb oder sind teurer weil wir etwas besser machen. Von dem

her nutzen sie die Transparenz auch für sich. Ich würde nicht sagen, es ist eine Big Data Sache.

Big Data ist eher auf die Kunden ausgerichtet um deren Zahlungsbereitschaft abzuschöpfen, damit

bekommen Unternehmen eine Idee welche Produkte dem Kunden anzubieten und welche Preise zu

verlangen. Big Data ist auf Kaufdaten und den Konsumenten

Sind Sie der Meinung dass die größten Nachteile die erhöhte Transparenz für Kunden und

die Gefahr von Arbitrage sind?

Arbitrage in dem Sinne nicht. Arbitrage in dem Sinne, dass man für den eigenen Bedarf da kauft

wo es am günstigsten ist. Ob man als Kunde zum Händler wird oder ob neue Akteure auf den Plan

treten, die es vorher nicht gegeben hätte, die als Händler Arbitrage nutzen, das mag passieren aber

ich glaube es ist ein gewisser Aufwand bei den meisten Produkten und diese Leute würden das

auch tun ohne dass es so eine Preistransparenz gibt. Wenn man das semi-professionell macht, dann

nimmt man sich auch die Zeit um rauszufinden, wie die Preise sind. Es ist vielleicht von Vorteil

wenn der Kunde die Transparenz nicht hat, kann der Kunde selbst im Ausland bestellen und

braucht nicht einen intermediären dazwischen.

Welche anderen Nachteile sehen Sie?

Transparenz kann man aus als Nachteil sehen weil Preise unter Druck geraten. Wenn der Kunde

mehr Transparenz hat verstärkt sich der Preis-Wettbewerb. Gerade bei standardisierten Produkten

kommt es schnell zu einem Preiswettbewerb, weil der Kunde vergleichen kann. Die

Preissuchmaschine sortieren ja direkt nach dem Preis und man hat als Unternehmen großen

95

Preisdruck. Ein Unternehmen hat auch einen gewissen Innovationsdruck. Wenn es nur das ist, dass

der Onlineshop immer aktuell ist.

Glauben Sie, dass die Vorteile von Transparenz die Nachteile überwiegen?

Ich glaube das kommt auf das Unternehmen und die Branche an. Kennen Sie das Versandhaus

Quelle? Man weiß nicht ob es nur am Internet lag, aber es hatte einen großen Einfluss – für Quelle

haben die Nachteile die Vorteile überwogen obwohl ein Versandhaus prädestiniert für das Internet

wäre. Die haben ja schon die Logistik und trotzdem vielleicht von Amazon plattgemacht worden.

Otto hat es geschafft – die gibt es noch.

Hat das Internet das Risiko und die Möglichkeiten zu Arbitrage vergrößert?

Ich denke schon. Als Konsument hat man durch das Internet leichter die Möglichkeit, Produkte zu

verkaufen; definitiv leichter als früher durch Kleinanzeigen-Blätter. In den Anfangsjahren von

Ebay gab es mehr Konsumenten, die zu Händlern wurden. Man kann ein spezielleres Publikum

erreichen und dadurch auch spezielle Artikel verkaufen.

Glauben Sie, dass hauptsächlich der erleichterte Zugang zu Märkten, geringere

Transportkosten und Freihandelszonen die Arbitrage Kosten verringern?

Sicherlich, ich glaube dass es da noch ein Problem ist, wegen Zoll in Amerika zu bestellen. In

Europa ist es einfacher zu bestellen. Gerade wenn Märkte zusammenwachsen sinken häufig die

Transportkosten. Es gibt bestimmte Unternehmen, Amazon als Beispiel, wenn man in Frankreich

ist muss man gar nicht im deutschen Amazon bestellen, sondern man kann auch die gleichen

Sachen bei dem französischen Amazon bestellen, dass dann eben mit den normalen französischen

Transportkosten schickt.

Wird dynamic pricing im Allgemeinen als unfair angesehen?

Ich verstehe Dynamic Pricing als Änderung der Preise im zeitlichen Ablauf. Eine

Preisdifferenzierung ist es nur in dem Sinne, dass Kunden die zu unterschiedlichen Zeitpunkten

kaufen unterschiedliche Preise habe. Klassischer Anwender sind die Billigfluggesellschaften.

Wenn sie auf die Webseite gehen hat jeder Flug nur einen Preis, wenn sie morgen schauen, dann

kann der Preis anders sein. Bei Lufthansa haben sie ganz viele Optionen – Sie können

verschiedene Klassen buchen, mit oder ohne Stornierungsmöglichkeit usw. Damit haben sie

innerhalb der Economy Class ganz viele unterschiedliche Preise, die sich zwar tendenziell ändern

aber doch weniger als bei RyanAir.

Grundsätzlich kommt es darauf an, wenn man eine segmentorientierte Preisdifferenzierung hat und

Kunden auf Grund Eigenschaften einordnet, Seniorenrabatt und sowas, das glaube ich kann als

unfair empfunden werden. Die Kunden können nichts daran machen, wie sie einsortiert sind.

Wenn man dagegen Preisdifferenzierung hat, die nicht auf Segmenten ansetzt sondern wo die

Kunden sich selbst einordnen, ist es besser. Es gab mal vor 10-15 Jahren als Amazon

unterschiedlichen Deutschen unterschiedliche Preise angeboten hat. Das war ein Riesenskandal

und 10 Jahre hat sich niemand mehr an dieses Thema ran getraut. Man konnte da auch nichts

dagegen machen und die Vermutung war, dass Stammkunden teurere Preise kriegen als

Erstkunden und sowas wird schnell als unfair gesehen. Ansonsten hängt es von der Branche ab,

beim Linienflugverkehr hat man sich daran gewöhnt, bei Kreuzfahrten ist es nicht akzeptiert wenn

der Tischnachbar einen anderen Preis bezahlt hat. Da muss man dann als Unternehmen die

Produkte verändern.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass dynamic pricing eher bei vergänglichen Produkten/Services

funktioniert?

Das ist ein anderer Aspekt, die Differenzierung funktioniert wenn Arbitrage nicht möglich ist.

Flugticket ist auf den Namen gebucht und wird am Flughafen kontrolliert. Bei einem Konzertticket

ist es was anderes. Bei einem verderblichen Produkt kann man z.B. den Platz im Flugzeug nicht

mehr verkaufen, hat man ein Ende des Verkaufszeitraums. Man muss das Ticket bis zum Abflug

verkaufen oder es hat den Wert Null. Das Führt dazu, dass man als Anbieter häufig im Zeitverlauf

fallende Preise hat. Aus der Kundenseite wird nichts verändert aber man hat in der Regel als

Anbieter den fallenden Preisverlauf weil man zu jedem Zeitpunkt überlegen muss, neben der

Zahlungsbereitschaft, will man das Produkt zu dem Preis verkaufen oder verkaufe ich es morgen

zu einem eventuell höheren Preis. Bei verderblichen Produkten geht das nicht ewig, daher ist der

Wert sinkend im Zeitablauf. Gerade bei Fluggesellschaften ist das ein wichtiger Grund für

dynamic pricing.

96

Ein weiteres Beispiel wäre ein Markt, wenn das Gemüse eine halbe Stunde bevor der Markt

schließt, günstiger verkauft wird weil das am nächsten Tag nichts mehr wert ist.

Warum funktioniert es mit diesen aber nicht mit anderen Produkten?

Ich glaube es liegt daran, dass sich die Leute daran gewöhnen mit der Zeit. Und dann natürlich,

dass man das Gefühl hat selbst Einfluss zu haben, was bei den Flugpreisen so wäre. Wenn Ihnen

Amazon den teureren Preis anzeigt, dann fühlt man sich schnell diskriminiert.

Welche Vorteile hat das Unternehmen durch dynamic pricing?

Gegenüber statischem pricing hat das Unternehmen, das sinnvoll dynamic pricing einsetzt einen

höheren Erlös und es hat häufig bessere Chancen seine Kapazität vollständig auszulasten. Man

kann durch Preisveränderungen die Auslastung gut steuern.

Ist dynamic pricing die Zukunft der Preispolitik? Wird dynamic pricing eine große Rolle in

der Zukunft spielen?

Es hat auf jeden Fall zugenommen, bei Produkten im Internet kann man Preise leicht ändern.

Früher war auf jedem Produkt ein Preisschild aufgeklebt, das war sehr aufwendig, weil man

Preisschilder immer neu kleben musste oder Schilder mit Preisminderungen aushängen. Insofern

ist es einfacher geworden und es gibt viele Untersuchungen zu Preisverläufen von Online

Kaufhäusern, bei denen man im Zeitverlauf sieht, dass sich Preise ändern. Ob viele Überlegungen

dahinter stecken, ist eine andere Frage. Vielleicht wird nur ausprobiert, ob Kunden die Preise

zahlen ohne dass die Preise selbst optimiert sind.

Weiß nicht ob sie mal in Frankreich im Supermarkt waren? Da sind die Preisschilder im Regelfall

elektronisch, das gibt es mittlerweile auch in einzelnen Supermärkten in Deutschland. Das macht

auch nur Sinn, wenn man in die Richtung Dynamic Pricing geht.

Das ist ein Zeichen, dass auch so eine Branche in diese Richtung geht.

Glauben Sie, dass der Konsument insoweit beeinflusst werden kann, dass es mehr

Möglichkeiten zur individuellen Diskriminierung geben könnte?

Ja denke ich schon. Gerade wenn die Kunden sehen, dass es für sie auch von Vorteil sein kann

weil es zu bestimmten Zeiten günstiger ist.

Stimmen Sie zu, dass dynamic pricing nur über Online Kanäle möglich ist, da die Kosten bei

Offline Kanälen zu hoch sind?

Es kommt drauf an wie Sie das dynamic pricing machen und wie oft man die Preise ändert. Offline

hat man Aufwand wenn man täglich Preise ändern will, bei einem Schlussverkauf eher weniger.

Schwer zu sagen was akzeptiert ist, Tankstellen ändern regelmäßig die Preise und es wird

akzeptiert. Eingeschränkt gibt es das in offline Kanälen, beispielsweise die Schlussverkäufe als

einfache Form von dynamic pricing, wobei immer wieder reduziert wird. Es gibt auch Beispiele,

die es schon sehr lange gibt.

Welche Herausforderungen bestehen bei der Implementierung von dynamic pricing?

Man muss es technisch schaffen, die Preise zu ändern – egal wie wenn man offline verkauft muss

man Preisschilder kleben und man muss es durchführen, dass der Preis sich ändert. Online ist es

genauso, auch hier muss man den Preis ändern. Man muss auch entscheiden, wie soll der Preis

sich ändern. Soll der Preis einen Preis abdecken oder möchten sie eine Marketing Maßnahmen

durchsetzen, bei dem der Umsatz und die Erlöse nicht so wichtig, oder geht es darum dass neue

Leute kommen. Das sind die beiden grundsätzlichen Herausforderungen. Es besteht auch die

Gefahr, dass die Leute es lernen. Das ist bei Pauschalreisen passiert, da haben die Leute gelernt,

dass es Last Minute Reisen gibt und diese viel günstiger sind. Jetzt warten viele auf diese Last

Minute Preise. Anbieter versuchen mit Frühbucherrabatten gegenzusteuern aber das machen sie

nur wegen dem Problem mit Last Minute, wo die Kunden abwarten und nicht 5 Monate früher den

Urlaub buchen. Für die Anbieter ist es ein Problem wenn Kapazitäten nicht verkauft werden.

Wenn man seine Preise zeitlich ändert, lernen Kunden auch abzuwarten. Das kann auch mit einer

örtlichen Preisdifferenzierung passieren, wenn die Leute ins Outlet fahren um günstig einzukaufen.

Sollte jedes Unternehmen danach streben, dynamic pricing zu nutzen?

Schwer zu sagen. Pauschal würde ich das nicht sagen aber tendenziell würde ich sagen ein

Unternehmen sollte schon darüber nachdenken oder sich zumindest sich damit beschäftigen, was

dynamic pricing ist und ob das eingeführt werden kann. Ob das für jeden gut ist, wie gesagt, es

kann halt auch negative Aspekte haben. Wer es nicht macht und die Voraussetzungen erfüllt sind

97

Bäckereien. Ich kenne keine Bäckereien die abends das Brot günstiger macht. Die wollen sich

nicht die Preise kaputt machen. Ob das die richtige Entscheidung ist, weiß ich nicht.

Was ist das erste, an das Sie bei NYOP Transaktionen denken? (Produkte, Industrien,

Plattformen?)

Das ist ein Thema, dass in der Forschung beleuchtet wird. Was mir einfällt, dass es das

ursprünglich aus Amerika kommt, es gibt es auch in Deutschland mittlerweile. Priceline haben

NYOP erfunden und ich glaube die haben sich dieses Wort auch schützen lassen. Priceline

vermittelt Reise und Flüge.

Ist NYOP der einfachste Weg, um willingness to pay einzufangen?

Gute Frage. Nein glaube ich nicht, sonst hätte man das früher erfunden und es hätte sich früher

durchgesetzt. Ich glaube, wenn das so ein super Weg wäre hätte es eine größere Bedeutung.

Glauben Sie der Erfolg von NYOP liegt daran, dass Konsumenten den Preis selbst

bestimmen dürfen und nicht an die Angaben eines Unternehmens gebunden sind?

Ja sicher, ich meine der Konsument gibt den Preis an und er kann höher sein als der Anbieter

verlangt hätte und dann ist das gut für den Anbieter. Wenn der Konsument einen niedrigen Preis

angibt, bekommt er das Produkt nicht, so gesehen gibt es auch keinen Schaden für den Anbieter.

Wenn der Anbieter sich einen Mindestpreis setzt, dann kommt er gut raus. Viele Leute nehmen

bisher nicht Teil, weil es aufwendig ist, auch wenn das nicht wirklich ein Argument, je nachdem

wie die Website gestaltet ist. Ich glaube wichtiger ist die Frage ob er Kunde am Ende damit

zufrieden ist. Ich glaube wenn ich ein normales Produkt kaufe zu einem Preis was ich im vornerein

kenne und das Produkt ist so wie es beschrieben ist, dann bin ich in der Regel zufrieden. Gerade

wenn ich geschaut habe, was das Produkt woanders kostet und es zumindest nicht viel billiger ist

woanders. Bei diesem NYOP, wenn ich vielleicht einen Preis gezahlt habe, der niedriger ist als

woanders, bin ich vielleicht immer noch unzufrieden, weil man sich denkt, man könnte auch noch

10 € weniger eingeben können und man hätte auch 10€ weniger gespart. Wenn man das Produkt

nicht bekommt, dann ist man auch unzufrieden. Vielleicht hätte man ja nur 2€ mehr eingeben

müssen. Das ist vielleicht ein Grund warum es sich nicht durchgesetzt hat. Weil der Kunde es

vielleicht auch als kompliziert empfindet, sich den Preis zu überlegen. Es gibt auch bei Ebay das

Phänomen, dass viele Sachen teurer verkauft werden als über eine Preissuchmaschine, weil wenn

die Leute mal mitsteigern, dann wollen die Leuten auch die Auktion gewinnen und das Produkt

haben.

Glauben Sie, dass der Großteil der Konsumenten die Vorteile von Coupons nutzt?

Ich benutze manche Coupons, ob das der Großteil macht, schwer zu sagen. Nein die Mehrheit der

mir zur Verfügung stehenden Coupons nutze ich nicht.

Gibt es Produkte bei denen generell eine höhere Prozentzahl von Coupons benutzt wird?

Diese Coupons, die im Briefkasten kommen und die man beim täglichen Einkauf verwenden kann,

dass die tendenziell benutzt werden glaube ich.

Wie kann ein Unternehmen dieses Wissen nutzen? – Wie können sie effektiv Coupons

einsetzen? (dynamische Coupons?)

Dynamische Coupons? Weiß ich nicht, weil es gib ja solche und solche Coupons. Die mit der

Zeitung kommen und für jeden gleich sind, und es gibt die etwas individuelleren Coupons. Weiß

nicht welche sinnvoller sind. Man kann immer sagen, individueller besser weil es mehr kann aber

es ist auch mehr Aufwand.

Appendix 6 - Interview Werner Tauss

Was hat sich in der Preispolitik der letzten Jahre geändert?

Ich gehe mal überwiegend auf den Bereich Flug. Da hat sich vor allem geändert, dass wir

wegkommen von den Konditionen, die in den Fares drin waren und von Price Fencing und hin zu

Fare Families. Ich habe also mehrere Typen mit unterschiedlichen Preispunkten. Diese Preispunkte

ändern sich täglich.

98

Glauben Sie, dass uns das Internet neue Möglichkeiten der Preis- Differenzierung bietet? Auf jeden Fall. Ich kann das Kundenverhalten viel besser analysieren und kann als Airline mehr

über den Kunden wissen. Im Internet sind die Möglichkeiten viel flexibler, Angebote anzuzeigen.

Nach welchen Kriterien sollte man diskriminieren?

Was ist dem Kunden bei Produkten wichtig und worauf legt er Wert. Bis zu der Frage was er

bereit ist zu bezahlen. Das kann man gut mit Marktforschung belegen. Das Unternehmen muss

herausfinden, was der Kunde will. Dabei kann man ganz schöne Überraschungen in der

Marktforschung erleben.

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis eines Konsumenten in offline und online Kanälen

unterscheidet? Auf welche Art unterscheidet sich der Referenzpreis?

Würde ich bezweifeln. Ich glaube der Kunde hat eine Bereitschaft eine bestimmte Summe zu

bezahlen, wie er daran kommt, macht keinen Unterschied.

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis zwischen verschiedenen Kulturen oder Ländern

unterscheidet? Ja

Welche anderen Faktoren können Einfluss auf den Referenzpreis haben?

Mit Sicherheit die Produktelemente. Wie flexibel ist das Produkt, kann ich es zurückgeben oder

was kostet eine Umbuchung beispielsweise. Bestandteile wie Gepäck inklusive. Diese

Unterscheidungen machen die Airlines in den Fare Families.

Gibt es eine Kaufsituation bei der der Referenzpreis keinen Einfluss auf die Entscheidung

hat?

Naja ich sage mal, es gibt ein Kundensegment, die sind unsensibel was den Preis angeht. Als

Consultant mit wichtigem Kundentermin bin ich bereit jeden Preis zu zahlen um am Ziel zur

richtigen Zeit anzukommen.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass eine höhere Online Transparenz dazu führt, dass Konsumenten

mehr Zeit mit der Suche nach Preis-Informationen verbringen?

Der Kunde nutzt die zusätzlichen Informationen die das Internet ihm bieten. Einerseits haben sie

Portale, die den Vergleich machen. Diese Portale nehmen Arbeit ab. Andererseits ist natürlich die

Frage, wie sehr vertraue ich den Portalen. Da kann es Sinn machen eigenständig weiter zu suchen.

Hat Transparenz einen Einfluss auf die Wahrnehmung von Fairness eines Konsumenten?

Ich sag mal so, Transparenz im Sinne: es ist von vornerein geklärt welche Bestandteile umfasst das

Produkt und es ist geklärt, dass der Preis sich ändern kann. Es ist nicht immer insofern transparent,

dass ich die Entwicklung in der Zukunft nicht kenne.

Und welche Konsequenzen hat (Un-) Fairness für die Beziehung zwischen Kunde und

Unternehmen?

Wenn mir das passiert und ich habe ein ungutes Gefühl, dann sammelt sich das an und irgendwann

habe ich keine Lust mehr auf dieses Unternehmen. Das Unternehmen verliert damit auch die

Seriosität.

Haben Kosten- und Preistransparenz einen direkten Einfluss auf die willingness to pay eines

Konsumenten?

Nein glaube ich eher nicht.

Welche weiteren Faktoren haben Ihrer Meinung nach einen Einfluss auf die willingness to

pay?

Das sind im Grunde die Elemente, was der Kunde braucht. Beispielsweise eine

Umbuchungsmöglichkeit. Brauche ich Verpflegung, brauche ich Internetverfügbarkeit. Das

definiert letztendlich die Preisbereitschaft.

Wie kann ein Unternehmen Transparenz als Vorteil nutzen?

Es ist wichtig, dass die Unternehmen klar kommunizieren, was die Vorteile und Risiken der

Produkte oder Services sind. Wenn der Kunde alles weiß, dann ist es fair.

Denken Sie dass die größten Vorteile von Transparenz die neuen Möglichkeiten der

Preispolitik und Marktforschung/Big Data sind?

99

Definitiv, ja. In der Wesentlichen Geschwindigkeit mit der ich Dinge in den Markt stellen kann,

seien es Preisveränderungen oder andere Spielregeln. Außerdem ist man sehr flexibel und kann

sehr gut das Kundenverhalten nachvollziehen. Bis zu welchem Schritt des Kaufprozesses geht der

Kunde und wann steigt er aus.

Sind Sie der Meinung dass die größten Nachteile die erhöhte Transparenz für Kunden und

die Gefahr von Arbitrage sind?

Eben, er hat die gleichen Informationen. Das ist auch im Wechselspiel zwischen zwei

Unternehmen wichtig. Wie gut ist mein Yield Management und wie gut ist das der anderen. Wenn

beide es sehr gut beherrschen, kann man das Marktniveau nach oben steigern. Falls er das nicht

beherrscht, dann kann es zu einer nach unten führenden Preisspirale führen.

Glauben Sie, dass die Vorteile von Transparenz die Nachteile überwiegen?

Ja absolut.

Für welche Situation/Industrie/Produkt könnte dies nicht der Fall sein?

Fallen mir spontan die Fernbusse ein, die machen das noch nicht so gut.

Hat das Internet das Risiko und die Möglichkeiten zu Arbitrage vergrößert?

Ja absolut, Ich würde das eher als Nebeneffekt einsortieren.

Ich glaube eher, dass wir in einem Trend sind, der sich dahin entwickelt, dass solche

Zwischenhändler es zunehmend schwieriger haben. Ich glaube die großen Konzerne werden dahin

kommen, dass sie die eigenen Produkte über das Internet selbst vermarkten. Wenn eine Airline nur

einen Bruchteil der Marge verdient, dann liegt das nicht mehr im Verhältnis zu den Ausgaben.

Glauben Sie, dass hauptsächlich der erleichterte Zugang zu Märkten, geringere

Transportkosten und Freihandelszonen die Arbitrage Kosten verringern?

Ja absolut.

Wird dynamic pricing im Allgemeinen als unfair angesehen?

Würde ich tendenziell vorsichtlich sein mit der Behauptung. Aus eigener Erfahrung mit den

Branchen mit denen ich arbeite (Kreuzfahrten, Luftfahrt), wird das noch nicht sonderlich genutzt.

Ich wüsste nicht, dass es das bereits in großem Detailgrad gibt. Sie arbeiten dran, aber momentan

gibt es das glaube ich nicht. Warum verschiedene Preis verlangt werden, das weiß man ja nicht.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass dynamic pricing eher bei vergänglichen Produkten/Services

funktioniert?

Ja. Wenn ich ein Produkt sehe bei dem es egal ist ob ich es heute kaufe oder nächste Woche, dann

funktioniert das nicht.

Welche Vorteile hat das Unternehmen durch dynamic pricing? Wenn sie es richtig machen, mehr Umsatz und mehr Marge, denn es kostet ja nicht viel, das richtig

zu machen. Um den gleichen Effekt auf der Kostenseite zu haben, muss man deutlich mehr Mühe

investieren. Damit versucht man eben den höchsten Preis zu finden, den der Kunde akzeptiert.

Ist dynamic pricing die Zukunft der Preispolitik?

Ich glaube das wird sich ständig weiterentwickeln.

Glauben Sie, dass der Konsument insoweit beeinflusst werden kann, dass es mehr

Möglichkeiten für dynamic pricing geben könnte?

Da ist eine immer weitergehende Entwicklung. IT wird immer schneller größere Datenmengen

verarbeiten können. Das lässt sich nicht zurückdrehen.

Stimmen Sie zu, dass dynamic pricing nur über Online Kanäle möglich ist, da die Kosten bei

Offline Kanälen zu hoch sind?

Es sind einmal die kosten und zum anderen die Geschwindigkeit, denn offline müsste man es

beispielsweise über Papier verteilen.

Welche Herausforderungen bestehen bei der Implementierung von dynamic pricing?

100

Man muss herausfinden, was kommt beim Kunden an und was nicht. Wenn ich nicht weiß was der

Kunde will oder der Wettbewerber macht, dann kann ich schnell Geld verlieren. Die

Zahlungsbereitschaft der Kunden zu kennen ist sehr wichtig.

Welche Auswirkungen hat diese Art von Pricing auf das Marketing im Allgemeinen?

Man muss sich darauf konzentrieren, die Stärke und Vorteile der Marke zu kommunizieren. Das

Marketing muss die Menschen von der Marke begeistern. Das Pricing sorgt dann dafür, den

richtigen Preis anzubieten, damit auch gekauft werden will.

Sollte jedes Unternehmen danach streben, dynamic pricing zu nutzen? Alle mit den Kriterien:

vergängliches Produkt, Reservierung. Ich glaube ein Unternehmen, das das nicht nutzt hat keine

anhaltende Chance zu überleben.

Was ist das erste, an das Sie bei NYOP Transaktionen denken? (Produkte, Industrien,

Plattformen?) Eine von vielen Varianten, wie man eine Preisbereitschaft ermitteln kann.

Letztendlich denke ich an die Beispiele; ich bin flexibel im Preis und dafür muss der Kunde in

anderen Bereichen flexibel sein. Es gibt bestimmte Preispunkte, wenn ich den in den Markt stelle

kriege ich meinen Markt voll. Diese Preispunkte kann ich über diese Modelle sehr gut

herausfinden. Wenn Transparenz herrscht und Kunden die Unterschiede in den Preisen finden,

dann gibt es keinen Ärger, weil der Konsument den Preis selbst bestimmt und sich nicht

beschweren kann.

Ist NYOP der einfachste Weg, um willingness to pay einzufangen?

Es ist ein sehr simpler Weg.

Glauben Sie der Erfolg von NYOP liegt daran, dass Konsumenten den Preis selbst

bestimmen dürfen und nicht an die Angaben eines Unternehmens gebunden sind?

Ja und das hat verschiedene Komponente. Ich als Unternehmen lerne die Preisbereitschaft aber das

andere ist die Fairness, denn als Kunde hat man sich bewusst entschieden.

Funktioniert dieses Prinzip mit jedem vergänglichen Produkt? Ja

Wie kann ein Unternehmen einen positiven Einfluss auf den Konsumenten ausüben? Ich weiß nicht ob man die Bereitschaft erhöhen kann, aber man kann Kapazität erhöhen, wo sie

nicht ausreichend besteht, bei Tageszeiten/Jahreszeiten/Destinationen.

Glauben Sie, dass der Großteil der Konsumenten die Vorteile von Coupons nutzt?

Aus persönlicher Einschätzung, bin ich bei sowas eher skeptisch. Man merkt es im Internet: Man

wird zugeschüttet und es gibt kaum etwas, bei dem es keinen Coupon gibt. Wenn ich alles nutzen

wollte, müsste ich sehr viel Zeit investieren. Es gibt Leute, die machen einen Sport daraus, ich

gehöre es nicht dazu.

Welche Art von Konsument nutzt die Vorteile von Coupons bewusst?

Ein Preissensibler, der auf die Jagd geht. Er kauft auch Dinge, die er nicht braucht, aber er hatte

einen Coupon dafür.

Sind dynamische Coupons die bessere Alternative?

Ich bin kein großer Freund von Coupons, wenn ich 10 Mails bekomme, dann ist das unbestellte

Werbung.

Was würden Sie einem Unternehmen raten?

Ich habe das bisher nicht empfohlen.

Appendix 7 - Interview Tim Brzoska

Was hat sich in der Preispolitik der letzten Jahre geändert?

Gefühlt machen sich immer mehr Formen Gedanken um Pricing weil sie merken, dass sie auf

anderen Hebeln schon viel gemacht haben und da keine Potentiale sehen. Daher rückt der Fokus

immer mehr auf Pricing. Daher werden die Arten, wie man das Pricing angeht immer

professioneller und differenzierter. Nur noch einen Preis anzugeben und zu sagen: „Friss oder

Stirb“ wird immer seltener. Es wird auch immer mehr geschaut, wie man Zahlungsbereitschaft

101

durch differenziertes Pricing abschöpfen kann. Das ist immer mehr das Ziel, das Unternehmen

haben. Außerdem wird wichtiger, eine gewisse Konsistenz ins Pricing zu bekommen, da der Preis

am Ende auch einen Einfluss auf das Marken-Image hat. Wenn man nicht konsistent arbeitet, kann

man viele Kunden verlieren und das Image schädigen.

Glauben Sie, dass uns das Internet neue Möglichkeiten der Preis- Differenzierung bietet?

Ja und Nein. Ja, rein technisch gesehen hat man viel mehr Möglichkeiten, den Kunden gezielter

anzusprechen, weil man gezieltere Informationen über den Kunden hat und es technisch besser

funktioniert, Preise zu ändern. Die Herausforderung ist, dass auch mehr Transparenz herrscht, das

heißt eine große Herausforderung im Handel – früher wusste man nicht, was ein Elektronik

Händler in München für Preise nimmt und das war egal, weil man in Köln gekauft hat. Heute geht

man ins Internet und geht da zu einem Elektronikhändler und wenn man im Internet einen Preis

sieht und er ist nicht der gleiche, wie wenn ich in einen Laden gehe, dann wundere ich mich schon.

Das ist die Herausforderung, die durch das Internet vor allem bei den Konsumgüter-Händlern

besteht. Es wird immer schwieriger, Preisdifferenzierung über Kanäle zu betreiben. Außerdem ist

durch das Internet der Kunde nur einen Klick vom nächsten Händler entfernt und in

Preissuchmaschinen kann ich Produkte und Preise vergleichen – dadurch wird

Preisdifferenzierung erschwert.

Nach welchen Kriterien würden Sie Preis differenzieren? Die besten Möglichkeiten sind Fencing, also wenn ich klar abgrenzen kann warum Preise

unterschiedlich sind. Im Dienstleistungsbereich gibt es Studenten-Rabatte, das kann man leicht

nachprüfen und andere Kunden verstehen, warum Studenten ein bisschen weniger bezahlen. Wenn

der Kunde nicht mehr versteht, warum man Preise differenziert ist es ein Problem. Es muss klipp

und klar sein, warum die Preise sich unterscheiden – es muss einen Mehrwert im Geschäft

darstellen – eine gute Beratung, ein guter Laden. Warum sollte ich auch sonst andere Preise

bezahlen?

Wenn man diese Erklärung nicht hat, wird es schwierig, vor allem wenn die Preise transparent

sind. Beim Fliegen hat jeder einen anderen Preis bezahlt, weiß aber niemand also interessiert es

keinen. Wenn ich aber einen teuren Fernseher morgens kaufe, den dann abends oder im Internet

billiger sehe, dann bin ich nicht zufrieden.

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis eines Konsumenten in offline und online Kanälen

unterscheidet?

Ich glaube schon, dass sich mittlerweile der Gedanke verfestigt hat, dass man es online günstiger

bekommt. Man erwartet das ein bisschen. Obwohl ich glaube, der Mehrwert online ist größer als in

Läden, weil die convenience größer ist. Online konnte man immer günstiger anbieten, weil sie

geringere Kostenstrukturen haben. Die haben verpasst zu erkennen, dass ihr Kanal mehr Wert für

den Kunden darstellt. Das ist vorbei, dementsprechend hat sich das verfestigt.

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis zwischen verschiedenen Kulturen oder Ländern

unterscheidet?

Ich weiß nur, dass sich in anderen Ländern das Thema online Handel schon stärker durchgesetzt

hat, weil die Kunden bereit sind, dort im Internet mehr zu bezahlen. Ich weiß nur nicht ob das eine

kulturelle Geschichte ist oder eher die Tatsache, dass man in Deutschland überall Discounter hat.

Ob das kulturell oder marktbezogen ist kann ich nicht sagen.

Wie kann ein Unternehmen den Referenzpreis beeinflussen?

Indem ich mein Angebot entsprechend gestalte. Umso höherwertiger das Produkt, desto höher die

Zahlungsbereitschaft. Auch über die Zusammenstellung kann ich das steuern. Wenn ich einen

hohen Preis-Anker stelle, ist der Kunde bereit mehr für andere Produkte zu bezahlen. Im

Discounter sehen Sie oft Reisen angeboten, warum machen die das? Wenn man einen hohen

Preispunkt sieht, dann wirkt alles drum herum billiger. Da gibt es Preispsychologische Tricks, die

man anwenden kann. Man kann auch einen selektiven Vertrieb nutzen um die

Zahlungsbereitschaft zu steigern. Der Preis kann auch als Indikator für Qualität genutzt werden,

das wird viel in der Luxus-Industrie gemacht, da gibt es teilweise inverse Preis-Absatz-

Funktionen, das heißt je teurer das Produkt, desto mehr wird es verkauft. Da gibt es sehr viele

Möglichkeiten. Natürlich ist auch das Produkt an sich sehr wichtig.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass eine höhere Online Transparenz dazu führt, dass Konsumenten

mehr Zeit mit der Suche nach Preis-Informationen verbringen?

Ich glaube schon, viel mehr als früher. Das hängt stark von dem Produkt ab. Da gibt es

102

verschiedene Dimensionen, die das beeinflussen. Wie viel investiere ich, wie stark bin ich

emotional involviert – wie wichtig ist das Produkt. Beispielsweise Kleidung – damit stelle ich

mich dar, aber ich suche nach Preisen. Aber bei Kleidung ist der Vergleich eher schwierig, weil sie

sich schwierig vergleichen lässt. Ist es ein Impulsgut oder ein Plankauf, auch das spielt eine Rolle.

Wie viele Entscheider sind involviert, das beeinflusst die Suche ebenfalls. Es kommt natürlich

auch darauf an, wie oft man ein Produkt kauft.

Haben Kosten- und Preistransparenz einen direkten Einfluss auf die willingness to pay eines

Konsumenten?

In gewissen Bereichen auf jeden Fall. Sowohl nach oben als auch nach oben. Transparenz auf der

Preisseite bedeutet oft auch mehr Transparenz auf der Qualitätsseite. Wenn ein Produkt gut ist, bin

ich auch bereit mehr zu zahlen.

Denken Sie dass die größten Vorteile von Transparenz die neuen Möglichkeiten der

Preispolitik und Marktforschung/Big Data sind?

Der Vorteil ist natürlich, dass ich eine viel größere Kundengruppe ansprechen kann. Das ist glaube

ich der größte Vorteil. Den Vorteil kann nicht jeder nutzen, weil das Internetverhalten sehr

eingeschränkt ist. Es gibt nur noch einige wenige Startseiten auf die der Kunde sucht. Wenn ich da

nicht bin, dann bringt mir das Internet auch nichts. Das Internet bringt mir nur was, wenn ich es

schaffe, im relevanten Set des Kunden zu sein. Man kann auf Plattformen aktiv werden, aber da

kann ich mich nur über Preis profilieren.

Ansonsten, wenn ich Kunden habe, dann weiß ich viel mehr über sie. Wenn ich die Informationen

richtig auswerte, dann kann ich den Kunden auch gezielt ansprechen. Das können nicht viele, denn

die Datenanalyse ist sehr komplex. Spielwarenhändler haben ein starkes Problem, in Läden ihren

Mehrwert darzustellen und im Internet gibt es nur wenige Händler, die das vertreiben. So

jemandem empfehle ich, zu schauen, wie er seinen Zielkunden aufgreifen kann. Auch für

Hersteller ist das Internet ein gewisses Risiko, weil sie die Vermarktung nicht mehr zu 100%

steuern können. Das kann auch zu Markenschädigung führen.

Sind Sie der Meinung dass die größten Nachteile die erhöhte Transparenz für Kunden und

die Gefahr von Arbitrage sind?

Das ist ein Riesenproblem.

Hat das Internet das Risiko und die Möglichkeiten zu Arbitrage vergrößert?

Das Internet macht es einfacher, Produkte im Ausland zu bestellen. Daher ist das Risiko größer

als in der Vergangenheit. Auch durch die Währungsschwankungen in der Welt. Das ist auch auf

der B2B Seite so, gerade bei Großhändlern, die im Internet agieren.

Wie kann Marketing im Allgemeinen Arbitrage entgegen wirken?

Was kann man gegen Arbitrage machen? Man sollte immer im Blick haben, dass die

Zahlungsbereitschaft im eigenen Land und in anderen Ländern. Wer profitiert von Arbitrage? Man

kann die Händlerpreise nicht direkt beeinflussen. Man kann das also nur über Listenpreise und

Konditionen machen, sodass extreme Preisunterschiede nicht vorkommen.

Wird dynamic pricing im Allgemeinen als unfair angesehen?

Zum einen muss es transparent sein, dass er es überhaupt merkt. Wenn es dann keine Erklärung

gibt, dann ist es schlecht. Es gibt immer mehr elektronische Preisschilder – es gilt die Frage: Kann

ich das innerhalb eines Tages ändern? Eher nein, denn sonst kann es sein dass der Kunde es direkt

merkt. Das ist im Laden. Im Internet kann es schon mal passieren dass morgens und abends die

Preise unterschiedlich sind. Das wirkt nicht so unfair, denn man ist gewohnt, dass es dynamisch

ist. Wenn man aufgrund persönlicher Eigenschaften, zum Beispiel ob ich ein iPad oder ein anderes

Tablet benutze, im Preis differenziert wäre, dann wäre ich zickig.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass dynamic pricing eher bei vergänglichen Produkten/Services

funktioniert?

Auf jeden Fall. Knappheit. Das funktioniert aber auch bei Produkten mit hohen Fixkosten und

geringen Variablen Kosten. Aus Konsumentensicht versteht jeder, dass bei Knappheit ein Produkt

teurer wird. Das kann man erklären. Bestimmte Mechanismen sind vom Konsumenten erlernt.

Welche Vorteile hat das Unternehmen durch dynamic pricing?

Man kann Zahlungsbereitschaft abschöpfen. Und man kann die Kapazitäten ausnutzen.

103

Ist dynamic pricing die Zukunft der Preispolitik?

Ich glaube es wird dynamic pricing immer geben. Wenn Unternehmen schlau sind, werden sie es

nutzen. Man muss es nur schlau nutzen. Der Konsument darf sich nicht ausgenutzt fühlen. Es gab

mal Getränkeautomaten, bei denen war die Preissteuerung über die Außentemperatur gesteuert. Je

wärmer es wurde, desto teurer wurden die Getränke. Das kam nicht gut an.

Stimmen Sie zu, dass dynamic pricing nur über Online Kanäle möglich ist, da die Kosten bei

Offline Kanälen zu hoch sind?

Nein ich stimme nicht zu. Es wird dynamic pricing überall geben.

Welche Herausforderungen bestehen bei der Implementierung von dynamic pricing?

Die große Herausforderung ist, dass vernünftig auszusteuern. Genau zu wissen, wann ich welche

Preise nehmen kann.

Was ist das erste, an das Sie bei NYOP Transaktionen denken? (Produkte, Industrien,

Plattformen?)

Dass es nicht funktioniert – jedenfalls nicht, wenn der Kunde das nicht öffentlich machen muss.

Ohne Peer Pressure und ein klares Bild zur Kostensituation funktioniert es nicht. Oft machen das

Restaurants.

Ist NYOP der einfachste Weg, um willingness to pay einzufangen?

Aus meiner Sicht nicht. Die Leute haben zu wenige Preisanker.

Glauben Sie, dass der Großteil der Konsumenten die Vorteile von Coupons nutzt?

Sehr geringe Einlösquoten. Das muss nicht allgemein heißen, dass wenig genutzt wird, man wird

oft einfach überschüttet.

Sind dynamische Coupons die bessere Alternative? Was würden Sie einem Unternehmen

raten?

Ja absolut. Damit kann man die Bedürfnisse des Kunden besser ansprechen.

Appendix 8 - Interview Irene van der Wal

Do you think the internet actually offers new ways of price discrimination?

Not so much new ways, but more ways for a supplier to offer prices

Do you believe that reference prices differ between offline and online channels?

No, not really

Do you believe that reference prices differ between different cultures?

Not so much cultures, but it can differ per countries/regions

Can you imagine a situation where the reference price of a product has no influence on the

decision process?

Yes, I can imagine situations that UVP is not taken into account for a buying decision of a

customer. For instance if a customer really wants to have a specific product I believe he/she is

much more interested in the actual price he/she has to pay.

What ways of influence does a company have on the reference price?

A manufacturer can set/influence the UVP but the suppliers/resellers define the actual price.

Manufactures can communicate UVPs online on their website and to their

distribution/reseller/retail channels.

Do you believe that more online transparency influences people to spend more time looking

for price information?

I don’t think that pricing online is at all transparent. Prices changes depending on time or even

sometimes on your profile or internet buying/searching behavior. There are also many suppliers

offering the same or similar products which creates more different prices. I do believe though that

104

people spend more time to find a good price for them online, but mainly for products that do not

belong to your daily needs.

For which kind of product do people spend more time looking on the internet?

For products that do not cover their daily needs, like IT equipment, vacations, Flight tickets/hotels,

household/garden utilities, clothes…

Do you believe that transparency influences the perception of fairness?

It might be the case if it was really transparent… but at the moment I do not believe that the online

pricing processes help to create a sense of fairness… it might be even the opposite… offers

nowadays can be customized for each individual which does not provide a customer with a sense

of fairness or equal treatment.

Does transparency have an influence on the willingness to pay?

Yes I think that real transparency can help a customer to accept a certain price.

What other factors have influence on willingness to pay?

The customer needs to be able to effort the price, other factors are the quality of the products and

the service of the supplier/manufacturer. Also exclusivity of a product can have an influence.

What are the advantages of internet transparency for companies? Do you consider new

pricing possibilities and better consumer knowledge as the main advantages?

If with companies the manufacturers are meant then I am not so sure what the real advantages are

other than that it can reach more customers, which you otherwise might not have reached… for

Suppliers/Resellers the advantage is that they can differentiate pricing for different customers

(groups).

Do you believe that the main disadvantages are the increased transparency, especially in

terms of arbitrage risks?

It is not so much the pricing transparency online that provides more cross border shipments, but

more the fact that customers and traders/brokers have more access to information of other

countries suppliers/resellers to compare prices and order online. For a manufacturer anther

disadvantage I see is price erosion.

Do you think that the overall advantages are greater than the disadvantages? Do you know of

any situation where this might not be the case? Industries, products? Give an example.

Difficult to say, depends also if you are manufacturer or supplier/reseller and where you are in the

distribution chain… it for sure is much more complex…

Do you think the internet has actively increased the risk of arbitrage?

Yes it brought the possibility also to a normal customer, where in the past such activities were

much more driven by traders/brokers.

Are there certain products for which arbitrage is more likely than for others? Which

industries are more affected than others?

Yes consumables for products, but also books/cd/dvd and clothing & accessories, small utilities…

In your opinion, do access to markets, decreasing transportation costs and free trade zones

decrease the cost of arbitrage?

The accessibility has increased… it is something now that everyone can do.

How can marketing work against arbitrage?

Creating products / value propositions for only specific markets or cultures/countries.

Do you think that dynamic pricing is generally considered an unfair pricing technique by the

consumer?

It can go 2 ways… consumers that are willing to invest the time to wait for the cheapest offer will

like the dynamic pricing method. Consumers that can’t invest that time will feel that they are not

treated equally and have the feeling that they always pay a high price…

Do you think that dynamic pricing works rather with perishable goods than non-perishable

goods?

105

In theory I think it should work better with perishable goods, but if you look at flight tickets it also

seem to work for non-perishable goods.

Do you consider dynamic pricing to be important for the future or is it merely a trend?

I don’t think it is a trend, it will continue to play a role to match supply and demand.

Do you think that individual pricing can only be realized in online channels because

implementation in offline channels is too costly?

I think it can also be offered in offline channels… I even believe that that happens already in a

different. Look at bazars where you can negotiate the price, this is also done in offline channels.

What are the greatest challenges for companies concerning the implementation of dynamic

pricing?

Collecting data points of customers and competitor supplies in the area to differentiate price;

ensure that with offering different prices sustain profitable enough and have the right tools to

measure that.

Do you believe that NYOP transactions are the easiest way to capture the consumers’

willingness to pay? Yes

Is NYOP successful because the consumer determines the price himself and therefore feels a

higher sense of fairness?

It is not the sense of fairness, but more how much a consumer can pay and is willing to pay for a

type of product. If the consumer finds out that he/she has paid much more in the end then the

neighbour this can then also end up in feelings of unfair treatment…

Do you believe that the majority of consumers takes advantage of coupons? No

Do you think that dynamic coupons (individual coupons depending on the shopping behavior

of the consumer) make more sense than traditional ones?

It can provide more focus to only offer coupons a consumer is interested in, and increase the usage

Appendix 9 - Interview José Francisco Guzmán Tanikawa

What are the major changes that occurred in pricing over recent years?

Internet represents a great change that affects pricing, because it makes the decision process much

faster. People can check prices easily, so markets are more sensible to prices now than before the

internet era. Also globalization is a trend that has affected pricing, because competition in these

days is worldwide, so now you can compete in different markets and vice versa.

In general, what kind of pricing should companies do?

Unfortunately, most companies have cost driven or profit driven pricing strategies; those strategies

fails to know the perceived value of the brand by the target market and in consequence, companies

fail to translate that value into the product price and that creates a “bump” in the marketing mix.

Do you think the internet actually offers new ways of price discrimination?

The internet by itself doesn’t do that, price discrimination is achieved when you find different

targets that have different price sensitivities or that assign a different value to a same product.

Internet offers you the possibility to access those different markets, but you first need to identify

them and observe if there is a difference between price sensitivity.

What kind of new methods do you know about? Which kind of price discrimination would

you recommend for to a company?

I think that there is no best/worst strategy for price discrimination. The trick is to find the

difference between the targets, that’s the tough question. How do I do the segmentation in order to

find different responses to price? When you find the segments, it is easiest to know how you are

going to do the price discrimination.

Do you believe that reference prices differ between offline and online channels? Do you

believe that reference prices differ between different cultures?

106

Yes, but the odds of existing reference prices are different between them. In an online market,

reference price is almost a must. You can easily have a reference price, just going to another

website of a different store or provider. In offline channels, you need to do the job, and go store by

store doing that. Some consumers are not willing to do that, so they are not going to have a

reference price or an “accurate” reference price. Looking for this differences among cultures it is a

little more difficult. I don’t think that the culture by itself could be a more significant driver than

the off/online one.

Which other factors have influence on reference prices? Does this, in your opinion, hold for

all kinds of products?

Well, I think the more price sensibility, the more probable is a high influence of the reference

price. Also in a product of high involvement, in which you need to be sure about the decision that

you are going to make, a reference price is important. Also in products that communicate luxury, it

is important to have a reference price, because if you don’t have it, you don’t know if you are

communicating right.

Can you imagine a situation where the reference price of a product has no influence on the

decision process?

Commodities perhaps, or products with low involvement in which you are willing to give it a try,

the reference price is not that important. Anyway, you always have a reference price or at least a

floor and a roof of how much you are willing to spend on that product, in the end, it has the same

purpose.

What ways of influence does a company have on the reference price?

Depends of the leadership they have in the market. Generally the leader in the market sets the

reference price of the category. Sometimes challengers create new categories or subcategories of

products, and the reference price is a part of the architecture of that new category.

Do you believe that more online transparency influences people to spend more time looking

for price information? It depends how important the decision it is to you. The involvement in the

decision is crucial in order to know the amount of information the customer is willing to have. If

you have a low involvement product like a soap, consumers are not willing to handle a lot of

information but for an insurance or a car, they will be.

What are the main changes that arise with the internet for consumers?

Faster decisions, a broad amount of SKUs to choose, a lot of information to handle

(manufacturers, users recommendations, critics from specialized media, etc.)

What are the consequences of higher transparency?

The more transparency, the pickier the consumer will be about misleading perceptions but on the

other hand, it can boost confidence for a company.

For which kind of product do people spend more time looking on the internet? Do only certain

kind of people look for information?

Of course that depends on the segment itself. A millennial will be much more willing to invest

time looking on the internet than a baby boomer. But even between millennials, there are different

segments and interest between them.

Do you believe that transparency influences the perception of fairness because consumers

can build up their knowledge and experience?

If they have the enough knowledge to “understand that transparency” I think that yes. But if not, it

can mislead an inexpert consumer. For instance, for a mechanical engineer, it’s quite important to

know the details of the car they are buying and have transparency of the costs of the vehicle, but

for “John Smith” perhaps it will be too much information and he would create his own conclusions

that could be wrong or at least different, just because you are giving them that information.

How does the consumer react to transparency?

Hard to know. I think that if a consumer is not expecting or demanding the transparency, he could

not react the way we are looking for.

What other factors have influence on fairness perception?

Brand equity it is a big factor that have a great influence of fairness perception.

107

Which consequences does the feeling of fairness or unfairness have for the

customer/company relationship?

It depends of the amount of options that the consumer has and also the variance of fairness

perception that the consumer has from the competition. For example, you can have a great feeling

of unfairness with the company, but it is the only company that provides you that product or

service or, that perception is equal with other companies, then the consequences are low or null.

Also it depends on the loyalty between consumer and company; if a loyal consumer feels an unfair

relation with the company, their reaction will be stronger against the company that if he is a brand

switcher or if he has a low brand equity of that brand.

How can a company influence the fairness perception of a consumer?

Constructing a strong brand equity and a big loyalty can create a fairness perception of the deal.

Also positive “real” comments in social media can create a fairness perception very fast.

Does transparency have an influence on the willingness to pay?

I think that it has, but there are other factors that could be more important like the competence

reaction or the consumer trends and behaviours.

What other factors have influence on willingness to pay?

Consumer segment behavior, competence (reaction and actual), external variables (like economics

or even the weather; you are more willing to pay a higher price for a coffee when it is cold than

when it is hot).

Does this apply to all consumers or are there differences?

No, there are differences; it depends on the market segment. That is precisely what a willingness to

pay model should find.

How can companies use price transparency to their advantage?

First of all, the transparency by itself should give them an advantage; 2nd, the issue by itself should

be relevant for the target market; 3rd, competence should be unable to take advantage by the

transparency effect.

What are the advantages of internet transparency for companies? Do you see new pricing

possibilities and better consumer knowledge as the main advantages? If not, what are the

most important advantages?

Of course, the best advantage is knowledge, which is power for the consumer. The trick is to use

that knowledge in favour of the company.

Do you believe that the main disadvantages are the increased transparency, especially in

terms of arbitrage risks? What other disadvantages can you imagine? Do these differ with

industries? Arbitrage and cannibalism are always risks in these strategies. People should take

advantage of the transparency and make an additional gain if they know how to exploit the gap

that they have found. Or other consumers will shift their behaviours and buy similar or other

products that give the same value and are a better price option (if the company has a portfolio with

different SKUs)

Do you think that the overall advantages are greater than the disadvantages?

I think that it depends how you deploy the strategy. If you are careless with the execution of the

strategy and you don’t create barriers or controls to mitigate or decrease the arbitrage, the loss

could be more than the gain.

Do you think the internet has actively increased the risk of arbitrage?

Mhhh… perhaps it has increased the perception of the opportunity, but internet by itself doesn’t

provides the tool to take advantage, because the go-to market cost of the internet is significant

lower that the one of the person or company that can take advantage of the revenue. Of course, he

can deploy products to people that are out of range of the internet by himself, but it’s a little more

complicated to take advantage of the opportunity than in traditional retailer marketing.

Which other effect does the internet have on arbitrage?

I think that it doesn’t have a great effect, because internet could reach everybody. Perhaps if

people don’t have a way to pay online (credit card, PayPal account, etc.), it could represent an

108

opportunity for them. Another thing is, that the product is not available for a country with the

original internet seller for some or all consumers and you can make the product available to them.

Are there certain products for which arbitrage is more likely than for others? Which

industries are more affected than others?

The higher the amount of sales of a product with more retailers in the distribution channel, the

greater the risk or arbitrage (if you applied, of course, price discrimination strategies).

That is because it is much more complicated for you to notice the arbitrage with a lot of retailers,

that with a few of them.

In your opinion, do access to markets, decreasing transportation costs and growing free

trade zones decrease the cost of arbitrage?

It can help to promote arbitrage, but the most important thing it is that both parts can take profit

from the situation. Of course that all of this factors could help, but if there is not a big gap between

the two markets or regions in which the arbitrage it’s done and price sensitivity (or brand equity)

it’s also quite different, the reductions in costs are not enough.

How do companies protect themselves from arbitrage?

The most obvious is to not create a price gap so big, that it could motivate arbitrage. Other options

could be to reduce the amount of merchandise that a client can buy, having different codes

products for different markets (so you at least could know that you have been affected by

arbitrage) and really good overview of the retailers (suddenly a retailer is selling a lot of products,

but other retailers in other regions have a considerable reduction in their sales or the consumer

even quits buying and buys from a wholesaler or somebody else).

How can marketing work against arbitrage?

Sometimes a diverse portfolio could work, regional brands with strong brand equity could work

against arbitrage. Perhaps you can sell the same product in different markets, but with different

brands that have and strong local brand equity.

Do you think that dynamic pricing is generally considered an unfair pricing technique by the

consumer? What is the most likely reaction of the consumer?

If the price should be driven by the value that a consumer (or a segment of consumers) are giving

to a product, then dynamic pricing is very fair. The problem it is that the value that a target of

consumers gives to a product is different to other, so the perception to price is different. The fair or

unfair concept depends of which consumer segment is buying the product. And also, that

perception of value could change from one day to another in the same segment; so that is the

backbone of dynamic pricing.

What are possible consequences of dynamic pricing? How would you go to avert the

risks/negative consequences or change the consumers mind?

The trick is that you can identify patterns or variables that could, with some degree of accuracy,

pinpoint a segment of consumers from another. Airlines fares do that. A business traveller is

willing to pay more for the same ticket that a leisure traveller. Leisure travellers generally buy

their tickets earlier (1 or 2 months) than business travellers (1 week or some days before). The

main goal of dynamic pricing is the same as with revenue management; to take out the more value

from the market, but if you don’t identify the variables that can trigger the different behavior and

value from the market, then perhaps you can lose revenue or the income of a company.

Do you know of famous examples of dynamic pricing that may or may not have been

successful? Why?

All the travel industry it’s full of successful implementation of dynamic pricing. Here you also

have Revenue Management, that add some interesting features, because the services that are sold

are perishable and you cannot stock them, so that adds more complexity to the equation. But

American Airlines provided a good example in the 80s, of a successful implementation of the

principles of dynamic pricing. If the value of the product doesn’t change between time and some

observables variables between different targets, then dynamic pricing it’s more difficult to have

success. If you are going to sell ice cream in a cold weather, it doesn’t mind how much you shift

prices, the demand of that product is not very willing to change because of that.

Can you imagine any products where individual prices are accepted by the consumer?

109

You mean that the product is sold by unit and not by group or package? If that´s the main topic, it

depends on the average transaction size that the product has in that market or retailer. For instance,

individual portions of shampoo wouldn’t work in a store like Costco or Sam’s, but it could work

on an airport quick store or a convenience store in a highway.

Do you think that dynamic pricing works rather with perishable goods than non-perishable

goods?

It has more probability to increase or decrease the value in perishable goods and because of that,

dynamic pricing could be better, but is not a rule. For example, you can change the price of a

sweater or an umbrella depending of the weather condition.

How can a company take advantage of dynamic pricing?

As I said before, the trick is to identify the variables that could tell us the different segments with

different values perceptions and also the behavior of those segments. An incorrect segmentation

could lead a company to an unsuccessful dynamic pricing strategy.

Do you consider dynamic pricing to be important for the future or is it merely a trend?

It is not a trend, it is somehow new, but since the patterns and behaviours of customers remain in

the same way, dynamic pricing will be a good pricing tool.

Do you think that consumers change enough for more individual pricing techniques to

become possible?

Human beings like habits, and habits and patterns are difficult to modify, but not impossible. Of

course, there are segments of consumers easier to modify them than others. I think that a good

marketing campaign, which triggers a behavior in the customer can do that.

Do you think that individual pricing can only be realized in online channels because

implementation in offline channels is too costly?

Well, indeed it’s more complicated the implementation of individual pricing in offline than in

online, so in most of the situations, costs related with implementation in offline could overshadow

the benefits of it.

What are the main cost factors that cause the differences in costs?

Market costs and the business model. What´s the cost of an eBook that is downloaded to your

mobile device? What´s the cost of a paper book that you buy in a bookstore? It is not only the go

to market cost, also production cost it’s far different from one choice to another. And besides that,

the perceived value of buying to eBook anytime you want it, besides the “buying cost” of going to

the bookstore and buying it is important. Of course, for some customer segment, buying an eBook

is not an option, no matter the price of it (because they don’t have a mobile device, because they

prefer paper, because they don’t have a credit card or something to buy the book on line. etc.)

What are the greatest challenges for companies concerning the implementation of dynamic

pricing?

Again, a correct segmentation, a good trigger of the drivers that can identify those segments and

the tools to know the value perception of each segment its critical. Also a correct implementation

of the strategy it is very important.

Would you recommend a company to pursue dynamic pricing? What would dynamic pricing

indicate for marketing in general? What other marketing measures would have to be implemented?

If the company can take advantages of it, and have the resources; of course they should go. But if

you are in markets that are not so dynamic or that there are not visible differences between values

(commodities), it’s not worth its value.

Do you believe that NYOP transactions are the easiest way to capture the consumers’

willingness to pay?

If you remove the brand equity factor… yes, because it will measure just the price sensitivity to

the product that it is sell, but you can analyse the benefits from the product because generally, you

don’t know the brand or supplier of whatever you are bidding. The problem is that you don’t do

this in real life, generally the price value is associated with the brand, so you can make a judgment

if the price of that brand reflects the value of the brand.

With which kind of products does NYOP work?

110

More than products, its consumers with strong brand equity influence. Would you imagine a fancy

purse with this strategy? What price would you suggest for the purse if you don’t know the brand?

What is the first thing that comes to your mind about NYOP transactions (products,

platforms, industries, cases, etc.)? Can you think of any other techniques that work

similarly?

Technique by itself reminds me how things could work in B2B or with government tenders.

Is NYOP successful because the consumer determines the price himself and therefore feels a

higher sense of fairness?

Perhaps, risk adverse consumers could favour this strategy.

Does this work with all products? How can a company positively influence this process?

I don’t think that this strategy work for every product. Mass consumption products or high brand

equity products are not going to work well with this technique.

Do you believe that the majority of consumers takes advantage of coupons?

Not all of them. Consumers with high price sensitivity are more willing to use them, but even

some of them wouldn’t be able to use them. Coupons are sometimes complicated to redeem

because you have to remember the coupon and things like that. Many companies have created

mechanisms to make coupon redemption a little higher, but sometimes that causes that consumer

that were willing to pay full price, to receive a discount even if they didn’t want it.

What influences a consumer to pursue coupons?

First of all…. High price sensitivity, sometimes also a sense of fair trade or getting something

extra is also a big influence for pursing coupons.

Which kind of consumer pursues coupons etc.? Are there products where more consumers

try to find a cheaper price and others where they don’t care?

Again, price sensitivity is the trigger. If there is not a high price sensitivity in buying the product,

then the coupon is worthless. Sometimes products that are more or less the same, a preference

could be triggered with a coupon. Trial of a product is also something that can be accomplished

with coupons.

How can a company use this knowledge to implement coupons? (Dynamic coupons?)

Loyalty cards could help to use dynamic couponing. Pet stores like Petco use the loyalty as a

coupon card, and the discounts could change with multiple factors related to patterns, demands,

etc.

Appendix 10 - Interview Wolfgang Sessler

Glauben Sie, dass uns das Internet neue Möglichkeiten der Preis- Differenzierung bietet?

Ja selbstverständlich. Das ist natürlich so, dass wir als Daimler das Internet als Basis und Plattform

nutzen, um Preise darzustellen. Es geht soweit, dass man das Fahrzeug konfigurieren kann und

einen Preis in Echtzeit anzeigen lassen kann. Das unterscheidet nicht, wer der Kunde ist und das

wiederrum macht auch Probleme, wie im Nutzfahrzeug-Geschäft weil wir dort Unterschiede

machen. Ein Großkunde bekommt möglicherweise einen größeren Nachlass weil er mehr

Fahrzeuge auf einmal kauft und diese Fahrzeuge sind speziell und entsprechend gebaut und

erlauben einen größeren Nachlass. Kleinkunden bekommen den eventuell nicht. Das kann man im

Internet nicht abbilden. Ganz wesentlich ist im Gegensatz zum PKW Geschäft haben wir bei den

Nutzfahrzeugen keine allgemein Preistransparenz im Markt und der Kunde sich auf einen

Listenpreis nicht festlegen kann. Im LKW Geschäft gibt es gar keine Listenpreise mehr. Wohl aber

einen Konfigurator, ich kann also ein Fahrzeug ausstatten, erhalte aber keinen Preis – anders im

Transporter Geschäft, dort kann ich mir ein Fahrzeug zusammenstellen bis zu technischen

Einzelheiten und am Ende habe ich einen Listenpreis. Das ist aber nicht der Preis den ich zu

bezahlen habe, das ist nicht der Transaktionspreis – der ist sehr unterschiedlich.

111

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis eines Konsumenten in offline und online Kanälen

unterscheidet? Bei Mercedes ist es so, dass die Preiswahrnehmung durchaus unterschiedlich ist

zu dem tatsächlichen Preis. Wir sind es von PKW gewöhnt dass wir teurer sind als alle

Wettbewerber und dabei sind die Wettbewerber BMW und Audi und wir haben in jedem Segment

ein Preis Premium und sind teurer – darauf kann sich der Kunde verlassen. Im

Nutzfahrzeuggeschäft ist das anderes – hier gibt es keine Premium Hersteller, hier sind die

Wettbewerber Fiat, Citroen, Ford etc.

Hier herrschen andere Vorstellungen, von PKW beeinflusst wird immer der höchste Listenpreis

und auch Transaktionspreis erwartet – dem ist nicht so.

Die Diskrepanz zwischen Wahrnehmung und der tatsächlichen Preisstellung ist enorm. Durch

Marktforschung ist uns bewusst, wie groß die Vorstellung des Preises ist. In allen Segmenten wird

unser Preis überschätzt, wie der potentielle Kunde denkt.

Glauben Sie, dass sich der Referenzpreis zwischen verschiedenen Kulturen oder Ländern

unterscheidet?

Die Preisvorstellung ist in der Tat sehr unterschiedlich. Wir haben uns lange mit Europa

beschäftigt und langsam wird unser Preis nicht mehr ganz so erhöht – vor allem im Vergleich zu

VW – wahrgenommen. Aber es gibt kein Land in dem der Preis von Mercedes als niedriger

eingeschätzt wird als die Wettbewerber, dabei ist das der Fall.

Trägt das Internet dazu bei, dass höhere Transparenz herrscht?

Preisstrukturen sind intransparent, nur wenige der Kunden machen Preisvergleiche. Auch das

Internet bietet keinen objektiven Preisvergleich, weil nur Listenpreise vergleichbar sind, dabei sind

alle Preise nachlassbehaftet, bis zu 30%. Bei LKW gibt es deshalb keine Listenpreise mehr, weil

es hier in den späten 90er Jahren bis zu 50% Preisnachlässe gab.

Es ist also auch nicht gewünscht, dass der Kunde die Preisnachlässe kennt oder fehlt schlicht

die Kommunikation?

Es fehlt die Kommunikation. Wenn die Listenpreise nicht verlässlich für den Kunden sind, weil er

weiß, es gibt auf jeden Fall Nachlässe, er aber nicht weiß wie groß diese sind, dann veräppelt man

den Kunden, der fühlt sich dann betrogen. Was gelernt ist, ist gelernt, Schnäppchenkäufer sind

Schnäppchenkäufer. Dann kann es passieren, dass ich einen Listenpreis immer noch fabulöser

darstelle, der Kunde sich aber nicht mehr darauf verlassen kann.

Beeinflussen Online Foren und Austauschplätze über erhaltene Nachlässe das Fairness

Gefühl eines Kunden?

Natürlich. Es gibt den Stammtisch; Gewerbetreibende und Dienstleister treffen sich und

diskutieren. Wenn der eine 5% Nachlass bekommen hat und der Andere 30%, dann ist das

natürlich ein Grund sich zu echauffieren. Wobei bei Mercedes keine großen Unterschiede in den

Nachlässen gemacht wird, beispielsweise beim Kauf eines Sprinters ist der Rabatt immer in etwa

der Gleiche. Es gibt andere Hersteller die das tun, VW macht das sehr extrem. Das Modell von

VW gegenüber dem Sprinter ist der Crafter. Da kann es schon sein, dass man zwischen 10% und

30% Nachlässe bekommt. Der Kunde wird taxiert und wenn ein Angebot des Wettbewerbs dem

Kunden vorliegt, kann der Verkäufer durch seine Spielräume das Angebot preislich unterbieten,

bis an den Punkt, an dem keine Erlöse mehr gemacht werden.

Das liegt an den hohen Wiederkaufsraten von 90%. Wenn Sprinter, dann immer Sprinter. Wenn

VW, dann immer VW. Es muss viel passieren, damit ein Kunde die Automarke wechselt. Problem

ist wenn Kunden über die unterschiedlichen Nachlässen Bescheid wissen.

Was passiert wenn die Leute rausfinden? Kann das zum Verstoß der Marke führen? Oder

nutzt das der Kunde bei einem Wiederkauf zu seinem Vorteil, weil er weiß wie viel Rabatt er

erwarten kann?

Das ist sehr schwer zu greifen, da VW die Politik fährt, die Kundennettopreise möglichst zu

verschleiern, sodass Intransparenz in den Markt gelangt; mit immer neuen Sondermodellen,

Editionsmodelle, Aktionen etc. um zu vermeiden, dass Transparenz entsteht.

Hat das Internet das Risiko und die Möglichkeiten zu Arbitrage vergrößert?

Wir versuchen zu verhindern, dass die sogenannten Übergrenzgeschäfte zur Normalität werden.

Wir können zum Beispiel am Drei-Länder-Eck Transparenz durch die Niederlassungen nicht

112

verhindern, aber es ist die Ausnahme. Wir haben sehr unterschiedliche nationale Kundenbindung,

die es nicht einfach macht, in anderen Ländern zu kaufen.

Glauben Sie, dass hauptsächlich der erleichterte Zugang zu Märkten, geringere

Transportkosten und Freihandelszonen die Arbitrage Kosten verringern?

Sollte man meinen, aber das ist eigentlich nicht der Fall. Obwohl wir einen EU Markt haben, weil

es unterschiedliche Vorgehensweisen gibt, in UK gibt es zum Beispiel Fahrzeuge auf Lager „build

to stock“ und in Deutschland „build to order“, auf Bestellung.

Wie kann Marketing im Allgemeinen Arbitrage entgegen wirken?

Wir haben normalerweise im Nutzfahrzeugbereich die Betriebe mit ihrer zugehörigen Werkstatt,

vor allem in der Garantiezeit. In dieser Zeit sollte die Werkstatt mit der landesspezifischen

Ausstattung konform ist. Hier unterscheiden sich die Länder wie Frankreich und Deutschland

schon sehr. Eine deutsche Vertragswerkstatt würde einen französischen Sprinter nicht ohne

weiteres aufnehmen. Oft wird auch geleast oder finanziert, hier sind Serviceverträge mit

einbegriffen.

Was wird aktiv in Richtung Preiswahrnehmung unternommen?

Die Preiswahrnehmung von Mercedes wird überschätzt, Preisvergleiche könnten helfen, um diese

komplett falsche Preiswahrnehmung zu verhindern. Trotzdem liegen unsere Listenpreise höher,

hier muss man aufpassen, denn wir können auch keine geringeren Listenpreise machen, ohne dass

Wettbewerber reagieren.

Der Sprinter, der traditionell als deutsches Markenprodukt immer noch in Düsseldorf produziert

wird, wird in manchen Märkten regelrecht verramscht. Der Grund für die niedrigen Preise sind die

Verkaufsgesellschaften, die argumentieren, dass sie die vorgebebenen Mengen mit den Preisen

nicht schaffen und für höhere Mengen die Preise nach unten gehen müssen. Das stimmt nicht. Es

gibt hier keine Nachfrageelastizität. Niedrigere Preise werden die Menge nicht erhöhen.

Ist ein Einstiegspreis eine bessere Möglichkeit?

Die Sticker-Fahrzeuge sind als Fahrzeug meist untauglich. Sie dienen lediglich der

Preiskommunikation, um ins Relevant Set zu kommen.

Wird dynamic Pricing im Allgemeinen als unfair angesehen?

Es ist gelernte Wirklichkeit. Das Bier in Frankreich am Strand ist teurer als das in Ihrer

Stammkneipe. Man ist es gewohnt, das in allen Konsumbereichen zu erleben. Bei

Investitionsgütern ist es durch die rationale Werteinschätzung anders. Im Automobilbereich

verstehen die Leute auch, wenn nach Kriterien wie der langjährigen Kundenbindung preislich

differenziert wird.

Sind Sie der Meinung, dass dynamic Pricing eher bei vergänglichen Produkten/Services

funktioniert?

Bei Reparaturen wird es immer andere Preise geben. Es gibt Vorgaben, aber die Werkstatt

unterscheidet sich. Das ist auch irgendwie akzeptiert.

113

Publication bibliography

Adams, John S. (1965): Inequity in social exchange. In Leonard Berkowitz (Ed.):

Advances in experimental social psychology, vol. 2: New York: Academic Press,

pp. 267–299.

Bakos, J. Yannis (1991): A strategic analysis of electronic marketplaces. In MIS

Quarterly 15 (3), pp. 295–310.

Bakos, J. Yannis (1997): Reducing buyer search costs: Implications for electronic

marketplaces. In Management Science 43 (12), pp. 1676–1692.

Bannock, Graham; Baxter, Ron E.; Davis, Evan (1992): The Penguin dictionary

of economics. 5. ed. London: Penguin books.

Biswas, Abhijit; Blair, Edward A. (1991): Contextual effects of reference prices in

retail advertisements. In Journal of Marketing 55 (3), pp. 1–12.

Bitran, Gabriel R.; Ferrer, Juan-Carlos.

Bloomsbury Business Library (2007): Business & management dictionary: A&C

Black Publishers Ltd.

Bolton, Lisa E.; Warlop, Luk; Alba, Joseph W. (2003): Consumer perceptions of

price (un)fairness. In Journal of Consumer Research 29 (4), pp. 474–491.

Briesch, Richard A.; Krishnamurthi, Lakshman; Mazumdar, Tridib, Raj, S.P.

(1997): A comparative analysis of reference price models. In Journal of

Consumer Research 24 (2), pp. 202–214.

Brynjolfsson, Erik; Smith, Michael D. (2000): Frictionless commerce? A

comparison of internet and conventional retailers. In Management Science 46 (4),

pp. 563–585.

Burnkrant, Robert E.; Unnava, H. Rao (1995): Effects of self-referencing on

persuasion. In Journal of Consumer Research 22 (1), pp. 17–26.

Campbell, Margaret C. (1999): Perceptions of price unfairness. Antecedents and

consequences. In Journal of Marketing Research 36 (2), p. 187. DOI:

10.2307/3152092.

Carroll, Kathleen; Coates, Dennis (1999): Teaching price discrimination: some

clarification. In Southern Economic Journal 66 (2), pp. 466–480, checked on

7/22/2015.

Cassady, Ralph (1946): Techniques and purposes of price discrimination. In

Journal of Marketing 11 (2), p. 135. DOI: 10.2307/1246769.

114

Chernev, Alexander (2003): Reverse pricing and online price elicitation strategies

in consumer choice. In Journal of Consumer Psychology 13 (1-2), pp. 51–62.

Clerides, Sofronis K. (2004): Price discrimination with differentiated products.

Definition and identification. In Economic Inquiry 42 (3), pp. 402–412.

Cox, Jennifer L. (2001): Can differential prices be fair? In Journal of Product &

Brand Management 10 (5), pp. 264–275.

Dastidar, Krishnendu Ghosh (2006): Third-degree price discrimination in

oligopoly. In The Manchester School 74 (2), pp. 231–249.

Debevec, Kathleen; Romeo, Jean B. (1992): Self-referent processing in

perceptions of verbal and visual commercial information. In Journal of Consumer

Psychology 1 (1), pp. 83–102.

Degeratu, Alexandru M.; Rangaswamy, Arvind; Wu, Jianan (2000): Consumer

choice behavior in online and traditional supermarkets. The effects of brand name,

price, and other search attributes. In International Journal of Research in

Marketing 17 (1), pp. 55–78.

Elegido, Juan M. (2011): The ethics of price discrimination. In Business Ethics

Quarterly 21 (4), pp. 633–660, checked on 7/10/2015.

Elmaghraby, Wedad; Keskinocak, Pinar (2003): Dynamic pricing in the presence

of inventory considerations. Research overview, current practices, and future

directions. In Management Science 49 (10), pp. 1287–1309.

Encaoua, David; Hollander, Abraham (2007): First-degree discrimination by a

duopoly. Pricing and quality choice. In The B.E. Journal of Theoretical

Economics 7 (1), pp. 1–19. Available online at

https://papyrus.bib.umontreal.ca/xmlui/bitstream/handle/1866/1481/2005-01.pdf,

checked on 6/28/2015.

Federal Anti-Discrimination Agency (2006): Equal treatment act.

Fay, Scott (2004): Partial-repeat-bidding in the Name-Your-Own-Price channel.

In Marketing Science 23 (3), pp. 407–418.

Fulgoni, Gian (2014): Numbers, please: Big Data: Friend or foe of digital

advertising? Five ways marketers should use digital big data to their advantage. In

Journal of Advertising Research 53 (4), pp. 372–376.

Galitz, Wilbert O. (2008): The essential guide to user interface design. An

introduction to GUI design principles and techniques. 2nd ed. Hoboken: John

Wiley & Sons Inc (CourseSmart).

115

Garbarino, Ellen; Lee, Olivia F. (2003): Dynamic pricing in internet retail: effects

on consumer trust. In Psychology & Marketing 20 (6), pp. 495–513.

Garbarino, Ellen; Maxwell, Sarah (2010): Consumer response to norm-breaking

pricing events in e-commerce. In Journal of Business Research 63 (9-10),

pp. 1066–1072.

Granados, Nelson; Gupta, Alok; Kauffman, Robert J. (2006): The impact of IT on

market information and transparency: A unified theoretical framework. In Journal

of the Association for Information Systems 7 (3), pp. 148–178.

Granados, Nelson; Gupta, Alok; Kauffman, Robert J. (2008): Designing online

selling mechanisms: Transparency levels and prices. In Decision Support Systems

45 (4), pp. 729–745.

Granados, Nelson; Gupta, Alok; Kauffman, Robert J. (2010): Information

transparency in Business-to-Consumer markets: Concepts, framework, and

research agenda. In Information Systems Research 21 (2), pp. 207–226.

Hardesty, David M.; Suter, Tracy A. (2005): E-tail and retail reference price

effects. In Journal of Product & Brand Management 14 (2), pp. 129–136.

Hardie, Bruce G. S.; Johnson, Eric J.; Fader, Peter S. (1993): Modeling loss

aversion and reference dependence effects on brand choice. In Marketing Science

12 (4), pp. 378–395.

Heeler, Roger M.; Nguyen, Adam; Buff, Cheryl (2007): Bundles = discount?

Revisiting complex theories of bundle effects. In Journal of Product & Brand

Management 16 (7), pp. 492–500.

Henry, Paul (2005): Is the internet empowering consumers to make better

decisions, or strengthening marketers' potential to persuade? In Curtis P.

Haugtvedt, Karen A. Machleit, Richard Yalch (Eds.): Online consumer

psychology. Understanding and influencing consumer behavior in the virtual

world. New Jersey: Psychology Press, pp. 345–360.

Hinz, Oliver; Hann, Il-Horn; Spann, Martin (2011): Price discrimination in e-

commerce? An examination of dynamic pricing in Name-Your-Own-Price

markets. In MIS Quarterly 35 (1), pp. 81–98.

Holmes, Thomas J. (1989): The effects of third-degree price discrimination in

oligopoly. In The American Economic Review 79 (1), pp. 244–250, checked on

7/9/2015.

Huang, Jen-Hung; Chang, Ching-Te; Chen, Cathy Yi-Hsuan (2005): Perceived

fairness of pricing on the Internet. In Journal of Economic Psychology 26 (3),

pp. 343–361. DOI: 10.1016/j.joep.2004.03.002.

116

Huppertz, John W.; Arenson, Sidney J.; Evans, Richard H. (1978): An application

of equity theory to buyer-seller exchange situations. In Journal of Marketing

Research 15 (2), pp. 250–260.

Janiszewski, Chris; Lichtenstein, Donald R. (1999): A range theory account of

price perception. In Journal of Consumer Research 25 (4), pp. 353–368.

Jayaraman, Vaidyanathan; Baker, Tim (2003): The internet as an enabler for

dynamic pricing of goods. In IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 50

(4), pp. 470–477.

Kahneman, Daniel; Knetsch, Jack L.; Thaler, Richard (1986): Fairness as a

constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. In American Economic

Review 76 (4), pp. 728–741.

Kalwani, Manohar U.; Yim, Chi Kin; Rinne, Heikki J.; Sugita, Yoshi (1990): A

price expectation model of customer brand choice. In Journal of Marketing

Research 27 (3), pp. 251–262.

Kalyanaram, Gurumurthy; Little, John D. C. (1994): An empirical analysis of

latitude of price acceptance in consumer package goods. In Journal of Consumer

Research 21 (3), pp. 408–418.

Kalyanaram, Gurumurthy; Winer, Russell S. (1995): Empirical generalizations

from reference price research. In Marketing Science 14 (3), pp. 161–169.

Kannan, P. K.; Kopalle, Praveen K. (2001): Dynamic pricing on the internet.

Importance and implications for consumer behavior. In International Journal of

Electronic Commerce 5 (3), pp. 63–83.

Landsburg, Steven E. (2010): Price theory and applications. 8th ed. Australia,

Mason, OH: South-Western/Cengage Learning.

Lattin, James M.; Bucklin, Randolf E. (1989): Reference effects of price and

promotion on brand choice behavior. In Journal of Marketing Research 26 (3),

pp. 299–310.

Levy, Daniel; Bergen, Mark; Dutta, Shantanu; Venable, Robert (1997): The

magnitude of menu costs: Direct evidence from large U.S. supermarket chains. In

The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (3), pp. 791–825.

Machlup, Fritz (1955): Characteristics and types of price discrimination. In

Business Concentration and Price Policy, pp. 397–440, checked on 6/28/2015.

Mankiw, N. Gregory (2008): Principles of economics. 5th ed. Mason, Ohio: South

Western Educ Pub.

117

Manyika, James; Chui, Michael; Brown, Brad; Bughin, Jacques; Dobbs, Richard;

Roxburgh, Charles; Byers, Angela (2011): Big data: The next frontier for

innovation, competition and productivity. McKinsey Global Institute.

Marn, Michael V.; Rosiello, Robert L. (1992): Managing price, gaining profit. In

Harvard Business Review, 1992, pp. 84–93, checked on 3/26/2016.

Maskin, Eric; Riley, John (1984): Optimal auctions with risk averse buyers. In

Econometrica 52 (6), pp. 1473–1518.

Masterson, Rosalind; Pickton, David (2010): Marketing. An introduction. 2. ed.

London: SAGE.

Maxwell, Sarah (2008): The price is wrong. Understanding what makes a price

seem fair and the true cost of unfair pricing. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley. Available

online at http://www.loc.gov/catdir/enhancements/fy0741/2007032153-d.html.

Mayhew, Glenn E.; Winer, Russell S. (1992). An empirical analysis of internal

and external reference prices using scanner data. In Journal of Consumer

Research 19 (1), pp. 62–70.

McAfee, R. Preston (2008): Price discrimination. In Wayne Dale Collins (Ed.):

Issues in competition law and policy, vol. 1. 3 volumes. Chicago: ABA Book

Publishing; American Bar Association, pp. 465–484, checked on 6/30/2015.

McConnell, Campbell R.; Brue, Stanley L.; Flynn, Sean Masaki (2012):

Microeconomics. Principles, problems, and policies. 19. ed. New York, NY:

McGraw-Hill/Irwin (The McGraw-Hill series economics).

Milgrom, Paul (1987): An essay on price discrimination. University of California,

Berkeley. Institute of Business and Economic Research.

Milgrom, Paul; Weber, Robert J. (1982): A Theory of auctions and competitive

bidding. In Econometrica 50 (5), pp. 1089–1122.

Miller, Roger LeRoy (2012): Economics today. The micro view. 16th ed. Boston:

Addison-Wesley/Pearson (The Pearson series in economics).

Monroe, Kent B. (1973): Buyers' subjective perception of price. In Journal of

Marketing Research 10 (1), pp. 70–80.

Monroe, Kent B.; Lee, Angela Y. (1999): Remembering versus knowing: Issues

in buyer's processing of price information. In Journal of the Academy of

Marketing Science 27 (2), pp. 207–225.

Nguyen, Adam; Heeler, Roger M.; Buff, Cheryl (2009): Consumer perceptions of

bundles. In Journal of Product & Brand Management 18 (3), pp. 218–225.

118

Nicholson, Walter; Snyder, Christopher M. (2010): Intermediate microeconomics

and its application. 11th ed. Mason, Ohio: South-Western/Cengage Learning.

Oh, Wonseok; Lucas, Henry C. (2006): Information technology and pricing

decisions: Price adjustments in online computer markets. In MIS Quarterly 30 (3),

pp. 755–775.

Phlips, Louis (1983): The economics of price discrimination. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Pigou, Arthur Cecil (1920): The economics of welfare. 1st ed. London: Macmillan

and Co., checked on 6/28/2015.

Rajendran, K. N.; Tellis, Gerard J. (1994): Contextual and temporal components

of reference price. In Journal of Marketing 58 (1), pp. 22–34.

Robinson, Joan (1969): The economics of imperfect competition. 2. ed. London:

Macmillan.

United States Congress (1936): Robinson-Patman Act. 15 U.S.C. § 13.

Source: United States Code.

Schmalensee, Richard (1981): Output and welfare implications of monopolistic

third-degree price discrimination. In The American Economic Review 71 (1),

pp. 242–247.

Schneidau, R. E.; Knutson, Ronald D. (1969): Price discrimination in the food

industry: A competitive stimulant or tranquilizer? In American Journal of

Agricultural Economics 51 (5), pp. 1143–1148.

Shapiro, Carl (1983): Premiums for high quality products as returns to reputation.

In The Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (4), pp. 659–680.

Shepherd, William G.; Shepherd, Joanna M. (2004): The economics of industrial

organization. 5. ed. Long Grove, Ill.: Waveland Press.

Sinha, Atanu R.; Greenleaf, Eric A. (2000): The impact of discrete bidding and

bidder aggressiveness on sellers' strategies in open English auctions: Reserves and

covert shilling. In Marketing Science 19 (3), pp. 244–265.

Sinha, Indrajit (2000): Cost transparency: The net's real threat to prices and

brands. In Harvard Business Review, 2000, pp. 43–50.

Smith, Michael D. (2002): The impact of shopbots on electronic markets. In

Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 30 (4), pp. 446–454.

Spann, Martin; Skiera, Bernd; Schäfers, Björn (2004): Measuring individual

frictional costs and willingness to pay via Name-Your-Own-Price mechanisms. In

Journal of Interactive Marketing 18 (4), pp. 22–36.

119

Spann, Martin; Tellis, Gerard J. (2006): Does the internet promote better

consumer decisions? The case of Name-Your-Own-Price auctions. In Journal of

Marketing 70 (1), pp. 65–78.

Stigler, George Joseph (1987): The theory of price. 4. ed. New York, NY:

Macmillan.

Stole, Lars A. (2007): Price discrimination and competition. In M. Armstrong, R.

Porter (Eds.): Handbook of industrial organization, vol. 3. 3 volumes: Elsevier

(Handbook of Industrial Organization), pp. 2221–2299.

Synder, Herbert; Davenport, Elisabeth (1997): What does it really cost?

Allocating indirect costs. In The Bottom Line 10 (4), pp. 158–164.

Tang, Fang-Fang; Xing, Xiaolin (2001): Will the growth of multi-channel

retailing diminish the pricing of efficiency of the web? In Journal of Retailing 77

(3), pp. 319–333.

Terwiesch, Christian; Savin, Sergei; Hann, Il-Horn.

Tirole, Jean (1988): The theory of industrial organization. 1st ed. Cambridge,

Mass.: MIT Press.

Vaidyanathan, Rajiv; Aggarwal, Praveen (2003): Who is the fairest of them all?

An attributional approach to price fairness perceptions. In Journal of Business

Research 56 (6), pp. 453–463. DOI: 10.1016/S0148-2963(01)00231-4.

Varian, Hal R. (1985): Price discrimination and social welfare. In The American

Economic Review 75 (4), pp. 870–875.

Varian, Hal R. (1989): Price discrimination. In Richard Schmalensee, Robert

Willig (Eds.): Handbook of industrial organization. 1. ed., [7.] reprint. 3 volumes.

Amsterdam: Elsevier (1), pp. 597–654.

Varian, Hal R. (1992): Microeconomic analysis. 3. ed., internat. student ed. New

York: Norton.

Vickrey, William (1961): Counterspeculation, auctions and competitive sealed

tenders. In The Journal of Finance 16 (1), pp. 8–37.

Wierich, Ralf; Zielke, Stephan (2014): How retailer coupons increase attitudinal

loyalty - the impact of three coupon design elements. In European Journal of

Marketing 48 (3/4), pp. 699–721.

Winer, Russell S. (1986): A reference price model of brand choice for frequently

purchased products. In Journal of Consumer Research 13 (2), pp. 250–256.

Wolk, Agnieska; Spann, Martin.

120

Xia, Lan; Monroe, Kent B.; Cox, Jennifer L. (2004): The price is unfair! A

conceptual framework of price fairness perceptions. In Journal of Marketing 68

(4), pp. 1–15.

Zettelmeyer, Florian (2000): Expanding to the internet: Pricing and

communications strategies when firms compete in multiple channels. In Journal

of Marketing Research 37 (3), pp. 292–308.

Zhu, Kevin (2002): Information transparency in electronic marketplaces: Why

data transparency may hinder the adoption of B2B exchanges. In Electronic

Markets 12 (2), pp. 92–99.