june 26, 2006 - peri · web viewtodaro, michael p. and stephen c. smith. 2005. economic development...

86
November 4 th , 2007 G G ROWTH ROWTH S S TRATEGIES TRATEGIES AND AND P P OVERTY OVERTY R R EDUCTION EDUCTION : : THE THE I I NSTITUTIONAL NSTITUTIONAL C C OMPLEMENTARITY OMPLEMENTARITY H H YPOTHESIS YPOTHESIS Robert Boyer PSE - PARIS-JOURDAN SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES (Joint Research Unit CNRS-EHESS-ENPC-ENS) 48, Boulevard Jourdan 75014 PARIS, France Phone: (33-1) 43 13 62 56 — Fax: (33-1) 43 13 62 59 e-mail: [email protected] web site: http://www.jourdan.ens.fr/~boyer

Upload: lamtram

Post on 19-Jun-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

November 4th, 2007

GGROWTHROWTH S STRATEGIESTRATEGIES ANDAND P POVERTYOVERTY RREDUCTIONEDUCTION: : THETHE I INSTITUTIONALNSTITUTIONAL CCOMPLEMENTARITYOMPLEMENTARITY H HYPOTHESISYPOTHESIS

Robert Boyer

PSE - PARIS-JOURDAN SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES

(Joint Research Unit CNRS-EHESS-ENPC-ENS)

48, Boulevard Jourdan 75014 PARIS, FrancePhone: (33-1) 43 13 62 56 — Fax: (33-1) 43 13 62 59

e-mail: [email protected] site: http://www.jourdan.ens.fr/~boyer

Revision of the paper prepared for the Workshop on “Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes”, organized by UNRISD, Geneva, February 21-23rd, 2007.

Page 2: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

ABSTRACT

. This chapter starts from the limits of the policies that assume a significant de-connection between antipoverty strategies and the logic of the growth regime and that mainly rely upon market mechanisms. By contrast, a branch of the new institutional economics argues that a complete set of coordinating mechanisms is constitutive of really existing economies and that they are more complementary than substitute. The Institutional Complementarity Hypothesis (ICH) may be useful for analyzing simultaneously the antipoverty policies and the viability of growth regimes. The different brands of capitalism are the outcome of complementary institutions concerning competition, labor market institutions, welfare and innovation systems. Generally, such configurations cannot be emulated by poor developing countries, but reviewing the preliminary findings of the UNRISD country case studies suggests some common features to all successful experiments. Basically, antipoverty policies are efficient when they create the equivalent of virtuous circles within which growth entitles antipoverty programs and conversely these programs sustain the speed and stability of growth. Two methods are proposed in order to detect possible complementarities and design accordingly economic policies: the Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) on one side, national growth diagnosis on the other side. A special attention is devoted to the timing of policies and the role of policy regimes. A brief conclusion wraps up the major findings and proposes a research agenda.

3

Page 3: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

GGROWTHROWTH S STRATEGIESTRATEGIES ANDAND P POVERTYOVERTY R REDUCTIONEDUCTION: : THETHE IINSTITUTIONALNSTITUTIONAL C COMPLEMENTARITYOMPLEMENTARITY H HYPOTHESISYPOTHESIS

CONTENTSI. INTRODUCTION.....................................................................................5

II. UNDER DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY: THE FAILURE OF MONO-CAUSAL EXPLANATIONS.....................................................5II.1. The conventional orthodoxy and its limits...............................5II.2. The institutional analyses and their responses........................5

III. THE INSTITUTIONAL COMPLEMENTARITY HYPOTHESIS IN A NUTSHELL........................................................................................5III.1. No single coordinating mechanism can warrant the viability

and efficiency of a national economy.......................................5III.2. The various coordinating mechanisms are more

complementary than substitute................................................5III.3. A definition of complementarity and related concepts...............5

III.3.1...............................................................Supermodularity........................................................................................5

III.3.2..............................................................Complementarity........................................................................................5

III.3.3....................................................................Compatibility........................................................................................5

IV. DEVELOPED ECONOMIES: A SUGGESTIVE INTERPRETATION OF MAIN STYLIZED FACTS....................................................................5IV.1. The origin of a paradox............................................................5IV.2. Four examples..........................................................................5IV.3. From dyadic to triadic complementarity: towards an

understanding of complex institutional architectures.............5IV.4. The institutional complementarity at the level of growth

regimes.....................................................................................5IV.5. Some welfare systems may generate virtuous circles…but do

not last for ever........................................................................5IV.6. The diversity of welfare configurations....................................5IV.7. “Commodification” is not the only future of welfare systems..5

V. DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY REDUCTION STRATEGIES: SOME PRELIMINARY RESULTS..................................................................5V.1. Do not extrapolate successful policies designed for already

developed countries.................................................................5

4

Page 4: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

……But take into account the specific context of developing countries...................................................................................5

V.2. The art of creating virtuous circles by coordinated policies….5……But they do not last for ever!.............................................5

V.3. The crucial role of political alliances…....................................5……That differ from one country to another............................5

V.4. An aggiornamento in development strategies.........................5

VI. SOME METHODS IN ORDER TO APPLY THE INSTITUTIONAL COMPLEMENTARITY HYPOTHESIS.................................................5VI.1. A first method for detecting successful configurations............5VI.2. A second method: combining two diagnoses about the origin

of poverty and the inhibiting factors of growth.......................5VI.3. How to go from here to there?.................................................5

VII. CONCLUSION: ORGANIZING THE SPILL-OVERS BETWEEN CASE STUDIES AND INSTITUTIONAL COMPLEMENTARITY THEORIZING.....................................................................................5

VIII. REFERENCES........................................................................................5

5

Page 5: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

I. INTRODUCTION

For many governments and most international organizations, the reduction of poverty is now a crucial objective for the current decade and even the millennium. But the major issue is then to design and implement the related policies. A brief retrospective analysis suggests that the previous policies have had mitigated outcomes and therefore they cannot be generalized to lagging countries.

More precisely, the impact of internal and external liberalization has been reassessed. In some cases, the strengthening of market forces and price mechanisms has been quite helpful in reducing poverty, if not inequalities: it seems to be the case for China and other Asian countries. In other instances, the full liberalization of product, labor and financial markets has been quite detrimental to macroeconomic stability since the bursting out of major financial crises has exacerbated poverty creation in the very same countries that represented themselves as dominated by a large middle class: one recognizes the dramatic transformation of the Argentinean economy.

Similarly, during the 90s, many economists and international institutions stated that a good macroeconomic policy and environment was a necessary and sufficient condition for a stable and fast growth and consequently for a large poverty reduction. This hypothesis has been falsified by the trajectory of most Latin American countries, where the implementation of the so-called Washington consensus has significantly pauperized a fraction of middle classes. Even for some Asian countries, the implementation of stabilization programs after the 1997 financial crises has aggravated poverty, far from reducing it. The Indonesian trajectory is quite illustrative of this unexpected outcome.

Therefore since the early 2000s, experts and governments are searching for new strategies in order to promote what is called in most Latin American countries “growth with equity”. This aggiornamento has been associated with a clear perception that the motto “the same size for all” has failed therefore the challenge is to take more explicitly into account the specificities of each national economy. In order to address these two core issues, the present chapter is built upon a threefold hypothesis:

For any country with massive poverty, policies that target poverty as if it were marginal feature within prosperous economies are totally inadequate. It is much more relevant to explicit the interrelations between the contemporary structural transformations, emerging growth regimes, and their impact upon poverty and inequality.

1

Page 6: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

A recent development in institutional analysis provides a tool in order to cope with this challenge. The Institutional Complementarity Hypothesis (ICH) explains why not any single policy tool is able to reduce poverty: basically, several instruments have to be combined in order to generate a viable economic regime that reduces poverty.

Whereas the implicit reference to a pure market economy implies frequently the reference to a one best way and canonical institutional configuration, ICH points out that several configurations may trigger the emergence of a virtuous circle, within which growth and poverty reduction are closely associated.

Building upon this analytical framework, this chapter is organized as follows. It is first important to survey briefly the nature of conventional antipoverty strategies and explicit the reasons for rather unsatisfactory outcomes. A core argument of the present chapter is precisely that there is no single panacea for promoting a high growth with equity, since market mechanisms are far from being the only existing and efficient coordinating mechanisms (II). A second step of the analysis is devoted to the general presentation of the ICH that precisely builds upon the complementarity of various coordinating mechanisms as key factors in the viability and stability of a growth regime and simultaneously poverty reduction. The purpose of any institutional design should be to organize such a complementarity in order to propitiate the emergence of a virtuous circle: antipoverty policies enhance growth and conversely the dividends derived from growth allow their financing (III). Since the concept of ICH might be unfamiliar to the reader, it might be enlightening to show how this framework helps in understanding some major stylized facts for developed economies. Basically, combining two or more institutional forms, somehow imperfect with respect to a pure market arrangement, may nevertheless deliver quite satisfactory outcomes in terms of economic efficiency and social justice. Various examples of such configurations are provided concerning the social democratic institutional configuration or the variety of the institutional arrangements fitted for a knowledge-based economy (IV). Nevertheless, it is important to show that ICH can be applied to developing countries, delivering original results concerning the variety of configurations able to promote growth with equity. The purpose is not to mimic or extrapolate the developed world arrangements but to use the related methodology in order to diagnose what are the relevant complementarities in each national case study. Some examples extracted from the national studies of the UNRISD program are given as a first step in the full implementation of this methodology (V). Finally, any progress in the direction of a better understanding of contemporary issues calls for the implementation of some original methods that stick to the specificities of each case study, in space and historical time (VI). A conclusion sketches a research agenda, featuring close interactions between the basic concepts of ICH and the investigation of national case studies (VII).

2

Page 7: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

II. UNDER DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY: THE FAILURE OF MONO-CAUSAL EXPLANATIONS

The emergence of the sub-discipline of development economics took place when economists had to recognize that the theories they have been elaborating for mature industrialized countries do not fit with the main features of the rest of the world. Thus, the analyses of development have explored the impact upon growth of alternative hypotheses by contrast with those adopted by conventional growth theory. Basically, economic instability, poor growth performance and the persistence of poverty were interpreted as an evidence for the absence of a key single factor that has evolved continuously through time. Firstly, the scarcity of capital has been blamed and then the lack of entrepreneurship, thirdly the absence of competition, and finally a poor human capital formation have been attributed a key role in the absence of development. More recently the lack of transparency, economic freedom, and ultimately good macroeconomic governance, have been perceived as key factors inhibiting growth and poverty reduction (table 1). Since the 90s, the so-called Washington consensus has diffused all over the world a basic vision: full liberalization, both internal and external, was the key strategy for promoting growth and eradicating poverty. In retrospect, the relevance of this strategy has to be reassessed.

3

Page 8: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Table 1 – Under-Development theories: a succession of mono causal interpretations?Contents/

Explanatory goals factors

Self-perpetuating growth

Higher standards of

living

Technological and

institutional modernizati

on

Human development

(health education,…)

Less pover

ty

Empo-wermen

t

Development as a form of freedom

Ecological sustainabil

ity

4

Page 9: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Development of capital

Neo-classical theory of growth

SOLOW (1956; 1957)

5

Page 10: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Entrepreneurship

Schumpeterian theoryHAGEN (1962)

An appropriate pricing system

Theory of equilibrium

SCHULTZ (1964)

The opening up of an economy

Open economy modelKRUEGER (1979)

Human capital Theory of endogenous growthLUCAS (1988; 1993)

The basic institutions of capitalism

The new institutionalismNORTH (1981; 1990)

6

Page 11: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Good governance World Bank(1993-2001)

Absence of corruption

State and corruption

MAURO (1995)Democracy Democracy and Growth

BARRO (1996)Promotion of rights and freedom

Development as a form of freedom

SEN (2000)

EnvironmentEcological modelMEADOWS (1972);

CHAKRAVORTY (1997)

7

Page 12: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

II.1. The conventional orthodoxy and its limitsBasically, the so-called Washington consensus was built upon five main

pillars. This framework was perceived as rather coherent and relevant, but the last decade has largely mitigated this statement.

The first pillar assumed that pure market mechanisms imply the

convergence towards full employment, and that it is the best strategy in order to alleviate the sources of poverty linked to underemployment and unemployment. De facto, no careful analytical studies substantiates this belief about the positive role of liberalization on poverty reduction (Reddy 2007). One can find striking counter examples. On one side, back to the 90s, the Argentinean government was among the very best followers of the strategy of full liberalization both internal and external: this has not prevented the pauperization of a large fraction of the population and finally the financial collapse of the country. On the other side, continental China has liberalized most product markets, but not removed strong public interventions in the economy: the poverty rate has drastically declined but the inequalities have been widening.

Another basic assumption was that any welfare policy or institutionalization of workers/citizens rights was bounded to push the economy out of its “natural equilibrium”. Consequently, any measure explicitly devoted to the reduction of poverty, may end up into the opposite, i.e. and extension of poverty. Such an unintended outcome has actually been observed, but this does not mean that whatever adequate pro-poor policy is bound to fail. Remember that the celebrated social democratic model of Sweden came out of a very turbulent period characterized by rural poverty and large emigration out of the country. Various cases studies of UNRISD program suggest that some social transfers can simultaneously benefit to poor people and stimulate growth as experienced in South Africa (Seekings 2007) and in Botswana (Selolwane et al. 2007).

Conventional approaches rely heavily upon a rather specific method, benchmarking. It assumes that it is easy to attribute the success of a strategy to a single device. Consequently governments should try to implement it into their economy in order to improve past poor performance. This approach suffers from a basic weakness: the quite impressionistic diagnosis of the unique factor at the origin of a successful strategy. Most of these diagnoses have proven to be false concerning the secrets of the German social market economy in the 70s, the Japanese model in the 80s, and then the Silicon Valley dynamism in the 90s. Basically, a series of economic institutions contribute to the viability and success of a growth regime, and it is not so easy to try to directly import such a complex nexus of social compromises and coordinating mechanisms. It is crucial to understand

8

Page 13: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

a specific configuration and its internal dynamics, as a precondition for designing a pro-growth and pro-poor policy.

A derived conclusion was precisely that lagging countries should try to import the complete institutional setting of the most successful country during the present period. Actually this assumes that there is a single one best configuration, with possibly strong complementarities, for example between market-competition and democratic principles. The recent literature on the diversity of capitalisms (Hall and Soskice 2001) and the previous comparative analysis inspired by régulation theory (Boyer 1996; Amable 2003) challenge this uniqueness and explain that various complementarities and political alliances justify a significant variety of institutional configurations. This opens some opportunities for developing countries that are not bound to emulate the best strategy observed in the developed world.

Another pillar of the Washington consensus stated that a sound macroeconomic policy is the necessary and sufficient ingredient in order to promote full employment and rapid growth. Of course, unwise public policies extending debt and generating high and unstable inflation have proven to be quite detrimental to growth and poverty reduction: most Latin-American countries during the 70s and 80s followed such a trajectory. Nevertheless, the return to a more orthodox macroeconomic policy in the 90s has not been sufficient for a complete reversal of previous negative trends: slow and unstable growth, rising inequalities, large unemployment and surge of informal labor have persisted (IADB 1995; 1996). Therefore, experts and governments have to design other policies directed towards innovation, institutional reform and growth and this might be especially important for poverty reduction.

II.2. The institutional analyses and their responsesAt the opposite of the ideal of a pure market economy, recent advances

in institutional economics enlarge the scope of analysis and provide a more balanced view about the coherence and viability of market economies. For development theories, this means the adoption of a systemic and institutionalist approach that could be summarized by the following motto: getting the institutions right according to the legacy of past economic specialization, social traditions and present political choices (Boyer 2006d). This helps in correcting the limits of previous conceptions of development.

Any really existing economy display a significant variety of coordinating mechanisms, much more diverse than the conventional opposition between Market and State. If the first mechanism relies upon interest and horizontal interactions among actors, at the opposite, the second is built upon obligation and an asymmetric

9

Page 14: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

exercise of power. Therefore, if one takes into account both the motive of action (either interest or obligation) and the distribution of power among actors (either symmetric or typically hierarchical) four other coordinating mechanisms emerge: the private hierarchy of organizations and firms, the community, the association, and finally network. Hence societies and economies exhibit a multiplicity of institutional arrangements, more or less imperfect, that have to be compared one with another and not with a mythical pure market economy (figure 1).

10

Page 15: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 1 – A synopsis of different modes of coordination and institutional arrangements

Mot

ive

for

Actio

n

MODE OF COORDINATION AND DISTRIBUTION OF POWER

Inte

rest

HORIZONTAL VERTICAL

1 MARKET 2 HIERARCHY

6ALLIANCE

5NETWORK

Obl

igat

ion

3 COMMUNITY

4STATE

Recent research on development has stressed the possible role of social capital in the functioning of contemporary developed economies (Putnam 2000), but also in the process of economic development (Narayan 1999). Actually this term tries to capture the role of personal and collective networks concerning the flow of information, economic exchanges and the provision of a modicum of security to individuals. But there is another meaning that originates from the research on welfare States: by providing some basic collective goods related to health, education and security, the corresponding expenditures should be classified as investment, since they contribute to social capital formation. Its volume and composition are therefore factors of production and contributors to growth. This new framework was first proposed by Dutch scholars (Visser and Hemerijck 1997) and more recently by social scientists from Scandinavian countries (Esping-Andersen 1990; 2003). In a sense, the theory of capability by Amartya Sen (2000) is recognizing that some welfare enhancing supply of public goods may benefit simultaneously to poverty reduction and stimulation of growth. Within these new analytical frameworks, some welfare policies aiming at the development of workers and citizens securities may have favorable productive impact and positively affect the dynamic efficiency of the economic regime. For instance, income security may imply high wages but simultaneously higher productivity and easier acceptance of innovation and structural change: short run extra costs can be associated to a larger dynamic efficiency. Similarly, work life security may imply some constraints detrimental to short run performance of firms but it is an incentive to more innovations and higher growth. It is specially so for health, education and training

11

Page 16: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

expenditures. The same reasoning can be applied to skill security or voice and representation security. Therefore the search for social justice is not necessarily detrimental to growth performances, i.e. a strategy that makes compatible poverty reduction and growth (figure 2).

12

Page 17: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 2 – How some social policies may enhance dynamic efficiency

CONCERN FOR SOCIAL

JUSTICE

Short-run negative impact on

employment

Productivityhike

Ambiguous short-run impact upon

employment

+

INCOME

SECURITY

Incentive to labor- saving innovation

Medium-term higher-productivity increases

-

Innovation and technical change

+

Higher wage More demand +

HIGHER DYNAMIC

EFFICIENCYVOICE- REPRESENTATION

SECURITY

Voice allows better organization

Better economic reactivity of firms

Higher potential growth

+

DECENTWORK

WORK AND LIFE SECURITY

Healthier population and workers

Higher participation rate, less absenteeism

+ +

+ Labor supply

SKILL SECURITY

More competent workforce

Ability to cope with innovation +

13

Page 18: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

LABOR-MARKET SECURITY

More riskacceptance

-

Moral-hazard problems Unemployment trap

14

Page 19: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Isolated best practices cannot be simply imported at the level of national institutional building, since they have to be combined existing institutions and organize complementarities among new and old institutions. In some cases, a quite efficient institution in one country may prove to be detrimental to economic performance when transplanted to another country, with distinctive productive organization, social values and political intermediation. For instance, during the 90s, many analysts of the new economy thought that the scarcity of venture capitalist was the main constraint limiting European growth. In retrospect, it is quite clear that once that limitation has been removed, most European economies still have been lagging, by lack of the complementary institutions observed in the Silicon Valley, i.e. a new pattern for intellectual property rights, close relations between university and business, as well as a very active local labor market for highly qualified individuals (Boyer 2004b). Conversely, the absence of typical venture capital, American style, does not seem to have prevented some Scandinavian countries to be quite successful in implementing a knowledge based economy, i.e. the underlying paradigm to the late new economy.

This last remark points out a quite general teaching of contemporary institutional research: given the same productive paradigm and configuration for the world economy, there exist several successful configurations that display different complementarities among basic economic institutional forms. This result has been observed during the Golden Age when at least four brands of capitalisms coexisted and developed complementary specializations (Boyer 2004b, Amable et al. 1997). This plurality of institutional architectures persist in the present era of technological paradigm shift and globalization: the knowledge economy and the related growth regime are compatible with quite contrasted complementarities. In the social democratic case, a comparative institutional analysis shows that a good and quite diffuse general education, life long learning and a large investment by firms in knowledge are the precondition for the ability to master information and communication technologies and nurture innovations that provide the competitiveness of the national economy (figure 3).

Figure 3 – The social democratic configurationLife long learning

THE SOCIAL DEMOCRATI

C INSTITUTIO

NS

Good and homogeneous

general education

Ability to master ICT

and innovation

15

Page 20: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Investment in

knowledge

But this is not at all the unique configuration: a knowledge based economy can be the outcome of a large deregulation of quite all markets and the diffusion of science pushed innovations. In this context, the defense of intellectual property rights and incidentally sophisticated financial innovations and markets are crucial components of this configuration, typical of the American way to a knowledge based economy (figure 4).

16

Page 21: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 4 – The deregulated, Science pushed configurationPressure

to innovatio

n

THE MARKET LED

ECONOMIES

Competition on

product markets

Market for

competences

Leading role and science

based innovation

The empirical analysis (Boyer 2004c) reveals a third configuration, probably the most interesting for contemporary developing economies. Actually, until the 70s, some lagging countries such as Ireland were constrained in their development by the existing international relations and their inability to forge the social and economic organizations relevant for their insertion into the Fordist productive paradigm. With the changing pattern in their relations with the world economy and the emergence of a productive paradigm based upon information and communication technologies, some of these countries have been successful in designing and implementing the institutional forms required by this new context. Consequently, the club of industrialized countries that was supposed to be definitely closed for outsiders, is now open for many South Asian countries, India, China, and not only Ireland (figure 5).

Figure 5 – Leap frogging for lagging countriesOpening to the world economy

17

Page 22: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

MISMATCH BETWEEN INSTITUTIONS AND TECHNOLOGICAL

PARADIGM

Rupture of the

Fordist paradigm

Catching up

New opportunity with

ICT

A last rebuttal of the conventional vision about growth and poverty is derived from the advances in macroeconomic theory. Basically the core assumption that long term growth is the mere outcome of a series of shift in the short run macroeconomic equilibrium of an economy has been falsified by the analysis of the two last decades. Clearly, growth is a matter of surplus creation and its productive reallocation, in conformity with the old classical vision. When the degree of sophistication of the economy increases, it is not sufficient to invest a large volume of saving, since it becomes necessary to innovate in order to permanently renew the competitive advantage. Beneath this general approach, the factors constraining this process appear to be quite specific to each group of countries. Therefore, traditional comparative analysis and cross section econometric studies have to be replaced by a precise investigation of the characteristics of a national trajectory in order to detect the hierarchy of the factors that are limiting growth and possibly poverty reduction (Hausmann et al. 2005).

III. THE INSTITUTIONAL COMPLEMENTARITY HYPOTHESIS IN A NUTSHELL

This approach belongs to the theoretical aggiornamento just described by the previous section. One of its merits is to overcome the conventional opposition between Markets and States as exclusive and antagonistic coordination mechanisms and it gives the basis for a better understanding of the complexity of the link between national institutional architectures and performances in terms of economic efficiency and social justice.

Within the quite dynamic field of the economics of the institutions, the Institutional Complementarity Hypothesis (ICH) has proposed a new research agenda in order to understand simultaneously the issue of the diversity of capitalism and how to design viable strategies for reforming the institutions inherited from the Second World War (Hall and Soskice 2003; Aoki 2001; Amable 2003). This framework has successfully been

18

Page 23: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

tested for developed and industrialized countries but one finds few references in the domain of development theory. The purpose of this short paper is to initiate such a research program.

III.1. No single coordinating mechanism can warrant the viability and efficiency of a national economy

This is at the core of institutional analysis.

On one side, any single institutional arrangement (IR) – a market is one of them – requires a precise organization, rules and norms, means of individual and collective compliance and these requirements have to be manufactured by the mobilization of resources outside this institutional arrangement. Under this respect the pure market competition is among the most demanding institutional arrangements and not at all a state of nature that would result from a spontaneous evolution. This is the converging conclusion of the microeconomic theory of asymmetric information, the findings of economic history about the emergence of markets and the evaluation of the fate of deregulation in OECD countries. The quite difficult and painful transformation of former socialist economies is quite illustrative of the fact that a market economy is a complex social and political construction (table 2).

19

Page 24: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Table 2 – Coordinating mechanisms: their governance and prerequisiteGOVERNAN

CE MECHANISM

S

ORGANIZATIONAL STRUCTURE

RULES OF EXCHANGE INDIVIDUAL MEANS OF COMPLIANCE

COLLECTIVE MEANS OF COMPLIANCE

MARKETS Free entry and exit

Voluntary spot exchange

Legal enforcement of control

Norm of private property

Bilateral exchange or market place (Wall Street)

Regulations to maintain a public market

Legitimacy of free market

COMMUNITIES

Informal membership evolves over long period of time

Voluntary exchange based on social solidarity and high degree of trust

Social norms and moral principles impose obligations

Highly institutionalized norms and rules require members to accept "corporate" obligations

Knowledge of others and reciprocity over time

NETWORKS Semiformal membership

Voluntary exchange over a time period

Contractual bonds

Personal relations

Bilateral or multilateral exchange

Resource dependence

Trust built outside the economic arena

ASSOCIATIONS

Formal membership

Restricted to members

Self-interest Some degree of compulsion

Multilateral exchange

Opposition insider/ outsider

Reputation effect Partially private administration

PRIVATE HIERARCHIES

Complex organizations which tend to become bureaucratic

Restricted to members, exchange based on asymmetric power, bureaucratic rules

Rewards to individuals

Highly institutionalized rules

Asymmetric power, threat of sanctions

Members socialized into corporate culture, use of sanctions

STATE Public hierarchy Unilateral action Exit (tax evasion, migration)

Coercion

De jure and imposed membership

Indirect and global political and economic exchange

Voice (vote, lobbying)

Social rules or norms

20

Page 25: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

On the other side, each institutional arrangement has a limited domain of applicability and cannot be extended to the entire economy. Some IR are adapted to allocate efficiently typical goods, some others are building the trust necessary to the coordination of complex productive chains, still others are devoted to the supply of public goods. Furthermore, equity concerns are not taken into account by the same IR that aim at the efficiency of allocation of resources. For instance, the market cannot deal with the determination of the supply of public goods, with externalities and with social justice concern. States have no clear superiority to allocate conventional goods but they are quite adapted to the coordination of strategic externalities and the delivery of public goods (table 3).

21

Page 26: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Table 3 – Each coordinating mechanisms has is own specific strengths and failures

TYPE OF FAILURE

COORDINATING MECHANIMS

MARKET COMMUNITIES

NETWORKS ASSOCIATIONS

PRIVATE HIERARCHIES

STATE

ENFORCEMENT

Needs an internal enforcement authority

Needs trust and loyalty, often coming from outside (family, religion, ethnicity)

Need an external enforcement authority

Usually relies on the state as an enforcer

Might enhance opportunistic behavior

Needs controls external to state bureaucracy (judges, parliament, market) to correct state abuses

Facilitates collusion and imperfect competition

Compatible with various types of competition

May facilitate cartelization and monopoly

Resembles enforcement mechanism of carrels

The ideal of internal markets might hurt incumbent workers

Lobbies can capture public interest goals

PUBLIC GOOD AND

EXTERNALITY

Cannot provide collective goods or deal with externalities

Can internalize some collective goods (quality, training) but not others (welfare, general public goods)

Useful for enhancing quality and training but not very good in providing for societal general welfare

Useful for establishing standards and quality, for setting rules of competition in the industry

Governance costs might exceed the benefits of internal division of labor

Can provide public goods but has difficulties in providing them in precise amounts

Inadequate monitoring of technical change and innovation

Members tightly integrated into community, have limited capacity for innovations

Weak in the provision of collective goods

Useful for providing many goods collectively that individual members cannot provide for themselves

Slow to react to changes in the environment

Might fail in inducing technical change

EFFICIENCY Some basic social relations cannot be provided by pure market mechanisms

Some goods cannot be delivered at sufficiently low costs

Slow to enhance efficiency and speed of adaptation, except in industries where technology is complex and rapidly changing

Facilitates cooperation and X-efficiency but not allocation efficiency

Deficient in cooperation and X--efficiency

Can be highly bureaucratic and cannot easily deliver goods at low cost

EQUITY Facilitates inequality in income and wealth

Might lead to retarded development

When widely developed into industrial districts, networks may facilitate greater equality and income distribution. When weakly developed, networks tend to increase societal inequality

Narrow encompassing associational structures lead to income inequality

Excessive multiplication of controllers (frustration and inequality)

Might enhance inequality (power and privilege)

22

Page 27: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

III.2. The various coordinating mechanisms are more complementary than substitute

The previous results have an important implication: the imperfections of one mechanism are to be corrected by another one, that itself calls for a third and different coordinating mechanism. The example of financial markets is enlightening: what is generally conceived as a pure market do suppose an organization of the transactions under the aegis of an association or a firm, themselves under the supervision of a public agency in charge of preserving the transparency and fairness of transactions. This agency can be captured by lobbies and this may call for direct State intervention. This complex mix displays different configuration across countries and is under permanent threat to be eroded by the generalization of opportunistic behavior. Consequently, the hegemony of a single IR is quite unlikely and generally successful configurations organize a de facto complementary between a whole spectrum of IR (figure 6).

Figure 6 – Combining various and complementary institutional arrangements in order to get a viable configuration

Citizens

Governed by an

association

State

intervention

CivilSociety

Example: the Stock

market

Market

Lobbies

23

Page 28: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

III.3. A definition of complementarity and related concepts

Actually, there is a risk of confusion of complementarity with seemingly similar but distinct concepts. The emergence of this term has been associated with some implicit hypotheses that have to be spelled out.

III.3.1 Supermodularity Two elements E and E’ are said to be supermodular if the performance

R of the conjunction of E and E’ is superior to any other mix of elements i.e.

R(E,E’) > R(E,A) A E’ and R(E,E’) > R(B,E’) B E This precise definition put strong limits to the use of the notion of

supermodularity. First the analyst has to explicit a criteria of performance that is not so evident (profit maximization for the firm, but what for capitalist economies as a whole: average profit rate , rate of growth, total factor productivity, level of employment and activity, equalitarian distribution of incomes, wealth,…). Second, the concept is clearly associated with the idea of optimum and maximization, a core trend of economic analysis but it is not necessarily so for sociology, law, history and so on. Basically, only sophisticated models (see for instance Amable et al. 2001) are able to prove such a supermodularity. But how can we diagnose supermodularity? It cannot be done by direct observation, since it requires the construction of a formal model engendering a series of fictitious worlds.

A good example of possible supermodularity relates to productive models. It has been argued that just in time, total quality control and high skill workers define a genuine productive model at odds with the previous Fordist model whereby mass-production of standardized good required less competence from the workers and less demanding consumers in terms of quality. The very concept of supermodularity has precisely been used in order to show that a continuous and piece mal adjustment of managerial tools was not able to promote the transition from the old to the new productive model (Milgrom and Roberts 1990).

III.3.2 ComplementarityTwo elements E and E’ are said to be complementary if the

performance R of the conjunction of E and E’ is superior to the performance of each element considered separately, i.e.

R(E,E’) > R(E) and R(E,E’) > R(E’) The concept of complementarity is less demanding that

supermodularity, since it only requires that the conjunction of two elements is Pareto improving with respect to the existence of only one of

24

Page 29: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

the two entities. Nevertheless, both complementarity and supermodularity require the choice of a performance criteria R and the ability to compare various systems in order to check the basic property. Either by using formal models or by observing a hierarchy in the ranking of systems composed respectively of only E, only E’ or both E and E’.

Some examples of possible complementarity might be useful to grasp the nature of this concept. According to many authors, a financial regime governed by direct finance is complementary with weak unions and the domination of short-term strategies and conversely, a patient financial regime built upon banks credit is complementary to a strong union, both involved into long-term strategies. Another example associates as complementary an accommodating monetary policy and flexible labor markets, a typical American configuration, whereas the monetary regime associated to a conservative central banker is seen as complementary to rigid labor markets that are supposed to explain European unemployment.

III.3.3 CompatibilityThis third notion is frequently confused with the second one…but it

should not! Actually E and E’ are compatible if they can be jointly observed in existing economies and societies, i.e.

There exists an economy such that: E E’

An interesting example is provided by Martin Höpner (2003) when he investigates the links between the dual management board system and employees’ codetermination. The tenants of a strong variant of VOC would call these institutions as complementary – having observed the good “performance” of the German economy until the early 90s – whereas the observation only says that they are compatible. The proof of complementarity would call for a theoretical model adding up and/or subtracting a complete series of institutions and assessing the related impact upon an agreed measure of performance.

IV. DEVELOPED ECONOMIES: A SUGGESTIVE INTERPRETATION OF MAIN STYLIZED FACTS

Frequently, institutions are conceived as pure constraints that are detrimental to economic efficiency because they block the free adjustments of preferences and production constraints via price formation. For Douglass North (1990) they are also enablers for the strategy of individuals, in dealing with uncertainty, coordination and interpretation of information. Thus, contrary to Chicago school’s conceptions, some mix of institutions may deliver better economic and/or social outcomes that a pure market economy. This conception considers that some constraints restricting economic opportunism, short-termism or

25

Page 30: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

allow the supply of some public goods, are quite essential to the competitiveness of firms and thus they may have beneficial impact on economic and social outcomes (Streeck 1997).

IV.1. The origin of a paradoxIn the Walrasian tradition, the equilibrium prices make compatible

preferences and technological constraints. This feature can be captured by the following equation that expresses that excess demand for each product and factor market is equal to zero.

Z = f (p, P, T ) 0 [ pw Cw, Nw ]

Net excess demand

Price Preferences Technology Equilibrium price

Consumption

Employment

Walrasian equilibrium

Unfortunately, the Walrasian auctioneer i.e. the global market maker, does not exist and has to be replaced by a series of institutions: a monetary regime (I1), a competition law, labor market institutions (I2). Therefore, individuals now not only react to the price signals but also according to the existing institutions that shape the formation of prices. A priori this institution rich economy displays a different equilibrium

Z = g (p, I1 , I2 ) = 0 [ pi Ci, Ni ]

Net excess demand

price

Institutions

Equilibrium price

Consumptio

n

Employment

Institutional equilibrium

For most economists, the name of the game is to compare the outcome of a totally abstract economy, the Walrasian one, for which any market equilibrium is Pareto optimum, with a more realistic economy with various institutions but still an auctioneer. It is easy to understand then that any institution can only deteriorate the fit between preferences and technological possibilities. But if really existing decentralized imperfect markets are introduced, the various institutions might help in reaching a satisfactory equilibrium. Ideally, the various institutional settings should be compared according to their economic and social outcomes. But this requires the equivalent of a social welfare function in order to derive a single index out of the distribution of economic outcomes among individuals. Concerning the issue of complementarity, this very simple formalization might help in understanding the difference between compatibility and complementarity.

Compatibility among institutions is observed when there exists a set of equilibrium prices, consumption and employment. Such a property is not necessarily fulfilled and thus this is a discriminating criteria in the assessment of the viability of alternative institutional architectures.

I1 and I2 are compatible if there exists an equilibrium E(I1 , I2)

26

Page 31: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Complementarity is a much more demanding criteria. First, the analyst has to compute an equilibrium with only the first institution I1 i.e. E(I1) and repeat the same operation for institution I2. Second, one adds the second institution and has to compute the new equilibrium E (I1, I2). Third and it is still more difficult, the economist has to adopt a welfare function in order to compare the two equilibria. Finally, the institutions I1 and I2

will be said complementary if their joint presence delivers a better outcome than each of the separate institutions. It can be captured by the two following conditions:

I1 and I2 are complementary if E(I1 , I2) E(I1) and E(I1 , I2) E(I2)

IV.2. Four examplesIf one stick to general equilibrium theory, one could introduce two

discrepancies with respect to the conditions that deliver an equilibrium. First increasing returns to scale (H1), second imperfect competition or more precisely oligopolistic pricing (H2) have positive influence upon the existence of an equilibrium. Whereas a pure competitive (H0) equilibrium does not exist with (H1), the existence of imperfect competition entitles the existence of an equilibrium i.e.

E(H1 , H2) E(H1, H0)

Recent research about institutional complementarity (Amable et al. 2002) shows by formal modeling that strong unions (SU) and patient capital (PC) provided by bank credit may deliver better macroeconomic outcomes than competitive labor (CL) markets and short-termism (ST) capital markets, i.e.

E(SU, PC) E(CL, PC) and E(SU, PC) E(SU, ST)

Similarly, theoretical and empirical investigations exhibit a rather surprising complementarity (Amable 2003; 2004). Traditionally, economists consider that product market deregulation (PMD) and labor market flexibility (LMF) strategies are to be undertaken simultaneously, because they complement one with another. But empirical analysis shows that a second configuration is built upon the complementarity between product market regulation (PMR) and a significant institutionalization of labor mobility (ILM). By contrast, the intermediate configurations (deregulation of one market, but strong regulation of the other one) display less satisfactory outcomes in terms of growth and employment.

E(PMD, LMF) E(PMR, ILM) and E(PMD, ILM) E(PMD, LMF) ; E(PMR, LMF) E(PMR, ILM)

27

Page 32: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

The viability of a banking system is threatened by periodic bank runs especially when free banking (FB) and fierce competition (FC) prevail. This has triggered the efforts of economists in order to find out regulations that could prevent such dramatic episodes. After nearly two centuries of recurring banking crises, practitioners and analysts finally find out the complementarity of two corrective devices. On one side a deposit insurance (DI) reduces the probability of bank runs but it simultaneously might induce banks to take more risk for their credit activities. Thus, on the other side, prudential ratios (PR) have been imposed in proportion to the risk taken for each category of credit (Borio 2003). We find again that this institutional equilibrium is better that the constraint- free equilibrium:

E(DI, PR) E(DI, FB) and E(DI, PR) E(FC, PR)

This leads to two general proposals expressing the same idea. First, two imperfections might be better than a single one, since they correct each other potential unbalances. Second, two constraints might be beneficial to the quality of economic equilibrium and social outcomes, provided they adequately interact each with another.

IV.3. From dyadic to triadic complementarity: towards an understanding of complex institutional architectures

The analysis can be pushed one step forward since the ICH extended to more than two institutions. Actually, when social scientists diagnose the existence of socio-economic models, they mobilize a complex web of institutions, organizations and markets.

The now well known flexicurity model is based upon the synergy of

three components (Boyer 2006a). Quite permissive labor laws concerning the hiring and firing of workers generate intense flows on the labor market. Such a permanent flux is accepted by workers under the condition of quite generous unemployment benefits. In order to counteract the possible adverse effects of this generosity upon the duration of unemployment, the system had to be completed by an active employment policy, based on a sophisticated mix of control of the unemployed and upgrading of their competencies (figure 7).

Figure 7 – The flexicurity configurationLabor laws

28

Page 33: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Employment policy

Denmark

Welfare

The Danish flexicurity is itself embedded into a social democratic model, typical of Scandinavian economies. They tend to show that a large openness to world competition can be associated to an extended universal welfare provided that the Social System of Innovation (SSI) is sufficiently dynamic and the State is responsive to the demands of citizens. It is the conjunction of at least four institutions (the welfare system, the form of competition, the style of innovation and finally the conception of the state) that is successful in terms of economic performance and limitation of inequalities. In isolation none of any single component could produce such a result, but each plays a determinant role in conjunction with others (figure 8).

Figure 8 – The small open social democratic economy Universal welfare

Modern State / Social

System of Innovation

Sweden

Large openness to the world economy

The contemporary German configuration is a good example of a triadic complementarity. A careful study of the transformation of the structure of governance of German firms (Hopner 2001) has exhibited a surprising compatibility between the adoption of shareholder value and the persistence of a significant power of wage earners via codetermination laws. How is such apparent oxymorum possible? One answer is precisely that a third institution, the welfare state allows the restructuring and employment reduction required by shareholder value by its financing of early retirement and unemployment (Boyer 2006b). The initial mismatch between two managerial styles has been overcome by a socialization by public budget of the externalities thus generated (figure 9).

29

Page 34: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 9 – an atypical complementarity Codetermina

tion

Early retirement Germany

Share holder value

These examples point out a specificity of the present analytical framework. Instead of analyzing separately the efficiency (and legitimacy) of any single institution, ICH deals with the coherence and viability of a whole institutional architecture. Therefore, the association of so-called “imperfect institutions” may sustain a rather efficient configuration. Given the diversity of formal and informal organizations in developing countries, this methodology is quite useful in order to detect and explicit actual institutional configurations, faraway from typical text book representation of a pure market economy.

IV.4. The institutional complementarity at the level of growth regimes

One may analyze the institutional configurations from the point of view of the viability of a growth regime and take the rate of growth as one of the criteria for deciding about the complementarity of a given set of institutions. This has proven to be useful in order to understand the difference among growth regimes within OECD economies.

For medium or large size economies during the Golden Age, the so called Fordist growth was based upon three core institutional arrangements: collective agreements that codified the synchronization of productivity and wage increases, a mass production system of standardized goods capturing increasing returns to scale and finally a large degree of autonomy with respect to foreign competition (figure 10).

Figure 10 – The golden age Fordist growth regimesFordist wage compromise

Domestic demand led

regime

30

Page 35: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Increasing returns to

scale

For small open economies, the precise mix of institutions that shape the growth regime is quite different from the previous one. The wages are set in the exporting sector in accordance with the preservation of the competitiveness of domestic firms in order to be compatible with the requirement of an export led growth. The productive organization is based upon the differentiation of products by quality and innovation. These complementarities do shape a growth regime that is a priori quite adapted to the new trends of the international economy (figure 11).

Figure 11 –– The Scandinavian social pacts Responsible

wage formation

Export led growth

Conciliatory fiscal policy

Therefore, the concept of institutional complementarity is quite useful in order to understand simultaneously the coherence and the diversity of growth regimes. It is of special interest when this methodology is extended to developing countries: given quite different mixes of formal and informal institutional arrangements, the related growth regimes may differ from those already detected for mature economies.

IV.5. Some welfare systems may generate virtuous circles…but do not last for ever

It is now possible to deal the issue of welfare: can redistributive measures sustain a dynamic growth regime? Retrospective and comparative analyses suggest the possible compatibility or even more complementarity between a large welfare State and a dynamic growth regime.

Within the Fordist growth regime, the intensity and predictability of productivity increases was sustaining a very specific capital labor accord that was codifying an institutionalized increase of real wage in line with productivity. This was the key component of an original growth regime that was satisfying the objective of each collective actor: high and stable profit for entrepreneurs, near full-employment and better standards of living for wage-earners, buoyant tax base for

31

Page 36: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

State and social welfare financing. Thus, contrary to the teaching of a pure short run macroeconomic analysis, an extended system of income redistribution and supply of public goods (education, health, security in response to unemployment,…) was exerting a positive role upon the stability and the legitimacy of this new institutional architecture (figure 12).

32

Page 37: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 12 – An extended welfare: a key component of the Fordist growth regime

IMPLEMENTATION OF

MASS PRODUCTION

Large productivity

increases

FAST AND STABLE GROWTH

Large real wage increases

THE WAGELABOR NEXUS IS

INSTITUTIONALIZED

Stability or reduction of

income inequalities

THE INCOMES OF THE POOR GROW FASTER

DIFFUSION OF THE WELFARE STATE

MIMETIC EVOLUTIONOF

LIFE STYLES

EASIER ACCESS TO MASS CONSUMPTION

AND WELFARE

The demise of this quite interesting regime brings at the forefront a key finding by régulation theory: the very success of this institutional configuration has brought adverse trends that have been cumulating and have transformed a virtuous circle into a vicious one. Firstly, the productive potential of Fordist methods has been exhausting through time. Secondly, the search for increasing returns to scale has triggered an unprecedented internationalization first of exchanges and then of production. Thirdly, financial liberalization, both internal and external, has eroded the previous institutionalized compromises, especially in terms of tax competition among national State. Hence a central conclusion: no institutional configuration, however efficient and satisfactory for social actors in the early beginning, can last

33

Page 38: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

forever. This is an important difference with respect to a branch of the economics of institutions based upon an intensive use of the hypothesis of rational expectation and the search for steady state growth regime.

Should one conclude from the previous statement that the epoch of the complementarity between an extended welfare and an efficient growth regime is over? Clearly, many OECD countries experience recurring financial deficits affecting the various components of their Welfare systems, especially concerning healthcare and pensions. But again, the small open Scandinavian economies exhibit an interesting counterexample. Of course, the various subsystems (unemployment benefit, pensions, health,…) have been rationalized, but the creation of new collective rights in response to emerging social needs has generated a new virtuous circle between a rejuvenated welfare State and an innovation led growth regime. Basically, the effective implementation of full gender equality has triggered an extension of labor supply for women, whereas this move has generated new jobs in the service sector in the direction of child care, elderly care and health. Coupled with a knowledge based economy, this domestic internal economics circuit has proven to be quite satisfactory in terms of response to social demand from citizens (figure 13).

Figure 13 – Gender equality and responses to ageing as the source of a new service led growth

Supply of skilledlabor

More supply of new and mature goods

Reforms of labor

legislation, welfare and tax

system

Extension of women

activity (two incomes family)

More servicerelated

jobs

New care and other services

Extendeddemand

34

Page 39: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Health and social

services

Ageing ofpopulation

Redesignof

institutional rules

Easier financing of public budget and

welfare

This is an invitation to investigate how the various institutional arrangements put forward by figure 1 can be combined in order to take into account the large diversity of contemporary Welfare States.

IV.6. The diversity of welfare configurations The central idea is to map the previous “molecules” into the structure

of the costs and benefits associated with each of the three spheres. Each national system is defined by the share of welfare fulfilled within families (domestic order), within large firms (corporatist or paternalistic strategy) or across the whole society via State interventions (citizenship as a basis for collective solidarity). One gets the following description of social security systems (figure 14).

Some countries exhibit a clear domination of a leading sphere. Former Soviet Union was a good example of a firm based welfare, since a majority of the benefits used to be provided by the firm, be they under a monetary payment or by direct provision of health, education leisure. By contrast, Sweden and Denmark are emblematic for society wide organized welfare, with universalistic values and a financing by general taxation. Southern Europe is a good example of the lasting role of family centered solidarity. The idea put forward by New Labor in UK would suggest that this is not necessarily an archaism (Giddens 1998) when the solidarity is extended from the family to the community and civil society supposed to manufacture trust and security (Fukuyama 1996).

But generally speaking, most systems combine the three sources of solidarity. In Japan for instance, a firm based social welfare goes along with an important role of the family, as well as a residual role of a minimalist society wide welfare. In France, the ideal of social security, i.e. society wide welfare is mitigated by the fact that the financing and in some case the supply of many components are provided by the firms. In the US, the provision of welfare is largely attached to the labor contract negotiated between the workers and the firms, with some limited examples of society wide welfare for specific categories of population. Under this respect, most Welfare States are hydrid.

35

Page 40: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 14 – At the origin of Welfare State diversity: three logics and organizing principles

SOCIETY WIDE ORGANIZED

*Sweden *Denmark

Netherlands* *

France

*Italy

*United

Kingdom

*Portugal

*Japan

*United States

*Spain

Former Soviet Union*

FAMILY CENTERED FIRM BASED

36

Page 41: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

IV.7. “Commodification” is not the only future of welfare systems.

The contemporary issue, widely discussed, about the role that should be attributed to privatization and market competition (Le Grand and Bartlett 1993; Esping-Andersen 1996; Myles and Pierson 2000) is thus largely redefined (figure 15). Basically, each society manifests a strong path dependency that is not due to pure historical accidents or circumstances but the very nature of social protection (Bonoli and Palier 1999; Palier and Bonoli 2000). The major issue, and the French case is quite enlightening under this respect, is the evolution within the triangle (State, family, firm). For instance, catching-up countries might need to replace domestic solidarity by society wide organization and this is the case for Spain and Portugal. Other societies, such as the German and the French ones, might call for a progressive shift from a typical Bismarckian system, i.e. largely firm based, toward more Beveridgian, Scandinavian type configuration.

Only few national social security systems display a clear move towards privatization and quasi market competition in the supply of welfare. A key reference under with respect is the Chilean strong move toward a leading role of private insurance, with a mixed evidence about the gain in terms of efficiency and the clear non egalitarian consequences for instance for health care provision (WHO, 2000:109). The second example is of course the American privatization of pensions, in a sense largely idiosyncratic to the North American Society (Montagne 2000; O’Sullivan 2000). But the most intriguing trajectory relates to the Dutch case: the extension of universal social rights concerning for example a fully equal treatment of part time and full time jobs has been associated with a significant reliance to market mechanisms for the provision of welfare (De Beer and Luttikhuizen 1998; Barbier and Theret 2000; Esping-Andersen 2000).

Therefore the choice is not between a purely public welfare and a totally privatized one, but governments and social partners are facing the tricky problem of reforming rather idiosyncratic configurations, that manifest strong path dependence and combine various logic and regimes for welfare provision (figure 16). At least four forces shape the contemporary transformations.

The privatization strategy is strengthened by the emergence of a finance led regime (Boyer 2000b) that develop so quickly stock markets that the old pay-as-you-go systems are presented as inefficient and even unfair, since workers do not get their share of the increased financial wealth (Orléan 2000). But many obstacles prevent the implementation of market mechanisms in the other welfare regimes, such as family, unemployment or sickness. Even the constitution of quasi markets between independent, generally non profit, institutions competing from the supply of welfare benefit is not so easy given the

37

Page 42: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

inertia and localization of the supply, the difficult of entry, the poor assessment of quality, the large transaction costs associated to the management of this competition by regional public bodies. Furthermore, if strict rules are not set by public authorities such as block contracts, private firms could cream skim the market and let the most severe risks to the public welfare (Le Grand and Bartlett 1993). Not to forget that the Chilean and American cases show a clear increase in inequality in the access to welfare, as a consequence of privatization.

38

Page 43: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 15 – Introducing market mechanisms in Welfare States: A fourth dimension.

PRIVATELY OPERATED AND MARKET LED

Netherlands

SOCIETY WIDE ORGANIZED, COLLECTIVELY ORGANIZED AND

SUPPLIED SwedenDenmark

United States

Italy * *

United Kingdom

Portugal *

France

*

Spain * Japan *

* * *

* *Former Soviet

Union

FAMILY CENTERED AND SUPPLIED

FIRM BASED AND SUPPLIED

39

Page 44: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

40

Page 45: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

A new financialized corporatist welfare is also emerging in the most dynamic industries or regions. In a sense it is an updating of the so-called Japanese model. Actually, until the early 90s, the Japanese employment system had been perceived as quite efficient and the industrial welfare provided by the large firm was conceived as complementing the internal labor market (Hanada and Hirano, 2000). This system is now under strain due to the poor macroeconomic performance of the Japanese economy and the difficulty for firms to provide the expected amount of welfare, especially pensions, given the low profit and the tiny real return of financial assets. But the management of some ICT American firms, for instance in the Silicon Valley, is in fact updating this model. First, the Japanese profit sharing is replaced by the diffusion of stock options and some components of welfare are idiosyncratically adjusted to the needs of each employees, in order to prevent him(her) to move to another company or even launch his(her) own start-up. Such an implicit welfare model cannot pretend to be universal, since it concerns mainly high level professionals, holders of scarce competence in high demand on the international market.

A community based welfare is too an updating of the family centered welfare typical of some contemporary economies, such as the Asian NICs. Actually, even in Europe, the mass unemployment hitting specially the young workers and the early retired employees has put forward the solidarity organized within the family and this still is a typical pattern for Southern Europe. Statistical surveys do show an increase in intergenerational transfers, largely a compensating mechanism for deficient society wide welfare. In a sense, the New Labor is theorizing this process and trying to extend the solidarity from the domestic circle to the community wider scale. It remains to be seen that will be the actual consequences of these theoretical conceptions upon the management of the British welfare. In any case, such a model cannot pretend to be the dominant one for many reasons. First, the family structure is transforming itself toward a two sources of income and gender neutral configuration that calls for a redesign of universal welfare as a precondition for its viability (Majnoni d’Intignano 1999; Esping-Andersen 2000; Théret 2000). Second, the same family or community pattern cannot generally prevail in Europe given the diversity of the national trajectories since one century. Third, from a theoretical point of view, the internationalization and financialization of modern economy propagate new risks that can only be insured at a wider level than the family or the community.

A modernization of universal welfare is far from defining an obsolete model. From a conceptual point of view, this is one of the best responses to globalization and it is not an accident if small open economies are at the forefront in the redesign of such a welfare model. By the way, it has to be remember that Sweden, Finland, Denmark experience a very good record in terms of technological advances and

41

Page 46: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

the insertion into the ICT revolution, while preserving the society wide character of their Welfare State (see figures 3, 8 and 13 supra). If institutionally the losers are sure to be compensated by the winners, then the speed of technical change can be enhanced, national competitiveness preserved, thus reconciling dynamic efficiency with social justice (see figure 2, supra). Contrary to a widely held belief, the negotiation by social partners of social pacts that set new rules for wage formation and welfare reforms is as efficient or even more than a typical market led strategy (Fitoussi and Passet 2000). Under this respect, in the 90s the Dutch model was widely recognized as one way quite different from the “Third way” but no less attractive (Visser and Hemerijck 1997). In 2007, the Danish flexicurity model is the implicit or explicit reference of most experts and policy makers in the domain of welfare (Boyer 2006a).

42

Page 47: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 16 – Four strategies for reforming the Welfare States: Contrasted national trajectories.

PRIVATELY OPERATED AND MARKET LED D

3. The “Third way”, Britain after Thatcher

SOCIETY WIDE ORGANIZED, COLLECTIVELY ORGANIZED AND

SUPPLIED

4. The Continental European way:

A

1. Privatization road, Chile, Thatcher, United States

hybridization Bismarck/Beveridge

1

2. New

financialized cor-poratist welfare from

4 the J firm to Silicon Valley

3

2

C

B

43

Page 48: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

FAMILY CENTERED AND SUPPLIED

FIRM BASED AND SUPPLIED

44

Page 49: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

This reminds that welfare systems do co-evolve along with national conceptions about social justice, political institutions that convert them into specific tax systems and social security regimes, and economic specialization. Given the present comparative evidence, it would be an overstatement to conclude that there is a single best way for organizing welfare, be it market-led, firm based, community centered or Society wide and collectively organized. For developing countries, this widens the scope of possible antipoverty policies that have to be tailored to their specific features and objectives.

V. DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY REDUCTION STRATEGIES: SOME PRELIMINARY RESULTS

Are institutional complementarity approaches restricted to industrialized democratic countries? This section argues that developing countries should not necessarily mimic the best practices of rich economies detected by ICH, but that they may try to detect genuine policies by a creative use of the same methodology. Clearly, specific economic specializations dominated by primary resources, poor State capabilities, overwhelming role of the informal sector in employment relations are among the main distinctive features that call for idiosyncratic approaches, tailored for each local or national case.

V.1. Do not extrapolate successful policies designed for already developed countries

Under this respect, many social sciences might be victim of their ambition and search for generality, inspired by the methodological principles of natural sciences. Macroeconomists are working hard in order to find out the general structure of a model that would explain quite all contemporary issues in economic policy making. Development economists build frequently general equilibrium applied models and are tempted to consider that nearly the same key parameters do characterize most ,if not all, national economies. Business schools use intensively the detection of best practices in order to find out general principles for management, whatever the sector or the locality. This aspiration to universal laws, however in conformity with scientific methodology, may hide the specificity of social sciences: they have to deal with a large variety of social political and economic organizations, far more complex than the configurations studied by physics or chemistry.

Let us take for example the Scandinavian social democratic countries as the reference and consider that the main if not exclusive determinant of low poverty rates is the large volume of spending for welfare. The policy recommendation in the direction of developing countries would be to extend welfare expenditures and eventually try to import the same

45

Page 50: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

organization. Some countries have followed such a path but they are far from reaping the same benefits in terms of poverty reduction and growth performance. The ICH helps in understanding why: a highly developed welfare goes along with three related and somehow complementary features (figure 17).

By definition, welfare and employment legislations only apply to formal labor. Since it is highly developed in mature economies, the policy has a real impact upon the evolution of total employment and wage income.

Clearly, the general inclusion of population into the democratic process gives everyone a say in the determination of economic and social policy, at least indirectly. One should not underestimate the impact of the access to the electoral process upon the incentives of governments to adopt welfare policies directed towards the mass – or the majority – of the population. Contemporary Brazil is a good example of the positive impact of democratization upon poverty reduction programs adoption (Draibe 2007).

High value added activities can easily finance not only good wages but also a quite extended social insurance coverage. In a sense, the social democratic economies exhibit a complementarity between innovation-led growth regime and generous universal welfare State.

Figure 17 –Developed economies: poverty reduction by large welfare transfers, but the context matters

High welfare spending

Formal labor is the rule 1

3 High value added

activities

46

Page 51: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Democracy is a source of

inclusion

2

Reduction of poverty and inequalities

Examples: Social democratic economies (Finland, Denmark, Sweden)

These are the hidden or at least frequently neglected components of the general institutional architecture that sustains a universal welfare State. Therefore if they are not fulfilled, an isolated program of welfare extension will not deliver the same expected outcomes.

……But take into account the specific context of developing countries

The Bostwana (Selolwane et al. 2007) and the South Africa (Leftwich 2007) cases incidentally deal with this issue. Given the local conditions, the antipoverty programs have had mitigated results, largely unintended. The present analytical ICH framework gives an interpretation of this process: the programs were not fitted to the local economic social and political configurations (figure 18).

In a society where informal labor is the rule, the strengthening of labor protection and welfare of formal employment may exacerbate inequalities between formal and informal workers and even induce employers to move away from formal employment contract. The more so, the weakest State capacity to enforce regulations. A quite paradoxical and unintended outcome indeed…at least for policy makers if not trained economists.

If the weakest groups of the population are somehow excluded from the political process, governments face no incentives to design and implement pro-poor policy, and this might be an explanation of the perverse mechanism pointed out by the previous paragraph. Only formal workers are able to influence the formation of political coalitions, whereas informal ones don’t. The low mobilization of the poorest is directly related to the scarcity / modesty of antipoverty programs. Therefore, changes in the political sphere might be a precondition for an effective pro-poor policy. Brazil under President Lula exhibits such a correlation (Draibe 2007)

Some localities, regions or countries are so poor that they cannot provide the minimum subsistence level to all the members of the society. In other cases, some surplus exists but it is appropriated by a small elite. In both cases, the low productivity of the economy a priori precludes the possibility of any redistribution towards the poorest,

47

Page 52: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

unless quite drastic and coherent structural changes take place in response to a major political, social or financial crisis.

Figure 18 – The poor countries context affects the outcome of the same policy

High welfare spending /

Protection of formal

employment

Informal labor is

dominant1’

3’ Low surplus created

Political oligarchy, source of exclusion

2’

More inequalities (formal/informal),

More poverty (less formal

employment)

Examples: Botswana, South Africa

Consequently, the same policy does not have the same impact in any region of the world. This makes quite necessary an adequate diagnosis of the factors limiting productivity, growth, employment (see section VI.2, infra).

48

Page 53: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

V.2. The art of creating virtuous circles by coordinated policies….

Contrary to the vision popularized by an extreme interpretation of path dependence (Crouch 1999; Streeck and Thelen 2005), such vicious circles, whereby underdevelopment and mass poverty reinforce each other, can be broken down in special circumstances when for instance a acute social, economic and political crisis make impossible the reproduction of the past, especially if the international relations change and a new productive paradigm emerges (see figure 5 supra). Actually, the Irish case (Kirby 2007) is a good example of such a change in a long term trajectory along which poverty was perceived as a fatality. Virtuous circles, if not miracles, can be created by collective action (figure 19).

Figure 19 – The creating virtuous circles: searching for complementarity institutional reforms and policies (Ireland)

NATIONAL AGREEMENTS Favorable international environment

Low Taxation

Attraction of FDI

Growth Employment

Wage moderatio

n

Up-grading of skills

+ +

+ +Legitimization

of a lean welfare

Reduction of poverty

The success, observed ex post, seems to proceed from the synchronization of complementary policies. All of them aim at shifting economic specialization towards high added value activities:

In order to attract high tech multinationals, the taxation of profit should be kept low by comparison of alternative location in Europe. The subsidies generated by the adhesion of Ireland to Europe have

49

Page 54: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

also played a role in the building of modern infrastructures, as a source of competitiveness.

National agreements between entrepreneurs association, unions and State look for the competitiveness of the Irish territory via a complex mix of wage moderation, skill formation various incentives in the direction of an industrial policy and innovation.

A rather lean Welfare State built upon minimal levels of universal entitlements to income along with market supplied services.

One does not observe a big push in welfare but the dynamism of growth, employment creation and productivity increases finally trickle down and eradicate a large fraction of poverty, without any clear redistribution of income from the rich to the poor. Even if the disadvantaged are treated as a residual category (Hardman 1998, quoted by Kirby 2007), a virtuous circle has taken place in Ireland, largely based upon complementary policies, without a leading role for welfare policy.

….but they do not last for ever!This is of course a limit of the “Celtic tiger” model: poverty reduction

does not mean a stabilization of inequalities. But it is not the only one, since the maturation of this new growth regime generates a series of structural transformations and emerging disequilibria (figure 20).

The shift of employment creation from the manufacturing sector to the financial sector and the construction may destabilize the previous source of competitiveness and the very engine of Irish growth.

These structural changes also bring a widening of income and wealth distribution and in such a context, the minimalist welfare State could be perceived as insufficient and this could trigger a de-legitimization of current policies.

Finally, the international context may turn less favorable, the net transfers from the European budget level off and new EU members may outperform Ireland by using the same strategy but more efficiently. This is a major risk to the Irish strategy of reduction of poverty, essentially economic led.

Figure 20 – The tensions in the Irish configurationNew EU members

use the Irish strategy

50

Page 55: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Financialization

Success of growth Construction

boomLess

competitiveness/ more inequalities

Lagging welfare and

infrastructures-

- More fragile / less legitimized

growth

+

V.3. The crucial role of political alliances… The previous analyses might suggest that the selection and

implementation of a “good policy”- i.e. Pareto improving- is essentially an exercise in applied economy. If politicians do not buy their pet program, the economists generally blame the irrationality of the groups that have blocked it or the lack economic expertise of decision makers. This feeling originates from a drastic underestimation of politics, defined as “all the activities of cooperation, conflict and negotiation involved in decisions

51

Page 56: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

about the use, distribution and distribution of resources” (Leftwich 2007:3). Therefore, the inner intricacies of the political process are crucial since any institutional reform of requires the formation and durability of a socio-political coalition in democratic regimes (figure 21). Of course, such a coalition is easier if the reform sets into motion a positive and increasing sum game, at odds with policies that would organize a mere redistribution from the rich to the poor at the cost of a possible negative impact upon economic activity.

The task of the social scientist is then to “identify, support and

encourage the political forces and coalitions which alone will create and sustain the institutional arrangements of development states dedicated to both growth and poverty reduction” (Leftwich 2007 :1).

Figure 21 – The interplay of political and economic determinants of institutional reforms

Hence an emerging new economic regime

Influences the bargaining power of various socio-economic groups

Impact upon individual support

Transcription into collective

Building of a political coalition

POLITY Sets the rules of the game Makes strategic choices

ECONOMY :

52

Page 57: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

….that differ from one country to another The fact that both some democratic and some authoritarian regimes

have succeeded in poverty reduction shows the absence of a canonical model. The complexity of the interactions between polity and economy probably explains the diversity of national trajectories in terms of growth regimes and anti poverty policies.

In the case of Finland the rupture with respect to the era of slow growth and mass poverty has taken place after the emergence of a quite genuine political coalition between social democrats and an agrarian party (Kiander 2007: 2-3). A rather stable and permissive international system has allowed the maturation of a export led growth regime that generated employment and the financial resources to extend the welfare coverage. The configuration has proven to be simultaneously rather efficient and legitimate. But when the external permissive conditions changed, a major structural crisis burst out after the collapse of Soviet-Union, and put an end to a quite successful growth regime (figure 22).

Figure 22– The creating virtuous circles: searching for complementarity institutional reforms and policies (Finland 1960-1980…)

POLITICAL ALLIANCE SOCIAL-DEMOCRATS AND AGRARIANS

Favorable international environment

Control of capital flows

Regulated market

Basic welfare

+ Export led growth

+

+

Employment

+Ability to

extend welfare +

53

Page 58: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Public employment

Legitimization and financing

+ Full employment

An equivalent feedback from political compromises to economic growth took place in Botswana but the political alliances were quite different indeed between cattle owners and government (Selolwane et al. 2007). The emerging complementarity between accelerated growth and an improvement in social indicators originated from a positive shock, i.e. the discovery of new and highly valuable natural resources. But similarly to the Finnish case, a prudent initial move concerning welfare was progressively extended, thus generating a cumulative transformation of the society and the economy (figure 23).

Figure 23– Botswana exhibits a totally different virtuous circle

POLITICAL ALLIANCE CATTLE OWNERS AND GOVERNMENT

Discovery of diamonds

Pro growth strategy

+ +

Infrastructure Health and Education

+ More resources

+ Faster growth

+ Rising inequalities

+Search for legitimacy

Improvement in social and health

indicators

+ Generalisation of welfare policies

Clearly, various configurations may exhibit a complementarity or at least a compatibility, between different institutional arrangements that themselves derive from quite specific political compromises.

54

Page 59: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

V.4. An aggiornamento in development strategies Finally, the present use of ICH to renew some development theory

brings an interesting perspective. Development economics has become systemic and institutionalist, given that they have benefited from the lessons learnt from history and from theoretical advances; and also because they are now imbued with their own conceptual foundations.

Comparative development analysis and modern economic theory actually constitute useful antidotes against those dogmatic visions and ideologies that attempt to pit interventionist conceptions against the neo-liberal vision. The end result is that no pure and unadulterated strategy, i.e. one which is based either on “100% State” or on “100% market”, has been successful – and theory has confirmed the innate limitations of any economic regime that is based on only one of these two mechanisms of co-ordination. A first solution thus consists of offsetting market failures by the appropriate State interventions and, vice versa, transcending the State’s limitations thanks to processes that mimic market competition wherever possible.

The crises that were observed throughout the 1990s reinforce this diagnostic. Whereas in the 1980s certain instances of under-development could be attributed to excessive interventionism, the financial crisis of 1997-1998 showed that the extension of the market to the financial sphere (and to derivative financial products) could also lead to a de-stabilization of even the most dynamic modes of development (e.g. South-East Asia). Too much market can be harmful to development. The 1998 disintegration of the “Washington consensus”, which had previously dominated international organization’s conceptions of development, attests to this awareness. Political leaders and experts have been looking for a new doctrine (in the noblest sense of the term). Most have recognized the need for a new institutional architecture or at least for new rules for running the international financial system.

This is the second path that we would like to open up in our attempt to solve the State/market dilemma (figure 24). On one hand, we now know that successful development depends on the complementarity between these two logics, and not on the affirmation of one or the other. Remember that the market is a social construction whose emergence and viability are predicated on a rich set of legal rules, codes and supervisory bodies. In addition, modern institutionalist research has stressed that the institutional arrangements serving as intermediaries between the State and the market (i.e. associations, communities, partnerships, etc.) can play a crucial role in reconciling the imperatives of dynamic efficiency (such as higher productivity or living standards) and social justice, construed here as an overly un egalitarian distribution of the fruits of growth.

55

Page 60: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

It is therefore illusory to blame one single factor for the hindrance of development. An approach that is based on interdependency, externality and complementarity is far superior. The systemic and changing nature of development has to be acknowledged.

56

Page 61: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 24 – From the Washington consensus to an institutionalist and systemic approach to development

THE CRISIS OF THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS

STATE AND MARKET : COMPLEMENTARITY WITHIN DIVERSE

INSTITUTIONAL ARRANGEMENTS

1. Instability or political crises 1. Re-legitimization of the State  as a promoter of growth and justice

2. Unemployment/growing inequality as a consequence of market adjustments

2. The market co-ordinates decisions on a day-to-day basis, the State makes strategic decisions

3. Fragility of financial and social institutions and weakness of certain actors

3. Encourages a density of institutional arrangements as well as actors’ organizational capabilities

4. Under--investment in collective infra-structure

4. The public sector is responsible for social cohesion and collective infrastructures

5. Major dependency on the international environment

5. Preservation of a balance between domestic needs and external competitiveness

6. De-stabilization of growth regimes as a result of capital flows

6. Differentiated opening up to the international economy, depending on national goals or the domains concerned

In the late 1990s In the early XXIth

century

On this theoretical background, what are the methods and analytical tools in order to implement pro-growth and antipoverty strategies?

VI. SOME METHODS IN ORDER TO APPLY THE INSTITUTIONAL COMPLEMENTARITY HYPOTHESIS

This section proposes some perspectives concerning the extension of the previous framework to the issue of poverty reduction outside the industrialized world

VI.1. A first method for detecting successful configurations

In order to counterbalance the tyranny of the deductive method that looks for a first best solution or a one best way, it might be interesting to approach inductively the issue of poverty reduction. Firstly, what are the countries that in the contemporary period or back to some previous episodes have been successful in significantly reducing poverty? Secondly, what are the factors possibly explaining these successes: the intensity, stability and nature of the growth regime (inward or outward looking, natural resources or innovation led); the volume and composition of welfare expenditures (education, health, income security, quality of public services); the degree and nature of regulation of labor markets (minimum wage, type of labor contracts, coverage of collective

57

Page 62: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

bargaining); the style of policy regimes (degree of centralization, nature of democracy, process of intermediation of conflicting interests). The first step is then to use Qualitative Comparative Analysis in order to detect the various configurations of the previous variables that are empirically associated to poverty reduction. This is the method that allowed the detection of the three configurations of the new economy exhibited by figures 3, 4, and 5. An alternative method would be to mix all the variables and use a cluster analysis to look for what is the grouping of successful countries that emerges.

This method could be useful to test the relevance and generality of the taxonomy of policy regimes of poverty eradication proposed by the project proposal elaborated by UNRISD (2005) in its Appendix 1 (legacy of the socialist model, Asian authoritarian development State, the democratic development State of Nordic countries, structural adjustment, good governance and pro-poor policy). Finally, a panel data analysis could mix cross section and time series in order to test more precisely the quantitative contribution of the variables typical of each regime.

VI.2. A second method: combining two diagnoses about the origin of poverty and the inhibiting factors of growth

By contrast, this second approach aims at capturing the features that are specific to a given country at a precise period in time. The issue is to detect what should be the most convenient policy mix compatible with a dual objective of growth promotion as source of productive employment and poverty eradication. The answer cannot be derived from pure theory since the precise structural conditions have to be analyzed in each national, regional or local context. In a sense, this is a drastic reversal with respect to the legacy of the so-called Washington consensus, according which the same general menu was supposed to fit all the domestic contexts.

Have we the relevant tools in order to make such an analysis? The long experience of development economics has recently delivered a quite interesting and stimulating method in order to cope with the diversity of developing as well as developed countries. The growth diagnostics (Hausmann et al. 2005) proposes to systematically review what are the multipliers associated to the relaxation of the various constraints inhibiting economic activity and to design accordingly economic policy and reform economic institutions. In some instance, a policy that delivers quite impressive result in one country may be inefficient, or worse detrimental, to growth in another and conversely. Actually, static efficiency – frequently associated to price flexibility – has to be distinguished from dynamic efficiency, i.e. the ability to improve

58

Page 63: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

cumulatively productivity and standards of living of an entire population. This dilemma has already been addressed to in section II.3 and figure 2).

It might be useful to rejuvenate a macroeconomic theory that has been quite enlightening in the 80s in order to propose an analytical framework that would transcend the opposition between Keynesian and neoclassical conception of the determinants of employment (Benassy 1982). Actually the so-called disequilibrium theory exhibits a series of determinants of employment. The unemployment is Keynesian if the limiting factor is effective demand, classical if the low profitability limits hiring, Marxian if the scarcity of productive capacity is at the origin of low employment. When applied to developing countries and to the analysis of growth and employment, this framework delivers three major teaching (figure 25).

59

Page 64: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 25 – A diagnostics approach to growth stimulation

WHAT ARE THE FACTORS LIMITING GROWTH?

Lack of demand Excessive costs Lack of productive capacity

Over- evaluation

of the currency

Bad policy mix

Low income Low productivity

High wage Low rate of return of capital

Uncertainty High real interest

rate

Change in monetary

policy

Adjustment of public

policy

Higher minimum

wage; unemployment

benefit

Better private

management

Too low a wage. Need for income

security

Lack of skills, education/training

Need for flexibility,i.e., wage reduction

More innovation

Lesstaxation

Reform of the

financial system

Monetary policy

60

Page 65: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

In many cases, the issue of labor market institutions and welfare reforms might be irrelevant, since the disequilibrium originates from totally different factors: an overvaluation of the domestic currency, an excessively high interest rate due to the lack of credibility of economic policy or a bad management of firms…In such a context, the search for wage flexibility for example may deliver second order results, since this is not the relevant constraints of growth. Too often, in the 90s, financial disequilibria have triggered excessive down grading of workers security in terms of wage, work intensity, welfare…

In some instances, growth and employment can increase by strengthening a precise form of workers rights. For instance, if unemployment is Keynesian, more income security for workers has a positive impact both on employment and profit rate. Similarly, when firms are limited by skill scarcity, a policy developing workers competences simultaneously improves macroeconomic performance and promotes welfare as well as a possible reduction of income inequality. In this case, there is a complementarity between employment level and a form of antipoverty policies. Nevertheless, this is not necessarily the case, and the precise social policy mix has to be tuned to the precise local situation at a given historical period.

Within a third configuration, labor flexibility might be required in order to increase productive employment if for instance classical unemployment is the main source of macroeconomic disequilibria. Alternatively, some collective agreements can codify automatic indexation to inflation and productivity, and this configuration that might appear unable to react effectively to new macroeconomic shocks. This case was quite frequent in the 70s and 80s (see figure 12) but that nowadays the majority of developing countries are suffering from the opposite disequilibrium: productivity increases mainly feed profit increase and relative prices decline but only marginally wage increase. The likelihood of this third configuration is now quite small in most developing countries.

The compatibility between pro-growth policies and antipoverty strategies can be addressed applying the same method of growth diagnosis to the analysis of the factors that explain poverty (figure 26). After a second diagnosis of the most efficient instruments against poverty, one can look for measures that simultaneously belong to the two diagnoses. The originality is to look for the policies that simultaneously reduce poverty and enhance growth. The previous general discussion and various examples suggest that such a policy set is not empty, but probably depends a lot from the local context. Actually, a pro-growth and antipoverty policy takes place within totally different institutional settings, since productive structures, social values and political choices significantly differ from one country to another. Furthermore, even within the same national economy, one could observe the coexistence of defensive flexibility – i.e. via wage reduction and work intensity increase –

61

Page 66: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

in some clusters along with offensive flexibility in others where the building of individual and collective competence is the main answer to technical change and evolution of world competition (Vijayabaskar 2005).

62

Page 67: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 26 – A diagnostics approach to poverty reduction

WHAT ARE THE FACTORS GENERATING POVERTY?

Macroeconomic management Labor Market Institutions Lack of access to public goods

Over- evaluation

of the currency

Bad policy mix

Inadequate income

distribution

Poverty trap

DualismEducation Health

Food security

Change in monetary

policy

Adjustment of public

policy

Redistributive taxation

Anti discrimination

measures

Rural / Urban Policy

Redesign of welfare

Minimal rights for informal workers

More spending

Decentralization Target diseases affecting

the poorer

Public program in favour of farmers

63

Page 68: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

64

Page 69: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

But the task of the expert does not end with the detection of possible and more satisfactory growth regimes.

VI.3. How to go from here to there?A rigorous economic analysis may well detect the key factors at the

origin of poverty and propose relevant policies. Will national governments adopt these policies and international organizations co-finance some of the programs derived from these policies? A political economic approach is then required. Efficient policies might be rejected by lack of legitimacy and conversely political legitimacy and social acceptability do not imply any economic rationality (figure 27).

Figure 27 – The duality between political legitimacy and economic efficiency

LegitimateHelps to

overcome possible

economic costsFirst

political decision

Better economic outcome

Economic benefits in

the long run

Consolidation of the coalition for pro poor policy

The timing of the costs and benefits of any economic reform plays a major role in its acceptability and legitimacy (figure 28).

If this is a win/win strategy for all the actors and for any subsequent period and it should be easy for the government to convince them to support the program. But this case is rather rare indeed (trajectory 1)

Initially, some individuals and groups may win but others may loose in the context of a positive gain of welfare at the economy wide level. Only in the long run do all the groups and individuals gain from the reform. Finally, the faster the growth, the larger the dividends of growth that can be redistributed, including to poor people, but explicit redistributive arrangements have to be built (trajectory 2). But in the transition period, the nature of the political process become crucial, the better dynamic efficiency can be blocked by the short termism implicit to electoral cycles or by the absence of legitimacy of a pro-poor policy.

65

Page 70: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

The political leadership is still more needed when the reform initially reduces national income if for instance a higher taxation of high incomes or profit initially triggers a flight of capital out of the country before the recovery of domestic investment (trajectory 3).

66

Page 71: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Figure 28 – The time profile of costs and benefits of an institutional reform

Net Economic benefit

3

2

1

Time

Thus policy regimes are crucial in the implementation of any pro-poor policies and this confirms one of the basic hypotheses of the UNRISD program.

67

Page 72: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

VII. CONCLUSION: ORGANIZING THE SPILL-OVERS BETWEEN CASE STUDIES AND INSTITUTIONAL COMPLEMENTARITY THEORIZING

The guiding principle of the present chapter is quite simple. How could Institutional Complementarity Theory enlighten one of the crucial contemporary issues in development, i.e. the design and implementation pro-growth and anti-poverty strategies? The present analyses converge towards the following provisional teachings.

1. The failure of mono-causal explanations of under-development and the limited efficacy of the benchmarking of anti poverty programs and the adoption by other countries of best practices call for a systemic and institutional approach to development. The motto could be “Getting the institutions right” not in the abstract, but taking fully into account the national legacy in terms of productive organization, basic social values and style of the political regime.

2. The Institutional Complementarity Hypothesis is part of this research agenda since it helps in assessing the viability and performance of a complete set of economic institutions. When poverty is a mass phenomenon, informal labor is the rule and economic performance poor, any anti-poverty has to be part of mix of policies that affect the very nature of the growth regime. Thus economic and social policies have to be at least compatible and ideally complementary.

3. Whatever the variety of national institutional embeddedness of these policies, they all share a common general principle: they aim at creating not miracles but virtuous circles via the promotion and coupling of higher value added products and processes with a legitimized distribution and redistribution of income towards the less privileged groups of the society. No ambitious social policy can be successful in a society with no productive surplus.

4. This theorizing inspired by ICH opens the possibility of various virtuous configurations for pro-growth and anti-poverty strategies and preliminary comparative international analyses confirm their diversity in response to local conditions and circumstances, such as the nature of the insertion into the world economy, past economic specialization, emerging new opportunities, the ability to build social and political compromises and to renegotiate them when required by major structural changes.

5. The Qualitative Comparative Analysis can be used to detect in contemporary world, but also back in history, the various implementations of successful anti-poverty growth regimes. It is

68

Page 73: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

still more important to mobilize this inductive method in order to explicit the various factors that may trigger the transition from a stagnant and poor society to a dynamic and rich economy. The complete case studies undertaken for the UNRISD program on “Poverty Reduction and Policy regimes” could be the starting point for a more systematic search for the characteristics of political processes that are determinant in the emergence of pro-poor coalitions.

6. The extension of Growth diagnoses to the search of poverty determinants opens another research agenda. Some case studies already show that adequate policies and institutional reforms can enter into synergy and deliver simultaneously an acceleration of growth and a structural reduction of poverty. In some instances, the breaking down of built-in inertia is up to a radical change in the political sphere, such as the end of a form of apartheid, or a transition to democracy.

7. This is an invitation to overcome a typical technocratic illusion that considers that the best practices, since they are Pareto improving, are self implementing. Quite on the contrary, it is crucial to detect, identify and support the groups and political coalitions which are able to design, implement and sustain the institutions and policies of a development state over a period of time sufficiently long for reaping the benefits of growth and poverty reduction.

VIII. REFERENCES

AMABLE, Bruno. 2003. The Diversity of Modern Capitalisms. Oxford University Press, Oxford.

AMABLE, Bruno, BARRÉ Rémi and Robert BOYER. 1997. “Diversity, coherence and transformations of innovation systems”, in R. Barré, M. Gibbons, Sir John Maddox, B. Martin, P. Papon Eds : Science in Tomorrow’s Europe, Economica International, Paris, p. 33-49.

AMABLE, Bruno, ERNST Ekkehard and Stefano PALOMBARINI. 2002. « Comment les marchés financiers peuvent-ils affecter les relations industrielles ? Une approche par la complémentarité institutionnelle. » L’Année de la régulation 2002, Vol. 6, éditions de Sciences-Po, Paris, pp. 271-288.

AMABLE, Bruno and Stefano PALOMBARINI. 2005. L’économie n’est pas une science morale. Le Seuil, Paris.

AMABLE, Bruno, GATTI Donatella and Jens SCHUMACHER. 2006. “Welfare-State Retrenchment: The Partisan Effect Revisited”. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, n° 22, pp. 426-444.

AMSDEN, Alice H. 2007. Escape from Empire The Developing World’s Journey Through Heaven and Hell, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop:

69

Page 74: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

AOKI, Masahiko. 2001. Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

BAIROCH, Pierre. 1997. Victoires et déboires : histoire économique et sociale du monde du 16e siècle à nos jours. Gallimard, Paris.

BANGURA, Yusuf. 2000. Public sector restructuring: The institutional and social effects of fiscal, managerial and capacity-building reforms. Occasional Paper N° 3, UNRISD, Geneva.

BANQUE MONDIALE. 2002. Des institutions pour les marchés. Rapport sur le développement dans le monde. Paris, Eska.

BARBIER, Jean-Claude and Bruno THÉRET. 2000a. “Welfare-to-work or Work-to-welfare? The French Case”, in Welfare-to Work Policies in Social Assistance: A Comparative Study, Neil Gilbert (ed.), New-York: Transaction Books.

BARBIER, Jean-Claude and Bruno THÉRET. 2000b. The French Social Protection System: Path Dependencies and Societal Coherence, Mimeograph IRIS - Centre d’Etudes de l’Emploi, presented at the ISSA International Research Conference, Helsinski, September 25-27.

BÉNASSY, Jean-Pascal. 1982. The Economics of Market Disequilibrium, Academic Press, Boston.

BONOLI, Giulano, and Bruno PALIER. 1999. “ Phénomènes de path dependence et réformes des systèmes de protection sociale”, Revue française de science politique, Vol. 49, n° 3, pp. 399-419.

BOLTANSKI, Luc and Eve CHIAPELLO. 1999. Le nouvel esprit du capitalisme, NRF, Gallimard, Paris.

BORIO, Claudio. 2003. Towards a macroprudential framework for financial supervision and regulation ?, BIS Working Paper N° 128, February, Bank for International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland.

BOYER, Robert. 1996. The seven paradoxes of capitalism…Or is a theory of modern economies still possible. CEPREMAP Couverture Orange N° 9620, Octobre.

BOYER, Robert. 2000a. The French welfare: An institutional and historical analysis in European perspective. CEPREMAP Working Paper (Couverture Orange) N° 2000-07, Paris.

BOYER, Robert. 2000b. “Is a finance-led growth regime a viable alternative to Fordism? A preliminary analysis”. Economy and Society, Vol. 29, n° 1, February 2000, p. 111-145.

BOYER, Robert. 2003. “Institutional Reforms for Growth, Employment and Social Cohesion: Elements of a European and National Agenda”, in Maria Joao Rodrigues Ed. The New Knowledge Economy in Europe Edward Edgar, Northampton, p.146-202

BOYER, Robert. 2004a. Une théorie du capitalisme est-elle possible ? Odile Jacob, Paris.

BOYER, Robert. 2004b. The future of Economic Growth, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK.

BOYER, Robert. 2004c. “New growth regimes, but still institutional diversity”. Socio-Economic Review, vol. 2, n° 1, p. 1-32.

70

Page 75: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

BOYER, Robert. 2006a. La flexicurité danoise. Quels enseignements pour la France. Opuscule CEPREMAP, Editions de l’ENS, Paris.

BOYER, Robert. 2006b. “What is the Future of Codetermination and Corporate Governance in Germany?” In Beckert Jens (ed) Transformationen des Kapitalismus. Campus, Cologne, pp. 135-157.

BOYER, Robert. 2006c. Employment and decent work in the era of ‘flexicurity’, DESA Working Paper n° 32, ST/ESA/2006/DWP/32 Economic & Social Affairs, United-Nations, , New-York, September.

BOYER, Robert. 2006d. “Half a century of development theories: an institutionalist survey”, George Stathakis & Gianni Vaggi (eds), Economic Development and Social Change: Historical roots and modern perspectives, Routledge Oxon (Canada) and New York, p. 29-73.

BOYER, Robert. 2007. « Comment concilier solidarité sociale et efficacité économique à l’ère de la globalisation : une lecture régulationniste. » In Serge Paugam (Dir.) Repenser la solidarité. L’apport des sciences sociales, PUF, Paris, janvier, pp. 887-914.

BRAUDEL, Fernand. 1979. Civilisation matérielle, économie et capitalisme XV-XVIIIe siècles. 3 Tomes. Armand Colin, Paris.

CROUCH, Colin. 1999. Capitalist diversity and change: Recombinant governance and institutional entrepreneurs, Oxford University Press, Oxford

DE BEER, P. and R. LUTTIKHUIZEN. 1998. « Le modèle polder néerlandais : miracle ou mirage ?, Réflexions sur le marché du travail et la politique de l’emploi aux Pays Bas », in Barbier J.C. et Gautié J., dir., Les politiques de l’emploi en Europe et aux États-Unis, PUF, Paris.

DRAIBE, Sonia M. 2007. The Brazilian Developentalist Welfare State: Policy Regime and Poverty Reduction, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

ESPING-ANDERSEN, Gosta. 1990. Three worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

ESPING-ANDERSEN, Gosta. 1996. Welfare States without Work: the Impasse of labor shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policies, in Esping-Andersen, G. (ed.), 1996, Welfare States in Transition. National Adaptations in Global Economies, London - Thousand Oaks - New Delhi, SAGE, pp. 66-87.

ESPING-ANDERSEN, Gosta. 2000. « A Welfare State for the 21st Century, Ageing Societies, Knowledge Based Economies and the Sustainability of European Welfare States », report for the Lisbon Summit, Spring, 37p (internet version).

ESPING-ANDERSEN, Gosta, GALLIE Duncan, HEMMERIJCK Anton and John MYLES. 2003. Why we need a new welfare State, Oxford University Press, Oxford

FITOUSSI, Jean Paul and Olivier PASSET. 2000. “Une analyse des raisons du succès des pays européens dans la lutte contre le chômage”, Rapport du Conseil d’Analyse Économique, .

FLIGSTEIN, Neil. 2001. The Architecture of Markets. An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First Century Capitalist Societies, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

71

Page 76: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

FRANZONI, Juliana Martinez. 2007. UNRISD Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes: The Costa Rican Case, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

FUKUYAMA, Francis. 1996. Trust. The social virtues and the creation of Prosperity. Free Press/Simon & Schuster, New York.

GIDDENS Antony. 1998. The Third Way. The renewal of Social Democracy, Polity Press, Lon don.

GREIF, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the path to the modern economy. Lessons from medieval trade. CUP, Cambridge.

HALL, Peter and David SOSKICE (eds). 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford University Press, Oxford.

HANADA Masanori and Yasuro HIRANO. 2000. “'Industrial Welfare' and the 'Company-ist' Régulation: an eroding complementarity”, in Boyer Robert, Yamada Toshio Eds, The Japanese Capitalism in Crisis, Routledge, London, p. 107, 128

HAUSMANN, Ricardo, Dani RODRIK and Andrès VELASCO. 2005. “Growth Diagnostics”, Mimeograph John Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, March.

HOLLINGSWORTH, Rogers J. and BOYER Robert (eds). 1997. Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

HÖPNER, Martin. 2001. Corporate Governance in Transition: Ten Empirical findings on Shareholder Value and Industrial Relations in Germany. MPIfG Discussion Paper N° 01/5, Cologne.

HÖPNER, Martin. 2006. “Varieties of capitalism.” In Jens Becket and Milan Zafirovski, International holder Encyclopedia of economic sociology, Routledge, London, pp. 40-44.

ILO. 2004a. World Employment Report, 2004-2005. International Labour Office, Geneva.

ILO. 2004b. Economic Security for a Better World. International Labour Office, Geneva.

INTER-AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT BANK. 1995. Overcoming Volatility. Economic and Social Progress in Latin America 1995 Report.

INTER-AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT BANK. 1996. Making Social Services Work. Economic and Social Progress in Latin America 1996 Report Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press.

JAMA, Mohamud A. 2007. Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes: The Case of Kenya, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

KIANDER, Jaakko. 2007. Long Term Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction in Finland, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

KIRBY, Peadar. 2007. Country paper on Ireland, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

72

Page 77: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

KU, Yeun-wen. 2007. Poverty Reduction and policy Regimes: Lessons from the Experiences of Taiwan’s Development, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

LAZONICK, William. 1991. Business Organization and the Myth of the Market Economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

LEE, Ching Kwan. 2005. Livelihood struggles and market reform: (Un)making Chinese labour after State socialism, Occasional Paper N° 2, UNRISD, Geneva.

LEFTWICH, Adrian. 2007. Development State Capacity, Institutional Reform and Poverty Reduction: The Primacy of Politics, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

LE GRAND, Julian and Will BARTLETT Eds. 1993. Quasi-Markets and Social Policy, Basingstoke, The Macmillan Press.

MONTAGNE, Sabine. 2000. “Retraite complémentaire et marchés financiers aux Etats-Unis”, L’Année de la régulation, Vol. 4, pp. 13-45.

MYLES, John, and Paul PIERSON. 2000. “ The comparative political economy of pensions reform ”, in Pierson, Paul (ed.), The New Politics of the Welfare State, Oxford, Oxford University Press.

NAGARAJ, N. 2007. Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes in India. A note of Research Proposals, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

NARANYAN, Deepa. 1999. “ Bonds and Bridges: Social capital and Poverty”, World Bank Working paper ,World Bank, July.

NORTH, Douglas C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New York.

O’SULLIVAN, Mary. 2000. “ Le socialisme des fonds de pension, ou « plus ça change… » : financement des retraites et corporate governance aux États-Unis ”, L’Année de la régulation, Vol. 4, pp. 47-88.

ORLÉAN, André. 2000. Le pouvoir de la finance, Odile Jacob, Paris.PAGÈS, Carmen. 2003. Good Jobs Wanted: Labor Markets in Latin

America. Inter-American Development Bank, Washington DC, October.

PALIER, Bruno. 1998. “ The french social protection system ”, in Portonnier, Jean-Claude (ed.), 1997, Glossaire bilingue de la protection sociale. Social Protection : a bilingual glossary, Vol. 1, Les termes français, Paris, MIRE, pp. 23-34.

PALIER, Bruno and Giulano BONOLI. 2000. “ La montée en puissance des fonds de pension : une lecture comparative des réformes des systèmes de retraite, entre modèle global et cheminements nationaux ”, L’Année de la régulation, Vol. 4, pp. 209-250.

POGGE, Thomas and Sanjay G. REDDY. 2007. Unknown: The Extent, Distribution, and Trend of Global Income Poverty, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

POLANYI, Karl. 1944. The Great Transformation. Traduc. Franç., Gallimard, Paris 1983.

73

Page 78: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

PUTNAM, Robert D. 2000. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon & Schuster.

REDDY, Sanjay G. 2007. Counting the poor: The Truth about World Poverty Statistics, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

REDDY, Sanjay G. and Thomas W. POGGE. 2007. How not to Count the Poor, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

SEEKINGS, Jeremy. 2007. Public Policy and Poverty Reduction in South Africa, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

SELOLWANE, Onalenna, SIPHAMBE Happy, NTSEANE Dolly, MAIPOSE Gervaise, BALOGI Tubana and Keitseope NTHOMANG. 2007. Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

SEN Amartya. 2000. Development as freedom,New York, Anchor Books. SERRANO, Franklin. 2007. Functional and Personal Income Distribution

and Poverty Reduction, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

STEPHENS, John D. 2007. The Politics of Poverty Reduction and Redistribution in Developed Democracies: Lessons for Less Developed Countries, Mimeograph UNRISD Workshop: Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes. Methodology Workshop, Geneva, 21-23 February.

STIGLITZ, Joseph E. 2003. Globalization and its discontents. Editions Fayard, Paris.

STORPER, Michael. 2005. « Society, community and economic development. » Studies in Comparative International Development, winter.

STREECK, Wolfgang. 1997. « Beneficial constraints: on the economic limits of rational voluntarism. » In Hollingsworth Rogers, Robert Boyer (eds), Contemporary capitalism, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 197-219.

STREECK, Wolfgang and Kathleen THELEN. 2005. Beyond continuity : Institutional change in advanced political economies, Oxford University Press, Oxford

THÉRET, Bruno. 2000. “Theoretical Problems in International Comparisons: Toward a Reciprocal Improvement of Societal Approach and “Régulation” Theory by Methodic Structuralism”, in Embedding organizations. Societal analysis of actors, organizations and socio-economic context, Marc Maurice and Arndt Sorge (eds), Amsterdam – Philadelphia: John Benjamins, pp. 101-115.

TODARO, Michael P. and Stephen C. SMITH. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK.

TOKMAN, Victor. 2006. Integrating the informal sector in the modernization process. Prepared for the UN/DESA Development Forum on ‘Productive Employment and Decent Work’, held on May 8 and 9 at United Nations Headquarters, New York.

74

Page 79: June 26, 2006 - PERI · Web viewTodaro, Michael P. and Stephen C. Smith. 2005. Economic Development (ninth edition). Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, UK. Tokman, Victor. 2006. Integrating

UNRISD. 2005. Poverty Reduction and Policy Regimes: A project proposal, Mimeograph October, Geneva.

VIJAYABASKAR, M. 2005. “Governance of flexible accumulation in clusters : can it create « decent work » in low income region”, Mimeograph Madras Institute of Development Studies.

VISSER Jelle and A. HEMERIJCK. 1997. A Dutch Miracle, Amsterdam University Press, Amsterdam.

WALLERSTEIN, Immanuel. 1999. Le capitalisme historique, Repères no 29, La Découverte, Paris.

WORLD HEALTH ORGANISATION. 2000. Annual report, Geneva and Oxford, Oxford University Press.

WORLD BANK. 2000a. World Development Report: Attacking Poverty, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

WORLD BANK. 2006 Equity Enhances the power of growth to reduce poverty, World Development Report, Washington.

75