industry dynamics and types of market … and markets.” as a result, market convergence often...

41
Paper to be presented at the DRUID Summer Conference on "Industrial Dynamics of the New and Old Economy - who is embracing whom?" Copenhagen/Elsinore 6-8 June 2002 Theme A Technical Change, Corporate Dynamics and Innovation INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET CONVERGENCE THE EVOLUTION OF THE HANDHELD COMPUTERS MARKET IN THE 1990s AND BEYOND First Draft Nils Stieglitz Philipps University Marburg Universitaetsstr. 24 35032 Marburg (Germany) tel +49 (0)6421 282-6592 fax + 49 (0)6421 282-6595 [email protected] May 9, 2002 Abstract: One recurrent theme in the discussion about the features of the ‘new economy’ is the claim that due to an increased rate of technological change and widespread deregulation, markets like telecommunications, computers, and entertainment are converging. After clarifying what is meant by market convergence, four different broad patterns of market convergence and their impact on industry dynamics are analyzed. The developed framework is then used to discuss market evolution and firm behaviour in the market for handheld computers. Keywords: Technological convergence, corporate strategy, handheld computer industry JEL codes: L1, L63

Upload: trinhkhuong

Post on 29-Mar-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

Paper to be presented at the DRUID Summer Conference on "Industrial Dynamics of the New and Old Economy - who is embracing whom?"

Copenhagen/Elsinore 6-8 June 2002

Theme A Technical Change, Corporate Dynamics and Innovation

INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET CONVERGENCE

THE EVOLUTION OF THE HANDHELD COMPUTERS MARKET IN THE 1990s AND BEYOND

First Draft

Nils Stieglitz

Philipps University Marburg Universitaetsstr. 24

35032 Marburg (Germany) tel +49 (0)6421 282-6592 fax + 49 (0)6421 282-6595

[email protected]

May 9, 2002

Abstract: One recurrent theme in the discussion about the features of the ‘new economy’ is the claim that due to an increased rate of technological change and widespread deregulation, markets like telecommunications, computers, and entertainment are converging. After clarifying what is meant by market convergence, four different broad patterns of market convergence and their impact on industry dynamics are analyzed. The developed framework is then used to discuss market evolution and firm behaviour in the market for handheld computers.

Keywords: Technological convergence, corporate strategy, handheld computer industry

JEL codes: L1, L63

Page 2: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

2

1. Introduction One recurrent theme in the discussion about the salient features of the ‘new economy’

is the claim that due to an increased rate of technological change and widespread

deregulation, markets like telecommunications, computing, and entertainment are converging

and will one day evolve into a huge multimedia industry (e.g. Collis/Bane/Bradley, Economist

2000). What is surprising is that the notion of convergence is often used in this context, but

seldom clearly defined, making its meaning quite vague (Katz 1996). For example,

Choi/Valikangas (2001, 426, their emphasis) recently defined convergence indiscriminately as

the blurring of “boundaries between industries by converging value propositions,

technologies, and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to

different authors.

The idea that markets converge goes back to Rosenberg (1976) and his study of the

emergence and evolution of the US machine tool industry. In the early 1800s, machines were

constructed in-house to the specific production needs of their end users. The degree of vertical

integration was therefore very high. A separate, specialized machine tool industry only began

to emerge in the mid-1800s. According to Rosenberg (1976), the main reason for this process

of vertical disintegration was the application of similar mechanical skills like drilling,

grinding, polishing, etc. to diverse final products. Rosenberg (1976) termed this process

technological convergence, since different industries increasingly relied on the same set of

mechanical skills. Industries which were apparently unrelated from the point of view of nature

and uses of the final product were very closely related on a technological basis. Examples for

these technologically convergent industries in 1800s are firearms, sewing machines, and

bicycles.

In evolutionary economics, Sahal (1985) and Dosi (1988) have developed similar

conceptions of technological convergence. They argue that certain technological paradigms

spread their effects over a range of industries and induce innovative activities in once stagnant

markets. An example is digital electronics and its impact on both the computer and

telecommunications industries (Hagedoorn/Duysters 1998, Rao 1999). From this perspective,

an important consequence of technological convergence is the broadening of the technological

base of large established firms (e.g. Cantwell/Fai 1999, Fai/Tunzelmann 2001). In order to be

able to adapt to technological change, large firms have to digest technological knowledge

increasingly developed in other industries but which has an impact on their businesses.

Furthermore, firms could use their broader technological base as a springboard for entering

new technologically convergent markets (Teece/Rumelt/Dosi/Winter 1994). Since

Page 3: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

3

technological competencies can be utilized in more than one industry, diversified firms

possibly have competitive advantages over their more focused competitors.

Not surprisingly, this idea figures prominently in the management literature on

corporate strategy and market convergence. Important early authors are Porter (1985) and

Hamel/Prahalad (1994), who argued independently that technological innovations and

political deregulation of product markets “blur” the boundaries of traditional industries.

Technologies (Porter 1985) and core competencies (Hamel/Prahalad 1994) can be exploited in

formerly different industries. At the same time, different existing products are becoming close

substitutes, since their functions are increasingly unified and bundled in innovative products

(Katz 1996, Yoffie 1997, Collis/Bane/Bradley 1997). Thus, from this point of view, industry

convergence not only implies the convergence of technologies but of products at the same

time. Furthermore, industry convergence can also lead to a convergence in complements. In

this case, previously unrelated products became complementary and tend to be used together

(Greenstein/Khanna 1997). The strategic response to this “new competitive landscape”

(Bettis/Hitt 1995) is an increased reliance on corporate networks and strategic alliances

(Gomes-Casseres 1996), and the migration and diversification of firms into new markets

(Reve 1990, Wirtz 2001).

Despite this common interest in the convergence of industries and technology, there

has been very little cross-fertilization between evolutionary economics and the strategic

management literature. The diversity of definitions and meanings of what market convergence

really means certainly does not help. Recently, Malerba (2002, 259) concluded his discussion

of sectoral systems of innovation by pointing out that

“even more work is necessary when the transformation of sectors involves not just

traditionally defined sectors […], but the emergence of new clusters that span

over several sectors, such as Internet-software-telecom, biotechnology-

pharmaceutical and new materials. Here, the analysis of sectoral systems has to

consider the integration and fusion of previously separated knowledge and

technologies and the new relations and overall dynamics among different types of

users and consumers, firms with different specialization and competencies, and

non-firms organizations and institutions and institutions grounded in previously

separated sectors”

The present paper contributes to these questions, in particular to the question of how

market convergence affects firm behaviour, innovative activity, and industry evolution. If

market convergence is to be more than a popular buzzword, the concept of market

Page 4: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

4

convergence needs more analytical clarity. Consequently, in the first section, four generic

types of market convergence are defined and related to the existing body of literature.

Building on evolutionary economics and industry life cycle theories, these four types of

convergence and their impact on market structure and firm behavior are discussed in the

second section of the paper. Specifically, it is asked what kind of effect these types have on a)

market entry, b) corporate strategy, and c) corporate alliances. In the third section, the

developed theoretical framework is applied to the analysis of the market for Personal Digital

Assistants (PDAs) and handheld computers in the 1990s and beyond. Three stages of industry

evolution are identified. In the formative stages in the early 1990s, industry evolution was

driven by complementary technological convergence. Following this convergence, the

industry entered a growth stage (mid-1990s to the end of the 1990s), which was characterised

by incremental innovative activities and rapid growth. Since the early 2000s, changes in the

competitive landscape of the industry are increasingly shaped by a convergence of different

products. Consequently, to fully appreciate the evolution of this particular industry, it is

necessary to take account of these different kinds of convergence. A fourth section concludes.

2. Convergence Defined If one is interested in a definition of market convergence, it is useful to reflect about

what is actually meant when talking about industries and, especially, markets. From an

economic viewpoint, a market is a locus of exchange. In order to understand the formation of

prices in a particular market, the relevant suppliers and demanders have to be identified

(Stigler/Sherwin 1985). This delineation of market boundaries is an important topic in

industrial economics, antitrust policy, and strategic management (Geroski 1998,

Pleatsikas/Teece 2001). Traditionally, markets are defined by the substitutability of the traded

products (Robinson 1969). In an influential book, Abbott (1955) argued that products should

be treated as substitutes if they satisfy the same want. In this vain, the demand theory

developed by Lancaster (1966) perceives a product as a bundle of multiple product

characteristics. Consumers do not derive their utility from the product as such but from the

embodied mixture of product characteristics. Substitutes are products that share common

characteristics, even if the exact mixture or specification of the characteristics varies.

Consequently, the boundary or width of a market (Lancaster 1979) is determined by grouping

products with similar characteristics. Moreover, to derive or increase the utility of certain

products it is required to jointly use other products, e.g. video recorder and video cassette.

Page 5: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

5

Products can not only be substitutes, but complements as well. Market definition has to take

this into account.

Besides this demand side approach to market definition, there is also a small but

growing stream of literature which tries to tackle the problem from the supply side. An early

attempt is Narver (1967). Building on Penrose (1959), he defined a market as a “supply

space” spanning firms with the similar resources and technologies. Integrating supply and

demand factors, Abell (1980) included the production technology in his conceptualisation of

market delineation. From a resource based view of the firm, Bettis (1998) claims that firms

compete against other firms that have similar resources, not just against firms producing

current product substitutes. Consequently, markets or industries should be defined by groups

of firms with similar resource bases. It is therefore possible to define a market from the supply

and from the demand side.

Dictionaries define convergence as the movement towards the same point or the

meeting of two elements. Applied to our discussion, this means that at least two existing

markets have to be effected by market convergence. Since markets can be defined by demand

or by supply factors, we can distinguish supply sided technological convergence from product

convergence on the demand side. Technological convergent markets produce different goods

and services with similar sets of technological capabilities. Convergent markets on the

product level, on the other hand, offer substantial substitute or complementary product

characteristics, but employ different technologies. Thus, markets can also converge either as

substitutes or as complements. Technologies can be substitutes and complements, too. In the

former case, an existing technology is replaced with another, while in the later case two

formerly unrelated technologies are used together.

To sum up, we can distinguish four generic types of market convergence (Figure 1).

Page 6: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

6

Figure 1: Four generic types of market convergence.1

Note that market convergence, whether technological or product convergence, is an

inherently dynamic process with three distinct stages. In the first stage, two existing markets

are unrelated from the supply and demand side. The process of convergence is then triggered

by an outside event, for example the invention of new technologies or political deregulation.

In the second stage, markets converge, implying on-going changes in market structures and

firm behaviour. Finally, in the third stage, the markets are related from a technological or

product market perspective, and market structures stabilize.

To characterize each generic type of market convergence in more detail, we employ a

framework advanced by Saviotti/Metcalfe (1984) and Saviotti (1996). They have developed

an approach which integrates the supply and demand characteristics of products and markets

in a common conceptual framework.2 A particular product can be represented by its

technology and product characteristics respectively (Figure 2).

1 For a similar representation, see Pennings/Puranam (2001). However, their treatment differs from our discussion on a conceptual level. In contrast to our approach, Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer preferences as endogenous, and interpret complementary product offerings solely as the bundling of products. Likewise, in their framework technological innovations only have an impact on the supply side, while deregulation and societal changes lead demand side convergence. 2 See also Gallouj/Weinstein (1997) for an extension of the concept to service industries.

Page 7: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

7

Figure 2: Technology and product characteristics (Source: adapted from Saviotti 1996)

On a basic level, the technological capabilities X1, X2,…, XN contain the knowledge

required to transform inputs and labour into a final product. This product exhibits a mixture of

certain characteristics C1, C2,…, CN which are used by the buyers to satisfy basic wants. As a

result, the product characteristics offered by a firm depends crucially on its technological

capabilities. From this starting point, it is now possible to define different types of

convergence, since the interrelationship between technology and product characteristics can

be made explicit.

2.1 Technological Convergence

In the case of technological convergence, unrelated product markets become related

from a technological point of view, because they begin to share the same technological

capabilities. As already mentioned, two principal causes for technological convergence can be

distinguished: technological substitutes and technological complements.

2.1.1 Type I: Technological substitutes

In this case, two markets exist which use different technological capabilities to

produce different products A and B. These products do not share any product characteristics

(Figure 3a).

A process of technological convergence is now triggered by the invention of a

technology XZ. This technology can be applied both in the production of product A and B,

and it is thus a technological substitute for older technologies in these markets. Consequently,

this process of technological convergence is characterized by the development and diffusion

of the new production technology and the parallel learning processes of the technological

users. Eventually, the older technologies XM and XM+1 will be replaced, and the former

unrelated markets become related from a technological point of view. In a pure case, as

Page 8: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

8

depicted in Figure 3a, XZ is a process innovation only. The main effect is to lower the

production costs of the two products. The product characteristics are not affected.

Empirically more relevant is the case in which process innovations induce changes in

quality of products. In many cases, process innovations not only make the production of

existing goods cheaper, but transform the trade offs associated in the bundling of product

characteristics, too (Rosenberg 1982). Process and product innovations are then

interdependent. Additionally, the new technology may also lead to changes in other

technologies. Thus, the initial invention, development, and diffusion of XZ leads to a complex

innovation process, in which the technological capabilities and products in the two markets

are constantly modified and improved. In this case, the technological convergence is

characterised by changes in the established market structures, since the process is now also

driven by product innovations.

Figure 3: Types of technological convergence

This generic type of market convergence is identical to Rosenberg’s (1976) classic

treatment of technological convergence. As described above, industries like firearms (“A”)

and sewing machines (“B”) became technologically convergent, since broad mechanical

capabilities like precision grinding (“XZ”) replaced older, more specialized technologies

(“XM”, “XM+1”) in those markets. This kind of technological convergence also lies at the heart

of the discussion surrounding the “new economy”. The productivity gains of the US economy

in 1990s are often tied to the diffusion of digital technologies in different industries, like

consumer electronics, financial services, telecommunications, and many more

(Jorgensen/Stiroh 2000). Accordingly, these technologies have been termed “general purpose

technologies” (Bresnahan/Traitenberg 1995, Helpman 1998, David/Wright 1999). Other

historical examples of general purpose technologies include the steam engine, rail transport,

Page 9: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

9

and electric power. General purpose technologies share the following characteristics

(Lipsey/Bekar/Carlaw 1998). They are

(1) applicable across a broad range of uses,

(2) offer a potential for use in a wide variety of product and processes,

(3) offer a wide scope for improvement and elaboration,

(4) and exhibit strong complementarities with existing and potential new technologies.

The former points highlight the technological convergence of markets, as defined above,

while the later two underscore the importance of subsequent innovations in products and other

existing technologies which can be induced by the new general purpose technology.

2.1.2 Type II: Technological complements

A different type of technological convergence, on the other hand, involves existing

technologies that are combined to develop entirely new products (Figure 3b). In other words,

existing technologies are fused together to create new technologies and products (Kodama

1992).

In this case, two markets exist which produce two separate products A and B with

different technological capabilities. A process of technological convergence is triggered by

the creation of new technology XZ that opens up the possibility to combine the existing

technologies XM and XM+1 to produce the new product C. Alternatively, the combination

could also be induced by regulatory changes. In this case, it has been technically possible to

combine the technologies, but it was not attempted due to government regulations.

This type of technological convergence is influenced by two learning processes. First,

since the product C is an entirely new product, an entrepreneurial process of trial and error

drives the technological convergence, since firms and buyers have to find out which basic

product characteristics constitute the product and how value is derived from it (Utterback

1993, Adner/Levinthal 2000). Second, the existing technological capabilities have to be

amended and developed in order to be able to modify and enhance the quality of the new

product. This process of technological learning is a significant force if technological

convergence is triggered by an entirely new technology XZ. Furthermore, there can be

important spill-over effects into the existing markets as well (Markides/Williamson 1995, Fai

2001).

An example of this complementary technological convergence is the emergence of the

market for handheld computers in the early 1990s. Partly triggered by new advances in

handwriting recognition technology (“XZ”), companies from different industries like

Page 10: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

10

telecommunications, computers, and consumer electronics combined different technologies

(“XM”, “XM+1”) to offer the first handheld computers (“C”).3

2.2 Product convergence

In the case of product convergence, established markets become related from a

demand point of view. They begin to share similar or complementary product characteristics,

leading to a convergence in substitutes or complements.

2.2.1 Type III: Product convergence in substitutes

A product convergence in substitutes leads to a greater substitutability of formerly

unrelated products as they increasingly share the same characteristics. As sketched out in

Figure 4a, a product “B” is changed to also include the new feature CM, making it a (partial)

substitute of product A. Once again, this generic type of market convergence is often sparked

by a new technological capability (“XZ”) which enables the changes in product

characteristics. Another possible cause is the deregulation of these markets, making it possible

to integrate a wider range of characteristics into the final product.

Independent of what causes the process, the speed and the pattern of market

convergence critically depends on the substitutability of the products. Products are closer

substitutes the more product characteristics they share. Since the potential array of product

characteristics depends on the underlying technological capabilities, the convergence in

products could also lead to changes in technological bases of the involved firms. Similar

product characteristics are frequently based on similar technologies, and we hypothesise that a

product convergence of substitutes is often followed and paralleled by technological

convergence. In this case, increasing competition between the two markets forces firms to

expand the product characteristics by incorporating features of the other market’s product.

Correspondingly, besides having to assimilate the new technology XZ, firms of both markets

also have to adopt existing technological capabilities of the other market. In an extreme case,

both markets merge into one larger market with very similar technologies and product

characteristics.

3 On a more aggregate level, Andersen (1998) finds in her analysis of the long term evolution of technological trajectories from 1890 to 1990 that recent technological progress has been shaped by the combination of diverse technologies into more integrated technological systems. Thus, it appears that the long term trend is fundamentally shaped by this type of technological convergence.

Page 11: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

11

Figure 4: Types of Product Convergence

Examples for this type of market convergence are manifold. For years, the discussion

about a multimedia industry has centered around digital broadband TV, and it has been

predicted that PCs and TVs will one day evolve into close substitutes

(Baldwin/McVoy/Steinfield 1996). Broadband TV allows to access a wide range of services,

like Video/Music-on-Demand, games, electronic shopping, etc. In the past, most of these

services could only be accessed via PCs, and there was no substitutability between TVs and

PCs. According to industry commentators, this might change with the advent of broadband

technology. Thus, the new broadband (“XZ”) technology has the potential to integrate certain

product features into a TV set like Internet access, electronic shopping, and Music-on-

Demand, which were formerly only accessible via a PC (“CM”).

2.2.2 Type IV: Product convergence in complements

Finally, in the case of a convergence in product complements, existing unrelated

products become complementary to one another. In the past, both products have been used

independently, and there was no connection between them from a demand perspective. Once

again, this process of market convergence is caused by a new technology which opens up the

potential to jointly use the two existing products (Figure 4b). In other words, the products are

now complementary to each other, delivering a higher value if consumed together.

Unlike the case of product convergence in substitutes, convergence in complements

does not lead to technological convergence. While a prerequisite for their joint use, the new

technology XZ is not needed to produce the existing products A or B individually. Its task is to

provide the “glue” for the two existing products. What is needed, however, is some kind of

standard that warrants the complementary use of the products. Consequently, product

Page 12: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

12

convergence in complements is also being shaped how and what kind of standards are being

set and modified.

An example of this type of product convergence is the development of the computer

language HTML and the introduction of graphical browser programs. These new technologies

(“XZ”) allowed private households to easily access Internet services via their PCs (“A”) and

existing telephone lines (“B”). Formerly, phones and PCs were two distinct products which

served different needs, e.g. “data processing” and “communications”. It was only after the

advent of the Internet that computers and telephone lines were perceived as complementary

products by private consumers.

The defined four cases of market convergence are fairly generic, and they represent

abstract “ideal types” in the sense of Max Weber (1988). Empirically, processes of market

convergence are paralleled by other innovation activities which have nothing to do with

convergence. In addition, different types of market convergence may be present at the same

time. For instance, as already discussed, product convergence in substitutes often brings about

a process of technological convergence. But the four generic types nevertheless allow the

identification and disentanglement of different drivers of change in convergent markets.

Furthermore, they provide a basic framework to structure and to explain broad patterns of

market convergence. The next section discusses these patterns in greater detail.

3. Industry Dynamics and Types of Convergence

3.1 Systems of Innovation and Firm Behaviour - A Conceptual Framework

In recent years, several authors have developed the related concepts of technological

regimes and of sectoral systems of innovation to organize different determinants of industrial

dynamics (e.g. Nelson/Winter 1982, Dosi/Malerba/Orsenigo 1994, Dosi 1997, Marsili 2001).

Malerba (2002, 250) defines a sectoral system of innovation and production as

„a set of new and established products for specific uses and the set of agents

carrying out market and non-market interactions for the creation, production and

sale of those products.”

A sectoral system is shaped by four main factors, namely (1) technological

opportunities, (2) cumulativeness of knowledge, (3) sources and accessibility of knowledge,

Page 13: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

13

and (4) appropriability of innovative rents, and we discuss each in turn (Malerba/Orsenigo

2000, Marsili 2001, Malerba 2002):

(1) Technological opportunities shape the incentive to invest into R&D. High technological

opportunities are present if new technological knowledge is applicable to a wide variety of

products or leads to large increases in the performance or quality of a product. Sectors with

high technological opportunities are characterized by higher investments into R&D and a

higher rate of innovations.

(2) The condition of cumulativeness of knowledge captures an important property of

evolutionary theories of economic change and its underlying theory of the firm (Nelson

1995). The knowledge base of a firm is the outcome of firm-specific and path-dependent

learning processes (Rosenberg 1976). Therefore, the knowledge base constrains the strategic

behaviour of firms, and it is an important source for first mover advantages and performance

differences between firms (Teece/Pisano/Shuen 1997). Because of differences in their

knowledge bases, firms differ in their ability to exploit the technological opportunities

(Nelson 1991).

The cumulativeness of knowledge is high, and learning is more rapid, if new knowledge

builds incrementally on the existing body of a firm’s knowledge. Cumulativeness is low, on

the other hand, if firms have to learn entirely new pieces of knowledge.

To add analytical clarity, the knowledge base of the firm can be separated into two broad

domains (Teece/Rumelt/Dosi/Winter 1994, Granstrand 1998). The first domain includes the

knowledge about the underlying technologies. These represent the technological capabilities

of the firm. A different knowledge domain consists of the specific knowledge about the

market and its products, its users, competitors, and applications. These are the marketing

capabilities of the firm. Teece (1986) considers these capabilities as complementary to the

technological capabilities since they enhance the value of an innovation.

(3) Besides cumulativeness, the sources and accessibility of knowledge are a second

important determinant of how easy it is to gain access to technological opportunities. Sources

of knowledge can be, for example, external sources like universities (Rosenberg 1982),

internal sources like users, suppliers, competitors, but also external firms active in other

sectors (Hippel 1988). The accessibility of knowledge depends on the codification of

knowledge, and the associated spill over effects. Important mechanisms for gaining access to

tacit knowledge are strategic alliances and other inter-organizational arrangements.

Furthermore, existing technological capabilities can also be accessed if they are embodied in

off-the shelf products (Demsetz 1991).

Page 14: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

14

(4) The appropriability conditions influence how difficult it is for an innovator to capture the

innovation’s profit. Appropriability is influenced, among other things, by the level of

competition and the accessibility of knowledge. Low appropriability conditions are present if

new knowledge is easily accessible by competitors, or the level of competition is high. If the

potential appropriability is high, technological opportunities are rapidly exploited, leading to

an upsurge in innovative activity.

These factors describe the important determinants of innovations and industry

structure. The industry life cycle theories offer a dynamic conceptualisation of these four

conditions, highlighting their evolution over time (Klepper 1997). These theories are therefore

an important backdrop for our discussion. But to capture how firm behaviour is influenced by

market convergence, additional dimensions are needed.

A first question concerns the corporate strategy of the established firms that are

involved in the process of market convergence. Broadly, they either have the option to focus

their business activities or to diversify into new markets. Taking up the above distinction

between domains of technological and marketing capabilities, it is possible to distinguish

between technological and product market diversification (e.g. Gambardella/Torrisi 1998,

Granstrand 1998, Piscitello 1998). Consequently, we can discern four different strategic

options on the corporate level (Figure 5).

Besides the behaviour of incumbent firms, it is also possible to discuss the role of new

entrants. These are firms that have previously not been active in the converging industries.

The threat of entry is especially high if, due to a low cumulativeness of technological

knowledge and easy accessibility of complementary capabilities, the technological and market

barriers to entry are low. In this case, new entrants are formidable competitors and an

important source of innovations.

Figure 5: Options of corporate strategy

Page 15: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

15

Finally, a key aspect of firm behaviour associated with market convergence is the

formation of interorganizational arrangements. It is often claimed that market convergence

leads to an upsurge in the number of strategic alliances and corporate networks

(Harianto/Pennings 1996, Duysters/Hagedoorn 1998, Santangelo 2000, Dittrich 2001). To

broadly describe the rationale for the formation of an alliance, we distinguish the direction

and the motivation of an alliance. Firms can form alliances vertically with suppliers and users,

or horizontally with competitors or firms in other markets. The motivation for an alliance is

either the creation of new capabilities or the joint use of existing capabilities (March 1991,

Mowery/Oxley/Silverman 1996, 1998).

3.2 Technological Convergence

3.2.1 Type I: Technological substitutes

If market convergence is characterized by a convergence in technological substitutes,

then technological opportunities are usually high. The reasons for this are two-fold. First, the

new technology can be exploited in many industries. Consequently, the basic innovation leads

to a variety of process innovations in different markets. The second reason is the effect on the

rate of product innovations in the established markets. Often, new processes will not only

bring about reductions in production costs but increase the likelihood for product

improvements as well. This critical link between process and product innovation is stressed in

the current debate about general purpose technologies, and it was already discussed in

Rosenberg’s (1976) classical study of the machine tool industry. A consequence for the

established market is an upsurge in competition, since the new technology raises the

likelihood of cost cuts and product innovations.

Technological convergence is often triggered by new technologies that solve older

problems; the cumulativeness of technological knowledge is as a result usually low. Like the

term “substitutes” suggests, older technological capabilities in the existing markets are

superseded by the new technology. In terms of Tushmann/Anderson (1986), technological

substitutes are competence-destroying. As a reaction, incumbent firms in the existing markets

have to update their technological knowledge base. Furthermore, the cumulativeness of

marketing knowledge associated with the new technology is low, because potential users of

the technology are the established firms in the existing markets. On the other hand, changes in

the knowledge about consumers, applications, and competitors in the existing markets are

cumulative. The complementary downstream capabilities of the firm are thus largely

unaffected by this type of market convergence.

Page 16: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

16

High technological opportunities and a low cumulativeness of technological

knowledge imply a high rate of entry upstream of the existing markets. The entry into

upstream markets is fostered by the low cumulativeness of marketing knowledge. The high

rate of entry into upstream activities eventually leads to a creation of a specialized supplier

industry that serves the existing markets. This process of market entry and of vertical

disintegration is, for example, described by Rao (1999), Fransman (2000), and Gaffard/Krafft

(2000) for the telecommunication industry. However, entry into the existing product markets

is made more costly and more risky by the downstream capabilities of the incumbent firms.

The process of market convergence also has an effect on the corporate strategy of the

existing and the new firms. For existing firms, a major challenge is to adapt their knowledge

bases to the new technology. They are thus forced to diversify their technological knowledge

base to keep up with the process of technological substitution. Many established firms

consequently react by pursuing a multitechnology strategy. While broadening their

technological capabilities, they focus their product market activities on established markets

(Gambardella/Torrisi 1998, Fai/Tunzelmann 2001). In contrast, a diversification strategy is

much more risky, even if new technological capabilities can be exploited in many markets.

The firms must not only learn and develop the new technology, but they also have to build up

the complementary marketing capabilities. Corporate strategies of new firms, on the other

hand, differ. Entrants are likely to pursue a focus strategy, concentrating on the development

of a specific application of the new technology for a distinct group of users. They are thus

specialized suppliers (Pavitt 1984). Successful suppliers are able to pursue a multimarket

strategy, exploiting their technological capabilities in a range of existing downstream markets.

An important mechanism to gain access to and to develop the new technology is the

formation of strategic alliances. They are especially vital if innovations in the new technology

persist, and the new knowledge is not readily accessible through off-the-shelf products. In this

case, established firms and suppliers form vertical alliances to create new technological

knowledge. An important outcome is the broadening of the established firm’s technological

knowledge base, and vertical alliances are for that reason an essential stepping stone of a

multitechnology strategy.

3.2.2 Type II: Technological Complements

In contrast to the case of convergence in technological substitutes, the technological

opportunities of technological complements are more limited. The driving force is the fusion

of existing technologies into novel products, and technological changes are usually confined

Page 17: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

17

to the new emerging market. Only if significant new technologies are developed for the new

markets, and these spill over into the existing markets, technological opportunities are higher.

This process of market convergence builds on existing technological capabilities, and

the cumulativeness of technological knowledge is high. The same does not apply to demand

and marketing capabilities. The new market implies new consumers, new applications, and

new competitors (Adner/Levinthal 2000). In other words, firms have to explore by trial and

error how potential consumers derive value from the product characteristics and which

mixture and interactions of characteristics constitute a dominant design

(Christensen/Suárez/Utterback 1998). Because of this fundamental learning process, the

cumulativeness of marketing knowledge is low.

Since established firms already have parts of the technological capabilities needed to

enter the emerging markets, they pursue a diversification strategy. The main entrants into the

emerging markets are consequently the established firms from existing markets. In contrast,

the entry of entirely new firms is low, because they lack the technological capabilities. Only if

these are accessible easily, for example through off-the-shelves products, then there is a

higher rate of entry. In this case, the low cumulativeness of marketing knowledge and the

learning process associated with the emergence of a dominant design opens a window of

opportunity for entrants. In this case, the technological capabilities of incumbent firms are not

an important first mover advantage anymore. Even more so, the incumbent’s early designs are

often framed by past experiences in the established markets, and this can hamper the trial and

error process. In other words, the local search processes in the new markets are still

constrained by the marketing capabilities that applied to the old market. In the new market,

these capabilities can be more a liability than an asset.

A crucial problem for established firms and entrants is that they only command parts

of the necessary technological capabilities, because the new product is the outcome of the

fusion of existing technologies previously employed in different markets. Firms have to

access the complementary technologies if they want to enter the market. A main mechanism

for gaining access to these complementary technological capabilities is through horizontal

alliances with established firms from other markets. Since alliances are formed to access

existing technologies, their impetus is the joint use of existing knowledge. Alternatively, firms

can also merge or acquire firms to integrate the complementary technologies.

Page 18: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

18

3.3 Product Convergence

3.3.1 Type III: Convergence in Substitutes

The technological opportunities in the convergence of product substitutes are low,

since the effects of a new technology are closely confined to the existing markets. New

technologies enable innovative changes in the characteristics of existing products. While

competitive pressures mount for the reason that these products evolve into substitutes, the

knowledge bases of the existing firms nonetheless allow the absorption of new technological

knowledge. The cumulativeness of technological knowledge is usually high, and the same is

true for the marketing capabilities of the established firms in the two existing markets,

because the existing products, applications, and dominant designs are the starting points for

product innovations. High uncertainty, however, exists about the new competitors and new

groups of customers, since the boundaries of the markets are “blurring” in the wake of new

product features (Greenstein/Khanna 1997).

The rate of entry by new entrants is low, because the incumbent firms can apply their

existing knowledge bases to cope with market convergence. They have all the capabilities to

successfully deal with the threat of entry, and the process of convergence is thus more driven

by their competitive actions than by the entry of innovative entrants. The incumbent’s

strategies are either focus or diversification. In the former case, firms concentrate on serving a

niche market. The creation of new knowledge is closely restricted to their existing

technological and marketing knowledge, and they passively adapt to the convergence process.

A more active role is played by the diversifiers. These firms’ competitive strategies are the

fundamental driver of this type of market convergence. They are vigorously seeking to

expand product characteristics and to extend their market reach beyond their traditional

industry boundaries.

In view of the fact that product convergence in substitutes often requires the adoption

of the other market’s technological capabilities, horizontal strategic alliances are an important

method to access these capabilities and jointly use the existing knowledge. Also, the

magnitude of mergers and acquisitions is increased, since diversifiers can rapidly expand their

technological base and market reach by acquiring other established firms in the “other”

market.

Page 19: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

19

3.3.2 Type IV: Convergence in Complements

The technological opportunities of a convergence in complements are generally high.

Like in the case of technological substitutes, the reasons are, first, the innovation avenues

opened by the new technology itself, and second, the potential changes in the product

characteristics in the existing markets. An illustrative example is the convergence in

complements of telecommunications and personal computers through Internet technologies.

Here, the complementarity of PCs and telecommunications was not only made possible by

new hard- and software, but tempted alterations in the characteristics of PCs (their hardware

and especially software) and of telecommunication services (Baldwin/McVoy/Steinfield

1996, Collis/Bane/Bradley 1997).

Since entirely new technologies often initiate the process of convergence in

complements, the cumulativeness of technological knowledge is low. In contrast, the

cumulativeness of marketing knowledge is often high, since customers and new applications

are tied to the existing products. Still, incumbent firms are often slow to respond to the new

technological opportunities. This opens up the possibility of entry for new entrants. As a

result, the rate of entry by new firms is high. Entrants pursuit a focus strategy, concentrating

on the development of the new technology and new complementary services. Once again, this

can be illustrated by the advent of the Internet, and the subsequent emergence of an “Internet

industry”.

The same is true for incumbent firms, since the gains from diversification are limited.

They can not exploit their technological base in the emerging new industry or in the other

established industry. More common than outright diversification are horizontal alliances

between incumbent firms and new entrants. These are often knowledge using, because the

new entrants can profit from the marketing capabilities of the established firms, while

incumbent gain access to the new technologies developed by the entrants. Incumbent and new

firms have a mutual interest in an expanded market due to the new complementarity of

products. A very important motive for the formation of knowledge using alliances in this type

of market convergence is the setting of standards that govern the interfaces between the

complements (Katz 1996,Yoffie 1997).

Page 20: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

20

3.4 Patterns of Market Convergence

The following table sums up the discussed broad patterns of market convergence. This

theoretical framework is applied in the next section to the evolution of the Personal Digital

Assistant and handheld computer market in the 1990s.

Type of Market

Convergence

Pattern of…*

Technological

substitutes

Technological

complements

Product substitutes Product

complements

Dominant Type

of Innovation

Process Innovation Product Innovation Product Innovation Product Innovation

Technological

opportunities

High Low Low High

Cumulativeness

- technology

- demand

- Low

- Low

- High

- Low

- High

- High

- Low

- High

Threat of New

Entrants

High Low Low High

Corporate

Strategy

- Multitechnology

(incumbent)

- Focus (entrants)

- Diversification

(incumbent)

- Focus (entrants)

- Focus

- Diversification

- Focus

Alliances

- direction

- motivation

- vertical

- knowledge creating

- horizontal

- knowledge using

- horizontal

- knowledge using

- horizontal

- knowledge using

Example Machine Tool industry

Personal Digital

Assistants

PCs versus TVs

Internet (PC, Online

Services)

Table 1 Patterns of Market Convergence

*Accessibility and appropriability conditions are very important building blocks of sectoral systems of innovation, and they have a major impact on the process of market convergence. Nevertheless, these conditions are idiosyncratic, and a stable relationship between the generic types of convergence and these conditions does not exist.

Page 21: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

21

4. Market Convergence and the Evolution of the Handheld Computer Industry

A handheld computer or Personal Digital Assistant (PDA) is a compact, palm sized

computing device. One of it’s defining product characteristics is the user’s ability to hold the

device in one hand while entering data at the same time. Today, input devices are either small

keyboards or stylus-based touch-screens with handwriting recognition. Other key product

characteristics are mobility, an expandable set of programs and applications, and the ability to

communicate with other devices like personal computers, fax machines, and cellular phones.

A PDA’s hardware consists of a microprocessor, solid-state memory, a liquid crystal display

(LCD), an input device, batteries, and various input/output ports and extension slots. The

software consists of an operating system and applications which are often stored permanently

in the Read-Only memory (ROM) or are available on cartridges and extension cards.

In the following case study4, it is shown how the evolution of the handheld computer

market was affected over time by three different types of market convergence. Actual market

processes roughly correspond to the broad patterns identified in the theoretical section of the

paper.

4.1 Technological complements and the search for a dominant design: 1984 to 1996

The early years of the handheld computer market were shaped by the fusion of

complementary technologies which had their roots in different industries. For example, LCD

displays and power management technologies emanated from the consumer electronics

industry, operating systems, memory chips, and handwriting recognition technologies from

computers, fax and paging technologies from telecommunications, and semiconductors from

computers and consumer electronics (Figure 6). Early market dynamics was thus driven by a

convergence in technological complements.

4 The data for the case study has been collected from public sources like press releases, business magazines, and industry publications. In addition, it builds and extends on earlier case studies of the PDA market (Bayus/Jain/Rao 1997, Yoffie et al. 1997, Gomes-Casseres/Leonard-Barton 1997, Wegberg 1998). A fully referenced version is available from the author upon request.

Page 22: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

22

4.1.1 Early Experiments: 1984-1992

The first handheld computing device sharing some of the characteristics of a PDA was

introduced by UK software company Psion in 1984 (Potter 1998).5 The Organiser was build

around a 8-bit Hitachi microprocessor, a 16 character LCD display, a tiny keyboard, and an

operating system developed by Psion. It featured a clock, simple calendar, math functions,

and a database with a search function. With the optional Science Pack, the Organiser was

capable of being programmed in its own simple computer language. The product was a

modest success and until the early 1990s, Psion sold over 500,000 units of the Organiser and

its successor, the Organiser 2.

Figure 6 Convergence in complementary technologies in the handheld computer market

The Organiser was basically a programmable calculator with a database and a simple

calendar. Early imitators were suppliers which had been active before in the market for

handheld calculators. In 1988, the Japanese consumer electronics companies Sharp and Casio

entered the market with Organiser clones that later evolved into the Wizard and Boss

electronic organizer series respectively. Both companies had commercialized early prototypes

of handheld computers in the beginning of the 1980s. Sharp had pioneered the development of

LCD displays in 1970s, and was the largest supplier of LCDs in the late 1980s. The Wizard

electronic organizers were based on LCD displays and semiconductors originally developed

for Sharp’s long-standing product line of calculators. The company could thus draw on its

existing technological capabilities to develop the Wizard. Casio, as a diversified electronics

company, was able to draw on its experiences in calculators, watches, and handheld LCD

television receivers. Early imitators were also other Japanese and US consumer electronics

companies like Seiko, Selectronics, Radio Shack, Rolodex, Royal, and Zenith. Despite the

5 A summary of major entries (and exits) into the handheld computer industry can be found in the appendix.

Page 23: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

23

number of market entries, Sharp and Casio quickly gained nearly 90 percent of the market

share for electronic organizers worldwide (1991), largely confining Psion’s customer base to

Europe.

Early electronic organizer models were stand-alone, non-programmable devices, with

rudimentary organizing functions like agenda, contacts, alarm, and note taking. A 1991

product survey by Consumer Reports (1991) described them as a cross between a pocket

calculator and a laptop computer. But the electronic organizers were not true computers, since

they were not able to run any other programs and applications, and their build-in features

were inspired by pen and paper organizers like Filofax. In 1989, two products were launched

that promoted the concept of a “palmtop computer”. These palmtop computers were supposed

to be more compact and mobile substitutes for laptop computers. The Portfolio was

commercialized by hardware computer supplier Atari and introduced to the European market

in 1988. The Portfolio had been designed and licensed to Atari by UK company Distributed

Information Processing (DIP), a Psion spin-off. In 1988, the US company Poqet Computer

Corporation was founded in the US by former Fairchild, Texas Instrument, and DIP

employees. In 1989, Poqet introduced the powerful, but high-priced Poqet PC. The Portfolio

and Poqet PC both were full-fledged MS-DOS compatible handheld computers built around

an Intel-licensed 80C88 microprocessor using off-the-shelf products in a highly innovative

way. Despite much praise from industry journals, especially for the Poqet, both products were

only very modest commercial successes.

An important introduction into the handheld computer market was the HP 95 LX that

Hewlett-Packard shipped in 1991. In just 16 months, HP had developed a handheld computer

which heavily built on its existing technological capabilities, especially in computing and the

design of scientific calculators. Hewlett-Packard had pioneered the scientific handheld

calculator in 1973 and had developed an early prototype of a handheld computer, the HP 75C,

in 1982. The HP 95 LX was based on Intel’s 8086 microprocessor and ran the MS-DOS

operating system. Besides rudimentary organizing functions, key features were a version of

Lotus’ spreadsheet software and an optional connectivity pack designed by Traveling

Software that linked the 95 LX to a desktop computer. The HP 95 LX was a modest

commercial success, and in the next three years, over 390,000 units were sold. In Europe,

Psion launched the Psion Series 3, a major revision of the Organiser, featuring organizing

functions, computing capabilities, and Psion’s own proprietary OS. The Series 3 was designed

with the help of, among others, microprocessor supplier NEC. In next year, Sharp introduced

the PC 3000. It was the result of an alliance with DIP. Like DIP’s Portfolio design, the PC

Page 24: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

24

3000 was based on a 80C88 microprocessor, and it ran DIP’s proprietary operating system

and applications.

Thus, in the early 1990s, two distinct segments in handheld computer industry existed.

The larger sub-market for electronic organizers was dominated by consumer electronics

companies Casio and Sharp, while in the smaller sub-market for palmtop computers Hewlett-

Packard, Psion, and Poqet were the leading suppliers. The large technologically diversified

companies Casio, Sharp, and Hewlett-Packard were able to draw on their technological in-

house capabilities to develop their handheld products, while entrants like Psion, DIP, and

Poqet relied on off-the-shelf products and, increasingly, on knowledge-using alliances.

Furthermore, while established firms choose to diversify, entrants focused their activities on

the emerging market.

Widespread adoption of handheld computers, however, failed to materialize. All these

early models relied on tiny keyboards that made entering data a slow and cumbersome

process. Industry observers argued that the user interface was the key problem of handheld

computers, and a major obstacle to mass market acceptance. The technological problems

surrounding the user interface were to act as a focusing device for further innovations in the

market. Incidentally, pen-based computing with handwriting recognition was predicted to be a

major new breakthrough technology for PC computers, and GriD, a Tandy division, had

introduced one of the first pen-based computer, the GRiD Pad in 1988. In 1991, Canon, IBM,

NCR, and Toshiba had announced plans to bring pen computers to market, and venture

capitalists financed start-ups developing pen-based computing technologies like GO and

Momenta. And following the path paved by Apple’s MacOS, software companies like

Microsoft, GeoWorks and General Magic were developing graphical user interfaces (GUIs)

that simplified user interaction. Thus, in the early 1990s, new technological opportunities

were opened by these innovations.

At the same time, new communication hardware like pagers and cellular phones were

introduced, while older technologies like fax machines evolved into mass market products.

New communication services like electronic messaging, and proprietary information networks

like for example CompuServe and AOL were brought to market. Demand for these innovative

communication products was steadily increasing. Additionally, the technological advances in

consumer electronics and computing continued rapidly, allowing for the development and

introduction of new technologies like CD-ROM and and DVD and the miniaturization of

existing technologies and products.

Page 25: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

25

Therefore, the stage was set for a range of product innovations in handheld computing,

fueled by the advances in technologies as diverse as telecommunications, computers, and

consumer electronics. In 1992, Apple, AT&T, and Tandy announced their entry into the

handheld computer market. In his product announcement speech, Apple CEO John Sculley

coined the name “Personal Digital Assistant” in early 1992. In next two years, established

companies from different markets like Amstrad (consumer electronics), IBM (computer

hardware), BellSouth (telecommunications services), Sony (consumer electronics), and

Motorola (computers, telecommunications hardware and services) brought to market different

PDA models. But by 1998, all these entrants had left the handheld computer market.

4.3.2 The Rise and Fall of the Personal Digital Assistants: 1992-1995

During the next years, incumbents Hewlett-Packard, Sharp, Casio, and Psion

continued to extend their products, adding new technologies and features. In 1993 and 1994,

seven major new handheld computers were brought to market by Amstrad, Apple, AT&T,

Tandy, Motorola, Sony, and IBM. The new entrants heavily relied on strategic alliances to

develop and market their products. Alliances were especially important if the product was

based on new technologies (Gomes-Casseres/Leonard-Barton 1997). However, knowledge

using alliances dominated because companies applied their existing technological capabilities

to new products.6

Apple Newton

Apple started to develop their first PDA, to be called the Newton, in early 1990. At the

same time, Apple began to weave a dense network of alliances for the Newton, spanning

computer hardware and software suppliers, consumer electronics, telecommunications, and

media companies. The first Newtons were shipped in August 1993. Within the first month,

50,000 units were sold, but subsequent sales were much lower than expected. Apple pulled

the plug on the Newton in 1998, having barely sold 120,000 units overall. Despite its

technological and marketing capabilities in the Personal computer market, Apple had failed to

turn the Newton into a successful mass market product.

To develop the Newton, Apple acquired a capital stake in the UK semiconductor

company Advanced RISC Machines (ARM) which was developing the low power

consumption ARM610 microprocessor chip that was later used in the Newton. An integral

part of the Newton was the pen-based user interface which was able to interpret cursive hand-

6 See the appendix for an extensive listing of alliance partners involved in the development and marketing of major products introduced in 1993.

Page 26: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

26

writing. Apple developed the operating system alone and the necessary handwriting

recognition software together with the Russian software company ParaGraph. Sharp

developed the LCD display for Newton and released a Newton under the Sharp brand, the

Expert Pad. Sharp also manufactured the Newton. Motorola and Siemens both negotiated

licences to develop complementary products for the Newton and to build devices based on

Newton’s technologies. Other partners included telecommunication companies like

BellSouth, US West, and Ameritech, but also publishing company Random House and online

service provider AOL.

The final product was a highly innovative product incorporating state of the art

technologies. But despite the high price, the Newton offered only limited functionality. The

handwriting recognition, while technologically advanced, was nevertheless error-prone and

unreliable for serious day-to-day use. Despite the lack of a keyboard, the Newton was quite

bulky. The much advertised communication features required the purchase of an additional

device and were limited to a send-only fax and a modem. An additional device was also

necessary to connect the Newton to a PC.

AT&T EO

During the 1980s, former telecommunication company AT&T had actively diversified

into semiconductors and computing, and had acquired hardware computer supplier NCR in

1991. In 1992, AT&T unveiled the Hobbit RISC microprocessor which became the integral

building block of the EO 440 “personal communicator” that was developed by the start-up

company EO. AT&T had financed EO’s start-up, and, shortly before the release of the EO in

the first half of 1993, acquired 51% of EO’s equity. Until it was discontinued in July 1994,

less than 10,000 units of EO personal communicators were sold. With the end of the EO, all

further developments of the Hobbit were stopped, ending AT&T’s engagement in

semiconductors.

EO Inc. was founded in 1991 as a spinoff of GO Corp. In the early 1990s, GO was one

of the leading companies developing handwriting recognition software (Kaplan 1994), and the

EO used the PenPoint operating system and handwriting recognition software developed by

GO. The basic hardware and software design of the EO was developed together with the UK

computer company Active Book Company. The manufacturer of the EO was Matsushita,

while Marubeni and Olivetti were distribution and sourcing support partners. Other alliance

partners included Sharp and an assortment of software start up companies that developed the

applications for the EO.

Page 27: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

27

AT&T’s long-standing involvement in communication services heavily influenced the

design and product characteristics of the EO which was announced not as a PDA but as a

“personal communicator”. The EO’s handwriting recognition software was only able to

interpret block letters, and its computer capabilities were more limited than Newton’s. But the

EO had a fax/modem built in that could also be linked to a cellular phone, and it was so able

to send and receive fax and send e-mails via AT&T’s EasyLink network. Additional features

included built-in microphone to voice annotate documents, and access to the Internet and

proprietary networks like CompuServe. But with its steep price, large and heavy design, poor

connectivity with PCs, and just 4 hours of battery working time, the EO failed on the market.

Tandy/Casio Zoomer

Casio had been one of the first movers in the market for handheld computers with the

Boss electronic organizer, while Tandy’s GriD subsidy had introduced one of the first pen-

based computers. Both companies were thus in a good position to exploit the commercial

opportunities of the handheld computer market. In 1992, Casio and Tandy had formed an

alliance to develop and market the Zoomer PDA, and, in stark contrast to Apple, they used

modifications of existing hardware and software to build the unit. Casio developed an Intel-

compatible CPU, which was equivalent to the 8086. With its long-standing production skills

in consumer electronics, Casio was also the main manufacturer, while Tandy distributed and

marketed the product. GeoWorks modified their existing GEOS operating system for the

Zoomer. Palm Computing, a GriD spinoff, provided the handwriting recognition software

based on technology originally devised for the pen-computer Grid Pad. Furthermore, Palm

Computing wrote most of the application and the connectivity software that was shipped with

the Zoomer.

At roughly the same price as the Newton, the Zoomer had very good personal

organizing and finance features, and provided easy connectivity with desktop computers. And

with an additional fax/modem, it was easy to send faxes, write e-mails, and access online

services like America Online. With nearly 100 hours of battery life, the Zoomer was a truly

mobile device. But like the Newton and the EO, the Zoomer had only poor handwriting

recognition, and it was bulky, too. Moreover, because of its dated Intel microprocessor and

Casio’s insistence on a very long battery life, the Zoomer was extremely slow. Launched in

October 1993, sales of the device were a lot poorer than expected. In March 1994, Casio

pulled out of the alliance, putting an end to the Zoomer project.

Page 28: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

28

Other entries

The UK consumer electronics company Amstrad was the first to bring to market a

self-styled PDA in March 1993. Amstrad had successfully diversified into computer hardware

during the 1980s by selling cheap home computers and PC clones using off-the-shelf

components. Amstrad applied this approach to the emerging PDA market. Together with UK

software company Eden and using its own vintage 8-bit Z80 microprocessor, Amstrad

developed the PenPad. It was the cheapest and lightest of all PDAs introduced in 1993 and

1994. Lacking any communication features, the programmable PenPad had a limited set of

software applications included and a very crude handwriting recognition technology. In the

same year, Amstrad had acquired the Danish telecommunication hardware supplier Dancall,

and announced the InfoPad for 1995, with strong communication features. With sluggish

sales of PenPad, and growing difficulties for Amstrad in other markets, the InfoPad was

never shipped.

The Simon was a joint development by IBM and BellSouth. Introduced in August

1994, it was a cellular phone with very rudimentary organizing features and electronic ink as

the main input device. The Simon was discontinued in 1995. Motorola introduced two PDAs

in 1994. The Marco was based on Newton’s technologies and included a wireless modem

allowing faxes and email to be sent, but it did not support voice communications. The Envoy

used Motorola’s own Dragon microprocessor. The operating software and communication

software had already been developed by General Magic. Like the EO, the Envoy was

supposed to be a “Computing Communicator” with very strong communication features. Like

the Envoy, it had a built-in wireless modem. Both PDAs gave access to Motorola’s own

proprietary ARDIS network. Sony’s Magic Link was marketed as a personal communicator as

well and it was also based on General Magic’s software. Motorola and Sony independently

announced their withdrawal from the PDA market at the end of 1996, Motorola having sold

less than 5,000 units of the Envoy and the Marco.

To conclude, as a consequence of new technologies like handwriting recognition there

was a wave of innovative entries into the emerging PDA market in the mid-1990s. An

important area for experimenting and learning was the product itself and its key

characteristics. The entrants tested different concepts and models of a Personal Digital

Assistant, and these concepts were heavily influenced by the firm’s pre-entry experiences and

the existing technological and marketing capabilities of the firms.

Page 29: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

29

With the Newton, Apple developed a highly innovative product which was, in essence,

a mobile information processor. Its design and features were inspired by the personal

computer. According to Steve Sakoman, the head of the Newton development division, “the

idea was to see if the personal computer could be rethought without carrying around a lot

baggage.” Furthermore, Apple planed to generate most of its profit from selling application

software for the Newton. Accordingly, like may firms in the computer industry, Apple freely

licensed their technology (McGahan et al. 1997). In contrast, AT&T’s participation in the

development of the EO, and Motorola’s and BellSouth’s background in telecommunications

lead to the creation of personal communicators with very strong communication features.

Profits were supposed to come from accessed communication services, less from the sale of

hardware. Amstrad’s experience in consumer electronics and the home computer market lead

to a cheap electronic gadget with limited functionality. But all these products failed more or

less spectacularly in the market.

The segment that continued to grow steadily during these years was the market for

electronic organizers. Sharp, Hewlett-Packard, Casio, and Psion continued to develop

incrementally their products, adding new features with each new product model. The market

grew steadily: In 1993, 685,000 handheld computers were sold worldwide. Two years later, in

1995, the market had nearly doubled to 1,200,000 units, a lot less than industry observers had

expected. But in the next two years, the market was to more than double, this time

unexpectedly. In 1997, PDA sales grew by more than 65 percent (Figure 7). This rapid market

growth can be attributed largely to the introduction of the Pilot PDA in April 1996.

Figure 7 PDA Sales worldwide 1993 to 2002 (*expected)

Page 30: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

30

4.3.3 The Pilot: A modest innovation

The software company Palm Computing7 had already been engaged in the

development of the Zoomer. After the demise of the Zoomer, Palm had initially focused on

writing software for handwriting recognition and connectivity packs for the Hewlett-Packard

line of handheld computers. But, due to the small market for handheld computers, the

potential for revenue was limited. Building on their experience in the handheld computer

market, Palm embarked on a mission to develop its own PDA, the Pilot. In their design, they

relied on off-the-shelf products. The Pilot was built around Motorola’s Dragonball processor

and an outdated Toshiba memory chip. For hardware design, Palm relied on Palo Alto Design

Group, and its manufacturing company was Singapore-based Flexotronics, a manufacturer

with a long-standing experience in consumer electronics.

In addition, Palm could build on their own technology for handwriting recognition,

Graffiti. Unlike other approaches to handwriting recognition, Graffiti did not try to interpret

the handwriting of the user, but forced the user to adopt a simple to learn, stylized alphabet.

Thereby, Graffiti was much more reliable and faster than other, more ambitious handwriting

recognition technologies. Palm also developed its own operating system, PalmOS. From the

beginning, Palm made its operating system available to independent software developers.

The shirt-pocket sized Pilot was designed expressly to complement a personal

computer. Accordingly, it only had limited, but tightly integrated features. Its standard

applications – calendar, address manager, to-do list, and memo pad – were launched instantly

by pressing a button. The synchronization between the desktop PC and the Pilot, often a

tedious task with other PDAs, was made easy by a specially designed docking cradle and

Palm’s own connectivity software. With a very low price, the Pilot became an instant hit.

Despite the lack of any communication features, and without sophisticated software packs, the

Pilot was successful, because in the words of one reviewer (Himowitz 1996, 224), it is a

“gadget that does a few things very well”. The Pilot was built according to quality standards

developed in telecommunications, as Yoffie/Kwak (2001, 59) remark “the Pilot adhered to the

telecommunications-industry standard of ‘five nines’, working 99.999% of the time, whereas

PC programs often crashed several times a day.”

The Pilot reached a market share of more than 70 percent of the US handheld

computer market at the end of 1996. In one year, the Pilot sold more than 500,000 units. After

7 Before the launch of the Pilot, Palm Computing was acquired by US Robotics in September 1995. It became a part of 3COM when 3COM acquired US Robotics in June 1997. In March 2000, after a successful IPO, Palm was an independent company once again. See Butter/Pogue (2002) for a history of Palm Computing.

Page 31: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

31

three and half years, Palm had sold more than 5 million units of different Pilot models. With

the Pilot, Palm established the dominant design for handheld computers for years to come.

The PDA was, above all, a mobile complement to a desktop or laptop computer. For that

reason, effortless synchronization with a desktop computer became an essential feature of a

PDA. Compactness, reliability, and ease of use became other defining product characteristics

of a PDA, while Palm’s Graffiti quickly evolved into the de facto industry standard for

handwriting recognition. In the next years, rivals tried to emulate the product characteristics

of the Pilot, and its basic design became the starting point for further product improvements

for all firms in the handheld computer industry.

As a startup company in the handheld computer industry, Palm was nevertheless able

to successfully enter the market for handheld computers because the technological knowledge

required to build a handheld was largely accessible through off-the-shelf products and

alliances. The critical new technologies like handwriting recognition and connectivity

software were developed in-house. Furthermore, Palm’s product design was not constrained

by existing marketing capabilities, while Palm’s involvement in the Zoomer project was an

important learning experience. Thus, Palm was able to exploit the window of opportunity

opened by the technological convergence in complements.

4.2 The handheld computer industry in the 2000s: Towards Product Convergence

After the success of the Pilot, the market for handheld computers grew rapidly.

Despite a number of market entries of established firms with a strong background in

computers and consumer electronics like, among others, Philips, Compaq, and Toshiba that

brought to market handheld computers based on a Microsoft operating system, Palm remained

the dominant firm in the next few years. Newly founded Handspring, a Palm spin-off, evolved

into its main competitor. In 2000, the two firms had a combined market share of nearly 80

percent worldwide. Innovative activities was incremental: Building on the dominant design of

the Pilot, the competitors added new features like color LCD display, voice recording and

music playing, while the existing features were improved.

At the same time, the wireless telecommunication markets is changing fundamentally.

With falling prices and increasing adoption, cellular phones evolved into genuine mass market

products. Due to advances in miniaturization technologies, cell phones got smaller and more

functional at the same time. Based on the WAP (wireless application protocol) standard,

Page 32: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

32

mobile phone producers like Nokia, Ericsson, and Motorola added rudimentary data

communication features to their devices. While adoption was slow, the WAP standard

nevertheless foreshadowed future development in wireless data communications. The SMS

(short message service) standard for simple text messaging, on the other hand, was an instant

hit. More demanding data communication is expected to be available via wideband networks

which provide higher bandwidth. Emerging technologies are GPRS (General Packet Radio

Standard) and especially the 3G/UMTS standard which is launched in 2002. Other emerging,

personal and local area network technologies are Bluetooth and 802.11b. All these emerging

wireless telecommunications technologies offer a higher bandwidth than the current GSM

(Global System for Mobile Telecommunications) standard. They finally make possible the

complementary use of cellular phones and multimedia online services. Consequently, cellular

phones and online services are converging as complementary products.

However, the same is true for PDAs. While many PDA models had data

communication features like fax, e-mail, and rudimentary Internet access, they were not the

key features as the success of the Pilot showed. The main task of a PDA still is data

processing. The emerging wireless telecommunications technologies thus open the possibility

to make data communication a key feature of a PDA, not an expensive add-on. In this context,

the ability to be always “online” appears to be a crucial feature. Using technologies developed

for paging devices, the Canadian company Research in Motion (RIM) introduced the

Blackberry wireless e-mail pager in early 1999 and it is a huge success with corporate clients.

Relying on a dated pager network, the Blackberry’s allows to instantly receive e-mails

without the need to actively go “online”. Thus, like a cell phone, the PDA is rapidly becoming

a complementary product to online services. As in mobile telecommunications, a convergence

in complementary products of PDAs and online services is at hand.

In addition, the miniaturization achieved in the production of cell phones makes the

integration of voice communication features in a PDA and vice versa technically viable. Early

attempts were the Simon, but also the Nokia Communicator introduced in 1996 and a

PalmOS-based cellphone by Qualcomm. These devices had only very rudimentary organizing

features, and could not be considered as a substitute for a PDA. But this is changing at the

moment. Telecommunication companies Kyocera, Samsung, Motorola and Nokia, and

Handspring have all released “intelligent cell phones” in late 2001, with many more models to

follow in 2002. These hybrid products are integrating the salient product characteristics of a

PDA and a mobile phone into one compact design. Thus, due to advances in miniaturization

Page 33: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

33

the product convergence in complementarities is paralleled by the convergence in product

substitutes of PDAs and cell phones (Figure 8).

Figure 8 Product Convergence in wireless communications and handheld computers

The technological opportunities in this constellation are high, since the emerging

wireless telecommunications technologies are leading to changes in the complementary

markets. First, there are the technological spillovers into the mobile phone and handheld

computer markets. The new possibilities for data communications and the resulting

convergence in complements prompt the search for new or enhanced product characteristics,

thereby speeding up the convergence of PDAs and cell phones. Second, innovations are also

induced in the online service and media industries. Here, new product offerings like wireless

Video/Music-on-Demand, gaming, and mobile commerce are becoming technically feasible.

The firms in the mobile phone and the handheld computer markets are reacting in

different ways to the new challenges. Virtually all companies are trying to exploit the growth

opportunities opened up by the complementary product convergence, and they are

accordingly extending the communications and multimedia features of their products. Many

of these firms are pursuing a focus strategy at the moment. For example, Palm has released its

first wireless, Internet-enabled handheld in 1999, and a handheld with a color LCD display in

early 2000. Palm’s strategy is to focus on the PDA market and not to develop convergent

hybrid cell phone/PDAs. Its latest model, the Palm i705, features instant messaging and push

e-mail technology like the Blackberry. For these communication services, Palm has formed

alliances with AOL (instant messaging), Ericsson (paging technology) and Cingular

Interactive (paging network). Furthermore, Palm has built up their own wireless network for

Internet access, Palm.net. In 2002, Palm introduced a Bluetooth extension card for its PDAs

that has been developed together with Toshiba. Palm has also entered alliances with Texas

Page 34: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

34

Instrument and start-up company Broadcom to develop wireless technologies and

applications. At present, Palm’s only stakes in the emerging market segment for hybrid

products are licenses for their PalmOS operating system to telecommunication companies

Kyocera and Samsung. Introduced in 2001, the Kyocera QCP 6035 and the Samsung SPH-

I300 were one of the first hybrid products on the market.

Beside Kyocera and Samsung, other telecommunication companies like Nokia,

Ericsson, and Motorola are also pursuing an active diversifying strategy by developing

hybrid models. Nokia has been an early mover in this market segment. In 1996, Nokia had

released the Communicator 9000, an early cell phone/PDA hybrid. While not very successful

commercially, it started Nokia’s ongoing involvement in the development of hybrids. In 1998,

Nokia was one the founding members of Symbian, a joint venture founded by Psion, Ericsson,

and Motorola. Symbian was formed to promote Psion’s EPOC operating system, originally

developed for Psion’s handhelds, as the standard operating system for wireless

communications. Matsushita joined as a stockholder in 1999, while Siemens became a

stockholding member in early 2002. Other, non-stockholding Symbian partners include Sony,

Philips, NTT DoCoMo, Oracle, Qualcomm, IBM, Sonera, and Sun Microsystems, but also the

music entertainment company Beatnik. In 2001, Nokia has released the latest Communicator

smart phone, the 9210, with great success in Europe. Building on former models, Nokia has

added a color screen, a powerful browser, and improved organizing features. Motorola and

the Sony Ericsson joint venture also released Symbian-based smartphones in 2001 and 2002.

In the PDA market, it is Handspring that has committed itself to a diversification

strategy. In late 2000, Palm shipped the VisorPhone module for Handspring’s Visor PDA.

Developed together with Belgian company Option International, the VisporPhone adds voice

and data communications to the Visor. With the acquisition of BlueLark Systems in 2000,

Handspring has extended its in-house technological capabilities in data communications.

BlueLark had developed the Blazer browser which can access not only Internet content

explicitly designed for mobile content but also standard HTML sites. To commercialize this

technology, Handspring has licensed the Blazer to telecommunication companies OmniSky

and Sprint, and to PDA maker Xircom. In late 2001, Handspring finally released a hybrid, the

Treo, with built-in voice communication. The GSM radio module had been developed by

French company Wavecom. Handspring is cooperating with telecommunications company

Sprint and telecommunications start-up Airprime to develop the 3G-enabled Treo during

2002, and it has also forged ties to wireless carriers such as VoiceStream, Cingular, and

Rogers, and online content providers like Microsoft’s MSN.

Page 35: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

35

It is too early to tell how the two types of product convergence will play out in the

handheld computer and mobile phone markets. But some of the salient features of these types

of convergence are already visible. The convergence of complements extends the

technological opportunities in these markets, and stimulates innovative activity in the existing

markets. For the underlying technologies of the complementary technologies, established

firms are looking for alliance partners in horizontal markets. The Symbian joint venture,

Palm’s licenses to Kycoera and Samsung, and Handspring’s cooperation with Sprint,

Xircomm, and MSN are examples. In addition, the product convergence in complements also

encourages entry by new firms like AirPrime, BlueLark, Broadcomm, and Wavecom into the

market for complementary technologies. These firms pursue highly focused strategies, and

they are important alliance partners for established firms.

As already explained, the product convergence of complements is also an important

driver of the product convergence in substitutes. Here, the established firms in the handheld

computer and mobile phone markets are introducing hybrid smart phones that substitute for

PDAs or cell phones. So far, the threat of new entrants has been negligible. The established

firms are building on their existing products, and use these as the starting point for the

development of these hybrid products. Over the years, Nokia has incrementally extended the

Communicator’s organizing features, while Handspring started from a PDA, first with an add-

on, later with a built-in voice communication module. An important consequence will be the

slow convergence of the technological capabilities of handheld computer and mobile phone

makers, probably leading to the long-term technological convergence of these diversifiers. On

the other hand, other established firms in both markets are continuing to pursue focus

strategies. Palm is the prime example. It remains to be seen how successful the hybrid

products really are, and how large the market segment for these convergent offerings will turn

out to be. This will influence the future viability of focus and diversification strategies.

5. Conclusions This paper has tried to contribute to the question of what kind of impact market

convergence has on innovations, market structure, and firm behavior. It has been argued that

four different ideal types of market convergence can be distinguished, and that these differ

markedly in their effects on industry evolution. To illustrate the framework, it has been

applied to explain the evolution of the handheld computer market in the last 20 years. It was

shown that different types of convergence shaped the evolution of handheld computers at

Page 36: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

36

various times. The observed patterns of market evolution broadly correspond to the theoretical

patterns of market convergence.

In the early stage of the market, market dynamics were driven by complementary

technological convergence of the computer, consumer electronics, and telecommunications

industries. These industries were the commercial backgrounds of entrants into the handheld

computer market, since they could exploit their existing technological capabilities to develop

new markets. To access missing technological capabilities, firms formed horizontal, usually

knowledge using alliances to access the technologies, or relied on off-the-shelf products. This

was also part of the reason why a start-up company eventually came to dominate the market.

Successful entry was also fostered by the low cumulativeness of the established firms’

marketing capabilities for entry into the handheld computer market. Recent developments in

the handheld computer market are influenced by product convergence. Emerging

telecommunications standards and technologies like 3G lead to a product convergence of

complements in the wireless telecommunications, handheld computer, and online services

industries. Innovative entrants are especially important for the development of the new

complementary technologies, since the cumulativeness of technological knowledge is low.

These entrants are important alliance partners for the established firms. Furthermore,

advances in miniaturization increasingly lead to the product convergence in substitutes of the

handheld computer and cellular phone industries. In this case, established firms of the two

markets are diversifying by developing hybrid products that incorporate product

characteristics of cell phones and PDAs. Since the cumulativeness of technological and

marketing knowledge is high, the role of entrants in this process of convergence has been

negligible.

By looking at one particular market in quite some detail, this qualitative case study

complements the more quantitative, inter-industry studies of technological convergence

(Gambardella/Torrisi 1998, Fai/Tunzelmann 2001).

Page 37: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

37

6. References

Abell, D.F. (1980): Defining the Business. Englewood Cliffs 1980.

Abbot, L.: Quality and Competition. New York 1955.

Adner, R./Levinthal, D.A. (2000): Technology Speciation and the Path of Emerging Technologies. In: Day, G.S./Schoemaker, P.J. (eds.): Wharton on Managing Emerging Technologies. New York et al. 2000,57-74.

Andersen, B. (1998): The evolution of technological trajectories 1890-1990. In: Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Vol. 9, 1998.

Bladwin, T.F./McVoy, D.S./Steinfield, C. (1996): Convergence: Integrating Media, Information, and Communication. Thousand Oaks.

Bayus, B.L./Jain, S./Rao, A.G. (1997): Too Little, too Early: Introduction Timing and New Product Performance in the Personal Digital Assistant Industry. In: Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. XXXIV, 1997, 50-63.

Bettis, R.A./Hitt, M.A. (1995): The New Competitive Landscape. In: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 16, 1995, S. 7-19.

Bettis, R.A. (1998): Comment on ‘Redefining Industry Structure For the Information Age’ by J.L. Sampler. In: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 19, 1998, S. 357-362

Bresnahan, T./Trajtenberg, M. (1995): General Purpose Technologies: Engines of Growth. In: Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 65, 1995, 83-108.

Butter, A./Pogue, D. (2002) : Piloting Palm. New York 2002.

Cantwell, J.A./Fai, F. (1999): Firms as the source of innovation and growth: the evolution of technological competence. In: Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol. 9, 1999, 331-366.

Choi, D./Valikangas, L. (2001): Patterns of Strategy Innovations. In: European Management Journal, Vol. 19, 2001, 424-429.

Christensen, C.M./Suárez, F.F./Utterback, J.M. (1998): Strategies for Survival in Fast-Changing Industries. In: Management Science, Vol. 44, S207-S220.

Collis, D.J./Bane, P.W./Bradley, S.P.: Winners and Losers: Industry Structure in the Converging World of Telecommunications, Computing, and Entertainment. In: Yoffie, D.B. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence. Boston 1997, 159-199.

Consumer Reports (1991): Need Organizing? November 1991, 768-774.

Demsetz, H. (1991): The Theory of the Firm Revisited. In: Williamson, O.E./Winter, S.G. (eds.): The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development. Oxford 1991, 159-177.

Dittrich, K. (2001): Internet alliances: a whole new game. Paper presented at the ECIS Conference, Eindhoven, Netherlands, September 20-23, 2001.

Dosi, G. (1988): Sources, procedures and microeconomic effects of innovation. In: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 36, 1988, 1126-1171.

Dosi, G./Malerba, F./Orsenigo, L. (1994): Evolutionary Regimes and Industrial Dynamics. In: Magnusson, L. (ed.) Evolutionary and Neo-Schumpeterian Approaches to Economics. Boston/Dordrecht/London.

Duysters, G./Hagedoorn, J. (1998): Technological Convergence in the IT Industry: The Role of Strategic Technological Alliances and Technological Competencies. In: International Journal of the Economics of Business, Vol. 5, 1998, 355-368.

Economist (2000): The Great Convergence Gamble, 12/09/2000, Vol. 357 Issue 8200, 2000, 67-68.

Page 38: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

38

Fai, F./Tunzelmann, Nicolas von (2001): Industry-specific competencies and converging technological systems: evidence from patents. In: Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Vol. 12, 2001, 141-170.

Gaffard, J.L./Krafft, J. (2000): Telecommunications: understanding the dynamics of the organization of the industry. Working Paper October 2000.

Gallouji, F./Weinstein, O. (1997): Innovation in services. In: Research Policy, Vol. 26, 1997, 537-556.

Gambardella, A./Torrisi, S. (1998): Does technological convergence imply convergence in markets? Evidence from the electronics industry. In: Research Policy, Vol. 27, 1998, 445-463.

Geroski, P.A. (1998): Thinking creatively about markets. In: International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 16, 1998, 677-695.

Gomes-Casseres, B. (1996) : The Alliance Revolution. Cambridge (Ma.) 1996.

Gomes-Casseres, B./Leonard-Barton, D. (1997): Alliance Clusters in Multimedia. In: Yoffie, D. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence, Boston, 1997, 325-369.

Granstrand, O. (1998): Towards a theory of the technology-based firm. In: Research Policy, Vol. 27, 1998, 465-489.

Greenstein, S./Khanna, T. (1997): What does industry convergence mean? In: Yoffie, D. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence, Boston, 1997, 201- 226.

Hamel, G./Prahalad, C.K (1994): Competing for the Future. Boston 1994.

Harianto, F./Pennings, J.M. (1994): Technological convergence and scope of organizational innovation. In: Research Policy, Vol. 23, 1994, 293-304.

Helpman, E., editor (1998): General Purpose Technologies and Economic Growth. Cambridge, Ma. 1998.

Hippel, E. von (1988): The Sources of Innovation. New York/Oxford 1988.

Himowitz, M. (1996): Why users love the Pilot. In: Fortune, Vol. 134, Issue 9, 224-226.

Jorgenson, D.W./Stiroh, K.J. (2000): Raising the Speed Limit: US Economic Growth in the Information Age. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Issue 1, 2000.

Kaplan, J. (1994): Start Up: A Silicon Valley Adventure. London 1994.

Katz, M.L. (1996): Remarks on the Economic Implications of Convergence. In: Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 3, 1996, 1079-1095.

Kodama, F. (1992): Technology Fusion and the New R&D. In: Harvard Business Review, Vol. 70, No.4, 1992, 70-78.

Lancaster, K.J. (1966): A new approach to consumer theory. In: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 14, 1966, 133-156.

Malerba, F./Orsenigo, L. (2000): Knowledge, Innovative Activities and Industrial Evolution. In: Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 9, 2000, 289-314.

Malerba, F. (2002): Sectoral systems of innovation and production. In: Research Policy, Vol. 31, 2002, 247-264.

Marsili, O. (2001): The Anatomy and Evolution of Industries. Cheltenham, UK 2001.

McGahan, A.M./Vadasz, L.L./Yoffie, D.B. (1997): Creating Value and Setting Standards. In: Yoffie, D.B. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence. Boston 1997, 227-264.

Mowery, D.C./Oxley, J.E./Silverman, B.S. (1996): Strategic Alliances and Interfirm Knowledge Transfer. In: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 17, 1996, Winter Special Issue, 77-91.

Mowery, D.C./Oxley, J.E./Silverman, B.S. (1998): Technological overlap and interfirm cooperation: implications for the resource-based view of the firm. In: Research Policy, Vol. 28, 1998, 507-523.

Page 39: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

39

Nelson, R.R. (1995): Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change. In: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 33, 1995, 48-90.

Pavitt, K. (1984): Patterns of Technical Change: Towards a Taxonomy and a Theory. In: Research Policy, Vol. 13, 1984, 343-373.

Pennings, J.M./Puranam, P. (2001): Market Convergence & Firm Strategy: New Directions for Theory and Research. Paper presented at the ECIS Conference, Eindhoven, Netherlands, September 20-23, 2001.

Penrose, E.T. (1959): The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. London 1959.

Piscitello, L. (2000): Relatedness and coherence in technological and product diversification of the world’s largest firms. In: Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Vol. 11, 2000, 295-315.

Pleatsikas, C./Teece, D. (2001): The analysis of market definition and market power in the context of rapid innovation. In: International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 19, 2001, 665-693.

Potter, D. (1998): Entrepreneurship: Psion and Europe. In: Business Strategy Review, Vol. 9, 1998, 15-20.

Porter, M.E. (1985): Competitive Advantage. New York 1985.

Reve, T. (1990): The Firm as a Nexus of Internal and External Contracts. In: Aoki, M./Bo, G./Williamson, O.E. (ed.): The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties. London 1990, 133-161.

Rao, P.M. (1999): Convergence and unbundling of corporate R&D in telecommunications: is software taking the helm? In: Telecommunication Policy, Vol. 23, 1999, 83-93.

Robinson, J. (1956), The Economics of Imperfect Competition. London 1956.

Rosenberg, N. (1976): Perspectives on technology. Cambridge 1976.

Rosenberg, N. (1982): Inside the Black Box. Cambridge/New York 1982.

Sahal, D. (1985): Technological guideposts and innovation avenues. In: Research Policy, Vol. 14, 1985, 61-82.

Santangelo, G.D. (2000): Corporate strategic technological partnerships in the European information and communications technology industry. In: Research Policy, Vol. 29, 2000, 1015-1031.

Saviotti, P./Metcalfe, S. (1984): A theoretical approach to the construction of technological output indicators. In: Research Policy, Vol. 13, 1984, 141-151.

Saviotti, P. (1996): Technological Evolution, Variety and the Economy. Cheltenham 1996.

Stigler, G./Sherwin, R. (1985): The Extent of the Market. In: Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 28, 1985, 555-585.

Teece, D.J. (1986): Profiting from Technological Innovation. In: Research Policy, Vol. 15, 1986, 285-305.

Teece, D.J./Dosi, G./Rumelt, R./Winter, S. (1994): Understanding Corporate Coherence: Theory and Evidence. In: Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 23, 1994, 1-30.

Teece, D.J./Pisano, G./Shuen, A. (1997): Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management. In: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 18, 1997, 509-533.

Tushman, M./Anderson, P. (1986): Technological Discontinuities and organizational environments. In: Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 31, 1986, 439-465.

Wirtz, B. (2001): Reconfiguration of Value Chains in Converging Media and Communications Markets. In: Long Range Planning, Vol. 34, 2001, 489-507.

Yoffie, D.B. (1997): Introduction: CHESS and Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence. In: Yoffie, D.B. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence. Boston 1997, 1-35.

Yoffie, D.B./Kwak, M. (2001): Mastering Strategic Movement at Palm. In: MIT Sloan Management Review, Fall 2001, 55-63.

Page 40: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

40

7. Appendix a) Major market entries and exits 1984 to 2001 in the handheld computer market

Year Entrant Product Origin Exit ?

1984 Psion Organiser Computer Software 2001

Casio Boss Consumer Electronics 1988

Sharp Wizard Consumer Electronics

Atari Portfolio Computer Hardware 1996 1989

Poqet Poqet PC Startup 1996

1991 HP LX 95 Computer Hardware

Amstrad PenPad Consumer Electronics 1996

Apple Newton Computer Hardware 1998

AT&T EO440 Telecommunications 1994

1993

Tandy Zoomer Consumer Electronics 1995

IBM/BellSouth Simon Computer Hardware /Telecommunications

1996

Motorola Envoy, Marco Computer Hardware 1996

1994

Sony MagicLink Consumer Electronics 1996

1995 Texas Instrument Pocket Solution Computer Hardware 1998

Compaq PC Companion Computer Hardware

Hitachi Handheld PC Computer Hardware

Nokia Communicator Telecommunications

1996

Palm Pilot Startup

Everex Freestyle Consumer Electronics

Franklin Rex-3-DS PDA Consumer Electronics

IBM (reentered) WorkPad Computer Hardware

LG Electronics GP40MHPC Consumer Electronics

NEC MobilePro Computer Hardware

Philips Velo, Nino Consumer Electronics

1997

Rolodex

(later: Xircomm)

REX PC Companion Consumer Electronics

1998 Olivetti/Royal DaVinci Computer Hardware

Handspring Visor Startup 1999

TRG

(renamed: HandEra)

TRGpro Startup

1999 RIM Blackberry Startup

Acer Slim Mate Computer Hardware 2000

Sony (reentered) Clié Consumer electronics

2001 Toshiba Genio Computer hardware

Page 41: INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET … and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. ... Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer

41

b) Alliances in the handheld computer industry for major products released in 1993 Product Company Industry Task Direction Motivation

Ameritech Communication Hardware/Services

Messaging Horizontal Knowledge Using

AOL Communication Services

Online Services Horizontal Knowledge Using

ARM Computer Hardware Microprocessor ARM 610 Vertical Knowledge Using BellSouth Communication

Services Development Online-Banking

Horizontal Knowledge Creating

Cirrus Logic Computer Hardware ARM licensee Vertical Knowledge Using GEC Plessy Computer

Hardware ARM licensee Vertical Knowledge Using

LSI Logic Computer Hardware Application specific chip Vertical Knowledge Using Motorola Computer/

Communications Hardware

Newton licensee Horizontal Knowledge Using

ParaGraph Computer Software

Handwriting Recognition Horizontal Knowledge Creating

Pen Magic Computer Software Software Horizontal Knowledge Using Random House Publishing Reference content Horizontal Knowledge Creating Sharp Consumer Electronics LCD display

Manufacturing Netwon licensee ARM licensee

Horizontal Knowledge Using

Siemens Electronics Newton licensee Horizontal Knowledge Using Sky-Tel Communication

Services E-mail services Horizontal Knowledge Using

Texas Instrument Computer Hardware ARM licensee Horizontal Knowledge Using Toshiba Computer Hardware CD-ROM Horizontal Knowledge Using US West Communication

Services Communication Services Horizontal Knowledge Using

Apple Newton

VLSI Technology Computer Hardware ARM licensee Vertical Knowledge Using Active Book Company

Computer Hardware Hardware and Software Design

Horizontal Knowledge Creating

Aha! Computer Software Software Horizontal Knowledge Using GO Computer Software Handwriting Recognition

Operating System Horizontal Knowledge Using

Ink Development Computer Software Software Horizontal Knowledge Using Lexis Computer Software Software Horizontal Knowledge Using Marubeni Electronics Sourcing

Distribution Horizontal Knowledge Using

Matsushita Consumer Electronics Manufacturing Horizontal Knowledge Using Notable Technologies

Computer Software Software Horizontal Knowledge Using

Olivetti Computer Hardware

Sourcing Distribution

Horizontal Knowledge Using

Pen Magic Computer software Financial Software Horizontal Knowledge Using PenSoft Computer Software Software Horizontal Knowledge Using Sharp Consumer Electronics LCD Display Horizontal Knowledge Using Slate Computer Software Software Horizontal Knowledge Using

AT&T EO

Sunselect Computer Software Software Horizontal Knowledge Using Casio Consumer Electronics LCD display

Microprocessor Manufacturing

Horizontal Knowledge Using

GeoWorks Computer Software Operating System Horizontal Knowledge Using Palm Computing Computer Software Handwriting Recognition

Software Horizontal Knowledge Using

Intuit Computer Software Financial software Horizontal Knowledge Using

Tandy Zoomer

AOL Communication Services

Online Services Horizontal Knowledge Using