inequality, aggregate demand and crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or...

40
Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises Matthieu Charpe * International Labour Organization Stefan K¨ uhn International Labour Organization April 23, 2012 Abstract This paper discusses the impact of inequality on output and employment using a DSGE model. In particular, the model looks at the impact of lower bargaining power of workers on aggregate demand via the labour share of income. To address this issue, the model combines a search and matching model with Nash bargaining over income distribution with rule-of-thumb households, nominal price rigidities, CES production function and lower zero bound on monetary policy. The model features an endogenous labour share of income arising from the wage bargaining. Rule-of-thumb households create a transmission channel going from functional in- come distribution to consumption decisions, which feed back on aggregate demand through nominal price rigidities. Low substitution between labour and capital limits the increase in labour demand following a decline in wages, while the lower zero bound prevents an investment boom to overbalance the decline in consumption. The main result is that following a decline in the bargaining power of workers, the result- ing drop in the labour share of income lowers consumption and aggregate demand. It follows that downward wage rigidities such as minimum wage limit the fall in out- put and employment. These results stand in contrast with standard New-Keynesian models. ——————— Keywords: Inequality, labour share, search, matching, crisis. JEL CLASSIFICATION SYSTEM: E24, E32, E62. * Corresponding author, [email protected], Bureau International du Travail, 4 route des Morillons 1211 Gen` eve - CH, +41 22 799 64 43 [email protected], Bureau International du Travail, 4 route des Morillons 1211 Gen` eve - CH, +41 22 799 68 67 1

Upload: others

Post on 30-Jul-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises

Matthieu Charpe ∗

International Labour Organization

Stefan Kuhn†

International Labour Organization

April 23, 2012

Abstract

This paper discusses the impact of inequality on output and employment usinga DSGE model. In particular, the model looks at the impact of lower bargainingpower of workers on aggregate demand via the labour share of income. To addressthis issue, the model combines a search and matching model with Nash bargainingover income distribution with rule-of-thumb households, nominal price rigidities,CES production function and lower zero bound on monetary policy. The modelfeatures an endogenous labour share of income arising from the wage bargaining.Rule-of-thumb households create a transmission channel going from functional in-come distribution to consumption decisions, which feed back on aggregate demandthrough nominal price rigidities. Low substitution between labour and capital limitsthe increase in labour demand following a decline in wages, while the lower zerobound prevents an investment boom to overbalance the decline in consumption. Themain result is that following a decline in the bargaining power of workers, the result-ing drop in the labour share of income lowers consumption and aggregate demand.It follows that downward wage rigidities such as minimum wage limit the fall in out-put and employment. These results stand in contrast with standard New-Keynesianmodels.———————Keywords: Inequality, labour share, search, matching, crisis.JEL CLASSIFICATION SYSTEM: E24, E32, E62.

∗Corresponding author, [email protected], Bureau International du Travail, 4 route des Morillons 1211Geneve - CH, +41 22 799 64 43

[email protected], Bureau International du Travail, 4 route des Morillons 1211 Geneve - CH, +41 22 79968 67

1

Page 2: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

1 Introduction

This paper contributes to the literature connecting inequality and business cycle models.

It presents a DSGE model in which rising inequality leads to an economic crisis through

its negative effect on consumption and aggregate demand. Our contribution is to show

that the transmission channel between inequality and macroeconomics takes place via

aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not

claim that these latter effects did not contribute to the actual crisis, but that the aggregate

demand channel has been under-studied in the existing literature.

A number of contributions have documented the increase in inequality before the

2007 crisis. Piketty and Saez (2003) as well as Atkinson et al. (2011) have described

the concentration of income in the top deciles of the population. Acemoglu (2003) and

Lemieux (2006) review evidence and factors explaining increasing wage dispersion be-

tween high skilled and low skilled workers. Looking at functional income distribution,

Blanchard (1997) and Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003) illustrate the decline in the labour

share of income. In this paper, we are interested in the functional rather than the personal

income distribution. Figure 1 shows that the labour share of income has declined in three

fourth of the 16 high income countries for which data are available over the period 1960-

2010. Section 2 further details the decline in the labour share of income in high income

countries.

Two fundamentally different explanations for the fall in the labour share exist. The

first claims that technological progress favored capital return, while the second identifies

institutional changes as the cause of this development. All explanations require a depar-

ture from the assumption of unitary elasticity of substitution in the production function,

which is usually made in RBC models. Choi and Rios-Rull (2009) and Arpaia et al.

(2009) study the importance of the elasticity of substitution ζ between factors of produc-

2

Page 3: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

tion on their relative shares.1 Institutional factors to explain a changing labour share can

range from lower unionization rates to globalization pressure, but are usually modelled

as a fall in worker’s bargaining power.2 This paper utilizes a general constant elasticity

of substitution (CES) production function as well as a labour market featuring bargaining

over wages and employment. As such, this model allows both for technological as well

as institutional factors to affect the labour share of income.

There are few attempts to link inequality and the crisis in the DSGE literature. In

standard New Keynesian models with a search and matching friction and bargaining over

income distribution, such as Sala et al. (2008), a decline in the labour share of income

increases output and employment. The main reason is that lower wages increase labour

demand by firms. Since the surplus from an additional match accruing to firms increases,

they have an incentives to post more vacancies. A strong supply side effect follows,

raising output. Additionally, changes in the income distribution have no effect on con-

sumption and saving decisions since the representative household receives both labour

and profit income.

The model presented in this paper differs from standard New Keynesian models along

three dimensions. First, the model creates a channel between income distribution and

consumption / saving decisions using households’ heterogeneity. A first type of house-

hold is optimizing and makes consumption, saving and investment decisions to smooth

inter-temporal consumption based on its permanent income. Additionally, a second type

1Choi and Rios-Rull (2009) show that an elasticity of substitution below unity (ζ = 0.75 in their model)is required for a DSGE model to qualitatively reproduce empirical cyclical wage share properties in re-sponse to technology shocks. In contrast, Arpaia et al. (2009) take the presence of low- and high-skilledlabour into account when investigating the impact of technical change and changes in the relative compo-sition in the labour force.

2Berthold et al. (2002) model putty-clay technology and capital, thereby featuring low substitutabilitybetween capital and labour in the short run and high substitutability in the long run. Under these assump-tions, a fall in workers’ bargaining power will temporarily reduce the labour share. Blanchard and Giavazzi(2003) focus on firm entry costs and show that lower bargaining power, through raising employment, raisesthe number of firms and thereby competition in the market, thus lowering the price markup. By abstractingfrom aspects of technology and factor substitution, they establish that the labour share will ultimately berelated to frictional costs, like entry costs, imposed on firms.

3

Page 4: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

of household, called rule-of-thumb household, has no access to financial markets, and

thus no saving or borrowing.3 This household relies exclusively on labour income when

employed or the replacement wage when unemployed. The presence of rule of thumb

households generates a transmission channel going from income distribution to consump-

tion decisions and aggregate demand.

Second, the paper introduces the possibility of a liquidity trap implemented with a

lower bound on the nominal interest rate, as in Christiano et al. (2009). In a liquidity trap,

a shortage of demand, causing deflation, cannot be met by a fall in the nominal interest

rate. As a result, the real interest rate rises, further lowering consumption and investment

demand. This paper shows that the negative aggregate demand effect caused by lower

workers’ bargaining power far outweighs the positive supply effects in a liquidity trap.

This channel is especially relevant in the 2008 crisis, when the collapse of the financial

system required central banks to reduce interest rates to very low levels. Section 5 shows

that the mechanism underlined in this paper are also relevant in the absence of a lower

zero bound. However, the liquidity trap amplifies the mechanism at work.

Third, the model assumes a CES production function, which encompasses both Cobb-

Douglas as well as Leontief production functions. Low degree of substitution between

labour and capital implies that a decline in wages does not trigger a large increase in

labour demand. This effect both produces fluctuations in the labour share of income as

well as reduces the size of the transmission channel going from wages to labour demand.

Summarizing, this paper highlights the importance of labour income as a driver of

aggregate demand. Additionally, the relevance of this effect is underlined by conducting

an experiment where a lower floor on real wages is introduced. Such a floor can be

motivated by the downward rigidity of nominal wages, or by policy action in the form of

a minimum wage. Under such circumstances, the crisis induced by increased inequality

3There is a large literature on rule of thumb households, see for instance Galı et al. (2007) or Boscaet al. (2001).

4

Page 5: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

is actually less severe since aggregate demand does not fall as strong.

The paper conceptually closest is Kumhof and Ranciere (2010). These authors also

investigate the potential crisis-inducing impact of rising inequality. In their paper, work-

ers react to falling wage income by increasing indebtedness, which eventually can cause

an economic crisis. In contrast to this paper, Kumhof and Ranciere (2010) disregard ag-

gregate demand effects by using a highly stylized model, assuming constant employment

and abstracting from capital accumulation.

The next section reviews empirical evidence on the time series properties of the func-

tional income distribution. Section 3 presents the mathematical derivation of the model

used. Section 4 outlines the calibration strategy used, while Section 5 presents the simu-

lation results. Finally, the last Section concludes.

2 Trends in the labour share of income

Figure 1 illustrates the decline in the labour share of income, which has taken place

in the majority of 16 high income countries for which data exist over the period 1960-

2010. Data are taken from the AMECO database. The adjusted wage share is defined as

percentage of GDP at current factor cost (Compensation per employee as percentage of

GDP at factor cost per person employed.) The decline has been gradual and continuous

in 11 out of 16 countries over the period 1960-2010. The largest drop took place in

Ireland, Japan and Austria with an annual growth decline of -0.54 percent, -0.38 percent

and -0.38 percent respectively. Italy, Norway and Finland displays declines around -0.30

percent annual, while the USA and Canada are close to -0.2 percent. More moderate

declines took place in France -0.17 and Sweden -0.10. Interestingly, this decline has

mainly taken place over the past two decades. In Australia and the Netherlands, the

labour share is constant but displays a large increase in the 1970’s and a long correction

thereafter. Contrastingly, in Denmark and the UK, the labour share has been fluctuating

5

Page 6: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

around a constant trend. Lastly, Belgium is the sole country in which the labour share

has been increasing at an annual rate of 0.17 percent.

[Figure 1 about here.]

These relatively large fluctuations in the labour share of income confirm existing stud-

ies. Blanchard (1997) and Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003) for instance make a similar

analysis and point to labour market rigidities as a source of these fluctuations.4 How-

ever, this result is not consensual since Kaldor predicted that the labour share is constant

around 65%. Picketty (2001) for instance makes a similar statement based on long term

time series. Contrastingly, Solow (1958) argues that while constant at the aggregate level,

the wage share displays excessive fluctuations at the sectoral level. Recently, as a similar

analysis has been conducted on US data by Young (2010).

A reason to explain the absence of a consensus on the trends in the labour share of

income is the measurement difficulties. A first issue is the treatment of quasi public ad-

ministration and the financial sector in measuring the value added. A second issue is the

contribution of stock options and the income of the self-employed in the compensation

of labour. Askenazy (2003) shows for instance that correcting for the self-employed as

well as for quasi public administration affects the trends in the labour share significantly

in France and the USA.

This paper does not intend to engage in the debate of the long run properties of the

labour share. However, since the under-shooting in the labour share is a short to medium

run phenomena, it raises the question of the economic consequence of this deviation on

aggregate demand and economic activity.

4See Bentolila and Saint-Paul (2003) for a similar analysis.

6

Page 7: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

3 Model

3.1 Households’ heterogeneity and aggregate quantities

There are two types of households, optimizing households denoted by subscript o and

rule of thumb households denoted by subscript r. We define the total number of house-

holds, consumption, employment and total labour endowment (labour supply) of each

household type as ϒi,t , Ci,t , Ni,t and Li,t for i = [o,r], respectively. The total aggregate

quantities are then given by the sums of these, thus Ct =Co,t +Cr,t and the equivalents.

Consumption per household ct =Ctϒt

is then given by

ct = øcco,t +(1−øc)cr,t , (1)

where øc =ϒo,tϒt

is the share of optimizing consumers in the total population, and ci,t =

Ci,tϒi,t

for i = [o,r]. We assume that each household has a maximum labour endowment

of unity. We assume that rule of thumb households fully use their labour endowment,

thus Lr,t = ϒr,t . For optimizing consumers, we assume that their labour supply can be a

fraction υ , thus Lo,t = υϒo,t .5 This allows the model to encompass different cases. The

standard rule-of-thumb set-up as presented in Galı et al. (2007) corresponds to υ = 1. The

polarized case where optimizing households are capitalists and rule of thumb households

are workers as in ? is given by υ = 0. The standard New Keynesian model with a single

optimizing households is achieved by assuming øc = υ = 1.

The employment rate nt =NtLt

is given by

nt =ønno,t +(1−øn)nr,t , (2)

where øn =υøcøp

is the share of optimizing consumers in the workforce and øp = 1− (1−

υ)øc. When υ = 1, then øn = øc and øp = 1. The aggregate employment per household

is given by Ntϒt

= øpnt

5We set this fraction exogenously. A model extension could have this value be determined endoge-nously, for example as a function of wealth.

7

Page 8: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Since only optimizing households hold a capital stock, per household investment and

capital stock are defined as

xt =øcxo,t (3)

kt =øcko,t (4)

3.2 Labour Market Flows

In the model presented in this paper, all households face equal probabilities of finding or

loosing a job. Hence, we specify the labour market flows in aggregate quantities only.

All workers not working in a period are unemployed and looking for a job. The pool

of unemployed (relative to the labour force L) is given by ut = 1− nt−1. Unemployed

workers can be matched to a job and start working immediately in that period. The

matching function (again specified as relative to the labour force L) is mt = γmuγt v1−γ

t ,

where mt are new matches, vt are posted vacancies, γ is the elasticity of matching to

unemployed workers and γm is the overall matching efficiency.

Three definitions are used to describe the labour market: the probability of filling a

vacancy, qt = mt/vt , the job finding probability pt = mt/ut and labour market tightness

θt =vt

1−nt. The model assumes quadratic employment adjustment cost ϕn,tht following

Gertler and Trigari (2009), which are specified in terms of the hiring rate ht =mt

nt−1. 6

Jobs separation probability is 1−ρ . Employment at t is given by the remaining stock

of workers plus new matches.

nt = ρnt−1 +qtvt (6)

Thus, workers that were employed at t − 1 and who loosed their job are immediately in

6The functional form used is as in Gertler and Trigari (2009)

ϕn,t =κ2

h2t nt−1 (5)

8

Page 9: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

the pool of unemployed and are able to find a job in period t again. The probability of

filling a vacancy, qt and the job finding probability pt are given by:

qt =γm

(1−nt−1

vt

)γ(7)

pt =γm

(vt

1−nt−1

)1−γ(8)

3.3 Households

Optimizing and rule of thumb households maximize their inter-temporal utility function

maxUi,t =∞

∑j=0

β t+ ju(ci,t+ j) for i = [o,r], (9)

where β is the time discount factor and the period utility function u(ci,t) is defined as

u(ci,t) =c1−σ i

i,t

1−σ i for i = [o,r].

Both types of households face the employment dynamics constraint.

ni,t = ρni,t−1 + pt(1−ni,t−1) for i = [o,r]. (10)

3.3.1 Rule of Thumb Households

Rule of thumb households do not have access to financial markets. Therefore, their bud-

get constraint is given by their labour income plus their unemployment benefit payments

wu.

cr,t ≤ wtnr,t +wu(1−nr,t), (11)

The household maximizes its utility (9) subject to the employment and budget con-

straints, (10) and (11). The consumption of rule of thumb households is given by their

9

Page 10: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

budget constraint (eq 11), which is always binding. Furthermore, the marginal utility of

consumption λr,t (the Lagrange multiplier on the budget constraint) is given by

λr,t = c−σ r

r,t (12)

The first derivative of the utility function Ur,t with respect to nr,t yields

Vr,t = λr,t(wt −wu)+βEt [Vr,t+1(ρ − pt+1)] ,

where Vr,t is the Lagrange multiplier on the employment dynamics constraint (10), and

can thus be interpreted as the marginal utility value of a job to a household. It is useful

to define the value of a job in terms of a consumption good, thus we define Hnr,t =Vr,tλr,t

.

We then obtain

Hnr,t =wt −wu +βEt[Λr

t,t+1 (ρ − pt+1)Hnr,t+1], (13)

where Λrt,t+1 =

λr,t+1λr,t

is the stochastic discount factor for rule of thumb consumers.

3.3.2 Optimizing Consumers

Like rule of thumb households, optimizing households also earn labour income and un-

employment benefits. These quantities have to be scaled by the relative labour market

participation υ when expressing in per-household terms. Additionally, they can invest in

bonds paying a gross nominal interest rate Rn,t . When Bo,t is the total nominal quantity

of bonds held by optimizing households, then bo,t =Bo,tPtϒo

is the real stock of bonds per

optimizing household. Finally, they can accumulate physical capital ko,p,t subject to the

accumulation function

ko,p,t = (1−δ )ko,p,t−1 + xo,t(1−ϕk,t), (14)

where ϕk,t are capital adjustment costs.7

7Capital adjustment costs follow the usual specification ϕk,t =ηk2

(xo,t

xo,t−1−1

)2, so that ϕk = 0 at the

steady state.

10

Page 11: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Optimizing households are allowed to vary the usage of physical capital by the fac-

tor uk,t , to earn a return uk,trk,t on their physical capital stock. There is a cost ℑ(uk,t)

associated with capacity over- or under-utilization.8 Actual capital is determined by

ko,t =uk,tko,p,t−1 (15)

The budget constraint of optimizing households is given by

co,t + xo,t +bo,t +ℑ(uk,t)ko,p,t−1

≤ wtυno,t +wuυ(1−no,t)+ rk,tuk,tko,p,t−1 +Rn,t−1

πtbo,t−1 − τo,t +Πt , (16)

where Πt are profit receipts from firms, πt =Pt

Pt−1is the gross price inflation rate and Pt is

the aggregate price level.

The household maximizes its utility (9) subject to the employment dynamics con-

straint (10), the capital accumulation (14) and the budget constraint (16). We define the

Lagrange multipliers on the employment constraint as Vo (thus the marginal value of

a job), the budget constraint as λo (thus the marginal utility of consumption), and the

capital accumulation constraint as λk (thus the marginal utility value of a unit of capital).

Defining φt =λk,tλo,t

(Tobin’s q), the first order conditions are given by

λo,t = co,t−σo

(17)

Λot,t+1 =

πt+1

Rn,t(18)

φt = βEt(Λo

t,t+1[rk,t+1uk,t+1 −ℑ(uk,t+1)+φt+1 (1−δ )

])(19)

φt =

1−βEt

{φt+1Λo

t,t+1

(xo

t+1xo

t

)2(xt+1xt

−1)}

1−(

ϕt +xo

txo

t−1ηk

(xt

xt−1−1

)) (20)

rk,t = rkeψ(uk,t−1) (21)

Vo,t = λo,tυ(wt −wu)+βEt [Vo,t+1(ρ − pt+1)] ,

8The functional form is ℑ(uk,t) =rk

ψ

(eψ(uk,t−1)−1

), so that ℑ(1) = 0 and ∂ℑ(uk,t )

∂uk,t> 0.

11

Page 12: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

where Λot,t+1 =

λo,t+1λo,t

is the stochastic discount factor for optimizing households.

Similarly to rule of thumb households, we define the value of a job in terms of a

consumption good Hno,t =Vo,tλo,t

. We then obtain

Hno,t =υwt −υwu +βEt[Λo

t,t+1 (ρ − pt+1)Hno,t+1],

3.4 The Wholesale Good Firm

Wholesale good firms produce output using capital and labour using a production func-

tion of the form Y wt = F(Kt ,Nt). We specify a CES production function, which is homo-

geneous of degree one. Therefore, output per household can be expressed as

ywt =

[α(Bkkt)

ζ−1ζ +(1−α)(Bnøpnt)

ζ−1ζ

] ζζ−1

, (22)

where ζ is the elasticity of substitution, Bk and Bn are technology (scaling) parameters

and α is a share parameter. The Cobb-Douglas case occurs when ζ = 1.

The firm maximizes its value Ft , expressed as per household, by selling output at the

real price pwt ,9 renting capital kt at price rk,t , and hiring labour nt at price wt , subject

to the dynamic equation governing employment as well as the quadratic employment

adjustment cost. The value is given by

Ft = pwt yw

t −wtøpnt −κ2

h2t nt−1 − rk

t kt +βEt[Λo

t,t+1Ft+1], (23)

where Λot,t+1 is also the firms’ discount factor as they are owned by optimizing house-

holds. The first order conditions with respect to k, h and n (where we do not evaluate

9Section 3.7 specifies pwt .

12

Page 13: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

∂h/∂n as each firm is small) are given, in that order, by

rk = pwt α (Bk)

ζ−1ζ

(yw

tkt

) 1ζ

(24)

κht = Jt (25)

Jt = pwt an

t −øpwt +βEt

[Λo

t,t+1κ2

h2t+1

]+βρEt

[Λo

t,t+1Jt+1]

(26)

ant = (1−α)

(zn,tBnkν

g,tøp) ζ−1

ζ

(yw

tnt

) 1ζ

(27)

The marginal productivity of labour is given by an. Jt is the Lagrange multiplier on

the ”budget” constraint of employment dynamics (6), and thus can be interpreted as the

marginal value to the firm of having another worker.

3.5 Bargaining

Firms and workers engage in Nash Bargaining over the joint surplus, the outcome of

which is the wage w∗t . ηt is the workers relative bargaining power and is time dependant

since the experiment considered in this paper is a temporary shock on ηt .

w∗t ≡ max

{(Ht)

ηt (Jt)1−ηt

}, 0 < ηt < 1 (28)

The bargaining solution implies ηtJt = (1−ηt)Ht , where the aggregate worker sur-

plus is given as a weighted average of the individual surpluses according to their share in

the labour force, Ht = ønHno,t +(1−øn)Hnr,t .

The bargaining set, the total surplus, is given by St = wt −wt , where wt is the max-

imum wage when firms’ surplus Jt = 0, and wt is the minimum wage when workers

surplus Ht = 0. The negotiated wage is the weighted average of these reservation wages,

w∗t = ηtwt +(1−ηt)wt . By substituting Jt = κ qtvt

nt−1, we obtain

13

Page 14: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

w∗t =ηt

1øp

pwt an

t +(1−ηt)wu +ηt1øb

βEt{

Jt+1Λot,t+1 pt+1

}+ηt

1øp

βEt

{Λo

t,t+1κ2(ht+1)

2}+ηtρβ

(1øp

− 1øb

)Et

[Λo

t,t+1Jt+1]

+(1−ηt)β1−øn

øbEt

{Hnr,t+1(ρ − pt+1)(Λo

t,t+1 −Λrt,t+1)

}(29)

Hall (2005) demonstrates that real wage stickiness greatly improves the ability of a

search and matching model to match empirical employment dynamics. For this reason,

we follow him by utilizing the following wage rule

wt =ρwwt−1 +(1−ρw)w∗t (30)

The actual wage is a weighted average between the Nash bargained wage and the past

period’s wage.

3.6 The Final Goods Firm

The final good (expressed per household), yt , is produced in a competitive market ac-

cording to the following CES technology:

yt =

(∫ 1

0y

1µi,tdi

)µµ ≥ 1 (31)

where each input yi,t is a differentiated intermediate good. The term 11−µ indicates the

price elasticity of the demand for any intermediate good i. Each period, final goods

producers choose a continuum of differentiated intermediate goods, yi,t at price Pi,t , to

maximize their profits subject to the CES technology (31). The demand function for

intermediate goods can be derived as follow:

yi,t =

(Pi,t

Pt

) µ1−µ

yt (32)

14

Page 15: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

3.7 Intermediate Good Firms

Intermediate good firms purchase homogeneous goods from the wholesale sector and

relabel them to produce differentiated goods. These differentiated goods are then sold

in a monopolistic competitive market to the final good firms. Furthermore, we assume

that intermediate good firms are subject to price stickiness, whereby a fraction χ1 cannot

reset its price in a certain period and set price Pt−1. Of the fraction 1− χ1 that is able to

reset its price, only a fraction χ2 performs a full optimization of its reset price, setting P∗t ,

while a fraction 1−χ2 resets its price according to the simple rule Pb,t = Pt−1πt−1.

The aggregate price Pt is given by Pt = χ1Pt−1 +(1− χ1)Pt , where Pt = χ2P∗t +(1−

χ2)Pb,t is the aggregate reset price. Normalizing these equations by Pt , we get:

1 =χ1π−1t +(1−χ1)pt (33)

pt =χ2 p∗t +(1−χ2)πt−1

πt(34)

where p∗t =P∗

tPt

is the ”real” optimized reset price.

Firms being able to optimize choose price p∗t by maximizing their discounted stream

of real profits.

maxP∗

t

Et

∑s=0

(χ1β )sΛot,t+s

[P∗

tPt+s

− pwt+s

]yi,t+s (35)

subject to the demand equation (32). pwt represents the (real) purchasing price of whole-

sale goods, and thus the marginal costs.

The first order condition is

f1,t =1µ

f2,t (36)

where

f1,t =(p∗t )µ

1−µ yt pwt +Λt,t+1χ1βπ

−µ1−µ −1

t+1

(p∗t

p∗t+1

) µ1−µ

f1,t+1 (37)

f2,t =(p∗t )1

1−µ yt +Λt,t+1χ1βπ−µ1−µ

t+1

(p∗t

p∗t+1

) 11−µ

f2,t+1 (38)

15

Page 16: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Firms set their price not at the current optimal level but at the level they deem optimal

over the expected lifetime of their set price. In the presence of inflation, this means that

firms having reset their price earlier will have a lower relative price than firms that just

reset their price, and will therefore have a higher share of aggregate demand. This means

that marginal products are not equal across firms, but that there will be inefficiencies due

to price dispersion, denoted with the symbol st . This means that the quantity available for

aggregate demand, yt , is not necessarily equal to the quantity from the per firm production

function ywt , but only a fraction 1

stof it. Hence, we have the relationships

ywt =styt (39)

st =(1−χ1)p− 1

1−µt +χ1π

11−µ

t st−1 (40)

In a zero inflation steady state the optimal reset price will be given by 1µ = pw. Thus,

firms set price as a mark-up on nominal marginal costs.

3.8 Policies and resource constraint

Due to the lower zero bound on monetary policy, the interest rate set by the Central Bank

is the maximum of the interest rate as determined by a Taylor rule Rn∗t and zero.

Rnt = max [Rn∗

t ,0] (41)

The implementation of the zero bound is presented in Appendix B.

The Taylor rule sets the interest rate according to a criteria of interest rate smoothing,

and measures of inflation and output. ϕm is the parameter driving the Taylor rule inertia,

while ϕπ and ϕy are the parameters setting the response of the interest rate to inflation

and output.

Rn∗t

Rn =

{Rn∗

t−1

Rn

}ϕm{(πt

π

)ϕπ(

yt

y

)ϕy}1−ϕm

(42)

16

Page 17: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

The government pays unemployment benefits and finances these using lump sum

taxes on optimizing households, which is thus equivalent to debt financing.10 Therefore,

rule of thumb households are not subjected to cyclical tax fluctuations. The resource

constraint is given by summing the budget constraints of both type of households (11),

(16) as well as the profit equation of firms.

yt =ct + xt +κ2

q2t v2

tnt−1

+ℑ(uk,t)øcko,p,t−1 (43)

Finally, the exogenous process subjected to a shock in this paper is ηt , which evolves

according to the autoregressive process

ηt = (1−ρη)η +ρηηt−1 (44)

3.9 Equilibrium

The stationary equilibrium consists in processes for the flow variables [y,yw,c,co,cr,x,xo,an],

the stock variables [n,no,nr,k,ko,ko,p], the prices [Rn,rk,φ,uk,w,w∗, pw,π, p, p∗, f 1, f 2,s],

the labour market rates [q,v, p] and the utility and discount rates [J,Hr,λo,Λo,λr,Λr]

, given the structural parameters [øc,υ ,σo,σ r,β ,δ ,ψ ,ηk], the labour market param-

eters [κ,ρ ,γm,γ ,ρw], the production parameters [α,Bk,Bn,ζ ], the pricing parame-

ters [µ,χ1,χ2], the policy parameters [wu,ρm,ϕπ ,ϕy,τr,τo] and the exogenous process

[η ,ρη ] satisfying the equilibrium conditions given by equations (1), (2), (3), (4), (6),

(10), (7), (8), (11), (12), (13), (14), (15), (17), (18), (19), (20), (21), (22), (24), (25),

(26), (27), (29), (30), (33), (34), (36), (37), (38), (39), (40), (42), (43) and (44) and the

definitions Λit,t+1 =

λi,t+1λi,t

for i = [o,r].

4 Steady State and Calibration

The steady state of the model is given when all variables are constant over time. In

principle, the steady state can be solved given all structural parameters. In practice, it10τo,t = wu (1−nr,t +υ(1−no,t))

17

Page 18: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

is usual procedure to calibrate target values for certain variables and derive structural

parameters from these.

First, this paper calibrates a zero inflation steady state and normalizes the price level

to unity. Next, this paper calibrates the job separation rate ρ , the job finding rate p and

labour market tightness θ to match empirically observed values, and uses these to derive

the structural parameters γm and κ . Furthermore, it is useful with CES production func-

tions to normalize steady state output to unity. This requires the technology parameters

Bk and Bn to be computed as the inverse of the steady states of the factors of production,

k and n. These steady state values are easily derived using knowledge of the real interest

rate (given the discount parameter β ) and the job separation and finding rate.

Table 1 shows the parameter calibration used for the numerical simulations carried

out further below. The parameters are essentially taken from Gertler and Trigari (2009),

who estimated a similar model for the US economy. The relative risk aversion is identical

for both households σo = σ r and is set at 1. It follows that the utility function takes the

form of a logarithmic function. The time discount factor β is set at 0.992, generating

an annual interest rate of 3.2%. Capital depreciates at a rate of 2.5% per quarter, which

corresponds to 10% annual rate of depreciation. The cost of capital adjustment ηk is 3

and the cost of capacity utilization is set at 0.7 following the estimation made by Sala

et al. (2008) for the US economy.

The parameters of the labour market are conventional and taken from Shimer (2005).

The job surviving rate ρ is set at 90%, while the job finding probability p and the labour

market tightness are equal to 0.95 and 0.5 at the steady state respectively. The elasticity

of matching to unemployed workers γ is 0.5. An important parameter in search and

matching models is the replacement ratio ω . In models without strong wage stickiness,

a high value is needed to generate realistic employment fluctuations. Gertler and Trigari

(2009) estimate this value to be 0.72 in a model with wage stickiness and 0.98 in a model

18

Page 19: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

without wage stickiness. We choose an intermediate value ω = 0.9. Since restrictions

are placed on two variables p and θ , the steady states for labour market variables are

found by solving endogenously for the two parameters γm, the efficiency of the matching

function, and κ , the employment adjustment cost. They are respectively equal to 1.345

and 0.6572. These parameters produces an employment rate n of nearly 90% at the steady

state. Finally, wage rigidity is moderate with ρw = 0.3.

[Table 1 about here.]

The capital share α is set at 0.3 and µ is set at 1.11 for a mark up of 11%, generating a

labour share of income of 63% at the steady state. The coefficient Bk and Bn are equal to

0.1223 and 1.3003 respectively, which corresponds to the inverse of the steady state value

of the capital stock and employment in order to normalize the CES production function.

The set of parameters related to nominal price rigidities is conventional. 75% of firms are

unable to adjust their price to the optimal price every period. There is no price indexation

χ2 = 1. Monetary policy inertia ρm is set at 0.8, while the reaction of the interest rate

to inflation and output are 1.7 and 0.2 respectively. Lastly, the experiment undertaken

consists in a negative shock on the bargaining power of workers η , which is equal to 0.5

at the steady state. The shock is given by ε = 0.05η and produces a 1.5% decline in the

labour share of income in the baseline calibration. The persistence of the shock ρη is 0.9.

We define the baseline model when optimizing households’ participation to the labour

market is given by υ = 0.5. The share of rule of thumb households (1− øc) is 70%

as in Galı et al. (2007). Furthermore, the production function assumes a lower degree

of substitution between labour and capital, ζ = 0.6, an intermediate value between the

Cobb-Douglas case ζ = 1 and the Leontief case ζ = 0. To simulate a standard New Key-

nesian model, we set the share of optimizing households and the elasticity of substitution

between capital and labour to unity (øc = 1, υ = 1, ζ = 1). We also consider another

19

Page 20: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

extreme case where optimizing households are identified as capitalists, thus not earning

labour income (υ = 0). All intermediate calibrations are possible.

5 Results

5.1 Baseline results

This section presents the simulated results of a fall in worker’s bargaining power using

the model described in this paper. The solid line in Figure 2 shows the baseline cali-

bration, while the dashed line shows a standard New Keynesian model with search and

matching in the labour market.11 The figures for output, consumption and investment

below represent percentage point deviations in terms of GDP, which in turn is normal-

ized to one in steady state. Inflation, employment and the labour share are represented as

percentage point deviations.

[Figure 2 about here.]

The fall in bargaining power causes a fall in the labour share for three reasons. First,

workers can only bargain for lower wages, leading to a fall in real wages. Second, em-

ployment adjusts slowly with search and matching in the labour market. Third, with low

substitution between capital and labour, the price effect from a fall in the wage is not

countered fully by the quantity effect from an eventual rise in employment. In the stan-

dard New Keynesian model, only the first two effects are present, explaining why the

labour share quickly returns to its baseline value. Contrastingly, the labour share falls

by more than 1% on impact and stay below steady state for more than 15 quarters in the

baseline calibration.11The baseline calibration includes rule of thumb households øc = 0.3 and full participation of opti-

mizing households in the labour market υ = 0.5. The production function has low degree of substitutionbetween labour and capital ζ = 0.6. The parameters are presented in Table 1. The standard New Keyne-sian calibration assumes away rule of thumb households øc = 1, while optimizing households participatein the labour market υ = 1. The production function is Cobb-Douglas ζ = 1, while there is no bound onthe interest rate and no wage rigidity ρw = 0. Remaining parameters are identical to the parameters of thebaseline model.

20

Page 21: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

The experiment of lowering workers’ bargaining power usually raises output, con-

sumption, investment and employment in a Standard New Keynesian model. Firms’

surplus from employment relationships rises, thus increasing vacancies, the number of

matches, employment and output. This increases both the marginal product of capital

and aggregate saving, thus raising investment. Consumption rises since permanent in-

come increases. Inflation falls since the increase in employment and the fall in wages

lowers marginal costs.

The baseline calibration additionally takes several aspects into account that are ig-

nored by the standard New Keynesian model. First, the presence of rule of thumb con-

sumers makes the income distribution an important driver of aggregate demand. This

channel is absent in the standard model since a representative household earns all in-

come. Second, a lower elasticity of substitution between capital and labour implies a

larger fall in the labour share due to a fall in bargaining power since the price and sub-

stitution effects from a fall in wages do not cancel. Third, the baseline simulation allows

for the presence of a liquidity trap. The fall in aggregate demand lowers inflation, in re-

sponse to which the central bank should lower the nominal interest rate. In the presence

of a lower bound on the nominal interest rate, the fall in inflation actually raises the real

interest rate. This has a threefold effect. Vacancy posting falls since the surplus from

a match decreases, investment demand falls, and consumption demand by optimizing

households falls as well.

Summarizing, the baseline simulation allows for strong aggregate demand effects

in response to a falling bargaining power of workers to occur. The solid line in Fig-

ure 2 shows that under such circumstances a fall in workers’ bargaining power leads to

long-lasting reductions in important macroeconomic variables. Aggregate consumption

declines by 1.2 percent on impact. Output declines by 2.3 percent and employment by

1.7 percent. Additionally, investment also falls for 3 quarters. It follows that a reduction

21

Page 22: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

in worker’s bargaining power in a situation of economic recession with low interest rates

further depresses economic activity on impact.

5.2 Sensitivity analysis

This section presents some sensitivity analysis to illustrate the importance of the different

transmission channels at work in the baseline calibration. Figure 3 presents the sensitiv-

ity analysis concerning the impact of the income distribution as a driver of aggregate

demand. The solid line shows the baseline calibration as presented above. The dashed

line shows a calibration of limited labour market participation, where optimizing house-

holds behave purely as capitalists and do not participate in the labour market υ = 0. As

a result, a larger share of total consumption cannot be smoothed intertemporally.12 A

fall in bargaining power therefore leads to a larger fall in aggregate demand, and con-

sequently to a more severe depression of economic activity. Furthermore, the model is

moved closer to an instability region, thus producing a kink in the dynamic path of the

variables.13

The dashed-dotted line represents the case where there are no rule-of-thumb con-

sumers, thus there is no demand effect from changes in the functional income distribu-

tion (øc = 1 and υ = 1). However, the case still allows for the economy to be facing a

liquidity trap. In this case, the increase in aggregate saving described above, combined

with the fall in inflation, do not boost investment but cause the lower bound on the nom-

inal interest rate to be binding. Compared to the baseline model, the absence of income

distribution effects on aggregate demand cancels the importance of the lower bound.

[Figure 3 about here.]

Figure 4 shows that the mechanisms introduced by this paper, the importance of the

income of workers to support aggregate demand, induces a fall in output and employment12The wage share is more or less fixed due to our calibration strategy.13Increasing price stickiness or decreasing ζ moves the economy closer to the instability.

22

Page 23: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

after a fall in bargaining power even in the absence of a liquidity trap. The calibration

has been changed to have a low elasticity of substitution (ζ = 0.05), no lower bound on

monetary policy, while the share of optimizing households remains constant at υ = 0.5.

[Figure 4 about here.]

The solid line in Figure 4 shows that output and employment fall on impact. Due to

the low elasticity of substitution, the fall in bargaining power has a strong effect on the

labour share, which, coupled with price stickiness and the impossibility of consumption

smoothing, induces a strong negative demand effect. Nevertheless, the fall of the real

interest rate combined with the saving shock increase investment, which causes a quick

rebound of output. Although consumption falls on impact and stays below zero for 4

quarters, output increases. In the absence of a liquidity trap, the nominal interest rate

falls with inflation leading to a decline in the real interest rate. It follows that both labour

demand and investment react positively. The speed at which output recovers is partly de-

termined by the existence of capital adjustment costs, which delays investment decisions.

Monetary policy shortens the recession by stimulating both supply and demand channels.

This simulation assumes very low elasticity of substitution between labour and capi-

tal. The distinction between Leontief and Cobb-Douglas production function is a central

element of the literature discussing changes in the labour share. Following a change in

wages, the degree to which firms substitute capital and labour affects the level of employ-

ment. The labour share drops by 0.37 percentage point for an elasticity of substitution of

0.05 (in the Figure 4).14 The impact on output and employment is however quasi null,

given the strength of the other transmission channels.

The dashed line in Figure 4 corresponds to a case in which there is no participation

of optimizing households to the labour market υ = 0. This polarized distribution of in-

come between workers and optimizing households amplifies the wage-aggregate demand14The elasticity of substitution is 0.6 in the baseline case in Figure 2.

23

Page 24: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

channel. Output declines by 0.5 percentage point and stays negative for 2 quarters. The

fall in the labour share is also more pronounced at 0.5 percentage point.

The dashed doted line in Figure 4 shows the importance of nominal price rigidities.

The transmission channel between lower consumption and output depends on the pres-

ence of price stickiness. Increasing price rigidity from 4 quarters to 8 quarters magnifies

the demand side effects (dashed line). The fall in worker’s bargaining power lowers the

labour share further producing a larger drop in output and employment. Output and em-

ployment drop by 0.6 percentage point and 0.5 percentage point on impact respectively,

while they both stay negative for 3 quarters.

5.3 Minimum wage as a lower bound on wage

Figure 2 has illustrated the importance of labour income for aggregate demand in the

proximity of the lower zero bound in monetary policy. The transmission channel going

from labour income to aggregate demand modifies the traditional views on minimum

wage. In a standard New-Keynesian model, the minimum wage is seen as hampering the

downward adjustment in wages. This in turn limits labour demand of firms and amplifies

business cycle fluctuations. Contrastingly, in the present model, the minimum wage sets

a lower floor on labour income, which sustains consumption and aggregate demand. The

direct negative effect of the minimum wage on labour demand is balanced by its positive

impact on aggregate demand.

In this section, minimum wage is modelled in a similar way than the lower zero bound

in monetary policy. The actual wage is the maximum between the wage rule (eq 30) and

the minimum wage.

wt = max [wrt ,wmin] (45)

with wt the actual wage, wrt the wage according to the wage rule in eq 30 and wmin the

24

Page 25: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

minimum wage.

Figure 5 Panel A reproduces the baseline simulation with (dashed line) and without

a minimum wage (solid line). The calibration is similar to the baseline model presented

in Figure 2. The main result is that the minimum wage reduces the size of the recession

following a decline in the bargaining power of workers. The minimum wage reduces the

drop in output from 2.2 percentage point to 1.5 percentage point on impact. The drop in

the labour share of income is also smaller from -1 percentage point to -0.67 percent on

impact. It follows that the drop in consumption is significantly lower than in the absence

of a lower bound on wages, sustaining aggregate demand. A secondary effect is related

to the adjustment in price. Since inflation declines less in the presence of the minimum

wage, the increase in the real interest rate is more moderate, which is less detrimental to

investment and labour demand. The adjustment in the markup also sustains the surplus

from an additional match, which affects the hiring decisions of firms.

In Figure 5 Panel B, a similar mechanism takes place although the minimum wage

is applied to the set of parameters described in Figure 4. The dashed line shows that

a lower bound on the real wage also works in the absence of a liquidity trap. Income

and consumption of rule of thumb consumers is supported, which stabilizes aggregate

demand and lessens the negative impact of the fall in bargaining power.

[Figure 5 about here.]

6 Conclusion

The model presented in this paper shows that under certain conditions a change in income

distribution in favor of capital leads to lower employment and output. This result stands

in contrast with the conclusion from a standard New Keynesian model, which finds virtue

to wage moderation. To reach this result, the modelling strategy has been to reinforce the

transmission channel from income distribution to consumption decisions by combining

25

Page 26: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

rule-of-thumb households and nominal price rigidities. This transmission is strengthened

in the presence of a lower zero bound in monetary policy.

In the New-Keynesian model, the main transmission channel goes through labour

demand. The increase in consumption and investment follows from the increase in em-

ployment and permanent income. Contrastingly, in the present model, consumption drops

due to the presence of rule-of-thumb households, while investment is negatively affected

by the increase in the real interest rate. The lower zero bound also affects labour demand

negatively. It follows that lower bargaining power leads to lower output and employ-

ment in the presence of a liquidity trap. An important implication of this model is that

downward wage rigidity sustains aggregate demand and reduces the fall in output.

Two extensions to the present paper can be envisioned. The first is to allow workers to

have some access to financial markets, and thus engage in some limited borrowing. This

allows the study of the effect of inequality on household indebtedness, thereby following

Kumhof and Ranciere (2010). Second, the extension to a two country model allows

to study a number of research questions present on the current political agenda. In an

open economy, a falling wage will additionally raise export demand, depending on the

exchange rate regime. However, such a policy could be a beggar-thy-neighbor policy

by raising unemployment in the foreign country. Furthermore, international imbalances

might result. Given the results obtained in this paper, an interesting addition to the policy

debate is likely to result from these extensions.

26

Page 27: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

A Steady State

In a zero inflation steady state with π = 1, we can normalize the price level to unity, and

thus obtain p = 1, s = 1 and pw = 1µ . Furthermore, capital utilization is at unity uk = 1,

while Tobin’s q is unity φ = 1. Therefore, we can derive

Rn =1β

(46)

rk =

(1β−1+δ

)(47)

Given ρ and p, and calibrating γ , we can derive

γm =p

θ 1−γ (48)

q =γmθ−γ (49)

n =p

1−ρ + p(50)

v =θ(1−n) (51)

Since the replacement wage is the same for both types of households, the employment

ratio will also be the same in steady state, thus n = no = nr. The number of optimizing

consumers in employment approaches zero as υ → 0.

When using a CES production function, it is useful to normalize output at unity, thus

y= 1. This requires to set the technology parameters multiplying the factors at the inverse

of the factor’s steady state values.

Bk =rk

α pw (52)

Bn =1

øpn(53)

an =(1−α)(Bnøp)ζ−1

ζ

(1n

) 1ζ

(54)

Using this procedure, α actually represents the steady state factor share of capital. The

steady state value of capital is thus k = 1/Bk, while the steady state value of investment

is x = δk.

27

Page 28: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Furthermore, it is useful to define the replacement wage as a fraction ω of the steady

state real wage, thus wu = ωw. Using this equation as well as the steady state versions of

the labour market equations (25), (26), and (29), we can derive the steady state values of

w, and the parameter κ required for the labour market to solve to the equilibrium values

calibrated above. The system of equations to be solved is given by

κqvn

=pwan −øpw+β[

κqvn

ρ +κ2

[qvn

]2]

(55)

w∗ =η1øp

pwan +(1−η)wu +η1øb

βκqvn

p

+η1øp

βκ2

h2 +ηρβ(

1øp

− 1øb

qvn

(56)

w is be larger the smaller is øp. The intuition is that we calibrate output per household

to unity, while the labour share in the production function is α . A smaller labour force

participation (as is implied by smaller øp) requires a larger real wage. This will also

increase the consumption share of rule-of-thumb households.

We then get the steady state for Hnr

Hnr =(1−ω)w

1−β (ρ − p)(57)

The steady state of aggregate consumption is a residual of the resource constraint:

c =y− x− κ2

q2v2

n(58)

Lastly, consumption steady states of both type of households are defined as follow:

cr =wn+wu(1−n)− τr (59)

co =c− (1−øc)cr

øc(60)

B Zero Bound

The procedure for the introduction of a lower bound on a variable into a stochastically

simulated model in Dynare is described in Holden (2011). To introduce a bound on a

28

Page 29: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

variable, a sequence of non-autoregressive, one period, pre-known shocks to the variable

in question are introduced into the model. For each of these shocks, the impulse response

functions for all variables can be computed. Then, a linear combination of these shocks

is computed using an optimization procedure such that the added impulse response func-

tions from all these individual shocks plus the IRF of the original shock allow the bound

to hold on the variable in question. Finally, the IRF for all variables can be computed

given the linear combination of the lower bound shocks.

C Detailed Derivations

C.1 Household heterogeneity and aggregate quantities

The derivation of the rates øn and øp surrounding (2) is given by

Lt =Lo,t +Lr,t = υϒo,t +ϒr,t (61)

nt =Nt

Lt=

Lo,t

Ltno,t +

Lr,t

Ltnr,t (62)

nt =υϒo,t

υϒo,t +ϒr,t+

ϒr,t

υϒo,t +ϒr,t(63)

nt =υ ϒo,t

ϒtυϒo,t+ϒr,t

ϒt

+

ϒr,tϒt

υϒo,t+ϒr,tϒt

(64)

nt =υøc

υøc +1−øc+

1−øc

υøc +1−øc(65)

which equals the equations in the main text. Furthermore, we show that

Nt

ϒt=

Lt

ϒtnt

=υϒo,t +ϒr,t

ϒtnt

=(υøc +1−øc)nt (66)

29

Page 30: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

C.2 Optimizing households

The first order condition w.r.t. investment is

λo,t =λk,t(1−ϕk,t)−λk,txo,t∂ϕk,t

∂xo,t−λk,t+1xo,t+1

∂ϕk,t+1

∂xo,t

1 =φt

(1−ϕk,t −

xo,t

xo,t−1ηk

(xo,t

xo,t−1−1

))+φt+1Λo

t,t+1β(

xo,t+1

xo,t

)2(xo,t+1

xo,t−1

)(67)

All remaining foc are straight forward.

C.3 Wholesale Good Firm

The production function of the wholesale good firm is Y wt = F(Kt ,Nt), which can be

specified as

Y wt

ϒt= F

(Kt

ϒt,Nt

ϒt

)(68)

The ”constraint” of employment dynamics can be written as

nt = ρnt−1 +htnt−1 (69)

The Lagrange multiplier on this constraint is defined as Jt . Given this, the derivation of

the foc w.r.t. nt yields

Jt = pwt an

t −øpwt −βκ2

Et[Λo

t,t+1h2t+1

]+βEt

[Λo

t,t+1ht+1Jt+1]+βρEt

[Λo

t,t+1Jt+1](70)

which solves to (26) when using Jt+1 = κht+1.

C.4 Bargaining

The maximum and minimum wage in bargaining, wt when Jt = 0 and wt when Ht = 0,

are given by

wt =1øp

pwt an

t +1øp

βEt

[Λo

t,t+1κ2

h2t+1

]+

1øp

βρEt[Λo

t,t+1Jt+1]

(71)

wt =wu −1øb

βEt[(ρ − pt+1)

(ønΛo

t,t+1Hno,t+1 +(1−øn)Λrt,t+1Hnr,t+1

)](72)

30

Page 31: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

where we define øb = υøn+1−øn. Using the bargaining solution Ht =ηt

1−ηtJt as well as

the definition Ht = ønHno,t +(1−øn)Hnr,t , we can substitute for Hno,t

Ho,t =ηt

1−ηt

1øn

Jt −1−øn

ønHnr,t (73)

Applying w∗t = ηtwt +(1−ηt)wt , we obtain

w∗t =ηt

1øp

pwt an

t +(1−ηt)wu +ηt1øb

βEt{

Jt+1Λot,t+1 pt+1

}+ηt

1øp

βEt

{Λo

t,t+1κ2(ht+1)

2}+ηtρβ

(1øp

− 1øb

)Et

[Λo

t,t+1Jt+1]

+(1−ηt)β1−øn

øbEt

{Hnr,t+1(ρ − pt+1)(Λo

t,t+1 −Λrt,t+1)

}(74)

Finally, the substitutions ht =qtvtnt−1

and Jt = κ qtvtnt−1

are made.

C.5 Intermediate Good Firms

Maximization of the profit function (35) w.r.t. the demand function (32) yields

11−µ

P∗ µ

1−µt

∑s=0

(χ1β )sΛot,t+sP

− 11−µ

t+s yt+s =µ

1−µP∗ µ

1−µ −1t

∑s=0

(χ1β )sΛot,t+s pw

t+1P− µ

1−µt+s yt+s

P∗ 1

1−µt

∑s=0

(χ1β )sΛot,t+sP

− 11−µ

t+s yt+s︸ ︷︷ ︸f2,t

=P∗ µ

1−µt

∑s=0

(χ1β )sΛot,t+s pw

t+1P− µ

1−µt+s yt+s︸ ︷︷ ︸

f1,t

(75)

Deriving f2,t

f2,t =P∗ 1

1−µt

∑s=0

(χ1β )sΛot,t+sP

− 11−µ

t+s yt+s

=

(P∗

tPt

) 11−µ

yt +P∗ 1

1−µt

∑s=1

(χ1β )sΛot,t+sP

− 11−µ

t+s yt+s

=(p∗t )1

1−µ yt +χ1βΛot,t+1P

∗ 11−µ

t

∑s=0

(χ1β )sΛot+1,t+1+sP

− 11−µ

t+1+syt+1+s

=(p∗t )1

1−µ yt +χ1βΛot,t+1

(P∗

tP∗

t+1

) 11−µ

f2,t+1

=(p∗t )1

1−µ yt +χ1βΛot,t+1π

− 11−µ

t+1

(p∗t

p∗t+1

) 11−µ

f2,t+1 (76)

An equivalent derivation holds for f1, t.

31

Page 32: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

References

Acemoglu, D. (2003). Cross-country inequality trends. Journal of economic littera-

ture 113, 121–149.

Arpaia, A., E. Perez, and K. Pichelmann (2009). Understanding labour income share

dynamics in europe. European Economy Economic Papers (379).

Askenazy, P. (2003). Partage de la valeur ajoute et rentabilite du capital en france et aux

etats-unis: une reevaluation. Economie et statistique 363(1), 167–179.

Atkinson, A., T. Piketty, and E. Saez (2011). Top incomes in the long run of history.

Journal of economic litterature 49, 3–71.

Bentolila, S. and G. Saint-Paul (2003). Explaining movements in the labor share. Con-

tributions to Macroeconomics 3.

Berthold, N., R. Fehn, and E. Thode (2002). Falling labor share and rising unemploy-

ment: Long-run consequences of institutional shocks? German Economic Review 3(4),

431–459.

Blanchard, O. (1997). The medium run. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2,

89–158.

Blanchard, O. J. and F. Giavazzi (2003). Macroeconomic effects of regulation and dereg-

ulation in goods and labor markets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(3), 879–

907.

Bosca, J. E., J. Ferri, and R. Domenech (2001). Search, nash bargaining and rule of

thumb consumers. European Economic Review 55(7), 927–942.

Choi, S. and J.-V. Rios-Rull (2009). Understanding the dynamics of labor share: The role

of noncompetitive factor prices. Annals of Economics and Statistics 95/96, 251–278.

32

Page 33: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Christiano, L., M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo (2009). When is the government spending

multiplier large? NBER Working Paper 15394, 1–68.

Galı, J., J. D. Lopez-Salido, and J. Valles (2007, March). Understanding the effects of

government spending on consumption. Journal of the European Economic Associa-

tion 5(1), 227–270.

Gertler, M. and A. Trigari (2009). Unemployment fluctuations with staggered nash wage

bargaining. Journal of Political Economy 117(1), 38–86.

Hall, R. E. (2005). Employment fluctuations with equilibrium wage stickiness. American

Economic Review 95(1), 50–65.

Holden, T. (2011). Products, patents and productivity persistence: A DSGE model of

endogenous growth. Dynare Working Paper (4).

Kumhof, M. and R. Ranciere (2010). Inequality, leverage and crises. IMF Working

Papers 10/268.

Lemieux, T. (2006). Increasing residual wage inequality: Composition effects, noisy

data, or rising demand for skill? The American Economic Review 96(3), 461–498.

Picketty, T. (2001). Les hauts revenus en France au XXe siecle. Paris, Grasset.

Piketty, T. J. and E. Saez (2003). Income inequality in the united states, 1913-1998. The

Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 1–39.

Sala, L., U. Soderstrom, and A. Trigari (2008). Monetary policy under uncertainty in an

estimated model with labor market frictions. Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (5),,

pp. 983–1006.

Shimer, R. (2005). The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies.

American Economic Review 95(1), 25–49.

33

Page 34: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Solow, R. (1958). A skeptical note on the constancy of relative shares. The American

Economic Review 48(4), 618–631.

Young, A. T. (2010). One of the things we know that ain’t so: Is us labor’s share relatively

stable? Journal of Macroeconomics 32(1).

34

Page 35: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Figures

Figure 1: (adjusted) labour share of income (at factor cost)

6065

7075

6080

6065

7075

6065

7075

6570

75

6065

7075

80

6570

7580

5060

7080

6065

7075

6570

7580

6065

7075

5055

6065

70

6065

7075

6570

7580

7072

7476

78

6466

6870

72

1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020

1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020

1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020

1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020 1960 1980 2000 2020

Australia Austria Belgium Canada

Denmark Finland France Ireland

Italy Japan Netherlands Norway

Spain Sweden United Kingdom United States

labo

ur s

hare

of i

ncom

e (in

per

cent

age)

yearGraphs by country

35

Page 36: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Figure 2: Standard New Keynesian vs baseline model

0 5 10 15

−2%

−1%

0%

Output

0 5 10 15−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%

0.5%Consumption

0 5 10 15−0.5%

0%

0.5%Investment

0 5 10 15 −2%

−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%

0.5%Employment

0 5 10 15−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%Labour Share

0 5 10 15 −1%

−0.5%

0%Inflation

Baseline Model with lzb Standard New Keynesian Model

36

Page 37: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Figure 3: Sensitivity Analysis: Income Distribution

0 5 10 15−4%

−3%

−2%

−1%

0%

Output

0 5 10 15 −2%

−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%

0.5%Consumption

0 5 10 15−0.5%

0%

0.5%Investment

0 5 10 15−3%

−2%

−1%

0%

Employment

0 5 10 15−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%Labour Share

0 5 10 15−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%Inflation

Baseline Model with lzb Baseline Modelno participation

Baseline Modelno RoT consumers

37

Page 38: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Figure 4: Sensitivity Analysis: CES and Price Stickiness

0 5 10 15 −1%

−0.5%

0%

0.5%Output

0 5 10 15−0.5%

0%

0.5%Consumption

0 5 10 15 0%

0.1%

0.2%

0.3%

0.4%

0.5%Investment

0 5 10 15 −1%

−0.5%

0%

0.5%Employment

0 5 10 15 −1%

−0.5%

0%Labour Share

0 5 10 15−0.5%

−0.4%

−0.3%

−0.2%

−0.1%

0%Inflation

Baseline no lzb+ low substitution CES no participation High price rigidity

38

Page 39: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Figure 5: Minimum wage

0 5 10 15−2.5%

−2%

−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%

0.5%Output

0 5 10 15−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%

0.5%Consumption

0 5 10 15−1.5%

−1%

−0.5%

0%Labour Share

Baseline Model with lzb With minimum wage

(a) Panel A

0 5 10 15 −1%

−0.5%

0%

0.5%Output

0 5 10 15−0.5%

0%

0.5%Consumption

0 5 10 15 −1%

−0.8%

−0.6%

−0.4%

−0.2%

0%Labour Share

High price rigidity With minimum wage

(b) Panel B

39

Page 40: Inequality, Aggregate Demand and Crises · aggregate demand effects rather than supply side or financial effects. This paper does not claim that these latter effects did not contribute

Tables

Table 1: Calibration: baseline model

Structural parametersShare of Optimizing Consumers øc = 0.3Labour market participation of optimizing consumers υ = 0.5Relative risk aversion parameters σo = σ r = 1Discount factor β = 0.992Capital depreciation rate δ = 0.025Capital adjustment cost ηk = 3Capital utilization cost ψ = 0.7Labour market parametersExogenous job loss probability 1−ρ = 0.1Target job finding probability p = 0.95Labour market tightness θ = 0.5Matching elasticity γ = 0.5Implied matching function parameter γm = 1.345Implied employment adjustment cost κ = 0.6605Implied employment rate n = 0.9048wage rigidity ρw = 0.3Production parametersCapital share α = 0.3Elasticity of substitution ζ = 0.6Capital technology Bk = 0.1223Labour technology Bn = 1.3003Pricing parametersDemand elasticity µ = 1.11Price stickiness χ = 0.75Price indexation χ1 = 1Policy parametersReplacement rate ω = 0.9Interest rate smoothing ρm = 0.8Inflation response ϕπ = 1.7Output response ϕy = 0.2Bargaining power η = 0.5Bargaining power auto-regressive coefficient ρη = 0.9

40