latifa daadaoui encg, université ibn zohr, agadir -...

25
Governance for collective innovation: The French cluster initiative (pôle de compétitivité) for the new bio-based activities Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc [email protected] EMNET, Agadir, November 2013

Upload: dinhkhue

Post on 12-Sep-2018

251 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation: The French cluster initiative (pôle de compétitivité)

for the new bio-based activities

Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc

[email protected]

EMNET, Agadir, November 2013

Page 2: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 2/25

Abstract

« How to organise collective action to be innovative ?», here is a burning question. Collective action for innovation is characterized by a lack of knowledge that has to be created, and high uncertainty. The governance of these relationships is thus critical. Our research explores two elements: (i) the role of knowledge in the design of governance (ii) the main characteristics of governance design in the case of exploration involving different actors (research, industry) under government help within the French competitiveness clusters for new non-food applications called agro-resources industries. (1) The concept of governance has long been discussed in the literature but never defined and conceptualized for relations and for the particular and delicate case of knowledge issues (2) The link between three concepts always treated separately: Knowledge, innovation and governance. (3) The particular context of competitiveness clusters launched in France on 2005 is interesting to study. The aim of the cluster is to boost innovation and to have international visibility through a territorial base and combining the strengths of local Academic Research, Industry and Training under the eye of public power. Research question: How to govern collective action for knowledge process in the context of cluster competitiveness for new bio-based activities? Methodology: Since 2005, the innovation projects to develop this new technology of non-food applications of agricultural products abound. The collective exploration between research and industry under the benevolent eye of the public power is advocated among other organizational forms because of the great uncertainty that accompanies such projects. Organizational complexity and diversity of forms of relationship is special to this new industry called agro-resources. We used a qualitative and explorative methodology by studying the case of exploration of the second generation of bio-fuels. Findings: Our research provides an extended analytical framework for the study of governance in the context of collective innovation. We suggest that the hybrid governance is the most suitable for it. The design of efficient governance structures between industry and research must take into account the characteristics of innovation process. We found the existence of multi-level governance and using diverse mechanisms of governance and must be complement for high effectiveness. Contribution: Understanding what will determine the success or failure of collective innovation in terms of governance. We propose a framework for understanding the specific case of innovation and knowledge process in a new activity with great uncertainty and complexity. Our study helps to better understand the knowledge governance (Foss, 2007). Practical implications: Our research aims providing a renewed and extended perspective of the concept of governance. We give an insight on modern innovation processes, where the boarders between industry, research and public authority are blurred. For managers, this topic is critical: in this new biobased industry the competition is more time-oriented. Thus acquiring some competences in the ability to design proper governance structures for innovation process is probably one of the key elements of future success in fast moving market.

Keywords: Governance, collective innovation, knowledge, cluster, biobased activities.

Page 3: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 3/25

Introduction Innovate or die is the challenge facing firms but also nations in this new area of Knowledge Based Economy (KBE). Drucker (1985) stressed that the innovation is the mean allowing the value creation for the entrepreneur but the image of the isolated inventor in Schumpeterian tradition which inseminates the economy of an idea that is communicated by the sky is now fundamentally schematic and outdated. The process of innovation is not the same in Montpellier, Geneva or San Francisco, the appearance in France of the ‘competitiveness clusters’ attests that. This model of a multiplicity of actors working together in the process of innovation highlights the relationship and interaction between users, providers and institutions and entities that are part of the innovation system. Inventors and innovators are in community, in a coalition based on shared trust and embedded in a dense network of interactions (Scott & Brown 1999, Brown & Duguid, 2000, from Laursen & Salter, 2006). Drucker (1993) points out that innovation is none other than the creation and application of new knowledge to make them productive. Then we believe in the same vein of ‘Innovation Based on Knowledge’ (Nonaka and Takeuchi, 1997; Johannessen et al., 1999; Leonard-Barton, 1995; Amidon, 2001) that innovation and knowledge are two faces of the same coin. The success of innovation depends on the governance mode (Teece, 1996) for the mainstream of the governance literature. The Williamson transactional framework does not consider knowledge: its nature, its dimensions and its process. The need to develop a new scale of governance choice based on knowledge (as a base for innovation) is crucial to go in this new era of knowledge. This issue is even more critical when it is about exploring like those of valorisation of Agro-resources. Bio-fuel, agro-materials, bio-molecules, bio-energy are the four activities that researchers, industrials, agricultural cooperatives and institutions wishing to emerge and for which the ‘pôle de compétitivité’ Agro-Industries and Resources (IAR) was created. Our aim in this article is: (1) to link these three concepts: governance, innovation and knowledge, which have been widely studied, but there were little (or no) attempts made in the direction of connecting the three, by (2) exploring this question in the particular context of exploration as a regime of innovation for biobased activities in the case of the IAR French competitiveness cluster. First, we will highlight the link between innovation and knowledge, then defining governance and the shortcomings of the literature. Secondly we will introduce the concept of “knowledge governance” (Foss, 2006) which means choosing governance structures (e.g. markets, hybrids, hierarchies) and coordination mechanisms (e.g., contracts, directives, reward schemes, incentives, trust, management styles, organizational culture, etc.), for the purpose of influencing processes of creating, transferring and sharing knowledge. Then, we will be able to propose a framework analysis to apply to this French cluster for emerging biobased activities. As Simon has noted (1986): "a current priority in research organizations is to understand how they develop new products, bring new production methods and marketing and new forms of organization. This is the unfinished task that Chester Barnard has left us "(p.16).

Page 4: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 4/25

1. FROM KNOLEDGE TO INNOVATION/ PROCESS, INTERACTION AND SPACE 1.2. Innovation challenges

Nowadays, Innovation is a collective, interactive process, more and more territorialized (Daadaoui, 2012). As a result of these characteristics, innovation has to face some challenges: (1) the relationships are to build to avoid a partnership risk: as highlited by Powell (1990), collaboration can be accompanied by many relational risks. An interesting enlgish study concluded that collaboration make the R&D more complicated and risky (Tidd et al, 2001). Even if the number of new strategic alliances is gowing, the performance remains weak (Das et Teng, 2000). Opportunistic attitude (Larson et al., 1998), free-rinding (Dyer and Nobeoka, 2000), information leakage (Hamel, 1991 ; Szulanski, 2000), the difficulty to create an equilibrium between the individual and the alliance interests (Hamel, 1991), are feared. (2) The knowledge is to create : As précised by Nonaka et Takeuchi, 1997), understanding how organizations create new products, news methods and new organizational forms is important. But, it is more urgent and important to understand how organizations create knowledge that makes these different creations possible. This was a fundamental question in the modern philosophy of sciences (Lakatos and Musgrave, 1970) including various ideas on how we could organize the collective action to be more innovative (Popper, 1945). This calls officially a governance questioning. (3) The special innovation governance is to conceive: As highlighted by Teece (1996): “Innovation requires adapted governance modes”. Here it is about the conditions that could promote the collaborations, as pointed by Brousseau (2000) : “the process of cooperation is as important as having good partners and a good idea or project”. In the next paragraphs we will stop by the relation between knowledge and innovation to determine in the last paragraph our glasses to study innovation process.

1.2. Knowledge and innovation: definition and dimensions The innovation is the creation and implementation of new knowledge to make them productive (Penrose, 1956; Drucker, 1993). So, to identify the innovation we need to understand knowledge. Winter (1987) was the first to propose a typology of knowledge (Foss, 2006, 2007) depending on whether this knowledge is tacit / explicit, non articulated/ articulated, observable / non-observable, complex / simple, element of a system / independent. Thus depending on its dimensions, knowledge is easily transferable or is difficult to transfer, its property rights are difficult to define or not and so on. In this cartographic perspective, Henderson and Clark (1990), Hall and Andriani (2003) offer interesting typologies of innovation. The former distinguish incremental innovation, modular, architectural and radical, depending whether knowledge is unchanged or changed and concepts are reinforced or reversed. Hall and Andriani were more interested in the degree of incremental and radical innovations to distinguish minor and major degrees depending on the knowledge quantity and substitutability. More global and dynamic, we find in the literature of innovation the difference between exploration and exploitation. Holland (1975) was the first to make this distinction, then used by March (1991). The exploitation concerns the extension and refinement of knowledge and technologies (March 1991) without changing the nature of activities with a limited uncertainty of the environment. Exploration is characterized by the break with what is being done to focus on the discovery of new technologies (March 1991). The exploration is not the efficiency of operations but is a process which concerns the uncertain search for new business opportunities based on new technologies. Knowledge creation is more important than diffusion for the exploration innovation.

Page 5: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 5/25

1.3. Innovation as a process of transformation of knowledge In the vein of the 'Knowledge Based Innovation' we support the idea that the innovation process is the process by which knowledge is transformed, combined and implemented. Nonaka (1991, 1994), Nonaka and Takeuchi (1997) are still the main contributions to the understanding of mechanisms of knowledge transformation. The model of the creation and capitalization of knowledge is based on the distinction between tacit and explicit knowledge. Tacit knowledge is rooted in the action, the routines in a specific context (which can increase personal productivity at the individual level and the competitive advantage at the enterprise level). The explicit knowledge is knowledge codified, transmitted in a formal and systematic language. In organization, the creation and accumulation of knowledge occurs at three levels: at the individual level, group level, organization level. It uses four modes of conversion: (1) Socialization, tacit knowledge to tacit knowledge (2) Exteriorisation of tacit knowledge to explicit knowledge (3) Combination of explicit knowledge (4) Internalization of explicit knowledge to tacit knowledge to a higher level. Nonaka proposes the spiral of knowledge creation that explains the transition from tacit knowledge to explicit one and vice versa and between different levels. Our purpose here is to explore this dynamic of creating knowledge for innovation in an interorganizational context from the governance perspective. Particularly, the objective is to understand the emergence of monitoring devices and governance mechanisms when question of knowledge creation and sharing are at stakes. “The knowledge assets are mobilized and shared in a “ba”, where the tacit knowledge of individuals are converted and amplified by the knowledge spirale (…) (Nonaka et al. (2000). A “ba” is “shared place for emerging relationships” (Nonaka and Kono, 1999). This virtual, physic or mental place or combination of all of these places. Ba is a “resources concentration” of knowledge assets. 1.4. … To a framework to analyze the innovation process Our immersion into innovation literature conducted us to perceive innovation as a process of knowledge exchange and transformation between partners. The quality of this process depends on the quality of the relationships between them. Then, we conceive this process as a combination of these two dimensions : knowledge and partners in a specific context (figure4). In the same vein of others scholars (Kale, Singh et Perlmutter, 2000; Pisanon, 1990), we believe that the governance structure could make an order in the innovation process on distributing the roles, on coordinating the activities. Nevertheless, where scholars diverge is in the specific mechanisms to act and their role. In the next, section we will explore the governance corpus in order to design a framework to read the governance in the particular case of innovation.

Figure 1: Knowledge mode of conversion, Nonaka (1994)

Page 6: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 6/25

2. GOVERNANCE, KNOWLEDGE AND INNOVATION 2.1. Governance: the need for a new paradigm The concept of governance has been extensively studied by theorists of organizations (Westphal and Zajac, 1995). Governance means the way of organizing transactions (Williamson, 1994) and by extension the relationships. Its purpose is to achieve the correct order by public or private use of coordination mechanisms. The governance structure is the design of an institutional matrix in which the integrity of the transaction or set of transactions is decided (Williamson 1996) or an institutional model that governs trade in controlling opportunism (Dyer, 1997). Williamson proposed a complete matrix of choice of governance but not very suitable for this special transaction ‘knowledge’. With his two books' Markets and Hierarchies' and 'The Economic Institutions of Capitalism', Williamson built the theory of transaction costs where the analysis unit is the transaction. The choice of the appropriate structure is based on three criteria which are the characteristics of transactions, the uncertainty that accompanies these transactions, the frequency and specificity of assets involved. Williamson argues that when the specific asset is idiosyncratic, integration can reduce transaction costs. It must be said that it is opportunism that worries Williamson. We will build the definition of governance in a functional approach based on dichotomist function: disciplinary and cognitive (Charreaux), relational and contractual mechanisms (cf. figure 5). As several authors (Conner and Prahalad 1996, Kogut and Zander, 1996) we support the idea that the contextualization of governance by situations where knowledge is created raises the need for an extended theory. The innovation and dimensions of knowledge may explain the choice modes of coordination.

Figure 4: our framework to study innovation process

Knowledge attributes : - knowledge assets - interdependance / modularity /

tacit / explicit - space of exchange (Ba)

Partners and their relationships attributes :

- Diversity and number of partners - Social Embeddedness - Opportunism and appropriation - Conflicts

Innovation context : - Exploration/exploitation - Territorial anchor

Page 7: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 7/25

More specifically, two directions need to be explored: the question of governance levels, and the complementarity of governance mechanisms at different levels. Considering the first point, as Gomez highlights (2009), the actual theory of governance is inadequate to the study of new productive forms of action (for instance: clusters) in context of high uncertainty and complexity as those present in the phases of innovation for the emergence of new activities. This mismatch stems from the fact that: - It is difficult to establish property rights on economic rent from the collaborative networks as the dominant theory on corporate governance in the capitalist system is based on a clear allocation of these rights. - The stakeholders in a cluster have divergent interests on nature and time horizon and consensus can not be found on looking for a single collective benefit, as suggested by the theory of corporate governance. Renewal or looking for a new paradigm is especially urgent as there is a multiplication of these forms throughout the world both in the developed countries and in developing countries. On the second point, the work by Poppo and Zenger (2002) shows an interesting complementarity between formal contract and relational governance (i. e. the “social processes that promotes norms of flexibility, solidarity and information exchange” (Poppo and Zenger (2002:710). For them, the reason of this complementarity is to be found in the fact that customized contracts narrow the domain around which parties can be opportunistic. “Customized contracts specify contingencies, adaptive processes and controls likely to mitigate opportunistic behaviour and thereby support relational governance” (Poppo and Zenger, 2002:721). Nevertheless several questions remain unsolved; for instance the question of mutuality between parties, of problem of conflicts, problems of measurement of costs and of benefits of the exchange. These questions are particularly of interest in the situation of knowledge exchanges. As suggested by Antonelli (2005) the economics of knowledge has shifted from public goods then towards proprietary goods and finally towards localized technological knowledge. For Antonelli “at each point of time the topology of agents in the space of knowledge, hence their relative distance and structure of their relations and interactions are key features of the system” (Antonelli, 2005:14). In a general statement, the core question is, finally, whether or not this phenomenon of complementarity between governance mechanisms is to be observed in the context of knowledge creation and clusters. On these points the so called knowledge governance approach (hereafter KGA) brings interesting insights. We will develop this approach and its interests in the following point. 2.2. The Knowledge Governance Approach (KGA): According to Foss (2006, 2007), Grandori is the pioneer to have used the concept of ‘Knowledge Governance’, which he defines as: “Knowledge governance therefore means deploying governance mechanisms so as to maximize the net benefits from processes of transferring, sharing and creating knowledge. This is similar to the transaction cost minimizing logic of transaction cost economics.” He adds: “The approach may be briefly defined as a sustained attempt to uncover how knowledge transactions -which differ in their characteristics- and governance mechanisms -which differs with respect to how they handle transactional problems-, are matched, using economic efficiency as the explanatory principle.” The KGA starts from the hypothesis that knowledge processes (i.e., the creation, retention, and sharing of knowledge; Argote, 1999) can be influenced and directed through the deployment of governance mechanisms, in particular the formal aspects of organization that can be manipulated by management, such as organization structure, job design, reward systems, information systems, standard operating procedures, accounting systems, and other

Page 8: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 8/25

coordination mechanisms (cf. Grandori, 2001). The KGA asserts that such governance mechanisms should be seen as critical antecedents of knowledge processes. More specifically, Foss identifies the causes of the research gaps, mainly the missing micro analytic foundations (at the level of individuals) and the neglected role of organizational antecedents, as well as of the formal organization. On the contrary, Foss suggests that the governance approach, i.e. the specific combination of governance structures (market, hybrid, hierarchy) inside organizational forms will influence the knowledge process (sharing, integration and creation). Similarly he suggests that this is necessary to identify knowledge-based hazards, and “how does the deployment of governance mechanisms remedy such hazards” (Foss, 2007:42). An interesting development of the KGA literature is also the question of unit(s) of analysis. For Foss, the most applicable unit is the “knowledge transaction”, that is to say “the transfer of an identifiable ‘piece’ of knowledge from one actor to another one” (Foss, 2007:44). Nevertheless, the innovation does not appear in the KGA. 2.3. … To framework to analyze the innovation governance The concept of governance is multi-faced, to construct our glasses we had to deal different approaches: - Transaction theory (Willaimson, 1994) gives us a complete matrix but its disappointed us in the way that it remains a coercitive analysis of governance assigning it a disciplinary fonction. But how about the cognitive function that could exhort the cooperation and the knowledge creation? We believe that the extension of this matrix could give us a better insight to how to organize the collective action for innovation (Daadaoui, 2012). We believe in the vein of Brousseau and Raynaud (2004 ; 2006) that a multi-level approach of governance is very interesting in the way that there is a juxtaposition of a macro-level (the institutional environement), Meso-level (the private institutions) and Micro-levels (the bilateral governance) that shape the innovation and their projects. This multi-level analysis will suggest a partnership governance considering the different stakeholders. In our case the macro-level is the state, the meso-level is ‘le pôle de compétitivité’ and the micro-level is the project. In this communication we will focus on the Meso-level which is the “pôle de compétitivité” (PDC) (see next section). Then, our framework to deal with governance in innovation process is build on a triptych: governance structures, mechanisms and functions as designed in the figure 6:

Figure 6: A multilevel framework to study governance in innovation process

Micro-level

Meso-level

Macro-level

Governance dimensions

Governance structures : Strategic and operational

Govenrance mechanisms

Fonctions : disciplinary / cognitive

Page 9: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 9/25

3. « LE PÔLE DE COMPÉTITIVITÉ – PDC - » IAR : A FRENCH CLUSTER FOR BIORESOURCES In this section, we will present our case-study : “le pôle de compétitivité IAR”. First, we have to explain our methodological choice, then a monograph of the “PDC”. Finally, some results using our framework. 3.1. Methodology The literature had extensive discussions on the issue of governance, but left in the shadow of the descriptive and explanatory framework, concrete structures and governance mechanisms (Ehlinger et al. 2007). The aim of understanding suggests a qualitative exploratory approach involving a case study. Indeed the novelty of the research on governance in special context, where it is about exploration as a particular process of innovation aiming to develop new technologies and non-food applications for bio-resources that provide interesting analysis, that is a breakthrough innovation with great complexity and uncertainty. The application of this method is favourable in terms of feasibility and the research design, which can be explained by the following quote from Yin (1994:6) "In general, the case studies are preferred when the issues of" how "or" why "questions are asked, and when we focus on a contemporary phenomenon in the context of life." According to Glaser and Strauss (1967), the objective of the research case study is to "discover" a theory. The chosen field of investigation is the exploration in a ‘pôle de compétitivité’, this French version of cluster launched to enhance competitiveness and innovativeness of French industries. It was necessary to focus on the project dimension. We had the great opportunity to study the Industries and AgroResources (IAR) cluster for the developing new non food values of biomass and the mega project called “FUTUROL” for developing the 2sd generation of biofuels from the enzymatic process. The project had the same architecture as the cluster: researchers, industry and funders actors. The data was collected by interviews with different actors: academics, industries, policy-makers, by attending actors meetings and also analysing secondary data (reports, some presentations performed by the actors, some emails exchanges). All these data was organized using the NVIVO 8 in order to analyze them using our framework. - “FUTUROL” et “BTF” are the two projects concerning the biofuels of 2sd generation and covers a period of several years. This second generation has to be developed from two technological ways biological (an enzymatic way to benefit from the whole plant and to avoid the competition between energy and feeding) and the second one from the thermochemestry. Both of them are multi-partners projects. - In this exploration of biobased activities, the knowledge needed is a “new” knowledge (Peterson, 2010) combining scientific and industrial, generic and specific, tacit and explicit, complex and simple, collective and individual. There is “project” and “sub-project” scientific and industrial knowledge is completing each other, where explicit knowledge is combined, (report/reviews exchange, meetings, committees), implicit knowledge is exteriorized (project teams, ), explicit knowledge is internalized (exemple), tacit one is socialized (project-teams, Phd students). We identify then Nonaka’s creation process of knowledge. This creation aims to lead to innovation conducting to new market and new values. This innovation needed is systemic in the way that to go to go further in the 2sd generation of biofuels we need the results of 1st generation biofuels. We can summarize the characteristics of exploration in biobased activities as below:

Page 10: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 10/25

3.2. Industries AgroResources ‘IAR’ cluster: growing in green

« Giving to the most dynamic territories the means of European and global ambition: this is the vocation of the competitiveness clusters, which also embody a new vision of land management »

Jacques Chirac, President of French Republic, 2005

Our empirical focus is on emerging biobased industry where innovation has many facets. On the one hand, the origin of products for which it will give birth, 100% derived from renewable agricultural, functionality to the extent that they will produce no nuisance to the natural environment (biodegradability...), the technology that will be used to produce these products, which is still unknown in large part. But more important is the framework which has been created in 2005 for governing innovation by launching the French model of clusters called ‘Pôles de Compétitivité’ (PDC). The development of this process follows a model of encouraging open innovation industry-research-training relationships. This network connecting different actors detaining resources and capabilities and designing new activities proposes to break with the existent technology and to bring a radical change that will lead to the creation of a new value system, with ideas still fuzzy, exogenous uncertainty related to the project concerning the process, and the output, as well as a high endogenous uncertainty associated to the difficulty of assessing performance. Also the net is characterized by a significant level of complexity relating to the subject of the relationship (Biobased activities), the diversity of partners which belong to different organizational environment (Plewa et al, 2004), a complexity that induces a specificity of human, physical (Heide, 1994) and relational (network, other relations) assets. Jacquet & Darmon (2005) precise that: “each actor has a specific role, clearly defined and identified: the private sector is responsible for the cluster and the government represented by the public collectivities accompanying the device and participating in coordinating committees and funding”. All these different actors are joined in local and regional environment and maintaining relationships to innovate. The relationship in this context is tripartite between industry (big groups and SME’s), research centers (public and private) and training centers exchanging different streams of information, knowledge and skills by formal links like ‘committees’ “commission” and informal channel like “friendly discussion: “over a beer” or “over a game of human baby-foot!” (cf. figure 7).

Knowledge

Innovatio

n

Uncertainty

Actors Scientific /

industrial Tacit / Explicit

Complex/ simple

Collective/individual

Exploration of new non-food values of bioresources

Systemic

High level

Heterogen

eous

New

Figure 7: Actors and flows in IAR cluster

Skills/Knowledge

Informations Compétences

Page 11: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 11/25

In the definition of the IAR cluster (Jacquet & Darmon, 2005), each actor has a specific role, clearly defined and identified: the private sector is responsible for the cluster and the government represented by the ‘public collective bodies’ accompanying the device and participating in coordinating committees and funding. It is important to know the role of each one in terms of governance functions and mechanisms. In figure 8, we tried to propose a descriptive design of the IAR cluster, its components and its links to other levels. 3.3. Knowledge and partners in the PDC

“scholars love science, politics love to be elected, business love develop new activities profitabily” (interview IAR_ENT_I3).

(1) Partners: Characteristics and challenges The actors within the PDC are different with the aim to create new linkages between industry and science kingdom. Diverse cultures and disciplines are desired but an important cognitive distance is highlighted. Then, an opportunistic, free-riders attitudes are feared. The informations leakages is also a great problem that faces the governance of the PDC to encourage the partners to “play the game” of the exchange “there are people who come just to take informations …” ENT_IAR_I1. This is an industrial fear. Another problem resulting from this “melting pot” is a risk of inequalities in power’s distribution and dominations. Conflicts or tensions (like the actors preferred to call them) is normal in this relationships configuration: chapels tensions, PDC vs politics, territorial tensions and so on. Our analysis highlighted that in the PDC there is a collectivism to manage for instance how we could assure the appropriation of the PDC by all of us and the commitment of all the

Project

Research

Industry

Training BD

BD Office

Economic college

Scientific college

CCI / CRA2

Funders

OSEO/ AII6

ANR5

CDC7

Institutional Partners

Committee

Chef of police Regional

Council

Coordination

committee3

Ministries

DRIRE1

IAR Cluster

Territorial bodies

Institutional environment

Figure 8: Governance levels in IAR Cluster

Page 12: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 12/25

partners? Howe to create a Simon’s common purpose? How to avoid the behavioral excesses. And finally how to motivate and cementing the relationships ? (2) Knowledges : Characteristics and challenges - The open innovation model assumes that an organization alone could not claim its ability to drive innovation. The need is even greater for these new biobased activities claiming multi-skills and breadth of knowledge. Here, the scientific knowledge from the laboratory (new formulations, new discoveries of assets) similar to those from the industrial experience of the firm (market knowledge, processes following expertise etc..). This is tacit knowledge "(...) INRA for instance has a long history and is familiar with the plant material, it is no secret to it! "IAR_ENT_I2 and explicit" (...) has a large base of articles and patents "IAR_Ent_I5. - The PDC is the meeting place of different knowledge assts, here is a classical and claimed role of clusters. But in our case we could say that in addition to managing knowledge and facilitating its exchange, the PDC creates itself “new knowledge” via for instance the “Tremplin” data-base for economic intelligence, biomass cartography etc. - In terms of knowledge, the PDC has to face the question of the orientation of the knowledge production and the coordination of it. It is even more challenging in the biobased activities where many choices have to be done (thermochemistry vs biologie, which agricultural culture to promote ? etc.). Still opportunistic behavior in the appropriation of the knowledge are feared (3) Exploration vs Exploitation? The great novelty of PDC lies not only in the type of relationship and the great hope, but also in the nature of projects and knowledge related. "(...) In the past, we had more projects toward university that could have industrial applications then, but never projects with both high scientific and technological content at the same time that an industrial strategy!" IAR_Ent_Gov2. The desire to get out of the classical models of the innovation process where the flow of knowledge migrates from science to industry “push” or otherwise “pull” configuration. We are in another sphere where knowledge is co-constructed and evolve progressively along an industrial strategy. This last idea is rooted in the notion of the industrial heading of the project required. Are we more in exploration or exploitation in the cluster? The PDC have to manage the ambidexterity on it which judged as very fundamental for developing new bio-based activities. In the figure 9, we summarize these characteristics and challenges proper to the PDC in terms of Knowledge and partners.

Figure 9

Page 13: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 13/25

3.4. Governance in the PDC (1) Governance structures: - Strategic governance : representative and partnership The cluster was configured as an association (loi 1901) with associative bodies (figure 10). « an association is simple, flexible and neutral … » but « in association everyone is responsible, but when things go wrong no one is responsible ». the division has provided a compliance representative of two colleges in the decision-making bodies in order to take into account "the sensibilities of everyone" IAR_Ent_I3. Figure 9 illustrates the partnership and multi-scheme of strategic governance of the PDC. In this order we created various governance bodies that incorporate state and local authorities, despite the willingness of non-interference of the politics in the governance of the cluster. On 2008, three years after its creation, a 2.0 version of the PDC governance was established on giving a bigger place to SME’s and creating a new college of consular chambers and professional representations. Also, the introduction of the renewal of the BD by third of members to ensure the governance stability. (2) Operational governance: - The PDC director and the direction committee: this homo-communicator has to animate the network, and has to be the “drive belt” between the strategic level and the operationals. In this way, it was important that he has scientific and management skills. The direction committee is also constituted by external referees from science and industry to help DG to drive the PDC into the way designed by the strategic governance. Is this committee who “labellise” the project that the PDC will help to find financial, industrial and scientific support. They also organize the work of sectorial commissions. - Sectorial commissions were created, corresponding to four tasks that were set at the beginning of the implementation of the PDC. These "working groups" used to be "(...) instances of proposals, decisions belong to the supreme governing office and advice. The commissions have no decision-making capacity but are strongly encouraged to make recommendations and exchanges that arise in their enclosure can enrich the dynamics of the pole. These are commissions for exchange and consultation, but that can make proposals and recommendations. "IAR_Ent_I1. Even if these committees were a place of knowledge construction and production and a space of expression, they present some risks : the problem of confidentiality, progressive disinterest of industrials to attend these commissions, the responsibility and duties division and finally the legitimacy of these commissions- . The figure 11 illustrates this operational governance.

Page 14: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 14/25

Institutional partners

committee

Funders committee

Scientific committee

PDC

Board of directors

Office of board directors

Steering committee

DG

Scientific college

Economic college

Coordiantion committee

Expert

Expert

Regional council

Governor (préfet)

Local authorities

Funders : OSEO, CDC, FUI, ADEME

Expert

Expert

Regional and state services

Expert

Consular chambers Professional

representations

The arrows indicate the nominal and effective participation of one or more people, not just an information flow (exchange of document)

Figure 10 : strategic governance of the PDC

Page 15: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 15/25

(3) Decision making: Since this is a meta-organization or network of organizations working in innovation we was interested by what kind of decisions are made and by whom in the PDC. We identified a set of decisions that we classified into two major families (Figure 12): those “logistic” decisions made to organize the relationship between the PDC and the various stakeholders or stakeholder relationships. The second category relates to the “content” itself of the relationship which could be technical or scientific content (depending on the process of innovation, cf figure 12).

Main families of decisions within the PDC Relationship logistics (organizational, financial, human) Relationship content(scientific and technical)

New PDC members budget partnership with other clusters, interclustering status change planning of commissions international missions different receptions hiring new staff service creation within the PDC creating a directory of skills (annuaire de compétences) creation of « Kit végétal » (book project)

Creation of new commission (new thema) Project labellisation choice of topics for commissions discussion creation of the intranet creation of a business intelligence plateform launching specific and sectoral studies

Scientific college

Economic college

Management committee

DG

Commission 1 President + facilitator

Commission 2 President + facilitator

Commission 3 President + facilitator

Commission 4 President + facilitator

External experts or actors interested by the thematic

communication Service

Project engineering

International service

interclustering Service

PDC

Consular chambers Professional

representations

commission 5 President + facilitator

Commission 6 President + facilitator

Steering committee

Figure 11 : operational governance of the PDC

Figure 12 : Decisions within the PDC

Page 16: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 16/25

In an instrumentalist perspective, this distinction helps to visualize the decisions and ensure better governance System that we present in the figure crossing the levels of decision-making with their nature –content- (figure 13). (4) Governance mechanisms: + Formal mechanisms : - Statues are the primary –and classic- governance mechanism. They contain a set of rules guiding the life of the structure and the actions of its leaders. For PDC partners, the objective of the statutes is not controlling the behavior and actions of the leaders, but rather a framework for determining the obligations and clearly define the role of each member of the organization. - associative bodies established within the PDC: the office (operational and decision making), the Steering Committee (operational), a board of directors (endorse the decisions of the Bureau), a general assembly (approve decisions) and thematic committees are ad hoc committees that will allow fertilization of ideas and actors and assist the office in its reflection on this PDC associative project. The design of these bodies in the PDC differs from that

Decision level

Decision content

Strategic

operational

Relationship Content : scientific

and technical

Relationship logistic : financial, human,

organizational

Scientific committee

BD office

BD

Steering committee

Direction committee

DG

Coordination committee

Funders commission

Commissions

Means there is more a discussion than a link up or down decision-making It is a consultative body that influences the decision to be taken by the body which receives

the consultation It is an effective decision-making body. A dark line is a sign of the power in

decision-making

Figure 13 : A configuration of decision making according to the level and the content of the decision

Page 17: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 17/25

adopted by the mainstream literature on governance. If, in the disciplinary approach, the primary purpose of such mechanisms is to limit the discretion of management, this is not the case in the associations. These forums are designed to help leaders in the execution of their mission. Formal mechanisms here help to avoid opportunism due to the information asymetry. In a good demcoracy , the representation rule is strict in all these instances to avoid domination and to give the possibility of expression to everyone. However, this make things very heavy and then we loose flexibility that is recognized to the association. In this sense that the formal mechanism is supplemented and clarified by an informal mechanism, including trust and interpersonal relationship + Informal mechanisms: All the literature is accorded that Trust is an important ingredient for collaboration. Within the cluster, we used several informal mechanisms such as trust, interpersonal relationships and socialization. All these mechanisms are interdependent on each other, interact with each other and can not function alone. Trust feeds interpersonal relationships that strengthen themselves with socialization within the cluster (Figure 14). + External mechanisms : the state, the local authorities and financial funders are the main external stakeholders of the PDC and they put some mechanisms of control and monitoring : « contrat-programme », « convention ». The PDC must edit some document like « the strategic road map » proposed explaining the priorities of the PDC, report activity, accounting and financial audit. + A double disciplinary and cognitive approach and complementarity between formal and informal service of innovation actors.

Trust Interpersonal

links

Socialization

- Create and developp cohesion

- Coordinate - Prevent and manage conflicts and tensions

Figure 14 : Informal mechanisms: interaction and tasks

Page 18: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 18/25

In the figure 15, we summarize the use of our framework to the case of IAR PDC.

Challenges Gouvernance Innovation context

Partners characteristics

Knowledge caracteristics knowledge

Opportunism Cohesion Internal mechanisms External

mechanisms IAR PDC

Ambidexterity An important number of partners from different backgrounds (industrials, scientists, politics, local authorities)

Tacit and explicit Scientific Technical Industrial Modularity and interdependancy

- Asymmetry - Coordination - choice of orientation - Ownership

-, Free-riding - Information leak

- Internal and external legitimacy of the object - Legitimacy of the collectif - Common purpose to find

- Selection - Association with instances and statues - Strategic road map - Annual activity Report with indicators of monitoring and control

Statues instances BD BD’s Office Steering committee

- Institutional committee - Scientific committee - contrat –cadre / contrat de performance - reporting - strategic Audit - Accounting and financial audit

5. Conclusion : Implications 5.1. The role of PDC in innovation process (1) The facilitator: The IAR cluster has a positive effect on relational, structural and cognitive embeddedness. For this, the PDC is based on the different services created and a set of diverse but highly complementary mechanisms to support innovation (Figure 16). The role of the PDC is even more important when it comes to a project that is close to the exploration. In this context, the project labeling has given the legitimacy that the project needed to attract funders and industrialists. Nevertheless, that was not the case for the other project which is more in the exploitation phase. Embeddedness Mechanisms Activities

Relational embeddedness

- coordination tools - mechanisms of collective punishment - no formal arbitration mechanisms - informal arbitration mechanisms via interpersonal relationships

- labellisation - socials events, thematic commissions

Structural embeddedness

- mechanisms to reduce the information and knowledge asymmetry - mechanisms of reputation lock-in

The role of brokering and of gate-keeping of the PDC via les skills book PDC

Cognitive embeddedness - mechanisms of content definition

- All activities linked to the management of informations (collect, diagnostic, analyze) and creation of knowledge via the PDC letter and Tremplin platform.. - Activities linked to the protection of results and the management of intellectual ownership.

Figure 15 : Summary of characteristics of the innovation process, challenges and governance mechanisms within the PDC

Page 19: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 19/25

Figure 16 : Facilitator of the embeddedness

(2) The PDC is a ba … The case study confirms our intuition that the PDC is place the learning process and the fecundation of knowledge are done. And as Nonaka et al. (2000), describe the different stages of the knowledge conversion process requires internal structures to perform efficiently. This is what makes an organization more creative than another. In figure 16, we highlighted the conversion spiral on the PDC. In this context, contrary to the literature on districts where the emphasis is on spontaneous dissemination of information and knowledge process or the existence of a focal firm providing this mission, the governance structure and the team set up structure this process by providing a number of activities.

Conversion spiral Activities By:

Originating ba

Implicit to implicit

- Geographic proximity - European and international interclustering - Events opened to external stakeholders (French, European, international)

Dialoging ba

Implicit to explicit

- Thematic commissions and events between PDC members

Systemizing ba

Explicit to explicit

- News letter - Platform et intranet « Tremplin » - Reporting

PDC

Exercising ba

Explicit to implicit

- Trainings, PHD, new diplomas related to Biobased industries

A large governance including all the stakeholders

Figure 17: PDC as a ba

But in the wheel of knowledge, the PDC is not only a place and space where knowledge is created, but creates itself a special kind of knowledge. (3) The PDC creates a “generic” knowledge The literature of networks and clusters attributed to these gatherings the virtue promoting the generation of knowledge through the creation of "noise" and "atmosphere" that can encourage people to share, multiplying the chances of interactions that can lead the generation of knowledge and lead to innovations. However, in the IAR PDC, we found that it creates itself a knowledge that we described as "generic" as common, useful, usable and available to all (all the members of the cluster and some external privileged). In reaching this conclusion, we relied on the distinction made between knowledge and information (daadaoui, 2012). - Projects within the PDC: different stages, different needs The intervention of the PDC in innovation projects also depends, in addition to the innovation system to which the project (exploration vs. exploitation) belongs, the stadium in which the project is located. We identified three positions: - The project fuzzy and ill-defined concept: the actor or actors come to the PDC to find additional ideas, useful contacts in research or industry. - The project with a clear idea: looking for players to complete the round or (legal, financial, etc..) and Project engineering skills. - The project description, which R & D carried out, the full round and sometimes the consortium agreement already drafted. This project needs the PDC blessing (labeling) to give it credibility and legitimacy.

Page 20: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 20/25

5.2. Dynamic and participative governance … but « be careful of domination! » "It must be a well-made information if possible participatory, we will not make withholding information " IAR_Ent_Inst_2. Here is a rule inside the PDC and any other association that all the members could participate in the process of decision-making. Within the PDC, this participation goes beyond the borders of the PDC to integrate external stakeholders. Nevertheless, we were able to identify the importance of certain actors and elements inside the system. These actors can be organizations as individuals. However, it must avoid the power imbalances that can significantly affect the voluntary and volunteer spirit that should prevail in an "association we are in a world of associations extremely different backgrounds is associated, so it must be of caution snake to shock no one, not provoke anyone. And if you have the capacity for intervention, don't show it! " IAR_Ent_I1. Governance should be there to not reveal the dominations. We have also seen that the cluster's governance is not static and evolves with the evolution of the cluster life, " this ecosystem, that body man" who was born and grew up. Governance could also be assimilated by analogy to a living organism that grows, goes to adult age and reincarnates (we prefer note say decline). This development follows the trajectory of the cluster itself. We have seen that the emergence of the « pôle », the governance should be put in place and was played a central role in structuring collective action and in the network. The emergence phase is crucial in the life of a cluster, because a bad start may discourage players and give a wrong signal. Governance has, in this sense, a primary function of building cohesion, namely the construction of " what binds the actors and what a collective basis " (Segrestin, 2003, p.77). This cohesion can take the form of a common purpose, a shared ambition (launching this biobased industries for example) and can be accompanied by a common identity construction (the name, the brand, the colors of the cluster, for instance), the emergence phase and structure of the PDC requires the development of an " affectio societatis ", which allows the group and to the meta-organization to offset a structural weakness related to their inability to impose decisions through the development of a sense and common and "legitimate" values. In addition to the definition and construction of common sense and a general framework enabling collective action, governance provides control functions for collective action. At this stage contracting is not precise related to technical and scientific choice in one hand because of the embryonic state of knowledge on biobased activities and in the other hand the non-identification of the actors and what they can achieve. The focus here is on the relationship and the division of powers (Figure 18). More the PDC goes in solidifying relationships between internal and external stakeholders and stabilize it on the sidelines with the advancement of knowledge on non food uses and its possibilities, more contracting moves towards more specific contracts clear and sometimes with precise targets. The steering takes up more space with an orientation towards scientific and technical choices to do. Governance while look for more coordination than cohesion (Figure 18).

Page 21: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 21/25

Conclusion: complementary levels of governance for innovation We arrive at the conclusion that Macro and Meso levels are complementary in terms of governance not only in the logic of discipline and minimizing transaction costs, but also in relation to cognitive objective. The explanation cannot be limited only to the wiliness to protect knowledge assets, results, conflict management, but it is in cognitive function of governance. It mainly comes from a complementarity between the knowledge that each level generates (Figure 19). Each level deals with a level of knowledge: the macro-environment and the institutional environment provides players with a collection of informations in addition to availability of funds through arrangements (agencies, special funds or local authorities). Then, the meso-level materialized by the PDC (that interests us) is responsible for the generation, exchange of a generic knowledge (explicit or implicit). Actors in the process of generic knowledge can identify opportunities to develop more accurate and specific knowledge and thus to be organized within a project. This has a consequence on governance mechanisms used. Then we have a predominance of the disciplinary function by the institutional environment mainly wearing formal contractual mechanisms. Then, the meso-level seeks to develop a common cognitive field that will favor formal and informal mechanisms to ensure a predominantly cognitive function (Figure 19).

PDC emergence … … After 5 years …

- An association with GA of two colleges : economic and scientific - General Contractualisation between the association and the government through a framework contract (contrat-programme)less precision - Governance focuses on relationships and power management and decision making

- An association with GA of three colleges economic, scientific and consular chamber - Governance has been extended to chambers - Contractualisation more accurate with a performance contract - Clear and defined goals in time - Governance focuses on the content of the relationship

- The network to be constituted - The collective to be organized - Legitimacy to build - Lack of knowledge needed to developp the biobased activties - The management of collective action

- The group has been stabilized and extended - The legitimacy and the credibility seted - A better understanding of biobased activities - The management of collective action

Creation Maturity

Collectif et the knowledge state

Governance caracteristics

Figure 18 : The dynamics of the PDC governance

Page 22: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 22/25

Macro-level (Institutional environment)

Meso-level (PDC)

Knowledge Information (low level of knowledge)

Tacit / explicate generic knowledge

Disciplinary function High Low Cognitive function low High

Governance mechanisms

Formal mechanisms: contractual (contrat-cadre, reporting), committee (experts committee for instance)

Formal mechanisms: association, Informal mechanisms: relationships, reputation, trust

Figure 19 : Matrix of governance and knowledge Levels – function and mechanisms

Page 23: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 23/25

References: Amidon D. (2001) Innovation et management des connaissances, Edition d’Organisation Antonelli C. (2005) Models of knowledge and systems of governance. Working paper n°01/2005 Università Di Torino Brousseau E. (2000) La gouvernance des processus de coopération. La coopération industrielle. Economica. Paris. Brousseau E. & Raynaud E. (2006). The Economics of Private Institutions. An Introduction to the Dynamics of Institutional Frameworks and to the Analysis of Multilevel Multi-type Governance. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=920225 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.920225 Conner K.R. and Prahalad C.K, (1996). A Resource-Based Theory. of the Firm: Knowledge vs. Opportunism Organization Science, 7:5, 477-501 Daadaoui L. (2012). La gouvernance du processus d’innovation : cas de la valorisation non alimentaire des agroressources dans le cadre du pôle de compétitivité. Thèse de doctorat université Paris Dauphine. Das T. K. & Teng B. (2000). Instabilities of strategic alliances: An internal tensions perspective. Organization Science, 11(1), 77–101. Drucker P. (1985) Innovation and Entrepreneurship, Collins, New York.. Drucker P. (1993) Au-delà du capitalisme: la métamorphose de cette fin de siècle, Dunod, Paris, 1993. Dyer J.H. (1997). Effective interfirm collaboration: how firms minimize transaction costs and maximize transaction value. Strategic Management Journal. 18: 535-556. Dyer J. H. & Nobeoka K. (2000). Creating and managing a high-performance knowledge- sharing network: the Toyota case. Strategic Management Journal, 21(3), 345-367. Ehlinger, S., V. Perret and D. Chabaud (2007). Quelle gouvernance pour les réseaux territorialisés d'organisations. Revue Française de Gestion, 155-171. Foss N. (2006) The Emerging Knowledge Governance Approach: Challenges and characteristics. DRUID Working Paper No. 06-10 Foss N. (2007) The Emerging Knowledge Governance Approach: Challenges and characteristics. Organization. 14(1): 29–52 Gopalakrishnan S. Bierly P. and Kesseler, E.H. (1999) A re-examination of product and Process Innovation using Knowledge-Based View, The Journal of High Technology Management Research, 10:1,147-166 Gomez P.Y. (2009) Quelle gouvernance des pôles de compétitivité? La revue française de Gestion. Grandori A. (2001) Neither Hierarchy nor identity: Knowledge-governance mechanisms and the theory of the firm, Journal of Management Governance, 5 :3-4, 381-399 Hall R. and Andriani P. (2003) Managing Knowledge associated with innovation, Journal of Business Research, 56:2, 145-152 Hamel G. (1991). Competition for Competence and Inter-Partner Learning Within International Strategic Alliances. Strategic Management Journal, 12, p. 83 Hatchuel, A. & Weil B. (2002) “La théorie C-K: fondements et usages d’une théorie unifiée de la conception. Colloque sciences de la conception, Lyon. Henderson R.M. and Clark K.B. (1990) Architectural innovation: the configuration of existing product technologies and failure of established firms, Administrative Science Quarterly. Jacquet N. and Darmon D. (2005) Les pôles de compétitivité. Etudes de la Documentation Française. Johannessen JA., Olsen B (1999) Aspects of innovation theory based on Knowledge, International Journal of Information Management, 19:2, 121-139

Page 24: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 24/25

Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1996) What firms do ? Coordination, identity and learning. Organization science, 7:5, 502-518 Larson A., Bengtsson L., Henriksson K. & Sparks J. (1998). The Interorganizational Learning Dilemma: Collective Knowledge Development in Strategic Alliances. Organization Science 9(3), Special Issue: Managing Partnerships and Strategic Alliances, pp. 285-305. Laursen, K. and A. Salter (2006), 'Open for Innovation: The role of openness in explaining innovative performance among UK manufacturing firms', Strategic Management Journal, 27(2), 131-150 Le Blanc C. (2004) Pour un écosystème de croissance. Rapport au premier ministre (député des Yvelines district, France) Leonard-Barton, D. (1995) Wellsprings of Knowledge, Harvard Press. Möller, K. and A. Rajala (2007) Rise of strategic net – New modes of value creation. Industrial Marketing Management. 36, 895-908. Möller, K. and S. Svahn (2003) Managing strategic nets. A capability perspective. Marketing Theory. 3, 209-234. Nonaka, I. (1991) The Knowledge-creating Company, Harvard Business Review, 69:6, 96-104. Nonaka I. and Takeuchi H. (1997) La connaissance créatrice : la dynamique de l’entreprise apprenante, De Boeck Université. Nonaka I., Toyama R. & Konno, N. (2000). SECI, Ba and Leadership: a unified model of dynamic knowledge creation. Long Range Planning, 33(4), 4-34 Penrose, E.T. (1959) The Theory of the Growth of the firm, Oxford University Press, 3rd ed. Poppo, L. and Zenger T. (2002). Do formal contracts and relational governance function as substitutes or complements? Strategic Management Journal. 23, 707-725. Popper K. (1945). The Open Society and Its Enemies. London: Routledge. Powell W.W. (1990). Neither market nor hierarchy: Network forms of organization, Research in Organizational Behaviour, 12, 295-336. Richardson G.B. (1972) The organization of Industry, Economic Journal, 82, 883-896. Segrestin B. (2006) Innovation et cooperation interentreprises. Comment gérer les partenariats d’exploration? Editions CNRS économie. Szulanski G. (2000). The process of knowledge transfer: A diachronic analysis of stickiness. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 82(1), 9–27. Teece, D J. (1986) Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15, 285-305. Teece, D.J. (1996) Firm organization, industrial structure and technological innovation, Journal of economic Behavior & Organization, 31:2, 192-224 Tidd J., Bessant J., & Pavitt, K. (2001). Managing innovation: Integrating technological, market and organizational change (2nd ed.), Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, ltd. Westphal James D. and Zajac Edward J (1995) Who shall govern? CEO/board power, demographic similarity, and new director selection Administrative Science Quarterly , 40, 60 - 83. Williamson O. E. (1975) Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications, Free Press: New York. Williamson O.E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets and Relational Contracting. New York, Free Press. Williamson O.E. (1994), Les institutions de l’économie. InterEdition. Williamson O.E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. New York: Oxford university press. [1] Regional direction for Industry, Research and environment [2] Regional consular for industry, commerce and agriculture

Page 25: Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - …emnet.univie.ac.at/uploads/media/Daadaoui.pdf · Latifa Daadaoui ENCG, Université Ibn Zohr, Agadir - Maroc l.daadaoui@uiz.ac.ma

Governance for collective innovation

Latifa DAADAOUI 25/25

[3] Institutional Partners Committee: the two president of the regional council and the chef of department [4] Head of an administrative area [5] National Agency for Research [6] OSEO- AII: Regional agency for innovation [7] Caisse Des Dépôts: Public fund for the economic development [8] Regional Center for Innovation and Technology Transfer in Chemistry and Environment Websites: www.iar-pole.com; www.competitivite.gouv.fr