immigration and the canadian welfare state 2011

Upload: national-post

Post on 08-Apr-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    1/62

    Immigration&Refugee Policy

    Studies in

    May 2011

    Immigration and theCanadian Welfare State

    2011

    by Herbert Grubel and Patrick Grady

  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    2/62

  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    3/62

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    Studies in

    Immigrationand Reugee

    Policy

    May

    Immigration and theCanadian Welare State 2011

    by Herbert Grubel and Patrick Grady

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    4/62

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    5/62

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    ContentsSummary / v

    Highlights / vi

    Introduction / 1

    1 Taxes paid by immigrants / 4

    2 Benets received / 8

    3 Taxation and benets together / 12

    4 Other benets and costs o immigration / 14

    5 Policy recommendations / 23

    6 Summary and conclusions / 40

    Reerences / 42

    About the authors / 47

    Acknowledgments / 48

    Publishing inormation / 49

    Supporting the Fraser Institute / 50

    About the Fraser Institute / 51

    Editorial Advisory Board / 52

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    6/62

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    7/62

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    Immigration and the Canadian Welare State 2011

    Summary

    Tis publication provides an estimate o the scal burden created by recent

    immigration into Canada and proposes reorms to existing immigrant selec-

    tion policies to eliminate the burden. It uses a 2006 Census database to esti-

    mate the average incomes and taxes paid on these by immigrants who arrived

    in Canada over the period rom 1987 to 2004. It also estimates other taxes

    they paid and the value o government services they absorbed.

    Te study concludes that in the scal year 2005/06 the immigrants on aver-

    age received an excess o $6,051 in benets over taxes paid. Depending on

    assumptions about the number o recent immigrants in Canada, the scal

    burden in that year is estimated to be between $23.6 billion and $16.3 billion.

    Tese estimates are not changed by the consideration o other alleged benets

    brought by immigrants.

    o curtail this growing scal burden rom immigration, the study proposes

    that temporary work visas be granted to applicants who have a valid oer or

    employment rom employers, in occupations and at pay levels specied by

    the ederal government and determined in cooperation with private-sector

    employers. Immediate dependents may accompany successul applicants.

    Te temporary visas are renewable and lead to landed immigrant status i

    certain specied employment criteria are met.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    8/62

    vi / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    Highlights

    Nearly a quarter o a million immigrants have entered Canada annually during

    the last two decades. Te eects that these immigrants have had on economic

    and social conditions in Canada have been considered by Grubel (2005). He

    estimated that as a result o the immigrants low average incomes and the

    operation o the welare state with its progressive income taxes and universal

    social benets, in 2000 immigrants received rom all Canadians an annual net

    scal transer o $18.3 billion. Te main objective o this study is to improve on

    Grubels calculations using previously unavailable ocial income and tax data

    reerring to immigrants that arrived over a dierent and longer period. Te

    study used data rom the 2006 Census (2006 Census Public Use Microdata File

    [PUMF]) that contains inormation on 844,476 individuals. Tis sample rep-

    resents 2.7% o the Canadian population and allows making statistically valid

    generalizations or the entire population.

    Calculating the net scal cost o recent immigration

    In the year 20051 the immigrants in the Census database, who arrived in

    Canada over the period o 18 years rom 1987 to 2004, had an average income

    o $25,396, on which they paid an average o $3,438 in income taxes. Te

    comparable gures or all Canadians were $35,057 or income and $5,995 or

    taxes, based on the entire sample o individuals. Te data thus implies that,

    on average, immigrants incomes were only 72.4% o income earned by all

    Canadians and that they paid only 57.3% o taxes.

    Te study also took account o other taxes paid by immigrants and

    Canadians, such as sales and property taxes. It ound that immigrants on

    average paid $10,340 while all Canadians paid $16,501 in income and other

    taxes. Te study also considered the amount received as government bene-

    ts by the average immigrant and all Canadians, concluding that immigrants

    received $110 less in benets than all Canadians. Te combination o average

    tax payments and benets received resulted in the basic nding o the paper:

    in the 2005/06 scal year, the average net scal transer per immigrant came

    to $6,051 due to the $6,161 less taxes paid and $110 less in benets received

    by the average immigrant compared with the averages o all Canadians.Assuming that an average immigrant pays taxes and receives benets

    or 45 years between his or her arrival and end o lie, this basic estimate

    1 Calendar year 2005 overlaps the 2005/06 scal year. Both 2005 and 2005/06 are used

    in this publication because the census data is or calendar year 2005 and the scal data

    is or scal year 2005/06.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    9/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / vii

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    implies that each immigrant receives, on average, net benets worth $272,295.

    It also implies that the 3.9 million immigrants who arrived between 1987

    and 2004 received, in scal year 2005/2006, net benets worth $23.6 bil-

    lion. However, ater adjusting the number o immigrants or emigration and

    mortality, the number o immigrants receiving the net benets alls to 2.7 mil-

    lion and the estimates o the total net benets is reduced to the $16.3 billion.

    Tese gures should be seen in relation to some program spending

    by the ederal government. Tus, in the 2005/06 scal year the $23.6 billion

    transer to immigrants equals 4.7% o total program spending o $503 billion,

    and comes to 1.18 times the cost o general government services o $20 bil-

    lion and 1.79 times spending on the environment o $13.2 billion. Using the

    lower estimate o $16.3 billion or the transers, they represent 3.2%, 82%, and

    123% o the three selected ederal government spending gures, respectively.

    Other benets and costs o immigration

    Te study also examines popular propositions about benets provided by

    immigrants or Canadians that are not reected in the scal estimates. Te

    analysis concludes that none o these propositions hold up to close scrutiny.

    It is said that the ospring o immigrants will repay Canadians or the

    scal transers received by their parents and grandparents, but they would

    do so only i, persistently and on average, they have incomes and pay taxes

    much above the average o all Canadians. Tis outcome is unlikely given that

    the ospring o immigrants in the past eventually have taken on all o the

    characteristics o the average Canadian.

    Immigrants are believed to solve the problems o ununded liabilities o

    Canadas social programs. However, according to careul studies by actuaries,

    immigrants arriving in acceptable numbers cannot do so, simply and mainly

    because immigrants age and also receive the costly benets.

    Immigrants do ll jobs that Canadians do not want and thus benet

    the economy but, in the absence o immigration, these jobs would pay higher

    wages and would be lled by Canadians or eliminated by the application o

    labour-saving technology. Under these conditions, poverty in Canada would

    be reduced substantially.

    Immigrants raise aggregate national income but do not in the process

    increase per-capita incomes o all Canadians. In act, as the study shows,

    they lower per-capita incomes ater taxes, the most important measure o

    economic well-being.

    Policy proposals

    Te paper presents a proposal or immigration reorm that is aimed at the

    elimination o the scal burden imposed on Canadians through current poli-

    cies. Te principle or reorm is that the number and composition o immi-

    grants should be determined largely by market orces within a ramework set

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    10/62

    viii / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    and managed by government. Under the proposal, the overall immigration

    levels could increase, decrease, or remain unchanged, but would most likely

    decline signicantly.

    Te proposed system or selecting immigrants is based on the model

    that underlies the present NAFA rules, which allows the ree ow between

    Canada, Mexico, and the United States o workers who hold valid contracts

    or employment in the country o immigration and or a specied list o

    occupations. Under the proposed policy, persons entering Canada with such

    contracts and their dependants would be eligible to become immigrants in

    the traditional sense and ultimately to acquire citizenship ater remaining

    employed or a number o years. Te role o the government would be to set

    rules or the qualication o applicants, evaluate their health and security

    risks, and ensure that employment is maintained and that violators o rules

    are deported.

    Te implementation in practice o policies or immigrant selection

    based on these principles requires a large set o detailed rules, regulations,

    saeguards and standards, the design o which should be undertaken only

    ater intensive public consultation and input by experts. Te paper consid-

    ers a small number o such rules but is designed mainly to stimulate discus-

    sion about the proposed selection principles and the practicality o detailed

    implementation measures.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    11/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 1

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    Introduction

    Nearly a quarter o a million immigrants have entered Canada annually during

    the last two decades. Te eects that these immigrants have had on economic

    and social conditions in Canada have been considered in a number o papers

    and conerence volumes that have been published by the Fraser Institute (e.g.,

    Grubel, 2005, 2009). In particular, the study by Grubel (2005: 19) analyzed

    the economic eects o Canadian immigration. He estimated that, as a result

    o the immigrants low average incomes and the operation o the welare state

    with its progressive income taxes and universal social benets, immigrant

    who arrived between 1990 and 2002 received rom all Canadians an annual

    scal transer o $18.3 billion in 2002. Grubels study had to use a number o

    assumptions about magnitudes or which no ocial data was available and

    admittedly provided only a rough ballpark estimate.

    Te present publication replaces some o these assumptions with more

    comprehensive statistical data rom the 2006 Census (Statistics Canada, 2009),

    thus making the estimates more reliable and precise. Moreover, it includes

    data or immigrants who arrived ater 2002 and during years rom 1987 to

    1989, or whom data was either not available or not used in the study o 2005.

    At the outset, the reader should be warned that this paper has a very specic

    ocus and does not analyze a wide range o social and security problems sur-

    rounding Canadas present immigration and reugee policies. Tese issues

    are discussed in conerence volumes edited by Moens and Collacott (2008)

    and Grubel (2009), which contain chapters by experts working in several

    social-science disciplines.

    Outline

    Section 1 presents data on personal income taxes paid by recent immigrants

    and all Canadians in the sample and gives estimates o the amount o other

    taxes paid by the two groups. Section 2 considers the dierence in the value

    o government services consumed by immigrants and all Canadians. Section 3

    presents the scal costs imposed by immigrants by bringing together the

    estimates calculated in the preceding sections o tax paid and government

    benets consumed. Section 4 summarizes arguments about non-scal bene-ts and costs o immigration, which are relevant to assessing the scal issues

    in a broader economic context.

    Section 5 presents a proposal or a undamental reorm o the existing

    immigrant-selection policies, which is derived rom our ndings on the high

    scal costs o the present selection policies. Te policies proposed are not

    opposed to immigration but rather are intended to replace the judgement o

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    12/62

    2 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    civil servants on who is to be admitted into Canada with judgements made

    by private employers in Canada. Te nal section o the paper gives a sum-

    mary and some conclusions.

    In reading this publication, note that we ully accept the economic

    logic o the classical, textbook case or ree immigration with all o its posi-

    tive eects on reedom, national income, and global welare. We recognize,

    however, that this theoretical case or ree immigration is based on the key

    assumption that governments do not engage in income redistribution by pro-

    viding cradle-to-grave security through its welare-state policies. Tat this is

    clearly not the case or Canada provides the basis or our considerable and

    important modication o the classical case or ree immigration.1 As Milton

    Friedman, who was one o the twentieth centurys staunchest advocates or

    reedom, said: You cannot simultaneously have ree immigration and a wel-

    are state (Friedman, 1999).

    1 For an exposition o the classical case or immigration, see Grubel (1981) and or the ben-

    ets o a ree international circulation o brainy migrants, see Grubel and Scott (1977).A case can be made that immigration into a welare state orces government to abandon

    its costly social-welare programs or at least make it more ecient. Tis argument is not

    ound in the text-book case or immigration and our analysis and policy recommenda-

    tions are based on the view that the welare state will be changed only very marginally, i

    at all, by the pressures brought upon it by immigration. Te desire o the public or the

    benets o the welare state is simply too powerul to allow any signicant reductions in

    social benets.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    13/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 3

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    1 Taxes paid by immigrants

    Te basic inormation we use to estimate the personal income taxes paid by

    recent immigrants is shown in table 1. Tis inormation was derived rom the

    2006 Census Public Use Microdata File (PUMF), which was purchased rom

    Statistics Canada (2009). Te le contains 844,476 records, presenting data

    rom the 2006 Census on individuals representing 2.7% o the Canadian popu-

    lation. Tis sample is large enough to permit reliable conclusions to be drawn on

    the income taxes paid and transers received by recent cohorts o immigrants.

    As can be seen in table 1, the cohort o 64,792 immigrants in the data-

    base, who arrived in Canada over the period o 18 years rom 1987 to 2004,

    had, in the year 2005,2 an average income o $25,396, on which they paid an

    average o $3,438 in income taxes. Te comparable gures or all Canadians

    were an average income o $35,057 and income taxes o $5,995, based on the

    entire sample o 692,509 individuals age 15 and over or whom income and

    tax data was available.3 Te table also shows the average employment income

    or the two groups (used in the calculations in table 2). Te main dierences

    between income and employment income are that the ormer includes trans-

    er payments as well as earnings rom investments. Te data does not allow

    us to distinguish between these two sources o income earned in addition to

    that rom employment.4

    Te last row o table 1 shows the ratio o the average income o immi-

    grants to the average income o all Canadians: 72.4%; and the ratio o employ-

    ment income: 81.0%; and the ratio o income taxes paid: 57.3%, which was

    derived by dividing rows (1) and (2). Te income ratios are larger than the

    tax ratio because the progressivity o the income tax system results in all

    Canadians with higher incomes paying a proportionately higher amount in

    taxes than recent immigrants. Te ratio or taxes paid o 57.3% is used in the

    income tax calculations in table 2.

    2 Calendar year 2005 overlaps the 2005/06 scal year. Both 2005 and 2005/06 are used

    in this publication because the census data is or calendar year 2005 and the scal data

    is or scal year 2005/06.

    3 Tis includes all the individuals in the PUMF sample 15 years o age or older or whichdata was available. While it is the most appropriate group or the purposes o the current

    analysis , it is not the most appropriate or meaningul comparisons o income and tax. For

    that purpose, the sample should be limited to age groups that are most likely to be in the

    labour orce. See Grady, 2010 or this type o analysis or the 25-to-64 year age group.

    4 However, the data does show that investment income o immigrants is 41.4% o that

    earned by Canadians, which goes a long way to explain why the average income and

    employment income o immigrants is only 72% and 81% o all Canadians, respectively.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    14/62

    4 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    Characteristics o immigrants and income taxes paid

    Tere are our points worth noting about the calculations in table 1. First, the

    immigrants who arrived in 2005 are excluded rom our calculations since

    they were not necessarily in Canada or the ull year and their annual earn-

    ings would thereore be biased downward.

    Second, the ratios use the average incomes o all immigrants who

    arrived between 1987 and 2004, regardless o the act that they are hetero-

    geneous in a number o ways, just as the sample o all Canadians consists o

    persons o dierent age, education and other characteristics.

    Tird, one o the sources o heterogeneity among immigrants is that they

    include all classes o immigrants, which have dierent average levels o income:

    economic immigrants perorm the best, ollowed by amily class or reugees

    depending on the time horizon (Wanner, 2003; Abbott and Beach, 2009). Tis

    act has interesting implications or other analysis o immigration policies

    but it is not relevant to our calculations and thereore is not explicitly incor-

    porated. At the same time, however, it does strongly inuence our proposals

    or reorms o the immigrant selection system presented in section 5 below.

    Fourth, the heterogeneity o immigrants extends to their dierent

    lengths o stay in Canada. Numerous studies have shown that the earnings

    and incomes o immigrants improve through time as they adapt to, and

    become integrated into, the Canadian labour market.5

    5 Te increase in earnings o immigrants through time has attracted much attention rom

    researchers: Frenette and Morisette (2003), Worswick (2004), Picot and Sweetman (2005),

    and Picot (2008). Tese studies traced the incomes o the same cohort o immigrants

    through time. While our data is consistent with the ndings o these studies, it is worth

    noting that the results are not strictly comparable since our data reects the incomes o

    dierent cohorts in the year 2005 and not the incomes o the same cohorts through time.

    Table 1: Income and taxes paid by immigrants and other Canadians in 2005

    AverageIncome

    AverageEmployment

    Income

    AverageIncome Tax

    Paid

    Number oObservations in

    Sample

    () Immigrants $, $, $, ,

    () All Canadians $, $, $, ,

    () / () .% .% .%

    Note: Recent immigrants are compared with all Canadians, which includes themselves, because

    the government revenue and expenditure data, which must be adjusted, is or all Canadians.

    Source: Calculations by authors or recent immigrants and the entire Canadian population done

    rom Census PUMF(Statistics Canada, 9). Total income is provided by the variable totinc

    in the fle, and income tax by the variable inctax, both o which are averaged across individu-

    als to calculate averages. All recent immigrants and Canadians reporting income or income tax

    were included in the sample.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    15/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 5

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    In gure 1 we document this phenomenon using data in the PUMF le.

    Te graph shows the average income and taxes o immigrants relative to those

    o all Canadians as a unction o the time that immigrants have spent in Canada.

    For example, the average income o immigrants who arrived during the period

    rom 1999 to 2004 was 62.4% o the average income o all Canadians. For those

    who arrived during the years rom 1987 to 1992, the percentage was 83.6. Tus,

    our cross-sectional data or dierent immigration cohorts in 2005 shows the

    same improvement in the average income o immigrants the longer that the

    immigrant cohort is in Canada as that revealed by data on cohort perormance

    across time presented in the studies cited in ootnote 4.

    Other taxes

    Government revenues in Canada are raised not only through the personal

    income taxes just considered but also through a number o other taxes

    imposed by all levels o government. able 2 shows the types o taxes in

    One o the most interesting and disturbing acts about the incomes o immigrants is

    ound in Picot, Garnett, and Sweetman (2005). Tey discovered that the average incomes o

    cohorts have decreased through time and, while the incomes o these cohorts continued the

    usual pattern o rising as they became more integrated into the labour market, the most recent

    cohorts have never reached the income ratios attained by cohorts that had arrived earlier.

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    1987-19921993-19981999-2004

    Percentage

    Figure 1: Average income and income tax of recent immigrants as percentage of

    those of all Canadians, for cohorts arriving 19992004, 19931998, 19871992

    Source: Calculations by authors for recent immigrants and the entire Canadian population done

    from Statistics Canada, Census 2006 PUMF(2009). Total income is provided by the variable totinc

    in the le, and income tax by the variable inctax, both of which are averaged across individuals

    to calculate averages. All recent immigrants and Canadians reporting income or income tax

    were included in the sample.

    Average incomes

    Income taxes

    72.9%

    83.6%

    62.4%

    44.6%

    57.8%

    71.4%

    Period of arrival

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    16/62

    6 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    column (1), while column (2) gives the total revenue raised by each type o

    tax. Column (3) shows the percentage distribution o revenues among the

    categories. Column (4) translates this total into per-capita amounts, based

    on the countrys estimated population o 31.6 million in 2006. Te crucial

    estimate or our analysis is the per-capita taxes paid by immigrants in each

    o the types o taxes shown (6). It is unortunate that this inormation is not

    available rom publically available sources, nor can it be extracted rom the

    PUMF database.6 Tereore, the ratios shown in column (5) are based on

    assumptions spelled out below, but are deliberately biased in avour o over-

    stating rather than under-stating the amounts paid by immigrants.

    Tus, the ratio or Health and social insurance levies is assumed to be 100%

    on the grounds that these taxes are levied on only a maximum level o income

    that is reached by most immigrants. Te ratio or General sales taxes is assumed

    to be 72% on the grounds that the ederal value-added tax and provincial

    sales taxes are levied on consumer expenditures that are related to aver-

    age income ratios. Te ratio or Corporate income taxes is assumed to be 30%

    because recent immigrants are judged likely to hold only small amounts o

    6 Te inormation on the dierent types o taxes paid is absent rom the PUMF le because

    it is not collected. In the case o the personal income tax, the inormation is obtained

    through a link between the Census and income-tax data contained in the 1 orms led

    with Revenue Canada. Tis link occurs only or 1 lers who specically consent on the

    Census long orm.

    Table 2: Taxes paid by Canadians and recent immigrants, all levels o government, 2005/06

    () () () () () () ()

    Type o tax $ billions Percentageo totalrevenue

    Dollars percapita or allCanadians

    Tax paid byimmigrantsas % o allCanadians

    Dollars percapita paid

    by Immigrants

    Diference ($) inper-capita tax,

    () ()

    Personal income taxes , . , , ,

    Health & social insurance levies , . , ,

    General sales taxes , . , ,

    Corporate income taxes , . , ,

    Property & related taxes , . ,

    Other taxes , . , ,

    Total , . , n.a. , ,

    Note: The total taxes paid include those paid by immigrants, so that the average paid by non-recent immigrants shown is

    biased downward since recent immigrants are known to have below average tax payments.

    Source: Statistics Canada, ; calculations by authors.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    17/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 7

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    common stocks that bear the burden o the corporate income tax. In support

    o this assumption, we note that according to the PUMF data the immigrants

    investment income is only 41% o the average o all Canadians and that this

    probably includes a disproportionate amount o investments other than cor-

    porate stocks. It was assumed that the amounts paid as Property and related

    taxes and Other taxes were related to total income.

    Te last row o table 2 shows the sum o all taxes paid by the average

    immigrant ($10,340) and the average o all Canadians including immigrants

    ($16,501) in the scal year 2006 (ending March 31, 2006 and overlapping

    with the 2005 calendar year rom the Census). Tese values will be used

    below in the calculation o the scal transers rom other Canadians to recent

    immigrants.

    7 Economic theory suggests that corporate income taxes are passed on to consumers.

    However, this conclusion is not relevant to the present analysis. Instead, it is legitimate

    to ask who bears the direct scal burden o paying the tax as a result o the ownership o

    corporations.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    18/62

    8 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    2 Benefts received

    Government spending is designed to benet all people living in Canada.

    However, since one o the objectives o the welare state is to redistribute

    income, many spending programs benet those with low incomes propor-

    tionately more than those with high incomes, just as taxes all more heavily

    on those with high incomes than on those with low incomes. While the redis-

    tributive eects o government spending are clear in the aggregate, there is

    no statistical inormation available to allow direct accounting o the degree to

    which demographic groups like single mothers, the disabled, and immigrants

    benet rom each. Tereore, the ollowing analysis o the degree to which

    immigrants benet rom specic spending programs relies on assumptions,

    which are spelled out and justied or most categories by reerence to some

    ragmentary evidence that exists on the incidence o spending.8

    Our calculations o the expenditure component o the net scal trans-

    er to recent immigrants are presented in table 3. Column (1) lists the di-

    erent types o spending programs, column (2) total expenditures, and col-

    umn (3) expenditures per capita or all Canadians based on a population

    o 31.6 million. Te amounts in table 3 represent the spending by all levels

    o Canadian government, consolidated so as to remove intergovernmental

    transers. Program spending excludes debt-service payments o $44.8 billion,

    which do not provide current services or Canadians and immigrants and

    were thereore excluded rom our calculations. Tis exclusion is reasonable

    on the grounds that, to the extent that the past decits necessitating the inter-

    est payments resulted in the creation o tangible assets like inrastructure and

    8 In this context, it is useul to introduce two historic notes. First, at the time the social con-

    tract guiding the welare-state provisions was adopted, the issue o including immigrants

    was moot because they had records o economic success that prevented their identica-

    tion as a group needing net scal transers. Tereore, their arrival and existence were not

    an issue and no statistical records were kept ocially to record the benets they received.

    Te situation is dierent now. Recently arrived immigrants are a distinct and large group

    o people who, according to government statistics, have low average incomes and other

    needs that are covered under the contract. Yet records are still not being kept.Second, in Canada since 1980 even reugees who are not landed immigrants but are in

    the process o having their claims assessed or residency are automatically entitled to all

    the benets o the countrys social program. Tis condition is the result o the Supreme

    Court o Canadas Singh decision (Singh, 1985), which was based on the courts inter-

    pretation o the Charter o Rights and Freedoms. Parliament never took on the task o

    clariying the relevant clauses o the Charter to prevent the burden imposed on citizens

    by this ruling.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    19/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 9

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    the maintenance o intangible assets like reedom and the Canadian way o

    lie, they provide benets that accrue equally to Canadians and immigrants.

    Te gures in column (4) are central to the calculation o net scal

    costs presented in section 3. Tey show the percentage assumed to apply tothe benets received on average by recent immigrants relative to the bene-

    ts received by all Canadians under each type o program. In most columns,

    this gure is 100% and reects the view that recent immigrants benet as

    much per-capita as do other Canadians. In some cases, such as in the cat-

    egoryEnvironment, the underlying rationale should be obvious. Most readers

    will agree that all persons in Canada benet equally rom the maintenance

    Table 3: Benets received by Canadians and recent immigrants, all levels o government, 2005/06

    () () () () ()

    Type o government expenditure(program spending)

    Totalexpenditure($ millions)

    Per-capitabenets

    received ($)

    Benets receivedby recent

    Immigrants (% oother Canadians)

    Per-capitabenets received

    by recentImmigrants ($)

    General government services ,

    Protection of persons and property 43,299 1,370 72 987

    Health , , ,

    Social services , , ,

    Education 84,760 2,682 109 2,924

    Recreation and culture ,

    Labour, employment and immigration 2,480 78 120 94

    Housing 4,527 143 110 158

    Regional planning and development ,

    Transportation and communication ,

    Resource conservation and industrial development ,

    Environment ,

    Foreign afairs and international assistance ,

    Research establishments ,

    Other expenditures ,

    Total , , ,

    Note: Spending categories or which the immigrants are estimated to receive lower or higher benefts are show, e.g.:

    Protection of persons and property.

    Source: Statistics Canada, ; calculations by authors.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    20/62

    10 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    or improvement in the quality o the environment. Most o the other spend-

    ing categories to which the 100% gure has been applied should be similarly

    obvious.9 Let us now turn to a discussion o the spending categories or which

    the immigrants are estimated to receive lower or higher benets.

    Protection o persons and property

    Here we assume that the benets rom protection are proportional to income.

    Since the income o immigrants is 72% o that o Canadians, we use this

    gure here.

    Education

    Spending on Education, or which the percentage is assumed to be 109. Tis

    requires some explanation as it results rom an analysis o the three main

    underlying components: primary and secondary education, post-secondary educa-

    tion, and special retraining services (Statistics Canada, 2010). For primary and sec-

    ondary education, it is assumed that recent immigrants obtain a benet o 150%

    o the Canadian average. Tis reects the act that, according to the Census,

    recent immigrants received a per-capita share o child benets that is 66%

    higher than the Canadian average, but it also makes some allowance or the

    act that the child benet is income tested inating this number somewhat.

    For post secondary education, it is assumed that the benet is only 50% o the

    average. According to a study o the use o educational services in Canada by

    Horry and Walker (1994), the children o amilies with low incomes are less

    likely to attend institutions o higher learning than the children o amilies

    with high incomes. Te Census suggests this might be the case as the rate o

    attendance at school or recent immigrants was only 75% o the Canadian

    average. As attendance at primary and secondary schools is compulsory, the

    largest part o this dierence must be attributed to dierence in attendance

    at post-secondary institutions. For special retraining services, it is assumed that

    recent immigrants receive 20% more benets because o their greater need.

    For the ourth component, other education, it was assumed that recent immi-

    grants receive the same average per-capita benets as all Canadians.

    9 Te provision o many government services requires the use o large xed investments

    and the marginal cost o covering additional persons is near zero. Spending on roads

    and the environment are good examples. Te 250,000 immigrants who arrive every year

    amount to only a very small addition to the number o people who use Canadas roadsand other inrastructure. It can thereore be argued that their arrival does not necessitate

    new spending in these categories. However, this argument is valid only in the short run.

    Eventually, as more and more immigrants arrive and add to trac, the capacity o roads

    has to be increased to accommodate them. In the present analysis, we look beyond the

    short-run eects and assume that immigrants add to the need or xed investment in

    inrastructure and the agencies administering environmental protection so that the xed

    costs increase with the arrival o additional immigrants.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    21/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 11

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    Labour, employment and immigration

    Spending on Labour, employment and immigration is assumed to benet immi-

    grants 20% more than other Canadians because they have more dealings

    with the government on immigration issues related to the amily reunica-

    tion program, the processing o reugee claims, and related issues. Te low

    average incomes o immigrants also lead to the use o more benets under

    programs that deal with labour markets and employment.

    Housing

    Housing is the nal category o spending that immigrants are assumed to use

    more than other Canadians. Te assumption is that immigrants benet by 10%

    more than other Canadians on the grounds that upon arrival they have tem-

    porary access to ree or heavily subsidized housing while they settle and nd

    employment. Furthermore, the many low-income immigrant amilies bene-

    t disproportionately rom government programs designed to make hous-

    ing more aordable, particularly in the urban areas where they tend to settle.

    Total benefts

    Te last row o table 3 shows that the average per-capita amount o benets

    received by all Canadians exceeds that received by immigrants by $110, or

    $15,907 minus $15,797.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    22/62

    12 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    3 Taxation and benefts together

    Te scal cost imposed on other Canadians by recent immigrants through pro-

    visions o the welare state can be calculated by using the ollowing ormula:

    FT = (Ta Ti) + (Gi Ga),

    where FT is the average per-capita scal transer to immigrants rom all

    Canadians, Tis the average per-capita taxes paid, G is the average per-capita

    benet received through program spending, a denotes all Canadians, and i

    denotes recent immigrants. Using the gures derived in the preceding sec-

    tions, the scal costs are:

    FT = ($16,501 $10,340) + ($15,797 $15,907) = $6,161 $110 = $6,051

    Tis gure represents the central nding o this study: on average, immi-

    grants coming into the country between 1987 and 2004 received per-capita

    scal transers rom other Canadians worth $6,051 in the scal year 2006.10

    It is important to note, and is evident rom the analysis above, that

    these transers do not appear explicitly in any government accounts or other

    ocial statistics. Tey are simply the result o the way in which Canadas wel-

    are state operates and the ocially documented act that recent immigrants

    on average earn much lower incomes than other Canadians.

    It is useul to put the gure o $6,051 or the average, annual, per-capita

    scal transers rom all Canadians to recent immigrants in perspective. First,

    i the average immigrant pays taxes and receives benets or 45 years between

    his or her arrival and end o lie, every recent immigrant benets rom transers

    worth $272,295, disregarding all eects o discounting and ination. Second,

    during the 18-year period rom 1987 to 2004, a total o 3.9 million immigrants

    arrived in Canada according to the administrative data collected by Citizenship

    and Immigration Canada (2010). In the scal year 2006, they would have

    imposed a cost o $23.6 billion on Canadians i none o the immigrants had

    10 It is interesting to note that the equivalent gure in Grubel (2005) was $6,294, suggesting

    that the more reliable data on immigrants relative incomes and tax payments did not have

    a signicant impact on the estimate, though it might have been expected that the growth

    in average income and government spending during the ve additional years covered in

    the present study would have increased this number. But, this should be oset by the act

    that using all Canadians instead o other Canadians to calculate the amount o the scal

    transer tends to understate its amount.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    23/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 13

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    emigrated or died. However, because o emigration and mortality, o those 3.9

    million immigrants only 2.7 million still remained in Canada according to the

    2006 Census, a representative sample o which is ound in the PUMF database

    used in the basic calculation o costs above.11 Te annual scal subsidies to

    these remaining immigrants in 2006 were $16.3 billion.12

    o put these gures into perspective, it is useul to consider them in

    relation to some program spending by the ederal government in 2006. Te

    larger o the estimates, $23.6 billion, is 4.7% o total program spending o

    $503 billion, 1.18 times the cost o government services o $20 billion and

    1.79 times the spending on the environment o $13.2 billion. Using the lower

    estimate o $16.3 billion, the transers were 3.2%, 82% and 123% o the three

    selected ederal government spending gures, respectively.

    It is clear that the choice o the number o immigrants receiving scal

    transers made in the preceding calculations reects our judgement. We used

    the number o immigrants who have arrived in 1987 and later because it was

    ater Canadas controls on immigration were eased and the annual inow o

    immigrants was allowed to increase substantially. Tis is the group used in

    the compilation o the income and taxation statistics shown in table 1 and in

    the analysis presented in tables 2 and 3.

    It would also be quite deensible to use the number o immigrants who

    arrived over a longer time period, including those who arrived ater 2004 (i

    the data was available) and beore 1987. However, the purpose o our analysis

    is not to come up with the denitive estimate o the scal costs, but instead

    to show that Canadas current immigration policies are generating substan-

    tial scal transers rom all Canadians to recent immigrants. It is our hope

    that this will be sucient to encourage public discussion about the aord-

    ability o existing immigration policies and possible reorm proposals. And

    the need or this discussion will only become even more pressing over time

    as the size o the transers to immigrants will increase every year with the

    arrival o additional under-perorming cohorts o immigrants.

    11 An interesting issue is the extent to which the immigrants leaving Canada returned home

    or went on to greener pastures, perhaps in the United States. Tis is important because

    o its impact on the labour market perormance o immigrants. More research is needed

    on whether Canada is losing some o its most successul immigrants or only those who

    were unable to adapt to Canada. It would also be o interest to learn how many o these

    immigrants will return to Canada later in their lives to take advantage o Canadas gener-ous health and welare system.

    12 Te number or 2010 would be even higher as approximately another million immigrants

    (net) entered Canada over the period rom 2005 to 2009. I these immigrants and the

    predecessors continued to underperorm in the labour market as seems likely given the

    disproportionate impact o the recession on immigrants, another $5.9 billion could be

    added to the $16.3 billion, raising the net scal benets to immigrants net o emigrants

    in 2010 to $22.2 billion.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    24/62

    14 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    4 Other benefts and costs

    o immigration

    Many Canadians with whom we have discussed our estimates o the costs

    o current immigration policies have suggested that they represent only one

    part o the equation, neglecting some economic and social benets immi-

    grants bring to Canadians that are not included in the narrow estimate o

    scal transers to immigrants. Te nature and merit o these benets were

    discussed in Grubel (2005) and (2009). For readers not amiliar with these

    publications, we briey summarize, evaluate, and update the arguments here.

    Immigrants and their ofspring will eventually

    repay the scal transers they received

    Tis view is based on the notion that immigrants will repay the transers

    they have received once they are ully integrated into the economy and they

    and their children earn wages that are high enough. Clearly, the truth o this

    notion depends on how well the new Canadians and their children will do eco-

    nomically in the uture. I, in the uture, the average incomes o these immi-

    grants only just reach the average income o all Canadians, there will be no

    repayment o the transers since as a group they will only pay taxes that match

    the benets they receive. Immigrants will repay the transers only i they

    eventually earn signicantly more than average incomes or a period in their

    lives long enough to repay the earlier costs incurred on them. Unortunately,

    the available empirical evidence suggests that recent immigrants are not even

    closing the income gap with non-immigrants (Picot and Sweetman, 2005;

    Picot, 2008), a ar cry rom earning incomes above average.13

    13 Te statistical evidence on the persistence o immigrants low average earnings can be

    considered something o a surprise since Canada has used a points program or selection

    that puts heavy emphasis on educational attainment and language prociency and, as a

    result, has attracted disproportionately many immigrants who are proessionals with uni-

    versity education. However, in reality only a relatively small proportion (less than a th)

    o immigrants admitted are actually selected based on points and most are members orthe amilies o skill-class immigrants or amily-class immigrants.

    Attempts to explain this phenomenon point to the act that Canadian proessional

    associations oten do not accept the educational background o immigrants unless they

    pass examinations establishing their competence. Many immigrants do not pass these

    examinations and have to work in lower-paid occupations where the value o their

    human capital depreciates and they get caught in a low-wage trap that is extremely

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    25/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 15

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    Te ospring o immigrants are also not likely to repay the scal costs

    their parents have imposed on Canadians. Te reason is that, as these o-

    spring tend to integrate ully into Canadian society, their economic character-

    istics and average incomes tend to become the same as those o all Canadians.

    Tey receive on average benets equal to their average income and tax pay-

    ments so that they generate no scal surpluses.14 And there is no guarantee

    that this will happen even or the next generation i they are too disadvan-

    taged rom the onset by their parents low incomes.

    Immigrants are needed to solve the problem

    o ununded liabilities o social programs

    Te ununded liabilities o Canadas social programs are caused by low birth

    rates and the aging o the population, which were not expected when they

    were introduced in the years ater the Second World War. Te argument in

    avour o more immigrants to solve this problem is deceptively simple and

    appealing. Young immigrants will pay taxes that can be used to pay or the

    unds going to the elderly recipients o social program benets.

    Unortunately, while this simple argument is true in principle, it

    misses the magnitude o the existing problem, which has been studied by

    considering the best estimates o uture birth and death rates o Canadians

    and exploring what happens to the age structure o the population and the

    dicult to exit. And all o this is being exacerbated by the impact o the recent reces-

    sion, which has hit new immigrants and other recent entrants to the labour orce much

    harder than more established workers.

    Controversies exist over the causes o the ailure o highly educated immigrants to

    land jobs in Canada that are consistent with their qualications. One o the reasons maybe that the proessional associations set tests that discriminate against oreign educational

    attainments. Another may be that the quality o education obtained by the immigrants

    abroad does not meet Canadian standards or that potential employers do not know the

    quality o education provided by the degree-granting institutions and are unwilling to

    take the risk that the quality is low. Yet another possible explanation is that some o the

    certicates o educational attainment are bogus and that the Canadian ocials in charge

    o disqualiying individuals with such certicates have insucient resources to do so

    eectively. Chances are that all o these explanations o the poor economic record o

    highly skilled immigrants contribute to the phenomenon. Tere are thus many dicul-

    ties that must be overcome in any attempt to correct the situation.

    14It might also be noted that the issue o repayment o the scal burden is complicatedby the act that it is imposed on one generation o Canadians, which would not benet

    even i the ospring o the immigrants were to earn above-average incomes. Te scal

    surpluses thus generated would go to another generation o Canadians, which may or

    may not experience a reduction in immigration or the selection o immigrants that have

    above-average incomes and thus do not impose a scal burden on it. Tis possibility raises

    issues o the airness o intergenerational transers.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    26/62

    16 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    resultant dependency ratio (number o retired persons receiving pensions

    and requiring costly medical care relative to the number o persons working

    and paying taxes). One study o the issue is by Statistics Canada and comes

    to the ollowing conclusion:

    Even a substantial increase in the number o immigrants could not

    stop Canadas population aging. For example, i Canada was to admit

    our times as many immigrants per year, the populations median age

    would still increase, rom the current 38.8 to 44.1 years in 2056. Tis

    would mean an average o about one million immigrants per year or

    the next 50 years. Regardless, the proportion o seniors would increase

    rom the current 12.3% to 22.3% in 2056. (Statistics Canada, 2006: 6)

    In another study, Banerjee and Robson (2009) consider what number o

    immigrants would be required to maintain the current 0.2 dependency ratio

    (there are 20 retirees who receive benets rom the taxes paid by every 100

    workers). In one section o their study, they assume that uture immigrants on

    average are only 22 years old, which is an age that would make them long-term

    contributors to the unds needed to nance social benets or retirees. While

    it may be impossible to nd enough immigrants o this age, the assumption

    provides a powerul insight into the magnitude o the problem o ununded

    liabilities caused by the aging population and low birthrate.

    ellingly, Banerjee and Robsons calculations show that to maintain

    the dependency ratio at 0.2 until 2050, the annual rate o immigration would

    have to average about 2% o the population (it has been about 0.75% in recent

    years). Tis rate o immigration would raise Canadas population to 139 mil-

    lion in 2050 and the number o immigrants would be 1.8 million that year

    alone. In another calculation, they assume that the selection o immigrants

    continues to bring in immigrants with the same age characteristics as are

    produced under the present system. Tey nd that under these assumptions

    the maintenance o the dependency ratio would result in a population o 235

    million in 2050.

    Tese studies clearly indicate that immigration cannot solve the prob-

    lems likely to be caused by the aging o Canadas population. Te number

    o immigrants required would seriously tax the countrys ability to absorb

    them in the economy and society. It would also be very dicult to nd the

    required number o immigrants with the desired skills, education, and age,especially since in traditional source countries ertility is in decline and eco-

    nomic opportunities and incomes are rising rapidly.

    It can be argued that, while increased immigration cannot solve the

    problems o population aging and low ertility rates in Canada, it can at least

    make a contribution. However, as the simulations show, even small reduc-

    tions in population ageing require greatly increased rates o immigration;

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    27/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 17

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    and, as Banerjee and Robson point out, there are other, more ecient ways

    to decrease the size o ununded liabilities o the countrys social programs.

    Te best o these involves increasing the average age o retirement gradually

    by just two to three years.

    Te most obvious solution to the problem lies in an increase in the

    ertility rate o Canadians to the level o 2.1 children per woman, which is

    required or long-run stability o the population. Past attempts by govern-

    ments to increase ertility rates have not been successul, but it is interest-

    ing to speculate whether reduced immigration rates would do so. Consider

    that Canadians o child-bearing age weigh many actors when they decide

    on the number o children they wish to have. wo o these actors undoubt-

    edly are the cost o housing and concerns about the environment. As noted

    above, both o these actors are increased by the mass immigration that

    results rom present policies over many years. Tereore, it is possible that

    reduced immigration would raise the ertility rate o Canadians, and that

    could lower or even solve the countrys problem o ununded liabilities o

    social programs.

    Immigrants are needed to ll job vacancies

    Employers in Canada are strongly in avour o present high rates o immigra-

    tion because they consider immigrants to be an attractive source o workers

    to ll the low-paying jobs that Canadians do not seem to want or jobs that

    require high levels o skills and training that are scarce among Canadians. It

    is not possible to ault employers or taking this position. Tey are rightly

    concerned with the bottom-line o their businesses and they are entitled to

    lobby or policies to improve it.

    However, what is good or business is not necessarily always good or

    Canadians in general, especially i benets or business are paid or by the

    general public through higher taxes, as is the case with immigrants that ll

    the low-paying jobs and induce scal transers under the provisions o the

    welare state. Te public is repaid in part or these subsidies by lower pro-

    duction costs that are passed on to consumers through lower prices o goods

    and services. An empirical study is needed to establish whether taxpayers as

    consumers benet or lose in the process, but there is a strong presumption

    that they lose because government subsidies in any orm induce the ine-

    cient use o resources.

    Another aspect o the relationship between the need to ll job vacan-cies and immigration is that immigrants add to the demand or labour because

    o the purchases they make and demand or inrastructure they create. In this

    context, it is important to realize that in any dynamic market economy, there

    are temporary shortages and surpluses o labour, simply because o the exist-

    ence o business cycles, which have aficted market economies throughout

    history, even when the role o governments in the economy was minimal.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    28/62

    18 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    In addition, temporary shortages are aggravated by the length o time

    required to educate and train workers, especially or occupations requiring

    high levels o skill. Te labour shortages can be alleviated by migrants, but

    present immigration policies ail to vary immigration levels according to

    conditions in the business cycle and do not repatriate immigrants that are

    no longer needed during periods o high unemployment. o the contrary,

    under present policies, immigrants add to unemployment i they arrive when

    unemployment is high.

    Te question is, whether in the absence o immigration, Canada would

    suer rom a permanent shortage o workers. Economic theory suggests

    that such permanent shortages would not persist. I, or instance, workers

    in the garbage collection industry, which is sometimes cited as an industry

    with job vacancies Canadians do not want to ll, cannot be ound, employers

    would raise wage rates until the vacant jobs are lled. Employers would end

    up with the same rates o prot though, because they would adopt labour

    saving capital and the producers o the capital would come up with new

    technologies that would save even more labour and raise the skill level o

    the job. Teir prots would also be maintained as they pass on some o the

    higher labour costs to the consumers o their services. Tese higher costs

    in turn would induce consumers to reduce their need or garbage collection

    so that in the end, an ecient equilibrium in demand, supply, prices, and

    wages would be achieved.

    A similar process o adjustment as that described or low-skill and

    low-wage jobs would occur in industries that have vacancies or jobs requir-

    ing high levels o education and training. In the absence o immigrant work-

    ers, wages would rise and induce more Canadians to get the needed edu-

    cation and training until the shortages are eliminated. And, Canada does

    have an educational and training system capable o producing the required

    skilled workers.

    It is ironic that, under the present system that lls job vacancies with

    immigrants, there exists the possibility that immigration does not eliminate

    labour shortages but perversely worsens them. Te reason is that immigrants

    add to the demand or goods, services, and government inrastructure and

    other services. No empirical studies o this phenomenon have been made but

    it is interesting to note that the number o recent immigrants who have settled

    in Vancouver during the ve-year period rom 2005 to 2009 is 180,846,15 or

    36,169 per year, which comes to about 3,000 per month. I we assume thatthe average amily size o these immigrants is three, then there are 1,000 am-

    ilies requiring the construction o new dwelling units per month or about 250

    15 Te numbers used in this paragraph are ound in Citizenship and Immigration Canada,

    2010: Permanent residents, .

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    29/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 19

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    every week.16 Furthermore, these immigrant amilies add to the demand or

    spaces in schools, universities, hospitals, transit acilities, airports, roads, and

    bridges. Te construction o all o these acilities requires labour and creates

    labour shortages that in turn will be lled by even more immigrants that will

    require more construction, and so on in a never-ending cycle.

    Immigrants are needed or economic growth

    Immigrants increase the growth o aggregate national income and output,

    which is oten argued to be a desirable end in itsel. More sophisticated argu-

    ments are that such growth raises Canadas inuence in the world and that

    it results in dynamics that encourage growth by stimulating change and a

    general belie in progress. In act, maximizing aggregate national income is

    a totally inappropriate goal o government immigration policies. Te ocus

    should instead be on maximizing immigrations eects on per-capita income

    and thus living standards.1 o illustrate this point, it could be noted that ew

    Canadians would preer to live in China, which has the second highest aggre-

    gate national income but still has living standards, measured as per-capita

    GDP, o less than a tenth o Canadas.

    Te main nding o this study is that in recent years the low average

    incomes o immigrants in combination with the provisions o the welare

    state have reduced the average per-capita incomes o Canadians. Te issue

    thereore is whether a larger aggregate income osets these reductions in

    per-capita income because o the benets derived rom greater inuence

    in world aairs and the benecial dynamics that eed back on growth itsel.

    Te idea that the average Canadian puts value on the act that the

    country has more inuence on world aairs has not been tested empirically

    but, even i this were the case, it is sae to suggest that it is not as import-

    ant as the level o income. Te idea that aggregate economic growth driven

    16 In 2009, the number o principal skilled immigrants into Canada was 40,735. Tey

    were accompanied by their immediate amily o spouses and dependents numbering

    55,227. During the same year, 46,921 spouses, dependents, and older children arrived

    in Canada to join their spouses who earlier had arrived as skilled immigrants. Te total

    number o persons related to the 40,735 skilled immigrants thereore was 40,735 +

    55,227 + 46,921 = 142,983. Tis number implies an average amily size o 3.5 or the

    40,735 skilled immigrants.

    Tis calculation is merely illustrative since it does not account or the act that theamily reunication immigrants join skilled immigrants who had arrived in earlier years

    and that 17,179 parents and grandparents o skilled immigrants and their spouses arrived

    in 2009 and are likely to have joined their ospring in their dwellings. Available data does

    not permit these renements to the calculations to be made.

    17 A committee o Britains Upper House o Parliament criticized the Labour government

    or misleading the public by justiying its high immigration policies on the grounds that

    they raise total national income (Green, 2009).

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    30/62

    20 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    by high population increases leads to higher per-capita income involves the

    complicated and inconclusive empirical ndings o the theory and literature

    o economic growth.

    Moreover, per-capita income is only an imperect measure o living

    standards. Non-monetary actors like the pollution and congestion that

    increase with population growth and have negative eects on living standards

    also should be taken into account. I these determinants o living standards

    were properly reected in measures o living standards, the countries with

    low population growth could easily have higher real per-capita well-being

    than those with higher population growth. So or the purposes at hand, su-

    ce it to say that there is no conclusive evidence that a larger Canada would

    be better and would benet existing Canadians.

    Miscellaneous benets

    A nal set o benets oten mentioned in discussions over immigration poli-

    cies involves non-economic actors. One such idea is that, as citizens o a rich

    nation o caring individuals, Canadians are ennobled by allowing people rom

    the rest o the world to share the countrys economic riches, political stability,

    and tolerance and by allowing them to escape the misery ound in their own

    countries. While it is not possible to put any dollar value on such eel-good

    benets stemming rom our current immigration policies, it is legitimate to

    note that it comes at a considerable scal cost and that the same number o

    poor oreigners could be helped at a much lower cost through traditional

    oreign-aid programs. Canadas oreign assistance is budgeted at $5 billion in

    scal year 2010/2011, just over 30% o our estimate o the net scal transer

    to recent immigrants. Tese bilateral and international aid programs do not

    require the relocation o individuals that disrupt their lives, separate am-

    ilies, and bring large costs or taxpayers needed to assist immigrants settling

    in Canada.

    Another benet rom immigration oten mentioned is that it enriches

    the cultural lie o Canadians. Te value o this eel-good benet also is impos-

    sible to measure but it is legitimate to note that Canadians already enjoy an

    abundance o ethnic restaurants and estivals and that urther increases are

    likely to bring relatively smaller additional benets.

    A nal benet rom immigration oten mentioned is that a tolerant

    multicultural society nourished by immigrants is better than the Eurocentric

    society that existed beore the 1970s. Tis view is deeply entrenched in theminds o many Canadians and is a source o pride. However, as important

    research has shown, there are grounds or concern that the multicultural-

    ism existing in Canada carries with it threats to national unity, culture, and

    security,18 as well as the scal costs documented above.

    18 For a ull discussion o these issues, see Gallagher, 2009 and Mansur, 2009.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    31/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 21

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    Other costs: efects on poverty

    Canadians are concerned about the distribution o income, especially the

    proportion o amilies that have incomes below what Statistics Canada

    denes as the low-incomes cut o (LICO) levels.19 Unortunately, under the

    present immigrant selection system, large proportions o immigrants have

    incomes that are below the poverty line or prolonged periods ater their

    arrival in Canada. Tis act is documented in a study by Statistics Canada

    (Picot, Lu and Hou, 2009), the results o which are presented in table 4.

    Te data in this table shows that, based on market income, in 2005

    the poverty rate among Canadian-born was 23.2% while it was 32.7% among

    all immigrants. Tese gures imply that rate o poverty among immigrants

    was 60% greater than among Canadian-born. Te corresponding gures or

    income ater transers and beore taxes were 13.3% and 21.6%, respectively,

    indicating that the governments policies to reduce poverty are having the

    desired eect. However, the excess o poverty among immigrants under this

    denition o income remains at 60%.

    Te table also shows that the share o immigrants among Canadians

    with low income decreases with the length o time immigrants are in Canada

    and that ater 20 years in the country, immigrants have the same poverty rate

    as the Canadian-born. Tis desirable eect is due to the eorts o immigrants

    to improve their language and other skills needed to be successul in the

    labour market. However, again there is no guarantee that this will continue

    to happen in the uture at the same pace. Burton and Phipps (2009: 45)

    have ound that the position o children coming rom low-income amilies in

    the income distribution exhibited considerable stickiness and that this was

    exacerbated by their being non-white as are the greater majority o recent

    immigrants. However, it is clear that during the 19 years o above-average

    poverty rates, these immigrants receive above average amounts o benets

    aimed at reducing poverty. Te costs o these payments are a component o

    the scal burden estimated above.

    Note that these estimates are biased downward since they do not take

    account o the act that the immigrants with incomes below the poverty line

    tend to have low skills. Tey compete with Canadian-born workers with low

    skills and depress the wages they earn. As a result, the level o poverty among

    Canadian-born and the benets they are provided with are greater than they

    would be without the competition or jobs stemming rom the immigrants.

    Te act that poverty rates among immigrants relative to those amongthe Canadian-born do not continue to decrease ater 20 years provides

    indirect evidence that, ater initial periods o learning and labour market

    19 We cannot enter here into a discussion about the shortcomings o the LICO index as

    a measure o poverty. For a ull discussion o dierent denitions and measurement o

    poverty, see Sarlo, 1996.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    32/62

    22 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    integration, the economic perormance o immigrants generally is the same as

    that o other Canadians. I indeed this proposition is correct under the most

    optimistic o assumptions, it ollows that on average they pay taxes equal to

    the benets they receive, just as all Canadians do. Te immigrants, thereore,

    do not ultimately pay enough taxes to compensate Canadians or the scal

    costs they imposed during the 19 years when their economic perormance

    was below average. And, there is real risk that the continuing deterioration

    o the perormance o recent immigrants in the labour market could result in

    the end o the convergence that has heretoore characterized the Canadian

    immigration experience.

    Table 4: Low income-rates, Immigrants and Canadian-born, 2005 (Percent o all income earners)

    () () () () () () () ()

    Canadian-born

    Allimmigrants

    Years since immigration

    or less +

    Market income

    Percent . . . . . . .

    Ratio (3) (8)/(2) . . . . . .

    Ater transers, beore taxes

    Percent . . . . . . .

    Ratio (3) (8)/(2) . . . . . .

    Source: Picot, Lu and Hou, 9.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    33/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 23

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    5 Policy recommendations

    Beore turning to our proposals or changes in Canadian immigration poli-

    cies owing rom the ndings just presented, we wish to introduce some

    ideas that should enter into decisions about changes to immigration policies.

    First, most Canadians are happy to live with the welare state that redis-

    tributes income rom the rich to the poor, be they the unemployed, the sick,

    or the elderly. But the transers to immigrants are altogether dierent rom

    those to needy Canadians. Until they arrive at our borders, immigrants are

    oreigners and not part o the Canadian social contract that guides the welare

    state provisions. Immigrants are only here because we allow them to come, so

    that the scal burdens they impose can be attributed to our deliberate deci-

    sion to allow them to become landed immigrants. By the same token, we are

    ree to stop these scal burdens on ourselves i we choose to do so either by

    changing immigration policies or by severely limiting immigrants access to

    the benets o the welare state.

    Second, it is important to consider that Canadians have the right to

    limit access to the countrys social institutions, income, and wealth that they

    and their ancestors have created. In a sense, Canada is like a private club

    (Gibson, 2009), whose members have the right to exclude others rom shar-

    ing in its benets without proper compensation to existing members. Clubs

    do not allow non-members just to enter the premises and use the acilities.

    Nor do they allow individual members to grant the ree use o club privileges

    to outsiders just because it suits them. What is right or clubs in the minds

    o most Canadians should also be right or Canada.

    Tird, in a ree society like Canadas, individuals decide to maximize

    their well-being by considering choices they ace with regard to their work,

    spending, investment, and many other issues. One o these choices involves

    the number o children they wish to raise. Into this decision enter personal

    preerences, but also considerations about the eect that their children will

    have on the size o the countrys population, congestion, pollution, climate

    change, and overall quality o lie or themselves and the country and world

    as a whole. Te government o Canada should be obligated to respect the

    population growth that results rom the decisions made by Canadians andshould not change it without much more public consultation than has ever

    taken place concerning these consequences o population growth.20

    Finally, the precarious scal conditions o Canadian governments

    caused by short-run cyclical decits and, more important in the long run, by

    20 Tis idea is ound and discussed more deeply in Krikorian, 2008.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    34/62

    24 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    the ununded liabilities o social programs, give special urgency to the dis-

    cussion o immigration policies at the beginning o the second decade o the

    twenty-rst century. Changes in immigration policies can contribute to the

    alleviation, or possibly even the elimination, o scal decits. imely steps

    to curtail urther increases in the scal burdens imposed by poorly selected

    immigrants will reduce scal pressures on governments and curb the growth

    o underunded liabilities o social programs such as health and pensions. Te

    money saved could be used to lower taxes or reduce debt rom what they would

    be otherwise and ultimately to meet the scal demands o an aging population.

    Changes to immigration policies

    Changes in immigration policies have proound and complex eects on the

    economy, society, and culture. Tey need to be discussed publicly and widely.

    Indeed they should ultimately be subjected to a public reerendum or become

    a major issue in regular elections beore being enacted by parliament. Te

    changes to Canadas existing immigration policies that we propose are oered

    as a starting point or such discussions.

    As a general and important point, we want to make it clear that our

    proposed policies are not designed explicitly to reduce or move to zero the

    level o immigration. Tey are thus not anti-immigration. Rather they are

    aimed solely at eliminating the scal burden imposed on Canadians through

    current policies. As will be seen below, under our proposed policy changes,

    the number and composition o immigrants will be determined largely by

    market orces. Overall immigration levels could, in theory, increase, decrease,

    or remain unchanged. But whatever the new levels may turn out to be, they

    will prevent urther increases in the size o the existing scal burden.

    Te system or selecting immigrants to Canada proposed below repre-

    sents a radical reorm o Canadas existing immigration system. It shares some

    eatures with N status used relatively successully under the NAFA treaty

    signed by Canada, Mexico, and the United States. Under it, nationals o one

    o the signatory countries who possess specied skills and have valid oers o

    employment are allowed to take up residence in either o the other countries

    through a grant o N status (which or Mexicans requires a visa). Tis N

    status, which is initially or three years, can be renewed a number o times or

    even indenitely. However, it does not lead to permanent residency or green

    card status and thus does not qualiy the individual and his or her dependants

    to become immigrants in the traditional sense and ultimately to acquire cit-izenship. Holders o temporary work visas or status who become and remain

    unemployed or a specied time can be required to leave the country.21 Our

    21 Our proposal is also consistent with recommendations made by Sweetman (2004) and

    in the OECDs report on Canadas immigration system: Canadian immigration policy

    could make greater use o temporary work permits (2003: 123). Since this report was

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    35/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 25

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    proposal also bears some similarities with the existing emporary Foreign

    Worker Program (FWP), which has been expanded to cover growing num-

    bers o highly skilled and educated. But again the FWP does not include a

    generally available ormal pathway to permanent residency status (the Canada

    Experience Class, however, does allow FWs and students to apply or perma-

    nent residency status rom inside Canada).

    Te ollowing specic proposals contain time lines and other discrete

    criteria that in most cases are made provisionally and need to be discussed

    widely beore they are ready to be embodied in legislation. Readers should

    keep this act in mind and ocus on the merit o the general objectives o, and

    principles underlying, the proposed policies.

    1 Entry into Canada or settlement is granted only to oreigners who have a valid

    oer or employment in Canada in occupations specied in a list created by

    the ederal government with the assistance o private-sector employers. All

    the grounds or granting immigrant visas presently in place are to be discon-

    tinued, except those applicable to reugee claimants, which are largely set

    by international treaty obligations and will not be discussed here. And, the

    emporary Foreign Worker Program would, o course, also be replaced by

    our proposed new program,22 as would the Provincial Nominee Programs

    negotiated with most provincial governments.

    2 Applicants with valid job oers will receive temporary work visas or them-

    selves and visitors visas or their dependants. Te work visas will be valid

    or two years or as long as the oreigners remain employed and they can be

    extended or two more years. Te loss o employment is cause or deporta-

    tion ater a grace period o three months to nd a new job.

    3 Ater the end o our years, and unlike under the FWP, the oreigners admit-

    ted can become landed immigrants with all the rights and obligations

    accorded this type o visa presently. Landed immigrants become eligible to

    apply or ull citizenship two years ater they achieve this status.

    The role o government

    Te governments role in the operation o the proposed temporary work visa

    system is limited to:

    written with much input rom the government o Canada, it probably reects the views

    o inuential civil servants and politicians.

    22 Te rationale or the existence o other temporary worker programs should also be re-

    examined. While some, such as the Seasonal Agricultural Worker Program, seem to be

    working as intended, others like the Live-in Caregiver Program have been subject to abuse.

    But again a detailed assessment o these programs is beyond the scope o the present paper.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    36/62

    26 / Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    Fraser Institute / www.fraserinstitute.org

    1 speciying occupations or which temporary work visas are issued;

    2 excluding applicants likely to become a burden on the public health care sys-

    tem and/or a threat to national security;

    3 setting up and supervising a privately run system or the collection o inorma-

    tion about the residence and work status o holders o temporary work visas;

    4 ensuring that those holding work visas ollow the prescribed rules and enorc-

    ing rules or deportation.23

    Proposals in detail

    Te ollowing set o recommendations eshes out the basic ideas just pre-

    sented. O course, the devil is in the details, and many additional details

    would need to be worked out in actual legislation.

    1 Te issuance o temporary work visas (WVs) or entry into Canada requires

    documentation proving that the applicant has a legitimate job oer rom an

    employer in Canada and that the oer is or work specied in a list compiled

    and kept current by the government.

    2 Work visas will be issued by a Canadian embassy abroad or citizens o all

    countries other than the United States, who can obtain the visa at border

    points o entry.

    3 Te work visa is valid or two years. It can be renewed or an unlimited num-

    ber o times, or two years each time, upon presentation o evidence o con-

    tinued employment.

    4 Ater our years in Canada and continued employment, the holders o WVs

    can obtain permanent immigrant visas. Landed immigrants will be eligible

    to apply or citizenship two years later.

    23 Tis raises the issue o the governments ability to deport immigrants in Canada on WVswho do not comply with the terms o the visa. Te government has been trying to deal

    with this issue in the case o reugees. Unless some reasonably expeditious way o remov-

    ing oreigners rom the country can be arrived at, it will be extremely dicult, i not

    impossible, to impose any system o border controls on the inow o people rom abroad.

    One possibility that has been put orward is the use o the notwithstanding clause in the

    immigration legislation to remove the ull range o legal appeals right up to the Supreme

    Court guaranteed under the Charter o Rights and Freedoms.

    http://www.fraserinstitute.org/http://www.fraserinstitute.org/
  • 8/6/2019 Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011

    37/62

    Immigration and the Canadian Welfare State 2011 / 27

    www.fraserinstitute.org / Fraser Institute

    5 Te spouses and dependents o the holders o WVs may enter Canada under a

    program o amily work visas (FWVs), which allow them to accept employment.

    6 Te holders o WVs who lose their jobs must nd new employment within

    three months or leave Canada, unless the spouse is employed under the

    FWV provision.

    7 Investors and entrepreneurs who can document that they own at least $1

    million24 that they want to invest in Canada are eligible or investor work

    visas (IWVs) valid or two years, renewable biannually and allowing con-

    version into immigrant visas ater our years. Renewal o the IWV requires

    documentation that investments worth at least $1 million have been made in

    Canada and that the investor has led Canadian income-tax returns. Failure

    to provide evidence o an investment means that the investor is required to

    leave Canada within three months o the determination.

    Te radicial aspect o the proposed temporary employment visa program is

    that it is designed to eliminate the existing need or government employees

    to make judgments about the eligibility o applicants or immigrant visas that

    are based on documents o questionable value that the applicants submit. It

    also eliminates the need or government employees to make judgments about

    whether an applicant has the personal characteristics to succeed economi-

    cally in Canada. Instead, Canadian employers will make these judgments

    beore they issue employment contracts, having properly evaluated the suit-

    ability o the immigrants education, work experience, and language skills or

    success in the job.25 Tese employers are motivated by their own sel-interest

    to make the right decisions as wrong decisions lead to nancial losses and

    endanger the very existence o the employers enterprises. Tese nancial

    losses could be reinorced by penalties or a