governance structure and the creation and protection of ... · joint ventures in china jiatao li1...

26
RESEARCH PAPER Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of Technological Competencies: International R&D Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li 1 Zhenzhen Xie 2 Received: 26 October 2013 / Revised: 19 August 2015 / Accepted: 27 October 2015 / Published online: 27 November 2015 Ó Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2015 Abstract International research and development (R&D) joint ventures have been widely used by multinational enterprises (MNEs) to enhance knowledge creation in a global network of foreign subsidiaries while at the same time, managing the critical task of protecting the knowledge transferred and created. In emerging economies where institutions for protecting intellectual properties are likely to be weak, equity joint ventures (EJVs) are often used to meet the needs for knowledge protection by aligning the interests of partners in collaboration. However, the advantages of using EJVs come at a price—higher organizational cost and lack of flexibility. This study suggests two key factors that would affect the choice of EJVs as a risk-mitigating mechanism in protecting technological competencies: the scope of R&D activities and the types of joint venture (JV) partners. We propose that MNEs can reduce their use of EJVs when the scope of R&D activities is limited to research-oriented ones or when academic institutions are chosen as local partners. Furthermore, a large cultural distance between the host and home countries of MNEs tends to strengthen these effects. Collecting data from China Business Review, Business China, and the LexisNexis and Proquest databases, the authors conducted an empirical test with data on 319 international R&D JVs established in China during 1995–2002. The results largely support these hypotheses. Keywords R&D internationalization Joint venture Entry mode Partner choice R&D scope China & Jiatao Li [email protected] Zhenzhen Xie [email protected] 1 Department of Management, School of Business and Management, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Kowloon, Hong Kong SAR 2 Department of Innovation, Entrepreneurship and Strategy, School of Economics and Management, Tsinghua University, Beijing, China 123 Manag Int Rev (2016) 56:123–148 DOI 10.1007/s11575-015-0268-1

Upload: others

Post on 23-May-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

RESEARCH PAPER

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protectionof Technological Competencies: International R&DJoint Ventures in China

Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2

Received: 26 October 2013 / Revised: 19 August 2015 / Accepted: 27 October 2015 /

Published online: 27 November 2015

� Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2015

Abstract International research and development (R&D) joint ventures have been

widely used by multinational enterprises (MNEs) to enhance knowledge creation in a

global network of foreign subsidiaries while at the same time, managing the critical task

of protecting the knowledge transferred and created. In emerging economies where

institutions for protecting intellectual properties are likely to be weak, equity joint

ventures (EJVs) are often used to meet the needs for knowledge protection by aligning

the interests of partners in collaboration. However, the advantages of using EJVs come at

a price—higher organizational cost and lack of flexibility. This study suggests two key

factors that would affect the choice of EJVs as a risk-mitigating mechanism in protecting

technological competencies: the scope of R&D activities and the types of joint venture

(JV) partners. We propose that MNEs can reduce their use of EJVs when the scope of

R&D activities is limited to research-oriented ones or when academic institutions are

chosen as local partners. Furthermore, a large cultural distance between the host and

home countries of MNEs tends to strengthen these effects. Collecting data from China

Business Review, Business China, and the LexisNexis and Proquest databases, the

authors conducted an empirical test with data on 319 international R&D JVs established

in China during 1995–2002. The results largely support these hypotheses.

Keywords R&D internationalization � Joint venture � Entry mode � Partner

choice � R&D scope � China

& Jiatao Li

[email protected]

Zhenzhen Xie

[email protected]

1 Department of Management, School of Business and Management, Hong Kong University of

Science and Technology, Kowloon, Hong Kong SAR

2 Department of Innovation, Entrepreneurship and Strategy, School of Economics and

Management, Tsinghua University, Beijing, China

123

Manag Int Rev (2016) 56:123–148

DOI 10.1007/s11575-015-0268-1

Page 2: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

1 Introduction

Multinational enterprises (MNEs) have increasingly been internationalizing their

R&D activities to: (1) take advantage of host country scientific and technological

inputs, and (2) respond to local market needs and innovate closer to their product

markets and manufacturing facilities (Arvanitis and Hollenstein 2011; Belderbos

2003; Li and Xie 2011; Li and Zhong 2003; Luo 2006). Specifically, by engaging in

international R&D joint ventures (JVs), MNEs are able to focus on and invest in a

few areas of core competencies, to leverage the resources and capabilities of local

partners in other areas, and to reduce the uncertainty inherent in operating in

unfamiliar foreign business environments (Dunning 1994; Frankort et al. 2012;

Marin and Siotis 2008). Despite these advantages, the efforts made by MNEs to

develop new technological competencies through international R&D JVs, such as

by transferring and recombining knowledge, are likely to put their technological

competencies at risk of misappropriation (Evangelista and Hau 2009; Li et al. 2008;

Rivkin 2001). This creates tension between the creation and the protection of

technological competencies abroad. MNEs have been found to use equity joint

ventures (EJVs) to manage this tension. Compared with contract-based governance

structures, equity-based ones can help align the interests of the partners and thus

better protect technological competencies from potential misappropriation by

opportunistic partners (Che and Facchini 2009; Garcia-Canal et al. 2008; Hennart

1988; Li and Xie 2011; Pisano 1989).

However, compared with contract-based joint ventures (CJVs), EJVs incur

greater organizational cost and provide less flexibility (Dussauge and Garette 1999;

Hagedoorn 1993; Kogut 1988; Porter 1987). This could become a critical issue as

the importance of flexibility and adaptability for MNEs’ global success continues to

grow in the increasingly uncertain world (Koza et al. 2011). Thus, when the risk of

knowledge misappropriation is lower, MNEs tend to replace EJVs with CJVs.

Previous literature suggests that the risk of knowledge misappropriation is reduced

by MNEs through (1) limiting the scope of R&D activities (Li et al. 2008; Oxley

and Sampson 2004); or (2) choosing appropriate JV partner(s) who are not likely to

become direct competitors (Kang and Kang 2010; Li et al. 2008).

Unfortunately, prior research has not adequately addressed the following two

concerns. First, besides the advantages over CJVs in terms of knowledge protection,

EJVs are also good at facilitating knowledge sharing and transfer in international

R&D JVs by providing a more stable structure and more frequent interactions

between more committed partners (Jiang and Li 2009; Phene and Tallman 2012).

While CJVs may replace EJVs to increase partnership flexibility when the concern

over knowledge protection is reduced, they may still reduce the effectiveness of the

partnership if the partners do not value the flexibility offered by the contract-based

governance structure. Therefore, when MNEs consider replace EJV with CJV, they

need to take into account not only knowledge protection but also the importance of

flexibility in knowledge creation. This has not been adequately addressed in

previous literature. Second, prior research has largely ignored the heterogeneity

among partnerships. Because EJVs may suffer from higher organizational costs than

124 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 3: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

CJVs, the use of EJVs will most likely be reduced for those partnerships that suffer

more organizational costs, especially when the concern over knowledge protection

is reduced with limited scope of R&D activities or less opportunistic partners.

The current paper tries to fill these gaps by investigating how MNEs chose

governance structures in international R&D JVs in China from both the perspective

of knowledge protection and knowledge creation. Since the inputs and outputs of

research-oriented R&D activities are less likely to be subject to appropriation risks,

and the high uncertainty involved in research-oriented knowledge creation process

requires high flexibility in partnerships, CJV is a better governance structure than

EJV when an R&D JV focuses on research-oriented activities. Since academic

institutions are usually less opportunistic partners, and the divergence in long-term

objectives between academic institutions and MNEs increases the importance of

flexibility considerations in partnerships, CJV is a better governance structure than

EJV when the local partner is academic. Therefore, MNEs are less likely to adopt

equity-based governance structure in an international R&D JV when it focuses on

research-oriented activities or an academic local partner is chosen. Furthermore,

since the cultural distance between the host and home countries of MNEs tends to

increase EJVs’ organizational costs substantially (Pothukuchi et al. 2002), it is

likely to reduce MNEs’ preference for EJVs and increase the likelihood of EJVs

being replaced with CJVs when an R&D JV focuses on research-oriented activities

or an academic local partner is chosen. Data on 319 international R&D JVs

established in China during 1995–2002 largely support these arguments.

2 Theoretical Framework

2.1 The Governance Structure of R&D Joint Ventures

JVs are defined as organizational units created ‘‘…when two or more firms pool a

portion of their resources within a common legal organization’’ (Kogut 1988,

p. 228). They can take the form of either EJV or CJV. Whether to collaborate with

local partners in R&D through an equity-based or a contract-based JV is an

important decision, since the two entry modes represent different degrees of control,

resource commitment, and risks (Anderson and Gatignon 1986; Hagedoorn 1993).

EJVs are legally and administratively independent from the parent firms, but are

similar to hierarchical organizational structures as the parents share control and

profit (Williamson 1996). Transaction cost economics (TCE) suggests that due to

the shared control and profit, the hierarchical structure provides a higher level of

behavior control and better protection of the technological competencies within

EJVs (Garcia-Canal et al. 2008; Hennart 1988). The knowledge-based view

suggests that due to the formal structure and stable interaction between partners,

EJVs facilitate knowledge sharing between partners, especially the tacit and

uncodified knowledge (Kogut 1988), which further benefits collaborative knowl-

edge creation (Jiang and Li 2009). However, the semi-independent status of EJVs at

the same time leads to greater organizational costs and less flexibility (Kogut 1988;

Porter 1987), greater risks of there being differing strategic objectives between

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 125

123

Page 4: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

partners (Dussauge and Garette 1999), and a higher failure rate in the long-run.

Firms today are embedded in an environment where chaos, uncertainty and risk are

pervasive (Koza et al. 2011). This makes adaptability and flexibility more critical

for knowledge creation, and the drawbacks of EJVs more detrimental.

Like EJVs, CJVs are also separate organizational units that involve the sharing of

resources and risks, and commitment from the parents. However, CJVs are more

market-like compared with EJVs and do not involve equity sharing. The terms and

conditions regarding the pattern of a CJV partner’s contribution, profit distribution

and management control are not based on equity investments of the partner, but the

result of ex ante negotiations between partners (Wang 2007). Based on TCE, this

reduces the protection of the technological competencies within CJVs due to lack of

ex post profit-sharing arrangement and hierarchy-like behavioral control. However,

according to resource-based perspective, CJVs reduce resource commitment and

offer more flexibility in R&D investment, which is especially valuable in rapidly

changing technological development (Hagedoorn 1993, 2002; Harrigan 1988; Koza

et al. 2011; Wang 2007). In recent years, CJVs have become popular among R&D

JVs and also more prevalent in industry-academy collaborations (Kuittinen et al.

2009; Schmoch 1999).

To sum up, the choice between EJV and CJV structures in R&D JVs resembles

the make-or-buy decision with regard to intellectual capital as innovation inputs and

outcomes (Pakes and Griliches 1984). An EJV structure (closer to a ‘‘make’’

decision) partially internalizes the transaction, protecting proprietary intellectual

inputs and outcomes of JVs and benefiting knowledge sharing. However, it is

subject to higher resource commitment, higher organizational costs and less

flexibility. A CJV structure (closer to a ‘‘buy’’ decision) gets access to partners’

resources through a more arm-length relationship with good flexibility, but tends to

put the proprietary intellectual inputs and outcomes at risk and may suffer some

difficulties in knowledge sharing (Collinson et al. 2005; Pisano 1990).

2.2 Research Objectives and Choice of Governance Structure

International R&D investments can be categorized as either research-oriented or

development-oriented (Li 2010; von Zedtwitz and Gassman 2002). Overseas

investments in development-oriented activities are generally driven by market

conditions abroad which make it necessary or advantageous to adapt products and/

or processes to the local market (Li 2010). Such overseas development is

exploitation-oriented in the sense that it is existing products and technologies that

are being customized (March 1991). By contrast, overseas investment in more basic

research is generally driven by scientific, technological or supply-related factors,

such as the supply of engineers and technical knowledge in the overseas location (Li

2010).

The risk of proprietary asset leakage is different for development-oriented and

research-oriented R&D projects. Development work usually involves transferring

relatively mature, well-codified, and ready to be commercialized knowledge to the

host country (Frankort et al. 2012). In general, the value of such knowledge is more

immediate discernible to potential competitors, who find this type of knowledge

126 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 5: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

easier to understand, imitate, and put into practice (Teece 1976; Zander and Kogut

1995). This makes the risk of leakage with development-oriented R&D higher, and

the damage caused by the leakage is likely to be serious. On the other hand, the

outcomes of more basic research are less mature, less codified, and therefore more

costly for competitors to understand, transfer, imitate and apply (Diericks and Cool

1989; Teece 1976). Even if the knowledge does leak, the local competitors’

absorptive capabilities and complementary assets may be too limited to make good

use of it (Cantwell and Colombo 2000). Therefore, the risk of leakage with research-

oriented R&D is smaller, and any damage caused by leakage is likely to be less

serious. This suggests that limiting the scope of R&D to more basic research help

reduce the concern over protecting both the input and output of knowledge.

Therefore, limiting the scope of R&D to basic research may reduce the need of

adopting the equity-based governance structure in protecting the technological

competence of international R&D JVs.

At the same time, since the input and output of research-oriented R&D activities

usually involve substantial uncertainty but less resource commitment (Frankort

et al. 2012; Freeman and Soete 1997), firms usually prefer more flexible governance

structure (Cyert and March 1963). Therefore, partners may prefer to organize

research-oriented R&D activities with CJVs rather than with EJVs not only due to

reduced concern over knowledge protection but also for the flexibility offered by the

contract-based governance structure. To sum up, when the R&D activities

conducted in an international R&D JV are restricted to those that are less likely

to be misappropriated by local competitors and can be better conducted in a more

flexible structure, such as basic research, MNEs are less likely to rely on EJVs for

knowledge protection and creation.

Hypothesis 1 (H1): Ceteris paribus, when a foreign R&D investment is

research-oriented, the EJV mode is less likely to be chosen for the R&D JV.

2.3 Partner Selection and Choice of Governance Structure

Partner selection has long been believed to be one of the critical decisions a firm

makes when engaging in any partnership (see, for example, Chand and Katou 2012;

Geringer 1991; Hitt et al. 1995; Koot 1988). However, not until recently was partner

selection considered a mechanism through which firms in an R&D partnership can

protect their technological competencies (Li et al. 2008). It was discovered that by

differentiating between friends, acquaintances and strangers when choosing

partners, firms in R&D JVs can ‘‘control the threat of knowledge leakage and

retain their core proprietary assets’’ (Li et al. 2008, p. 315). In this study, we focus

on the choice between academic institutions (i.r., universities and research

institutes) and firms as R&D JV partners.

Ever since the linear model of innovation was proposed (Bush 1945), there has been

little doubt that academic research contributes substantially to the knowledge stock

available within a wide variety of industries in any country. Mansfield (1998) found that

13–15 % of new product introductions in seven industries could have been delayed

without the relevant academic research. In a similar vein, Nelson (1993) concluded that

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 127

123

Page 6: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

in industrial sectors such as the chemical, pharmaceutical, and electronics sectors, the

countries with the most competitive firms were those that also had strong academic

research programs in those arenas. Since collaborations between industries and

academic institutions constitute great channels for academic R&D spillovers and

commercialization, governments around the world by all means encourage such

collaborations (Mowery 2011). However, previous studies have also suggested that

industry-academic collaborations usually require higher flexibility because of the

divergence in long-term orientation between firms and academic institutions (Busom

and Fernandez-Ribas 2008). Firms can also conflict with academic institutions over the

topics, the timing and the form of disclosure of R&D activities (Bruneel et al. 2010).

Although many academic institutions are shifting from long-term research to

near-term research and commercialization of research outputs as a result of the

reduction in public funding (Cohen et al. 1994; Mansfield 1998), academic

institutions as a whole are not primarily profit-driven. Their incentives for

misappropriating the proprietary assets of the JVs would be lower than those of

profit-driven firms (Martinez-Noya et al. 2013). In addition, since academic

institutions often lack the complementary facilities (e.g., manufacturing plants,

supply chains, selling channels) needed to exploit the proprietary assets of the JVs,

their capabilities for misappropriation are also likely to be lower (Martinez-Noya

et al. 2013; Teece 1986). Therefore, selecting academic institutions as partners in

R&D JVs help reduce the concern over knowledge protection of MNEs.

Reducing the risk of knowledge misappropriation, choosing academic institutions

as JV partners diminishes the importance of using EJVs for the purpose of

knowledge protection. In addition, due to the divergence in long-term orientation

between firms and academic institutions, a more flexible governance structure, such

as CJV, is usually preferred in industry-academy collaborations (Bruneel et al.

2010; Busom and Fernandez-Ribas 2008; De Fuentes and Dutrenit 2012).

Therefore, by choosing academic institutions as partners and adopting a contract-

based governance structure, not only can MNEs protect knowledge outcomes from

misappropriation, they can also take advantage of investment flexibility which

usually benefits industry-academy collaboration.

Hypothesis 2 (H2): Ceteris paribus, when a foreign firm chooses academic

institutions rather than local firms as JV partners, the EJV mode is less likely

to be chosen for the R&D JV.

2.4 The Moderating Effect of Cultural Distance on Governance StructureChoice

There is an ongoing debate about the direct impact of cultural distance on

governance structure (Anderson and Gatignon 1986; Kogut and Singh 1988;

Hennart and Larimo 1998; Makino and Neupert 2000). Contradictory theoretical

arguments exist and the empirical findings are mixed (for a review see Zhao et al.

2004). In this research, the direct effect of cultural distance on entry mode choice

also tends to be ambiguous: on the one hand culturally distant MNEs find EJVs

128 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 7: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

more costly to run, on the other hand they face higher risk of knowledge

misappropriation and have to use EJVs for the purpose of knowledge protection.

A key difference between CJVs and EJVs lies in that an EJV involves semi-

hierarchical governance which is characterized by a higher level of behaviour

control while a contractual relationship is more concerned about outcome control.

Compared with outcome control, behaviour control involves more frequent

personnel communications and interactions, which is especially difficult and costly

in the absence of shared language, traditions, ways of thinking, and values

(Anderson and Gatignon 1986; Evangelista and Hau 2009). In addition, without

shared values it is also difficult for EJVs to align the interests of partners, as they

may value different things. Hence cultural distance makes EJVs more risky and

costly than CJVs (Pothukuchi et al. 2002).

At the same time, in emerging economies where the concern over knowledge

protection is salient, MNEs may have to tolerate the high risk and cost associated

with cultural distance and to choose EJVs in order to better protect their

technological competencies. In the current empirical context, MNEs with a larger

cultural distance from emerging economies are more likely to originate from better

developed countries and carry more advanced and mature technology which is

more likely to be subject to misappropriation. Therefore, culturally distance MNEs

may have to use EJVs to protect their knowledge in spite of its high cost and risk. To

sum up, the direct relationship between cultural distance and EJVs is likely to be

ambiguous. However, a moderating effect tends to be clear. When the risk of

knowledge misappropriation is mitigated by limited R&D scope and appropriate

local partner choice, the drawbacks of EJVs such as high management cost and low

flexibility becomes a salient issue. Cultural distance further exaggerates such

drawbacks and makes EJVs even less attractive. Therefore, in the presence of a

large cultural distance, MNEs are less likely to select EJVs when the nature of

research activities or partnerships demands less safeguarding (i.e., research-

oriented R&D activities or academic institutions as partners).

Hypothesis 3a (H3a): Ceteris paribus, as the cultural distance between the

home country of an MNE and China increases, the relationship proposed in

H1 will be strengthened.

Hypothesis 3b (H3b): Ceteris paribus, as the cultural distance between the

home country of an MNE and China increases, the relationship proposed in

H2 will be strengthened.

Figure 1 summarizes these hypotheses.

3 Methods

3.1 The Chinese Context

This study focused on international R&D investments in China. China’s ample labor

supply and huge local market make it an attractive location for developing and

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 129

123

Page 8: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

leveraging technological competencies, but poor intellectual property rights

protection makes guarding technology challenging and costly. MNEs intending to

invest in R&D must design a mechanism to protect their technology assets while

avoiding the drawbacks of the mechanism.

China has emerged as a leading global production centre and is among the most

important markets for many companies. It is thus not surprising that foreign R&D

JVs are focusing heavily on problems particular to the local market (e.g., Chinese-

language computer use). At the same time, some of the R&D JVs are devoted to

basic research and thus contributing to their parents’ global operations (Zhang

2011). EJV and CJV are two of the three major forms of foreign direct investment

(FDI) prescribed by the Chinese government. An EJV in China is a limited liability

company where equity and board control is shared by two or more partners (Pan and

Tse 1996; Wang 2007). A CJV in China must have a joint subsidiary separate from

parents and a discrete task structure, taking the form of either a limited liability

company or an economic entity without independent legal person status (Inkpen

2000; Plasschaert 1993). The FDI regulations issued by the Chinese government

during the study period had restrictions on foreign partners’ equity shares in EJVs in

some industries, but had no restrictions on MNEs’ choice over CJVs and EJVs.

Industry-academy collaborations through either CJVs or EJVs are widely observed

in China (Chinese Association of University-Run Industries 2001; Shapira and

Wang 2009).

Based on the regulations on Chinese-Foreign EJVs, if MNEs choose to invest as

an EJV, they have to take at least a 25 % share. In addition, the law provides veto

rights to minority shareholders when important decisions (e.g., the restructuring and

dissolution of an EJV) are made by the board. These measures were intended to

make sure that MNEs investing in an EJV in China are committed to the

relationship, and that minority shareholders are protected.

Fig. 1 Theoretical framework

130 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 9: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

3.2 Data and Sample

To examine the factors affecting the choice of R&D governance structure in China,

we developed a database from four data sources: China Business Review, Business

China, and the LexisNexis and Proquest databases. China Business Review is a

major bimonthly trade magazine published by the US-China Business Council, an

independent business association headquartered in Washington D.C. Data from this

source has been widely used in other international business research (e.g., Hu and

Chen 1993; Li and Zhong 2003; Pan and Tse 2000). The information from the four

data sources was cross-checked for accuracy. A careful review of these sources

uncovered 347 instances of foreign R&D JVs in China between 1995 and 2002

inclusive. After dropping the observations with missing data, 319 cases were

included in the analysis.

The R&D investments during the study period were spread across 14 industries

and 22 Chinese provinces. A majority were in technology-related industries such as

electronics or computer software (101 cases, 31.7 %) or in telecoms and the internet

(137 cases, 42.9 %). Major cities such as Beijing (48.3 %) and Shanghai (14.7 %)

attracted a large proportion of the investments. The investing firms came from 21

different countries, with over a half from the US (55.8 %).

3.3 Variables

The dependent variable in this study is equity JV governance structure, represented

by a dummy variable coded as ‘‘1’’ if the R&D investment was organized as an EJV

by the foreign investor and ‘‘0’’ for other arrangements. As many as 142 (44.5 %) of

the R&D JVs in the sample were EJVs.

There are three independent variables. The research orientation of an investment

was represented by a dummy variable coded according to its publicly stated

objective. The variable research-oriented was coded as ‘‘1’’ if the investment was

announced as being focused on basic research and as ‘‘0’’ for development-oriented

work. We first developed a coding sheet with key words for either development

focused activities (e.g., develop a specific product; develop an application solution)

or research focused (e.g., joint research, research collaboration), based on a content

analysis and prior literature. Two researchers independently coded each invest-

ment’s primary focus based on published information, company websites, and in

some cases, phone interviews with R&D directors and country managers. Through

subsequent comparisons and discussions, the two researchers reached consensus in

each case. Among the 319 investments, 81 (25 %) were considered research-

oriented.

The choice of local partner for an international R&D JV, that is, whether the local

partner was an academic institution or a local firm, was measured by the variable,

academic institution. This variable was coded as ‘‘1’’ if the local partner was an

academic institution (i.r., a university or research institute) and as ‘‘0’’ otherwise. In

42 (13.2 %) of the R&D JVs, academic institutions were chosen as partners by

MNEs.

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 131

123

Page 10: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

Following Kogut and Singh (1988), cultural distance was calculated as a

composite index using Hofstede (1980) four dimensions of culture:

CDj ¼P4

i¼1

Iij � Iic� �2

=Vi

h i=4, where Iij is Hofstede’s index of the ith cultural

dimension for the jth country, and Vi is the variance of the index of the ith

dimension. The subscript c indicates China, and CDj is the cultural distance between

the jth country and China.

Three groups of control variables were also included in the models. The first

group contained four transaction-level factors. To capture the host country

experience of MNEs, we measured (1) whether the focal investment is the first

R&D investment the MNE parent made in China, and (2) whether or not the foreign

parent had made any wholly-owned R&D investments in China prior to the focal

one. If the focal investment is the first R&D investment of the foreign parent, it was

coded as a dummy variable. Due to an intra-organizational imprinting effect, MNEs

which had used the wholly-owned entry mode before are thought to be likely to use

a similar equity-based entry mode again (Li and Yao 2010; Lu 2002). Prior wholly-

owned R&D entry experience was coded as a dummy variable. If there was more

than one foreign organization participating in an R&D investment, the dummy

foreign R&D consortium was coded as ‘‘1’’, and as ‘‘0’’ otherwise. However, if there

were no local partners, the R&D lab was considered as wholly-owned by the foreign

investors, and was excluded from the sample. We measured the geographical

distance as the distance in kilometers between the capital of the province where the

international R&D JV was located and the capital of the home country of the MNE

making the R&D investment.

The second group of control variables described host locations. It has been found

that institutional development of intellectual property rights protection tends to

influence inbound FDI (Khoury and Peng 2011). So first the level of regional

intellectual property (IP) protection was measured at the provincial level. The

measure was adopted from the institutional development (ID) indices developed by

the National Economic Research Institute (NERI) of China (Fan and Wang 2001,

2004). ‘‘The indices reflect the development status of market trading mechanisms

and other institutions in achieving more efficient market functioning’’ (Gao et al.

2010, p. 386). The Institute reports the level of IP protection of each province

annually, calculated using data from the reports of China’s State Administration for

Industry and Commerce, survey data, and the China Statistical Yearbooks published

by the National Bureau of Statistics of China. The indices have been used in

economics, management and finance research on China (Chen et al. 2006; Gao et al.

2010; Li et al. 2006). The ID indices published by the NERI provide a relative rather

than an absolute measure of institutional development for each province (Fan and

Wang 2001, 2004). Since the NERI only reported the ID indices after 1997, the

values of IP protection in 1995 and 1996 were estimated based on the values in

1997. In addition to the institutional development, the economic development of

host locations was also captured in the model. Regional GDP per capita and annual

regional GDP growth in the 3 years before each transaction were calculated. The

data source was again the National Bureau of Statistics of China. The Chinese

132 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 11: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

government has been issuing special policies for some regions since 1980 to attract

FDI. The policies removed some of the foreign ownership restrictions in these

regions and tend to influence MNEs’ choices of governance structures. To control

for the regional policy effects, we generated a dummy variable special economic

zone that is coded as ‘‘1’’ if an international R&D JV is located in a Special

Economic Zone, a coastal open city, or a non-coastal city that enjoyed the special

policies for coastal open cities; and as ‘‘0’’ otherwise.

The third group of control variables were industry dummies. To control for

industry differences, we included two dummy variables—electronics and telecom-

munications—in the models. In fact, the investments were in 14 industries, but the

majority were in technology-related industries such as electronics and computer

software or telecommunications and the internet. Firms in these two industry groups

may prefer different governance structures. The last group of control variables

contained regional dummies and year dummies. Regional dummies controlled for

any other regional effect, with Beijing as the baseline. Year dummies captured any

possible year effect, with 1995 as the base year.

3.4 Models

Following prior entry mode studies, we used logit models to test the hypotheses,

which allows for the use of a binary dependent variable (Hennart and Reddy 1997).

This is necessary because the dependent variable equity JV is a dummy variable that

takes value 0 or 1. The potential shared error variance of all firms from a certain

home country may result in biased standard errors and reduce the efficiency of the

logit estimates. To account for the shared error variance problem, we applied logit

regression with clustering techniques in Stata. All the interaction items were

calculated with centered variables. Given that a number of other studies have used

probit models to deal with binary dependent variables (Barnett and Carroll 1987; Li

2008), we also used probit models and found similar results, which are thus not

reported here.

4 Results

Table 1 presents the relevant descriptive statistics and correlations. The highest

correlation among variables was found between cultural distance and geographical

distance (q = 0.67). This is to be expected as geographical distance is usually the

source of psychic distance (Davidson 1980). Since the average variance inflation

factor (VIF) of all the models was 3.22, multicollinearity was not considered an

important issue in these analyses (Ryan 1997).

Table 2 reports the results of logit regression with adjusted standard deviation.

Hypothesis 1 predicts that the choice of a research-oriented objective for the R&D

investment will reduce the likelihood that an EJV governance structure is selected.

The coefficients of research-oriented were significantly negative in all the models,

supporting Hypothesis 1 (p\ 0.01 in models 2, 4; p\ 0.05 in models 5–6;

p\ 0.10 in model 7). Hypothesis 2 predicts a negative relationship between the

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 133

123

Page 12: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

Table

1S

um

mar

yst

atis

tics

and

corr

elat

ion

mat

rix

Mea

nS

.D.

12

34

56

78

91

01

11

21

3

1.

Eq

uit

yJV

0.4

50

.50

2.

Res

earc

h-o

rien

ted

0.2

50

.44

-0

.16

*

3.

Aca

dem

ic

inst

itu

tio

n

0.1

30

.34

-0

.16

*0

.20

*

4.

Cult

ura

ld

ista

nce

4.7

41

.62

-0

.16

*0

.05

-0

.01

5.

Fo

reig

nR

&D

con

sort

ium

0.1

10

.31

0.0

7-

0.0

7-

0.1

4*

-0

.05

6.

Fir

stR

&D

inv

estm

ent

0.4

60

.50

-0

.02

0.0

2-

0.0

1-

0.2

6*

-0

.00

7.

Pri

or

wh

oll

y-

ow

ned

R&

Den

try

0.1

50

.36

-0

.15

*-

0.0

60

.04

0.1

9*

-0

.04

-0

.22*

8.

Reg

ion

alIP

pro

tect

ion

0.0

01

.00

0.1

2*

-0

.13

*-

0.0

8-

0.0

30

.06

-0

.10

-0

.00

9.

Reg

ion

alG

DP

per

cap

ita

1.5

40

.73

-0

.01

-0

.03

-0

.05

-0

.05

0.1

6*

0.0

70

.04

0.4

7*

10

.R

egio

nal

GD

P

gro

wth

30

.71

20

4.6

60

.04

-0

.04

0.0

00

.06

-0

.05

-0

.10

-0

.06

0.0

7-

0.1

1*

11

.G

eog

rap

hic

dis

tan

ce

88

34.0

63

96

5.0

9-

0.2

1*

0.0

5-

0.0

40

.67*

-0

.09

-0

.04

0.1

9*

-0

.04

-0

.07

0.0

2

12

.S

pec

ial

eco

no

mic

zon

e

0.7

10

.45

-0

.11

*0

.01

-0

.02

0.0

10

.05

0.0

50

.00

0.1

9*

0.5

7*

0.1

0-

0.0

4

13

. Tel

ecom

munic

atio

n

0.3

20

.47

-0

.08

0.0

2-

0.0

50

.10

-0

.09

0.0

20

.17*

-0

.07

-0

.00

0.0

00

.05

-0

.06

14

.E

lect

ron

ics

0.4

30

.50

0.0

9-

0.1

6*

-0

.00

0.0

10

.04

-0

.13*

0.0

60

.11*

0.0

40

.05

0.0

50

.09

-0

.59*

N=

31

9

*p\

0.0

5

134 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 13: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

Table

2R

egre

ssio

nre

sult

so

fth

elo

git

mod

els:

the

lik

elih

oo

do

fE

JVs

bei

ng

ado

pte

d

Mo

del

1M

odel

2M

od

el3

Mo

del

4M

odel

5M

odel

6M

odel

7

Independentvariables

Res

earc

h-o

rien

ted

(H1

)-

0.4

2(0

.14

)**

-0

.37

(0.1

4)*

*-

0.3

8(0

.19

)*-

0.3

4(0

.16

)*-

0.3

6(0

.20

)�

Aca

dem

icin

stit

uti

on

(H2)

-0

.42�(0

.23

)-

0.3

6�(0

.21

)-

0.3

5(0

.22

)-

0.5

0(0

.12

)**

*-

0.4

8(0

.13

)**

*

Interactioneffects

Res

earc

h-o

rien

ted

xC

D(H

3a)

-0

.77

(0.3

4)*

-0

.77

(0.3

9)*

Aca

dem

icin

stit

uti

on

xC

D(H

3b)

-0

.35

(0.1

0)*

**

-0

.36

(0.1

1)*

*

Controlvariables

Cult

ura

ld

ista

nce

(CD

)0

.05

(0.1

6)

0.0

7(0

.17

)0

.02

(0.1

5)

0.0

3(0

.15

)0

.25

(0.1

4)�

0.0

4(0

.16

)0

.24

(0.1

5)

Fo

reig

nR

&D

con

sort

ium

0.1

8(0

.34

)0

.16

(0.3

2)

0.0

5(0

.33

)0

.06

(0.3

2)

0.0

8(0

.22

)0

.11

(0.3

2)

0.1

3(0

.33

)

Fir

stR

&D

inv

estm

ent

0.2

0(0

.29

)0

.19

(0.2

9)

0.2

1(0

.27

)0

.20

(0.2

7)

0.1

8(0

.30

)0

.16

(0.2

9)

0.1

4(0

.32

)

Pri

or

wh

oll

y-o

wn

edR

&D

entr

y-

0.5

3(0

.42

)-

0.6

2(0

.42

)-

0.5

0(0

.45

)-

0.5

9(0

.45

)-

0.6

4(0

.47

)-

0.6

3(0

.49

)-

0.6

8(0

.53

)

Reg

ion

alIP

pro

tect

ion

-0

.20

(0.1

3)

-0

.31

(0.1

2)*

*-

0.2

3�

(0.1

4)

-0

.33

(0.1

3)*

-0

.37

(0.1

6)*

-0

.25

(0.1

1)*

-0

.30

(0.1

4)*

Reg

ion

alG

DP

per

capit

a0

.36

(0.4

7)

0.2

1(0

.43

)0

.44

(0.5

0)

0.3

1(0

.42

)0

.49

(0.5

2)

0.3

0(0

.45

)0

.51

(0.5

8)

Reg

ion

alG

DP

gro

wth

0.0

0(0

.00

)0

.00

(0.0

0)

0.0

0(0

.00

)0

.00

(0.0

0)

0.0

0(0

.00

)0

.00

(0.0

0)

0.0

0(0

.00

)

Geo

gra

ph

icd

ista

nce

0.0

0(0

.00

)**

*0

.00

(0.0

0)*

**

0.0

0(0

.00

)**

*0

.00

(0.0

0)*

**

0.0

0(0

.00

)***

0.0

0(0

.00

)**

*0

.00

(0.0

0)*

**

Sp

ecia

lec

on

om

iczo

ne

-0

.97

(0.2

9)*

**

-1

.00

(0.2

7)*

**

-0

.97

(0.2

8)*

**

-1

.00

(0.2

7)*

**

-1

.06

(0.2

8)�

-1

.05

(0.2

6)*

**

-1

.13

(0.3

1)*

**

Con

stan

t1

.70

(1.3

0)

1.9

9(1

.14

)�1

.88

(1.3

1)

2.1

2(1

.12

)�2

.05

(1.1

1)�

2.4

6(0

.98

)*2

.39

(0.9

3)*

Industry

effects,yeareffect

andregionaleffectsincluded

Lo

gli

kel

iho

od

-1

82

.00

-1

77

.74

-1

78

.02

-1

74

.91

-1

72

.14

-1

71

.50

-1

68

.93

Chi

squ

are

74

.37

**

*8

2.9

1*

**

82

.34

**

*8

8.5

6*

**

94

.09

**

*9

5.3

9*

**

10

0.5

1*

**

Chi

squ

are

chan

ge

vs.

bas

elin

e8

.53

**

Mo

del

1

7.9

7*

*

Mo

del

1

14

.18

**

*

Mo

del

1

5.5

3*

Mo

del

4

6.8

3*

*

Mo

del

4

11

.95

**

Mo

del

4

N=

31

9.�p\

0.1

0;

*p\

0.0

5;

**p\

0.0

1;

**

*p\

0.0

01

.T

he

stan

dar

der

rors

adju

sted

for

ho

me

cou

ntr

ies

are

inth

ep

aren

thes

es

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 135

123

Page 14: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

choice of academic institutions as JV partners and the selection of an EJV

governance structure. Again the models provided support to Hypothesis 2. The

coefficient for academic institution was negative and marginally significant at the

10 % level under models 3–4, and significantly negative at the 0.1 % level under

models 6–7. In combination, the results supported the idea that MNEs consider the

EJV governance structure as only one of several mechanisms for protecting

technological competencies.

The moderating effects of cultural distance in Hypothesis 3a–3b were also

supported. The coefficient of the interaction between research-oriented and cultural

distance was significantly negative in model 5 (b = -0.77, p\ 0.05) and Model 7

(b = -0.77, p\ 0.05). The coefficient of the interaction between academic

institution and cultural distance was significantly negative in model 6 (b = -0.35,

p\ 0.001) and model 7 (b = -0.36, p\ 0.01). Hoetker (2007) encouraged the use

of graphical presentations in interpreting the results of logit regressions. The

predicted probabilities of EJV adoption as functions of research-oriented and

academic institutions and their interaction effects with cultural distance are

illustrated in Figs. 2 and 3. Except for the interacting variables, the predicted

probabilities of EJV adoption in both figures was calculated with all dummy

variables as the most frequent value and all continuous variables as their mean. The

figures showed that the probabilities of EJV adoption decreased when research-

oriented R&D activities were conducted in the JV, and when the local partner was

academic institutions rather than firms. Large cultural distance enhanced the

negative effects.

The nonlinearity of logit models means that ‘‘the relationship between a change

in the value of an independent variable and the estimated change in the probability

of a positive outcome cannot be directly discerned from the variable’s coefficient’’

(Zelner 2009, p. 1336). In order to count for this problem, a simulation-based

Fig. 2 The interaction effect of research-oriented and cultural distance on the likelihood of EJVs beingadopted

136 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 15: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

approach was suggested as a better way of interpreting the estimation results of logit

models by reporting differences in predicted probabilities associated with discrete

changes in key independent variable values (Zelner 2009). Figure 4 and 5 was

created with such an approach, showing the difference in predicted probabilities of

EJV adoption associated with a shift from the choice of R&D scope and JV partners

at different levels of cultural distance, along with the 95 % confidence interval for

this difference. Figure 4 indicated that, even though the estimated effect of

research-oriented on the probability of EJV adoption is negative, this effect is not

Fig. 3 The interaction effect of academic institution and cultural distance on the likelihood of EJVsbeing adopted

-.20

.2.4

.6.8

1

dpr (

EJV)

0 2 4 6 8cultural distance

Fig. 4 The differences in predicted probabilities of EJV adoption associated with shifting fromdevelopment-oriented R&D activities to research-oriented R&D activities at different levels of culturaldistance

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 137

123

Page 16: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

statistically significant at lower values of cultural distance because the 95 %

confidence interval includes zero. In contrast, at higher levels of cultural distance,

the effect of choosing research-oriented R&D activities is negative and significantly

different from zero. Similar pattern was found in Fig. 5. More detailed calculation

showed that the choice of research-oriented R&D activities and academic

institutions as partners led to significant decrease in the probability of EJV

adoption when cultural distance exceeds 4.34, which covered 83.70 % of all the

observations. This delivered a general support to Hypotheses 1, 2. The lack of

significance in the range of lower values of cultural distance tends to be due to

limited number of observations with lower values of cultural distance (King et al.

2000).

The null hypothesis of Hypothesis 3a is that the effect of the choice of research-

oriented R&D activities on EJV adoption when cultural distance is low (e.g.,

min = 1.02) is not smaller than that when cultural distance is high (max = 8.28). A

two-tailed test showed that the 95 % confidence interval of the difference between

the two effects is between -1.01 and -0.00, which rejected the null hypothesis and

delivered support to Hypothesis 3a. The same test was applied to Hypothesis 3b.

The 95 % confidence interval of the difference between the effect of choosing

academic institutions as partner on EJV adoption when culture distance is low and

the effect when cultural distance is high is (-1.17, -0.01). Again, the result

supported Hypothesis 3b. To sum up, all of our hypotheses were generally

supported.

Most of the control variables did not show significant effects on the dependent

variable. In fact, only geographic distance and special economic zone exhibited

consistent impacts. The estimate of the coefficient of geographical distance was

significantly positive (p\ 0.001). This showed that MNEs from home countries

more distant from China preferred EJVs. The significantly negative impact

(p\ 0.001) of special economic zone was a little surprising. It seems that MNEs

-.20

.2.4

.6.8

1

dpr(

EJV

)

0 2 4 6 8cultural distance

Fig. 5 The differences in predicted probabilities of EJV adoption associated with shifting from choosingfirms as partners to choosing academic institutions as partners at different levels of cultural distance

138 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 17: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

were more likely to form contractual R&D JVs in regions with less restriction on

FDI. A possible explanation is that in special economic zones the market institution

is better developed and MNEs found it easier to establish and manage contractual

relationships there. The negative impact of regional IP protection was significant

(p\ 0.05) in all models with research-oriented included. This indicates that MNEs

could replace an internal knowledge-protection mechanism (EJVs in this case) with

an external knowledge-protection mechanism (IP protection in this case) when the

latter is available.

5 Discussion and Conclusion

Multinationals in recent years have paid increasing attention to overseas knowledge

creation while reducing the use of equity ownership in overseas knowledge

protection (Koza et al. 2011). Because of the generally weak institutions in

emerging economies, how MNEs can protect their technological competencies

becomes a critical issue for both scholars and managers.

In this study, we have examined how the scope of the R&D JV and the nature of

the local partner may influence the choice between the equity and non-equity

governance structures for R&D JVs. We argue that the risk of knowledge

misappropriation is reduced when MNEs limit the scope of R&D activities to

research-oriented ones, or when academic institutions are chosen as local partners.

In these two cases, it is less likely that EJVs would be adopted as a knowledge

protective measure. One factor explaining the above negative effects might be the

limitation of EJVs in flexibility and adaptability, which are critical for knowledge-

creation in large emerging economies. CJVs as an alternative to EJVs work well in

managing the tension between knowledge creation and protection when the risk of

knowledge misappropriation is mitigated.

In addition, we examined MNEs’ heterogeneity in selecting a CJV rather than an

EJV when the risk of knowledge misappropriation is reduced. Since the cost and

difficulty of managing an EJV increase with the cultural distance between the

MNE’s home and host countries, for those MNEs that have limited the scope of the

R&D JVs to research-oriented activities and those have chosen academic

institutions as local partners, the likelihood of adopting EJVs is substantially

reduced when the cultural distance is large. This extended the previous work (e.g.,

Li et al. 2008; Zhao 2006).

Highlighting the importance of knowledge protection in the context of emerging

economies, this paper does not ignore the importance of knowledge creation. A CJV

offers an attractive governance structure for international R&D JVs because of its

flexibility and responsiveness. The main disadvantage of a CJV lies in its poor

knowledge protection. Therefore, we argue that international R&D JVs choose

CJVs when (1) risk of knowledge misappropriation is mitigated and (2) flexibility is

critical in the partnership. Research-oriented R&D activities involve high uncer-

tainty but low resource commitment, which calls for and allows for higher flexibility

in governance structure. Similarly, academic partnerships require higher flexibility

due to the divergence in long-term orientation between firms and academic

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 139

123

Page 18: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

institutions. CJVs are more effective structure in organization knowledge creation

when the R&D JV is dedicated to research-oriented activities or when academic

partners take part in.

In building this framework we aim to contribute to three literatures. First,

knowledge protection literature extensively discussed various modes of knowledge

protection mechanisms (e.g., patents, design registration, trademarks, trade secrecy,

lead-time advantages, design complexity, control allocation and interests alignment,

etc.), and how they can be complementary, substitutes or independent of each other

(Amara et al. 2008; Kloyer and Scholderer 2012; Thoma and Bizer 2013). It also

found that R&D internationalization increases the risk of knowledge misappropri-

ation (Berger et al. 2012), and inter-organizational collaboration tends to influence

the choice of knowledge protection mechanism (Kloyer and Scholderer 2012;

Leiponen and Byma 2009). These findings create spaces for research on complex

knowledge protection mechanisms in the context of international R&D collabora-

tion. Our research attempts to step into this niche and explores how EJV as a

knowledge protection mechanism are adopted or replaced with CJV for the purpose

of both knowledge protection and knowledge creation.

Our second contribution was made to entry mode literature. We have identified

the objective (be it research- or development-oriented) of an R&D venture as a key

factor influencing the choice of entry mode. Although the choice of R&D objective

is an important aspect of a global R&D strategy, this topic has not received adequate

academic attention. Limited prior research has examined the influence of R&D

objectives on the choice of entry mode. In addition, we have identified partner

selection as a key factor influencing the choice of R&D FDI entry mode. Prior

research concludes that the type of partner is a major factor determining the success

and failure of R&D collaborations (Belderbos et al. 2004; Fritsch and Lukas 2001;

Fritsch and Franke 2004; Lhuillery and Pfister 2009; Tether 2002). Different types

of partners possess different resources and capabilities and may behave differently

in R&D collaborative relationships (Kang and Kang 2010). However, research

focusing on partner selection for international R&D JVs (e.g., universities versus

local firms) is still in the embryonic stage (Cohen et al. 2002; Li 2010; van Beers

et al. 2008). The importance of industry-academy collaboration has greatly

increased in both industrialized and developing world over the last three decades

(Cohen et al. 2002; De Fuentes and Dutrenit 2012). As a result, the strategy of

having academic institutions as potential R&D JV partners has gained more

attention from scholars and companies alike. In this research, we suggest that

MNEs’ concern over the tension between knowledge creation and protection leads

them to favor academic institutions as partners in international R&D JVs as it

reduced the risk of knowledge misappropriation.

Another contribution of this research lies in our specific empirical context. The

internationalization of MNEs’ R&D investments into emerging economies has been

a recent phenomenon. Most emerging economies are characterized by frequent

changes in the regulatory framework and interferences from various governmental

authorities (Li and Yue 2008; Luo 2002). Property rights are either under-developed

or under-enforced (Jefferson and Rawski 1994). The tension between the creation

and the protection of technological competencies is especially strong in emerging

140 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 19: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

economies where the weak institutions make the protection of technological

competencies a very salient issue (Luo 2007; Zhao 2006). Previous research on

R&D globalization and decentralization has mainly focused on more developed

economies (Feinberg and Gupta 2004; Hansen and Lovas 2004; Papanastassiou and

Pearce 1999; Pearce and Papanastassiou 1996; Ronstadt 1978), with little attention

given to investing in R&D in emerging economies. Taking one of the largest

emerging economies, i.e. China, as an example, this study was intended to extend

previous work on this topic and build on some recent research on global R&D

investments in emerging economies (Keupp et al. 2009; Sun et al. 2010; Zhao

2006).

Although one of our main purposes of the paper is to extend the recent research

on global R&D investments in emerging economies (Mishra 2007), we believe that

the relationships we proposed in H2, H3 are generalizable to other economies, while

that proposed in H1 may be restricted to emerging economies where the problem of

knowledge misappropriation is salient. This is because limiting the scope of R&D to

research-oriented activities mitigates the difficulties associated with knowledge

protection as well as increases the concern over performance evaluation.

TCE argues that governance structures with high levels of control (e.g., EJVs)

can be used to deal with two governance problems—the performance evaluation

problem and the safeguarding problem (Rindfleisch and Heide 1997). The input and

output of development-oriented R&D activities are more likely to be misappropri-

ated by transaction parties in emerging economies. So EJVs are more likely to be

used to govern development-oriented R&D activities in order to minimize the

safeguarding problem caused by the opportunism of transaction parties.

However, just as development-oriented R&D activities are subject to a more

serious safeguarding problem, research-oriented R&D activities are subject to a

more serious performance evaluation problem. Compared with development-

oriented R&D activities, it might be more difficult to specify the input and output of

research-oriented R&D activities in a contract. This leads to the performance

evaluation problem, which can be countered by using EJVs to minimize the

opportunism of transaction parties.

We argue that in our research context, the safeguarding problem is more salient

than the performance evaluation problem for two reasons. First, the performance

evaluation problem associated with research-oriented R&D activities is reduced

since MNEs have superior technological capabilities and local partners mainly

provide human resources and tangible assets (Hitt et al. 2000; Yan and Gray 1994).

It is relatively easier for MNEs to evaluate these input and performance of local

partners. Second, the safeguarding problem associated with development-oriented

R&D activities is enhanced when (1) the R&D is close to the market, (2) the partner

has complementary assets, and (3) the host institution is weak in IP protection.

These conditions usually hold in emerging economies such as China.

To sum up, research-oriented R&D activities are subject to the performance

evaluation problem, while development-oriented R&D activities are subject to the

safeguarding problem. Both governance problems can be dealt with by adopting

EJVs. The relationship proposed in Hypothesis 1 tends to hold when the

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 141

123

Page 20: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

safeguarding problem is more salient, which is usually the case in emerging

economies rather than developed economies.

Another note to make here is that the low correlation between the two

independent variable, i.e. q = 0.20 between research-oriented and academic

institution, implies that MNEs collaborate with Chinese academic institutions not

just for research-oriented R&D activities. This counterintuitive evidence may be

specific to the national innovation system in China, which has also been found in

Finland (van Beers et al. 2008). It shows that the empirical support we found for our

two main hypotheses are not spurious relationships due to high correlations between

independent variables.

6 Implications and Limitations

‘‘…the last activity of the firm to be organised on an international basis—if it is at

all—is R&D’’ (Terpstra 1977, p. 25). The above assertion was mainly based on a

knowledge protection logic, i.e. technological competencies lie in the core

competencies of MNEs, which can be best protected by full internalization in

headquarters (Pisano 1990). However, this contradicts the need of better knowledge

creation by getting access to richer and more diverse technological resources. To get

access to overseas technological resources as well as protect the technological

inputs and outputs, it has been argued that EJVs have advantages in governing

transactions with overseas R&D investments because (1) they provide better

protection of knowledge and (2) they facilitate knowledge transfer between partners

(Hennart 1988). So we had expected the governance structures of international R&D

JVs to be predominantly EJVs. But it turned out that less than half (45 %) of the

international R&D JVs in our sample were EJVs. If EJVs are so suitable for R&D

JVs, why aren’t more JVs organized as such?

We explained this with the EJV’s limitation in flexibility and adaptability,

together with its high management cost. The literature on the choice of governance

structure for knowledge-intensive transactions has not paid adequate attention to

this side of the story. This paper suggests that the said disadvantages of EJVs may

outweigh its advantages in knowledge protection, in particular when the risk of

knowledge misappropriation is relatively low and when the drawbacks of EJVs are

very salient. Though the reduction in use of equity-based governance structure is

prevailing in FDI worldwide recently, we suggest that it tends to be more significant

when the following two conditions hold: (1) alternative investment arrangements

(e.g., choice of appropriate business scope and local partners) that favour flexibility

in governance structure mitigate the risk of knowledge misappropriation, and (2) the

organizational cost of equity-based governance structure are especially high due to

factors such as cultural distance.

This paper emphasizes the role of host institutions in balancing knowledge

protection and knowledge creation in international R&D JVs. In emerging

economies, the weak IP protection makes knowledge protection a very salient

issue, while the huge and changing global market makes organizational flexibility

and adaptability crucial for successful knowledge creation. Improved IP protection

142 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 21: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

and a more stable global market may alleviate the tension between knowledge

protection and knowledge creation, and further reduce the substitution effects we

observed in the current empirical context.

Our research gives the following managerial implications. First, the findings

suggest that the choice of governance structure for international R&D JVs should

not be isolated from other relevant decisions over the JV setup, such as whom to

partner with and what types of R&D activities to conduct. Second, managers who

are worried about knowledge misappropriation hazards in weak institutions do not

have to rely on transaction internalization to protect their knowledge. Limiting the

scope of business activities and choosing an appropriate partner may mitigate the

risk of knowledge misappropriation. Third, the cost of EJVs should never be

underestimated, especially when the cultural distance between the host and home

countries is large.

One important limitation of the current work is that it only focused on MNEs’

willingness to choose a certain governance structure, but ignored their ability to

actually implement that structure. Firms may not always be able to put the optimal

strategy into practice. Due to the lack of other firm-level data (e.g., the size of the

investment, and the size, R&D intensity and internationalization level of all parties

involved in an JV), we could not examine the ability of MNEs and local partners to

set up JVs with a certain governance structure. To counter that, we included the

regional economic development variables (i.r., regional GDP per capita and annual

regional GDP growth) in the models as control variables, expecting local partners

from more developed regions to be more capable of realizing synergies with MNE

partners. Unfortunately, none of the regional economic development variables

showed a significant impact on the choice between EJVs and CJVs.

A second limitation lies in the possible alternative explanations for our findings.

EJVs and CJVs differ in many other ways besides the level of knowledge protection.

For example, the cooperation synergies they are able to deliver to JVs would be

different (Phene and Tallman 2012). If CJVs create more JV synergies than EJVs

when the investment is research-oriented and academic institutions are chosen as the

local partners, similar results would be obtained. Unfortunately, given the current

data and literature we are unsure whether EJVs or CJVs create more JV value. This

should be a promising area for future research. Another field for future research lies

in testing the generalizability of our findings. It is important to examine if the results

hold in other emerging economies, or even in developed countries.

References

Amara, N., Landry, R., & Traore, N. (2008). Managing the protection of innovations in knowledge-

intensive business services. Research Policy, 37(9), 1530–1547.

Anderson, E., & Gatignon, H. (1986). Modes of foreign entry: a transaction cost analysis and proposition.

Journal of International Business Studies, 17(1), 1–26.

Arvanitis, S., & Hollenstein, H. (2011). How do different drivers of R&D investment in foreign locations

affect domestic firm performance? An analysis based on Swiss panel micro data. Industrial and

Corporate Change, 20(2), 605–640.

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 143

123

Page 22: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

Barnett, W. P., & Carroll, G. R. (1987). Competition and mutualism among early telephone companies.

Administrative Science Quarterly, 32(3), 400–421.

Belderbos, R. (2003). Entry mode, organizational learning, and R&D in foreign affiliates: evidence from

Japanese firms. Strategic Management Journal, 24(3), 235–259.

Belderbos, R., Carree, M., Diederen, B., Lokshin, B., & Veugelers, R. (2004). Heterogeneity in R&D

cooperation strategies. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22(8–9), 1237–1263.

Berger, F., Blind, K., & Cuntz, A. (2012). Risk factors and mechanisms of technology and insignia

copying-A first empirical research. Research Policy, 41(2), 376–390.

Bruneel, J., D’Este, P., & Salter, A. (2010). Investigating the factors that diminish the barriers to

university-industry collaboration. Research Policy, 39(7), 858–868.

Bush, V. (1945). Science the endless frontier: a report to the president on a program for postwar

scientific research. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.

Busom, I., & Fernandez-Ribas, A. (2008). The impact of particiation in R&D programs on R&D

partnerships. Research Policy, 37(2), 240–257.

Cantwell, J., & Colombo, M. G. (2000). Technological and output complementarities: inter-firm

cooperation in information technology ventures. Journal of Management and Governance, 4(1–2),

117–147.

Chand, M., & Katou, A. A. (2012). Strategic determinants for the selection of partner alliances in the

Indian tour operator industry: a cross-national study. Journal of World Business, 47(2), 167–177.

Che, J., & Facchini, G. (2009). Cultural differences, insecure property rights and the mode of entry

decision. Economic Theory, 38(3), 465–484.

Chen, G., Firth, M., Gao, D. N., & Rui, O. M. (2006). Ownership structure, corporate governance, and

fraud: evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 12(3), 424–448.

Chinese Association of University-Run Industries. (2001). Article of Chinese Association of University-

Run Industries. Beijing: Chinese Association of University-Run Industries.

Cohen, W. M., Florida, R., & Goe, W. R. (1994). University industry research centers in the United

States. Pittsburgh: Carnegie-Mellon University Press.

Cohen, W. M., Nelson, R. R., & Walsh, J. P. (2002). Links and impacts: the influence of public research

on industrial R&D. Management Science, 48(1), 1–23.

Collinson, S., Kato, H., & Yoshihara, H. (2005). Technology strategy revealed: patterns and influences of

patent-licensing behaviour in Japanese firms. International Journal of Technology Management,

30(3–4), 327–350.

Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

Davidson, W. H. (1980). The location of foreign direct investment activity: country characteristics and

experience effects. Journal of International Business Studies, 11(1), 9–22.

De Fuentes, C., & Dutrenit, G. (2012). Best channels of academia-industry interaction for long-term

benefit. Research Policy, 41(9), 1666–1683.

Diericks, I., & Cool, K. (1989). Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage.

Management Science, 35(12), 1504–1513.

Dunning, J. H. (1994). Multinational enterprises and the globalisation of innovatory capacity. Research

Policy, 23(1), 67–88.

Dussauge, P., & Garette, B. (1999). Cooperative strategy—competing successfully through strategic

alliance. Chichester: Wiley.

Evangelista, F., & Hau, L. N. (2009). Organizational context and knowledge acquisition in IJVs: an

empirical study. Journal of World Business, 44(1), 63–73.

Fan, G., & Wang, X. (2001). National Economic Research Institute Index of Marketization of China’s

Provinces. Beijing: Economic Science.

Feinberg, S. E., & Gupta, A. K. (2004). Knowledge spillovers and the assignment of R&D responsibilities

to foreign subsidiaries. Strategic Management Journal, 25(8/9), 823–845.

Frankort, H. T. W., Hagedoorn, J., & Letterie, W. (2012). R&D partnership portfolios and the inflow of

technological knowledge. Industrial and Corporate Change, 21(2), 507–537.

Freeman, C., & Soete, L. (1997). The Economics of Industrial Innovation. London: Pinter.

Fritsch, M., & Franke, G. (2004). Innovation, regional knowledge spillovers and R&D cooperation.

Research Policy, 33(2), 245–255.

Fritsch, M., & Lukas, R. (2001). Who cooperates on R&D? Research Policy, 30(2), 297–312.

Gao, G. Y., Murray, J. Y., Kotabe, M., & Lu, J. (2010). A ‘‘strategy tripod’’ perspective on export

behaviors: evidence from domestic and foreign firms based in an emerging economy. Journal of

International Business Studies, 41(3), 377–396.

144 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 23: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

Garcia-Canal, E., Valdes-Llaneza, A., & Sanchez-Lorda, P. (2008). Technological flows and choice of

joint ventures in technology alliances. Research Policy, 37(1), 97–114.

Geringer, J. M. (1991). Strategic determinants of partner selection criteria in international joint ventures.

Journal of International Business Studies, 22(1), 41–62.

Hagedoorn, J. (1993). Understanding the rationale of strategic technology partnering: inter-organizational

modes of cooperation and sectoral differences. Strategic Management Journal, 14(5), 371–385.

Hagedoorn, J. (2002). Inter-firm R&D partnerships: an overview of major trends and patterns since 1960.

Research Policy, 31(4), 477–492.

Hansen, M. T., & Lovas, B. (2004). How do multinational companies leverage technological

competencies? Moving from single to interdependent explanation. Strategic Management Journal,

25(8/9), 801–822.

Harrigan, K. R. (1988). Joint ventures and competitive strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 9(2),

141–158.

Hennart, J. F. (1988). A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal,

9(4), 361–374.

Hennart, J. F., & Larimo, J. (1998). The impact of culture on the strategy of multinational enterprises:

does national origin affect ownership decisions? Journal of International Business Studies, 29(3),

515–538.

Hennart, J. F., & Reddy, S. (1997). The choice between mergers/acquisitions and joint ventures: the case

of Japanese investors in the United States. Strategic Management Journal, 18(1), 1–12.

Hitt, M. A., Dacin, M. T., Levitas, E., Arregle, J. L., & Borza, A. (2000). Partner selection in emerging

and developed market contexts: resource-based and organizational learning perspectives. Academy

of Management Journal, 43(3), 449–467.

Hitt, M. A., Tyler, B. B., Hardee, C., & Park, D. (1995). Understanding strategic intent in the global

marketplace. Academy of Management Executive, 9(2), 12–19.

Hoetker, G. (2007). The use of Logit and Probit models in strategic management research: critical issues.

Strategic Management Journal, 28(4), 331–343.

Hofstede, G. (1980). Culture’s consequences: International differences in work-related values. London:

Sage Publications.

Hu, M. Y., & Chen, H. (1993). Foreign ownership in Chinese joint ventures: a transaction cost analysis.

Journal of Business Research, 26(2), 149–160.

Inkpen, A. C. (2000). A note on the dynamics of learning alliances: competition, cooperation, and relative

scope. Strategic Management Journal, 21(7), 775–779.

Jefferson, G., & Rawski, T. (1994). Enterprise reform in Chinese industry. Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 8(2), 47–70.

Jiang, X., & Li, Y. (2009). An empirical investigation of knowledge management and innovative

performance: the case of alliances. Research Policy, 38(2), 358–368.

Kang, H. K., & Kang, J. (2010). Does partner type matter in R&D collaboration for product innovation?

Technology Analysis and Strategic Management, 22(8), 945–959.

Keupp, M. M., Beckenbauer, A., & Gassmann, O. (2009). How managers protect intellectual property

rights in China using de facto strategies. R&D Management, 39(2), 211–224.

Khoury, T. A., & Peng, M. W. (2011). Does institutional reform of intellectual property rights lead to

more inbound FDI? Evidence from Latin America and Caribbean. Journal of World Business, 46(3),

337–345.

King, G., Tomz, M., & Wittenberg, J. (2000). Making the most of statistical analyses: improving

interpretation and presentation. American Journal of Political Science, 44(2), 347–361.

Kloyer, M., & Scholderer, J. (2012). Effective incomplete contracts and milestones in market-distant

R&D collaboration. Research Policy, 41(2), 346–357.

Kogut, B. (1988). Joint ventures: theoretical and empirical perspectives. Strategic Management Journal,

9(4), 319–332.

Kogut, B., & Singh, H. (1988). The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode. Journal of

International Business Studies, 19(3), 411–432.

Koot, W. T. M. (1988). Underlying dilemmas in the management of international joint ventures. In P.

Lorange (Ed.), Cooperative strategies in international business (pp. 347–367). Lexington:

Lexington Books.

Koza, M. P., Tallman, S., & Ataay, A. (2011). The strategic assembly of global firms: a microstructural

analysis of local learning and global adaptation. Global Strategy Journal, 1(1), 27–46.

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 145

123

Page 24: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

Kuittinen, H., Kylaheiko, K., Sandstrom, J., & Jantunen, A. (2009). Cooperation governance mode: an

extended transaction cost approach. Journal of Management and Governance, 13(4), 303–323.

Leiponen, A., & Byma, J. (2009). If you cannot block, you better run: small firms, cooperative innovation,

and appropriation strategies. Research Policy, 38(9), 1478–1488.

Lhuillery, S., & Pfister, E. (2009). R&D cooperation and failures in innovation projects: empirical

evidence from French CIS data. Research Policy, 38(1), 45–57.

Li, J. T. (2008). Asymmetric interactions between foreign and domestic banks: effects on market entry.

Strategic Management Journal, 29(8), 873–893.

Li, J. T. (2010). Global R&D alliance in China: collaborations with universities and research institutes.

Transactions on Engineering Management, 57(1), 78–87.

Li, D., Eden, L., Hitt, M. A., & Ireland, R. D. (2008). Friends, acquaintances, or strangers? Partner

selection in R&D alliance. Academy of Management Journal, 51(2), 315–334.

Li, H., Meng, L., & Zhang, J. (2006). Why do entrepreneurs enter politics? Evidence from China.

Economic Inquiry, 44(3), 559–578.

Li, J. T., & Xie, Z. (2011). Global R&D strategies in an emerging economy: the development and

protection of technological competencies. European Management Review, 8(3), 153–164.

Li, J. T., & Yao, K. (2010). The role of reference groups in international investment decisions by firms

from emerging economies. Journal of International Management, 16(2), 143–153.

Li, J. T., & Yue, D. R. (2008). Market size, legal institutions, and international diversification strategies:

implications for the performance of multinational firms. Management International Review, 48(6),

667–688.

Li, J. T., & Zhong, J. (2003). Explaining the growth of international R&D alliances in China. Managerial

and Decision Economics, 24(2–3), 101–115.

Lu, J. W. (2002). Intra- and inter-organizational imitative behavior: institutional influences on Japanese

firms’ entry mode choice. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(1), 19–37.

Luo, Y. (2002). Capability exploitation and building in foreign markets: implications for multinational

enterprises. Organization Science, 13(1), 48–63.

Luo, Y. (2006). Autonomy of foreign R&D units in an emerging market: an information processing

perspective. Management International Review, 46(3), 349–378.

Luo, Y. (2007). Are joint venture partners more opportunistic in a more volatile environment?’. Strategic

Management Journal, 28(1), 39–60.

Makino, S., & Neupert, K. E. (2000). National culture, transaction costs, and the choice between joint

venture and wholly-owned subsidiary. Journal of International Business Studies, 31(4), 705–713.

Mansfield, E. (1998). Academic research and industrial innovation: an update of empirical findings.

Research Policy, 26(7–8), 773–776.

March, J. G. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2(1),

71–87.

Marin, P. L., & Siotis, G. (2008). Public policies towards research joint venture: institutional design and

participants’ characteristics. Research Policy, 37(6–7), 1057–1065.

Martinez-Noya, A., Garcia-Canal, E., & Guillen, M. F. (2013). R&D outsourcing and the effectiveness of

intangible investments: is proprietary core knowledge walking out of the door? Journal of

Management Studies, 50(1), 67–91.

Mishra, B. P. (2007). Technology innovations in emerging markets: an analysis with special reference to

the Indian economy. South Asian Journal of Management, 14(4), 50–65.

Mowery, D. (2011). Learning from one another? International policy ‘‘emulation’’ and university-industry

technology transfer. Industrial and Corporate Change, 20(6), 1827–1853.

Nelson, R. R. (Ed.). (1993). National innovation systems: a comparative analysis. New York: Oxford

University Press.

Oxley, J. E., & Sampson, R. C. (2004). The scope and governance of international R&D alliance.

Strategic Management Journal, 25(8/9), 723–750.

Pakes, A., & Griliches, Z. (1984). Patents and R&D at the firm level: a first look. In Z. Griliches (Ed.),

R&D, patents and productivity. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

Pan, Y. G., & Tse, D. K. (1996). Cooperative strategies between foreign firms in an overseas country.

Journal of International Business Studies, 27(5), 929–946.

Pan, Y. G., & Tse, D. K. (2000). The hierarchical model of market entry modes. Journal of International

Business Studies, 31(4), 535–554.

Papanastassiou, M., & Pearce, R. D. (1999). Multinationals, technology and national competitiveness.

Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

146 J. Li, Z. Xie

123

Page 25: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

Pearce, R. D., & Papanastassiou, M. (1996). The technological competitivenss of Japanes multinationals:

the European dimension. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

Phene, A., & Tallman, S. (2012). Complexity, context and governance in biotechnology alliances.

Journal of International Business Studies, 43(1), 61–83.

Pisano, G. P. (1989). Using equity participation to support exchange: evidence from the biotechnology

industry. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 5(1), 109–126.

Pisano, G. P. (1990). The R&D boundaries of the firm: an empirical analysis. Administrative Science

Quarterly, 35(1), 153–176.

Plasschaert, S. R. (1993). The foreign exchange balancing rule in the People’s Republic of China. In L.

Kelly & O. Shenkar (Eds.), International business in China (pp. 88–108). London: Routledge.

Porter, M. E. (1987). From competitive advantage to corporate strategy. Harvard Business Review, 65(3),

43–59.

Pothukuchi, V., Damanpour, F., Choi, J., Chen, C. C., & Park, S. H. (2002). National and organizational

culture difference and international joint venture performance. Journal of International Business

Studies, 33(2), 243–266.

Rindfleisch, A., & Heide, J. (1997). Transaction costs analysis: past, present, and future applications.

Journal of Marketing, 6(1), 30–54.

Rivkin, J. W. (2001). Replication without imitation at moderate complexity. Organization Science, 12(3),

274–294.

Ronstadt, R. C. (1978). International R&D: the establishment and evolution of research and development

abroad by seven US multinationals. Journal of International Business Studies, 9(1), 7–24.

Ryan, T. Y. (1997). Modern regression analysis. New York: Wiley.

Schmoch, U. (1999). Interaction of universities and industrial enterprises in Germany and the United

States—a comparison. Industry and Innovation, 6(1), 51–68.

Shapira, P., & Wang, J. (2009). From lab to market? Strategies and issues in the commercialization of

nanotechnology in China. Asian Business and Management, 8(4), 461–490.

Sun, J., Debo, L. G., Kekre, S., & Xie, J. (2010). Component-based technology transfer in the presence of

potential imitators. Management Science, 56(3), 536–552.

Teece, D. J. (1976). The multinational corporation and the resource cost of international technology

transfer. Cambridge: Ballinger.

Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration,

licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285–305.

Terpstra, V. (1977). International product policy: the role of foreign R&D’. Colombia Journal of World

Business, 12(4), 34–42.

Tether, B. S. (2002). Who co-operates for innovation, and why: an empirical analysis. Research Policy,

31(6), 947–967.

Thoma, J., & Bizer, K. (2013). To protect or not to protect? Modes of appropriability in the small

enterprise sector. Research Policy, 42(1), 35–49.

van Beers, C., Berghall, E., & Poot, T. (2008). R&D internationalization, R&D collaboration and public

knowledge institutions in small economies: evidence from Finland and The Netherlands. Research

Policy, 37(2), 294–308.

von Zedtwitz, M., & Gassman, O. (2002). Market versus technology drive in R&D internationalization:

four different patterns of managing research and development. Research Policy, 31(4), 569–588.

Wang, Y. (2007). Managerial choice between equity joint ventures and contractual joint ventures in

China: a critical test of transaction cost economics and resource-based view. Asian Business &

Management, 6(4), 355–375.

Williamson, O. E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. New York: Oxford University Press.

Yan, A., & Gray, B. (1994). Bargaining power, management control, and performance in United States-

China joint ventures: a comparative case study. Academy of Management Journal, 37(6),

1478–1517.

Zander, U., & Kogut, B. (1995). Knowledge and the speed of the transfer and imitation of organizational

capabilities: an empirical test. Organization Science, 6(1), 76–92.

Zelner, B. A. (2009). Using simulation to interpret results from logit, probit, and other nonlinear models.

Strategic Management Journal, 30(12), 1335–1348.

Zhang, S. (2011). Multinational’s R&D in China and its implications for China’s national system of

innovation. In R. Pearce (Ed.), China and the multinationals: international business and the entry of

China into the global economy (pp. 42–58). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection… 147

123

Page 26: Governance Structure and the Creation and Protection of ... · Joint Ventures in China Jiatao Li1 • Zhenzhen Xie2 Received: 26 October 2013/Revised: 19 August 2015/Accepted: 27

Zhao, M. (2006). Conducting R&D in countries with weak intellectual property rights protection.

Management Science, 52(8), 1185–1199.

Zhao, H., Luo, Y., & Suh, T. (2004). Transaction cost determinants and ownership-based entry mode

choice: a meta-analytical review. Journal of International Business Studies, 35(6), 524–544.

148 J. Li, Z. Xie

123