gender and the division of household labor in older couples

Upload: ana-muntean

Post on 04-Apr-2018

219 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    1/24

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/Journal of Family Issues

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399The online version of this article can be found at:

    DOI: 10.1177/0192513X06296427

    2007 28: 399Journal of Family IssuesKarsten Hank and Hendrik Jrges

    European PerspectiveGender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples : A

    Published by:

    http://www.sagepublications.com

    can be found at:Journal of Family IssuesAdditional services and information for

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/cgi/alertsEmail Alerts:

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/subscriptionsSubscriptions:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navReprints:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navPermissions:

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399.refs.htmlCitations:

    What is This?

    - Feb 20, 2007Version of Record>>

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399http://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399http://www.sagepublications.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://jfi.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://jfi.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399.refs.htmlhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399.refs.htmlhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399.refs.htmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399.full.pdfhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399.full.pdfhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399.full.pdfhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399.refs.htmlhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://jfi.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://jfi.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://www.sagepublications.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/content/28/3/399http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    2/24

    Gender and the Division ofHousehold Labor inOlder Couples

    A European Perspective

    Karsten Hank

    Hendrik JrgesMannheim Research Institute for the Economics of Aging,University of Mannheim, Germany

    Using microdata from the 2004 Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in

    Europe (SHARE), this study takes a cross-national perspective to investigate

    the division of household labor among older couples (aged 50 years or more).

    Across nine continental European countries, the authors find considerable

    variation in the overall distribution of housework between partners, withmore egalitarian countries in northern Europe and more traditional countries

    in southern Europe. A multilevel analysis shows that about half of the

    between-country variance in the division of housework is due to differences

    in older couples characteristics, but that there are no country-specific effects

    of the main microlevel explanatory variables. Finally, the authors find a sig-

    nificant effect of macrolevel gender inequalities on couples division of

    housework, suggesting that older couples living in more gender-egalitarian

    countries are more likely to exhibit an equal sharing of household labor.

    Keywords: gender; division of household labor; older couples; Europe;

    SHARE

    Research on productive aging is growing rapidly (cf. Morrow-Howell,Hinterlong, & Sherraden, 2001; OReilly & Caro, 1994). Most of therelated literature deals with involvement of the elderly in volunteering (e.g.,

    Caro & Bass, 1995; Erlinghagen & Hank, 2006), grandparenting (e.g.,

    Hayslip & Kaminski, 2005; Pebley & Rudkin, 1999), or other work usuallyperformed for parties outside the individuals household. However, work

    performed within ones own household also has a substantial economic

    value. Without home production, one would have to buy substantially

    Journal of Family Issues

    Volume 28 Number 3

    March 2007 399-421

    2007 Sage Publications

    10.1177/0192513X06296427

    http://jfi.sagepub.comhosted at

    http://online.sagepub.com

    399

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    3/24

    more household services on the market (e.g., de Ruijter, Treas, & Cohen,

    2005; Stoller & Cutler, 1993). Although gender differences in other types

    of unpaid or informal work are also recognized (e.g., Herzog & Morgan,1992; Hook, 2004), they are particularly pronounced in the division of

    housework between spouses. Despite some changes across cohorts, with

    more recently born women doing less and their male partners doing

    somewhat more (both relative and total), today men generally contribute

    at most one third of core housework tasks (e.g., Bianchi, Milkie, Sayer,

    Folbre, & Matheson, 2000; Breen & Cooke, 2005; Shelton & John, 1996).

    Several studies dealing with postretirement changes in couples division

    of household labor show that the total amount of housework done mayincrease after retirement for both men and women, but that the traditional

    preretirement pattern largely persists (e.g., Dorfman, 1992; Solomon,

    Acock, & Walker, 2004; Szinovacz, 2000). So far, however, the division of

    household labor among older couples has not been analyzed in a cross-

    national perspective. Recent investigations for the general population

    strongly suggest that macrolevel factors, particularly gender inequalities,

    play a significant role in the distribution of housework between spouses

    (e.g., Breen & Cooke, 2005; Davis & Greenstein, 2004; Fuwa, 2004).Using data on couples aged 50 and older derived from the Survey of

    Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe (SHARE), this article estimates

    hierarchical linear models to investigate the relationship between societal

    context and the division of routine household labor in nine continental

    European countries. Before presenting the empirical analysis, we will

    briefly review the linkage between micro- and macrolevel aspects of

    gender and housework.

    400 Journal of Family Issues

    Authors Note: Both authors contributed equally to this article. We are grateful for comments

    by two anonymous reviewers. This research was supported by the European Community Fifth

    Framework Programs Quality of Life project under EC Contract QLK6-2002-002426

    (AMANDA). This article is based on data from Early Release 1 of SHARE 2004, which is pre-

    liminary and may contain errors that will be corrected in later releases. The SHARE data col-

    lection has been funded primarily by the European Commission through the Fifth Framework

    Program (Quality of Life Project QLK6-CT-2001-00360). Additional funding came from the

    U.S. National Institute on Aging (U01 AG09740-13S2, P01 AG005842, P01 AG08291, P30

    AG12815, Y1-AG-4553-01, and OGHA 04-064). Data collection in Austria (through theAustrian Science Fund, FWF) and Switzerland (through BBW/OFES/UFES) was nationally

    funded. Please address correspondence to Karsten Hank, Mannheim Research Institute for the

    Economics of Aging, University of Mannheim, Building L 13, 17, D-68131 Mannheim,

    Germany; e-mail: [email protected].

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    4/24

    Gender and the Division of Housework

    Various economic models play a prominent role in much of the literatureon household labor. Although the new home economics approach, put forward

    by Becker (1981), proposes that men and women specialize to maximize

    household utility or efficiency, the resourcebargaining power perspective

    focuses on power relations in the family (based on, for example, educational

    or income differentials between the partners), and the economic dependency

    model is centered on the assumption that women are forced to exchange

    household labor in return for economic support from a male breadwinner (cf.

    Brines, 1993; Greenstein, 2000, for example). These theories are compatiblewith general formulations of the relative resource hypothesis (a person with

    higher income will do less housework) and the time availability hypothesis (a

    person who spends more time in paid work will spend less time in house-

    work), which are putatively gender neutral, emphasize choice, and assume

    that housework allocation is governed by the rules and principles of exchange

    relations (Coltrane, 2000, p. 1214; see also Shelton & John, 1996, pp. 304ff.).

    However, it has been suggested that womens employment, time avail-

    ability, resources, conscious ideology, and power do not account for whywives still do the bulk of family work (Thompson & Walker, 1989, p. 857)

    regardless of demographic or life-course characteristics. The partners

    gender appears to be so influential that it is often considered to be the sin-

    gle most important determinant of the division of household labor. Theories

    on socializationgender role attitudes, for example, contend that people

    socialized to believe in gender-segregated work will conform to those

    beliefs (e.g., Coverman, 1985; Cunningham, 2005). Thus, men and women

    with traditional attitudes are expected to share less housework, whereas

    men and women with nontraditional attitudes are expected to share house-

    work more equally. It is assumed that people are automatically socialized

    into rigid gender roles from childhood onward, going along with the devel-

    opment of relatively fixed attitudes and/or deeply gendered personalities.

    These strict assumptions are rejected by more recent gender construction

    theories that incorporate the symbolic and performance dimensions of gender

    (cf. Shelton & John, 1996). As Coltrane (2000) posits, Doing specific house-

    hold tasks provides opportunities to demonstrate to oneself and to others that

    one is a competent member of a sex category with the capacity and desire toperform appropriately gendered behaviors (p. 1213). Thus, housework pro-

    duces not only household commodities but also gendered identities through-

    out the life course.

    Hank, Jrges / Division of Household Labor 401

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    5/24

    Gender ideology determines what a proper gender role is. Just as gender

    ideologies vary across individuals (e.g., Greenstein, 1996), the social con-

    struction of gender is highly context dependent and varies across nations orcultures. Mason (1997) defines the societal gender system as

    the socially constructed expectations for male and female behavior that are

    found (in variable form) in every human society. A gender systems expecta-

    tions prescribe a division of labor and responsibilities between women and

    men and grant different rights and obligations to them. (p. 158)

    Resulting macrolevel gender inequalitiesthat may be promoted or ame-

    liorated by the welfare state (Orloff, 1996; see also Geist, 2005)materi-

    alize in various spheres (cf. Huber, 1990) such as the educational system

    (e.g., Jacobs, 1996), the labor market (e.g., Chang, 2000), or the political

    arena (e.g., Elder, 2004). Naturally, they are also reflected in spouses divi-

    sion of work in the family (e.g., Sarkisian & Gerstel, 2004; Sundstrm &

    Duvander, 2002; Thompson & Walker, 1989) and in the household. Thus,

    Coltrane (2000) suggests that the almost universally observed pattern of

    household labor

    can only be understood by attending to the symbolic significance of house-

    hold labor in the social construction of gender and by analyzing the social,

    cultural, economic, and political contexts in which men and women form

    families, raise children, and sustain households. (p. 1208)

    Starting from Baxters (1997) five-country studycovering the United

    States, Sweden, Norway, Canada, and Australiaa number of studies have

    explicitly investigated the division of housework in advanced industrializedsocieties from a cross-national perspective (for an analysis of less devel-

    oped countries, see, for example, Sanchez, 1993, 1994). A universal find-

    ing is that wives contribution to household chores is still greater than their

    husbands, even in the most egalitarian countries (e.g., Davis & Greenstein,

    2004). More differentiated insights can be derived from recent work using

    multilevel modeling. For example, Batalova and Cohen (2002), who focus

    on the role of premarital cohabitation, show that national cohabitation rates

    in countries with higher levels of overall gender equality have equalizing

    effects on couples division of housework regardless of their own cohabita-

    tion experience. Fuwa (2004) elaborates on the role of macrolevel gender

    inequalities, arguing that male control over the political economy and

    male dominated ideologies at the macrolevel may act as discount factors

    402 Journal of Family Issues

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    6/24

    against the power of individual womens resources (p. 752; see also

    Blumberg, 1984). Thus, she expects that individual-level factors will have

    weaker effects on the division of household labor for women who live incountries with less pronounced gender equalityand vice versa. Using the

    same data source (the 1994 International Social Survey Programme; ISSP)

    and selection of 22 countries on which the study by Batalova and Cohen

    (2002) is based, Fuwa (2004) indeed finds that women living in less egalitar-

    ian countries benefit less from their individual assets in the negotiation of

    housework. This is supported by an analysis of a subset of countries from the

    1994 ISSP, which shows that equal sharing of household tasks is particularly

    rare in countries with a conservative welfare state regime, independent ofthe partners relative resources, time availability, or gender ideology (Geist,

    2005). Finally, utilizing the 2002 ISSP on Gender Roles, Stier and Lewin-

    Epstein (2005) examine the effects of employment-supportive policies,

    gender inequalities in the labor market, and general attitudes toward gender

    roles on households division of unpaid work in 25 countries. Although it is

    shown that employment policies have no direct effect on couples division of

    labor, the authors findings suggest that gender inequalities in the labor

    market and a countrys gender ideologies do affect the level of gender equal-ity in the family.

    To our knowledge, though, no cross-national research has been carried

    out yet that pays particular attention to the gendered division of household

    labor among older couples. Filling in this gap for continental Europe, our

    study complements recent time-use research that points to significant inter-

    gender and intercountry differences in time-use patterns at older ages (cf.

    Croda & Gonzalez-Chapela, 2005; Gauthier & Smeeding, 2003). It also

    adds a European perspective to the so far almost exclusively U.S.-centered

    literature on the division of housework in later life, particularly after retire-

    ment. And finally, it investigates possible interactions between couple char-

    acteristics and the households country of residence in determining patterns

    of household labor.

    Method

    Data

    The data for our study are drawn from the 2004 SHARE (see http://www

    .share-project.org for more information). The SHARE is modeled closely

    after the U.S. Health and Retirement Study, and it is the first European data

    Hank, Jrges / Division of Household Labor 403

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    7/24

    set to combine extensive cross-national information about the socioeco-

    nomic status, health, and family relationships of the elderly population (see

    Brsch-Supan et al., 2005). Release 1 of the data contains informationabout some 22,000 individuals aged 50 or older from 15,000 households in

    10 countries, representing Europes economic, social, institutional, and cul-

    tural diversity from Scandinavia to the Mediterranean, including Sweden,

    Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, France (excluded from our study

    because of missing macrolevel information), Switzerland, Austria, Italy,

    Spain, and Greece. Probability samples have been drawn in each participat-

    ing country; the weighted average household response rate in the face-to-face

    part of the survey is 62 percent (a thorough description of methodologicalissues is contained in Brsch-Supan & Jrges, 2005).1 Our analytic sample

    was restricted (a) to respondents living in a marital or nonmarital union at the

    time of the interview and (b) to couples for whom at least one partner filled

    out the surveys self-completion questionnaire (which includes the question

    on which our dependent variable is based). This results in a total of 4,135

    observations (see Table 1 for details).

    VariablesThis article deals with routine housework (Coltrane, 2000, p. 1210). The

    construction of the dependent variable modifies Davis and Greensteins

    (2004) measure, taking advantage of the fact that the SHARE provides both

    partners assessments of who takes the primary responsibility for routine

    household chores (see Lee & Waite, 2005, for a discussion of alternative mea-

    sures). This is a major improvement over existing data sets such as the ISSP.

    The (generic) English version of the SHARE questionnaire asks, Who in the

    couple takes or took the main responsibility for cooking, cleaning the house,laundry and ironing? with five answer categories: myself only, myself

    mainly, myself and my partner equally, my partner mainly, and my

    partner only (coded 1 through 5). Because this question was posed to both

    partners, responses were relabeled to distinguish husbands from wives. To

    account for possible discrepancies in spouses responses (cf. Kamo, 2000;

    Lee & Waite, 2005), we use the mean of their respective answers. This infor-

    mation has been recoded, resulting in a variable ranging from 0 (both part-

    ners agree that the wife does all housework) to 1 (both partners agree that thehusband does all housework).2

    On the right-hand side of the regression, we use a set of standard micro-

    level explanatory variables including the partners age, education, (gross)

    income,3 employment status, and health, as well as information about the

    404 Journal of Family Issues

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    8/24

    405

    Table1

    DescriptiveStatistics

    Austria

    Germany

    Sweden

    Netherlands

    Spain

    Italy

    Denmark

    Greece

    Switzerland

    Genderdivisionofhouseholdlabor

    .203

    .242

    .262

    .252

    .156

    .179

    .295

    .130

    .2

    45

    Proportionofcoupleswith

    .105

    .172

    .167

    .166

    .088

    .112

    .236

    .065

    .1

    43

    equaldivision

    oflabora

    Maleincomefemaleincome

    .630

    .681

    .550

    .738

    .739

    .678

    .519

    .692

    .6

    35

    Maleinlaborfor

    ce

    .241

    .315

    .405

    .348

    .255

    .227

    .467

    .408

    .4

    29

    Femaleinlaborforce

    .200

    .293

    .450

    .270

    .126

    .154

    .462

    .214

    .3

    81

    Unmarriedcoupl

    e

    .038

    .048

    .083

    .039

    .076

    .017

    .077

    .012

    .0

    48

    Couplesmeanage

    62.268

    62.900

    63.664

    62.004

    65.309

    62.922

    61.228

    60.511

    63.2

    35

    Malefemaleage

    difference

    3.005

    2.513

    2.898

    2.736

    2.730

    3.663

    3.014

    5.750

    2.8

    62

    Male,higheduca

    tionaldegreeb

    .272

    .366

    .298

    .261

    .070

    .085

    .336

    .220

    .3

    12

    Female,highedu

    cationaldegreeb

    .143

    .235

    .312

    .139

    .035

    .098

    .379

    .144

    .1

    90

    Householdincom

    e(naturallog)

    9.456

    10.178

    10.689

    10.527

    9.133

    9.202

    10.857

    9.169

    10.4

    27

    Maleretiredfrom

    laborforce

    .697

    .589

    .554

    .495

    .651

    .746

    .484

    .557

    .5

    19

    Femaleretiredfromlaborforce

    .470

    .431

    .461

    .140

    .135

    .368

    .427

    .241

    .3

    92

    Numberofchildren

    2.107

    1.939

    2.540

    2.434

    2.727

    2.137

    2.353

    2.079

    2.2

    28

    Malecaresforgrandchildren

    .277

    .284

    .339

    .392

    .267

    .222

    .362

    .199

    .2

    01

    Femalecaresfor

    grandchildren

    .339

    .332

    .415

    .446

    .349

    .305

    .396

    .230

    .2

    17

    Malelimitedbyhealthproblems

    .437

    .479

    .390

    .367

    .393

    .327

    .387

    .246

    .2

    75

    Femalelimitedb

    yhealthproblems

    .425

    .503

    .423

    .476

    .487

    .376

    .405

    .250

    .3

    33

    Onlymaleresponseavailable

    .036

    .032

    .099

    .068

    .023

    .066

    .048

    .030

    .0

    53

    Onlyfemaleresp

    onseavailable

    .050

    .031

    .106

    .080

    .023

    .051

    .066

    .046

    .0

    16

    GEM

    .746

    .849

    1.000

    .888

    .583

    .181

    .979

    .000

    .7

    49

    N

    419

    587

    605

    664

    341

    410

    351

    569

    189

    Note:GEM=

    Un

    itedNationsgenderempowermentmeasure.

    a.Shareofcoupl

    eswithvaluesequaltoorlargerthan.5forthedivisionofho

    useworkvariable.

    b.InternationalS

    tandardClassificationofEducationcategories4orhigher.

    Source:SHARE

    2004(Release1),authorscalc

    ulations.

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    9/24

    partnersmarital status and family responsibilities (see Table 1 for descriptive

    statistics). One advantage of our data is that we have true couple information,

    that is, individual data for each question asked of each partner. This advan-tage also complicates matters because each individual variable type enters the

    analyses twice. Overall, we have thus opted for rather parsimonious but

    robust specifications.

    We measure household income by the relative income position in each

    country. More precisely, we compute country-specific income quintiles,

    which enter the regression as a set of dummy variables. This has the addi-

    tional advantage of combining flexibility in functional specification with ease

    of interpretation. We treat differences in the partners income as an indicatorof relative resources. Relative income of partners is coded as a set of dummy

    variables for which the baseline category represents couples whose individ-

    ual income is in the same country-specific (individual) income quintile. Thus,

    the two dummy variables indicate whether the female partner is in a higher

    or lower income quintile than the male partner.

    Employment status is used as an indicator of time availability. In the

    SHARE, respondents are asked to self-report employment status by select-

    ing one of the following categories: (a) retired, (b) employed or self-employed, (c) unemployed, (d) permanently sick or disabled, and (e)

    homemaker. We code as working all respondents who say they are currently

    employed or self-employed. The employment status variable is also used to

    create an indicator for past labor force status (retired), which may have last-

    ing effects for retired couples (see below for a discussion).

    Because less traditional gender ideologies have been shown to be closely

    associated with cohabitation (Batalova & Cohen, 2002; Cunningham, 2005;

    South & Spitze, 1994), union type is used to account for the gender ideol-

    ogy dimension at the level of couples.

    We measure the age (or cohort; this is equivalent in cross-sectional data)

    of a couple by the average age of both partners. Age differences between

    partners, which might indicate intracouple power relationships, are also

    included as control variables. They are measured as the male age minus the

    female age. Education enters the analysis as one dummy variable for high

    education for each partner, where high education is equivalent to an

    International Standard Classification of Education (ISCED) code of 4 or

    higher (beyond upper secondary education).Past and current family responsibilities are measured by the number

    of children the couple has and by a dummy variable that equals 1 if the

    respondent said that during the past 12 months, he or she has regularly or

    406 Journal of Family Issues

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    10/24

    occasionally looked after grandchildren without the presence of the

    parents.

    The SHARE contains a large amount of information about the respon-dents health status (including specific diagnoses, symptoms, etc.). In the

    context of our study, we are particularly interested in the effect of health-

    related limitations on daily activities (such as housework). Our health indi-

    cator is derived from a global activity limitation question: For the past 6

    months at least, to what extent have you been limited because of a health

    problem in activities people usually do? (1) severely limited, (2) limited, but

    not severely, (3) not limited. In the empirical part, we do not distinguish

    between degrees of limitation.Our main concern, however, is the role of societal factors in older cou-

    ples division of household labor. Like Batalova and Cohen (2002) and

    Fuwa (2004), we use the United Nations gender empowerment measure

    (GEM; see United Nations Development Program, 2004) as a core measure

    of macrolevel gender inequalities. The GEM is an index based on the per-

    centage of parliamentary seats held by women, the percentage of female

    administrators and managers, the percentage of professional and technical

    workers who are women, and womens share of earnings income. It rangesfrom 0 to 1, where higher scores represent greater levels of empowerment

    for women. Because the GEM is not available for France, this country was

    excluded from our analysis.

    Analytical Strategy

    To investigate the interaction between micro- and macrolevel determinants

    of older couples division of household labor, we estimate hierarchical linear

    models (Bryk & Raudenbush, 1992). This and similar kinds of multilevel

    modeling have become a popular alternative to estimating separate models

    for each country (or other levels of context) in the analysis (see Teachman &

    Crowder, 2002, for a review). We follow a stepwise procedure, starting with

    the empty Model 0, which includes no independent variables at all and

    examines the overall couple- and country-level variances. In Model 1, all

    couple-level characteristics are entered into the regression with fixed effects

    across countries. In Model 2, we allow the coefficients of the three main

    couple-level variablesthe malefemale income gap, the partners employ-ment status, and union typeto vary across countries. Finally, Model 3

    includes cross-level interactions between the GEM and the intercept as well

    as the slopes of the three main couple-level variables.

    Hank, Jrges / Division of Household Labor 407

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    11/24

    Empirical Findings

    Before presenting our multivariate results, we will briefly discuss twomain descriptive findings, displayed in Figure 1. First, there is an obvious

    northsouth divide in the gender division of labor in the SHARE countries.

    This is reflected in the distribution of the proportion of couples in which the

    partners share household tasks equally (including the small number of cases

    where the husband does more). Although, for example, in Greece and Spain

    less than 10 percent of couples aged 50 and older exhibit an equal division of

    labor in the household, this is the case in about 17 percent of Dutch, German,

    and Swedish couples. The top rank is held by the Danes, where one out offour couples shares core household tasks equally.4 Second, there is strong

    indication for a close relationship between the division of household labor

    among older couples and macrolevel gender inequalities.5 Plotting the pro-

    portion of couples with an equal division of housework against the GEM

    reveals a clear positive association. The four countries with above average

    proportions of older couples sharing housework equallythe Netherlands,

    Sweden, Germany, and Denmarkare also the ones with the highest GEM

    scores (.8 or more). Similar associations are also found with single items ofGEM, such as the proportion of female members of parliament or the

    femalemale wage ratio (details not shown here).

    We now turn to the multivariate analysis (see Table 2; note that positive

    coefficients indicate a larger share of the male partner in total housework).

    In Model 0, the between-country variance of the intercept is statistically

    significant. The variance components in this empty model suggest that

    about 10 percent of the overall variance in the division of housework is due

    to between-country variance (cf. Bryk & Raudensbush, 1992). A similar

    order of magnitude is reported in the studies by Fuwa (2004) and Stier and

    Lewin-Epstein (2005), for example. Including couple-level variables in

    Model 1 reduces the variance of country-level intercepts by almost half

    (from .0030 to .0017) and the couple-level variance by 7 percent (from

    .0279 to .0259). Turning to our main microlevel explanatory variables, we

    find an asymmetric effect of relative income: Men with a lower income than

    their female partners tend to do somewhat more housework than those hav-

    ing about the same income as their partners (where equal income is defined

    as being in the same income quintile), but the difference is not statisticallysignificant (cf. Bittman, England, Sayer, Folbre, & Matheson, 2003).

    However, if the wife earns less than her husband, the husbands share in

    household duties is significantly lower than in couples with about equal

    408 Journal of Family Issues

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    12/24

    income. With regard to time availability, we find that mens participation

    in the labor force also decreases males participation in household chores,

    whereas if the female partner engages in paid work, her husbands share of

    household labor increases. Finally, living in a nonmarital union also increases

    mens participation in housework strongly, supporting the view that cohabi-

    tation goes hand in hand with less traditional gender ideologies.Both male and female higher education, which is also likely to be posi-

    tively correlated with less traditional gender ideologies, contributes to a

    more gender-equal division of housework (e.g., Coltrane, 2000). Older

    Hank, Jrges / Division of Household Labor 409

    Figure 1

    Gender Empowerment Measure and Shares of Couples With

    Egalitarian Division of Household Labor Across Europe

    Note: at = Austria; ch = Switzerland; de = Germany; dk= Denmark; es = Spain; gr = Greece;

    it = Italy; nl = Netherlands; se = Sweden.

    Source: SHARE 2004 (Release 1), authors representation.

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    13/24

    410

    Table2

    DeterminantsofCouples

    DivisionofHousework:ResultsofHierarchicalLinearModels

    Model0

    Model1

    Model2

    Model3

    SE

    SE

    SE

    SE

    Intercept

    .2176**

    .0184

    .2177**

    .0147

    .2175**

    .0141

    .2172**

    0.0064

    GEM

    .1168**

    0.0194

    Maleincomefemaleincomea

    .0234**

    .0065

    .0246*

    .0077

    .0246*

    0.0088

    GEM

    .0089

    0.0250

    Maleinlaborfor

    ceb

    .0454**

    .0111

    .0461**

    .0117

    .0452**

    0.0119

    GEM

    .0227

    0.0212

    Femaleinlaborforceb

    .0618**

    .0079

    .0616**

    .0086

    .0620**

    .0096

    GEM

    .0115

    .0252

    Unmarriedcoupl

    e

    .0493**

    .0121

    .0600**

    .0160

    .0527*

    .0177

    GEM

    .0364

    .0592

    Couplesmeanage

    .0021**

    .0005

    .0021**

    .0005

    .0022**

    .0005

    Malefemaleage

    difference

    .0002

    .0006

    .0002

    .0006

    .0001

    .0006

    Male,higheduca

    tionaldegree

    .0147*

    .0067

    .0152*

    .0066

    .0150*

    .0066

    Female,highedu

    cationaldegree

    .0161*

    .0075

    .0157*

    .0075

    .0170*

    .0075

    Householdincom

    e,1stquintile

    .0118

    .0083

    .0113

    .0082

    .0123

    .0083

    Householdincom

    e,2ndquintile

    .0109

    .0082

    .0104

    .0081

    .0102

    .0081

    Householdincom

    e,4thquintile

    .0099

    .0082

    .0099

    .0081

    .0093

    .0082

    Householdincom

    e,5thquintile

    .0080

    .0084

    .0068

    .0084

    .0071

    .0084

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    14/24

    411

    Maleretiredfrom

    laborforceb

    .0149

    .0116

    .0156

    .0115

    .0139

    .0116

    Femaleretiredfromlaborforceb

    .0226**

    .0074

    .0234**

    .0073

    .0244**

    .0074

    Numberofchildr

    en

    .0106**

    .0020

    .0105**

    .0020

    .0108**

    .0020

    Malecaresforgr

    andchildren

    .0145

    .0084

    .0147

    .0084

    .0148

    .0084

    Femalecaresfor

    grandchildren

    .0178

    .0081

    .0174

    .0081

    .0177*

    .0081

    Malelimitedbyhealthproblems

    .0008

    .0056

    .0007

    .0055

    .0004

    .0055

    Femalelimitedbyhealthproblems

    .0152**

    .0054

    .0147**

    .0054

    .0142**

    .0054

    Onlymalerespon

    seavailable

    .0422**

    .0114

    .0413**

    .0114

    .0409**

    .0114

    Onlyfemaleresp

    onseavailable

    .0310**

    .0110

    .0305**

    .0109

    .0298**

    .0110

    Variancecompon

    ents

    Intercept

    .0030**

    .0017**

    .0017**

    .0002**

    Maleincomefemaleincome

    .0002

    .0002

    Maleinlaborforce

    .0001

    .0001

    Femaleinlaborf

    orce

    .0001

    .0002

    Unmarriedcouple

    .0010

    .0008

    Level1

    .0279

    .0259

    .0257

    .0257

    Note:GEM=

    Un

    itedNationsgenderempowermentmeasure.

    a.Referencecategory:maleincome=

    femalein

    come.

    b.Referencecate

    gory:males(females,respectiv

    ely)whoareneitheremployed

    norretired.

    significantat10%.

    *significantat5%.

    **signific

    antat1%.

    Source:SHARE2004(Release1),authorscalc

    ulations.

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    15/24

    412 Journal of Family Issues

    couples (i.e., those with a higher mean age) exhibit the expected more tra-

    ditional pattern of housework, whereas the age difference between the part-

    ners has no significant effect. Similarly, the coefficients of the dummyvariables for different levels of household income turn out to be statistically

    insignificant. However, there is some indication for a nonlinear relationship

    between mens participation in household tasks and household income: The

    negative coefficients for the lowest and highest income quintiles suggest

    that the contribution of the male partner might be lowest at the upper and

    lower bounds of the income distribution.

    If the woman has retired, her husbands share of household labor

    increases. At first glance, this might seem to be a surprising result, contra-dicting findings of previous studies (e.g., Szinovacz, 2000). In our model,

    however, the reference category consists of women who are neither gainfully

    employed nor retired. Because these are mostly housewives, retirement in our

    model is an indicator of womens previous labor force participation, which

    is likely to facilitate a somewhat more equal division of housework between

    the partners even after retirement (assuming continuity in household roles;

    e.g., Dorfman, 1992).6 Male retirement tends to be negatively correlated

    with the dependent variable, but the respective coefficient is not statisticallysignificant.

    Family obligations have an effect on older couples division of house-

    hold labor in the senses that an increase in the number of children is asso-

    ciated with a decrease in males participation in household chores and that

    men caring for grandchildren also take larger responsibilities within their

    own households. Limitations by health problems are not significant if they

    affect men, but they do result in a stronger engagement of the husband in

    household duties if the female partners health is limited. As a final couple-

    level control variable, we use information about whether only the male or

    only the female partner answered the question about the division of house-

    work. Consistent with previous studies (e.g., Kamo, 2000), mens involve-

    ment in household chores is reported to be stronger if the informant is a

    man himself, whereas it appears to be significantly weaker if only the

    wifes response is available (see below for further discussion).

    Allowing the relative resources, time availability, and gender ideology

    indicators to vary across countries in Model 2 does not change the coeffi-

    cients derived from the previous model. The variance components for theslopes of the respective variables are not statistically significant, which

    means that their effects do not differ by country. Model 3 finally includes

    the GEMs effect on the intercept and on the slopes of the malefemale

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    16/24

    Hank, Jrges / Division of Household Labor 413

    income gap, the partners employment status, and union type. The coeffi-

    cient for the effect of the GEM on the intercept is .1168 and is statistically

    significant. This means that holding constant microlevel characteristics,mens contribution to housework in more gender-egalitarian countries is

    substantially larger than elsewhere. Moreover, including the GEM reduces

    the remaining between-country variance of the intercept by almost 90

    percent, from .0017 to .0002! However, as already indicated in Model 2,

    the coefficients for the main microlevel variables generally do not vary

    between countries with higher or lower GEM scores. The only exception is

    the marginally significant effect of the GEM on the slope of the male

    income < female income dummy, suggesting that men in countries withhigher values of GEM contribute somewhat more housework if they earn

    less than their female partner, whereas this is not the case in countries with

    lower values of GEM.

    Following a reviewers recommendation, we also estimated Model 3

    separately for men and women (see appendix). As expected from our own

    previous findings, the predicted average division of household labor is

    larger in the male model (.2317) than in the female model (.2031). In

    particular, the positive association between mens contribution to house-hold chores and cohabitation or health limitations of the female partner

    appears to be stronger if the interviewee is male. Moreover, the variance

    of country-level intercepts is larger in the male model (.0018 vs. .0005),

    pointing to a greater cross-national heterogeneity in mens than in

    womens responses to the housework question in the SHARE. In contrast

    to the initial (couple-level) Model 3 and the male model, the positive

    effect of the GEM on the cohabitation slope is marginally significant if the

    respondent is female. This finding, however, cannot be considered as suf-

    ficiently robust to argue that gender ideology would be more effective in

    attaining a more egalitarian division of housework in more gender-equal

    countries.

    Discussion

    Using microdata from the SHARE, this study is the first to investigate

    the division of household labor among older couples in a cross-nationalperspective. Across continental Europe, we find considerable variation in

    the overall distribution of household labor. One may roughly distinguish

    between more egalitarian countries in northern Europe, such as Sweden and

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    17/24

    414 Journal of Family Issues

    particularly Denmark, on one hand, and more traditional countries in the

    southern parts of Europe, above all Spain and Greece, on the other hand.

    Because we are dealing with cohorts born in 1954 or earlier, it is not sur-prising to find a generally lower level of mens participation in housework

    than might have been expected from studies that are representative of the

    whole population (e.g., Davis & Greenstein, 2004, p. 1265).

    The outcome of the multivariate analysis suggests an asymmetric, that is,

    gendered, effect of the partners relative income. If the wife earns less than

    her husband, for example, the husbands share in household duties is signifi-

    cantly lower than in couples with about equal income, but there is no statis-

    tically significant effect of relative income if the reverse case is considered.Mens participation in the labor force decreases males participation in

    household chores, whereas the female partners engagement in paid work

    increases her husbands share of household labor. In addition to this support

    for the time-availability hypothesis, we find evidence that less traditional

    gender ideologiesindicated by cohabitation and higher education

    contribute to a more gender-equal division of housework. However, our

    multilevel analysis reveals no country-specific effects of these couple-level

    characteristics. The latter finding is different from Fuwa (2004), who pro-vides evidence that relevant microlevel factors have weaker effects on the

    division of household labor for women who live in countries with less pro-

    nounced gender equality. The lack of support for the macrolevel discount fac-

    tor argument in our study may result from a common baseline level of gender

    equality in our sample of nine countries, which might be too high to allow the

    identification of effects such as those revealed in Fuwas analysis of 22 more

    diverse nations.

    Although our results point to a greater cross-national heterogeneity in

    mens than in womens responses to the housework question in the SHARE,

    a general finding is that about half of the between-country variance in the

    division of housework is due to cross-country differences in couples

    characteristics. Still, we find a significant effect of macrolevel gender

    inequalities on couples division of housework. Even when controlling for

    individual characteristics of the household, couples living in countries

    with higher scores of GEM are more likely to exhibit an equal sharing of

    household labor (see Figure 1). Discussing the mechanisms through which

    gender empowerment may work, Batalova and Cohen (2002) suggest thatnorms about the division of labor may . . . be affected by womens visi-

    bility in positions of public authority and prestige (p. 753). This points to

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    18/24

    Hank, Jrges / Division of Household Labor 415

    the role of broader cultural mechanisms in shaping cross-national variations

    in the division of household laborand although the GEM accounts for a

    major share of the between-country variance in the distribution of house-work, our analysis still points to the presence of (statistically) significant,

    unobserved macrolevel heterogeneity. Bianchi et al. (2000) conclude that

    much of the increase in mens share of housework observed in younger U.S.

    cohorts is because of their increased willingness to perform this labor,

    which is likely to have resulted from

    changed attitudes about what is expected, reasonable, and fair for men to

    contribute to the maintenance of their home [. . . as well as from . . .] cul-tural change in ideas about womens work. It is likely more acceptable for

    men to cook and clean, indeed, welcomed, for men to show competence at

    making a home-cooked meal, for example. (p. 219)

    Such intertemporal cultural changes are visible as cross-cultural differences

    in our investigation.7

    This study has some limitations that call for further research. First and

    foremost, the current SHARE data allow only a cross-sectional view. Thatis, we cannot observe actual changes in housework after retirement. Our

    rough cross-sectional evidence as well as previous U.S. research suggests

    that such changes tend to be small. However, the magnitude of these

    changes is likely not only to increase in the future (when new generations

    of more highly educated women will enter retirement), but also to vary

    across national contexts. Exploiting such intertemporal and intercountry

    variations should be a promising field for future research. Second, com-

    pared to the ISSP, for example, the sample of countries currently repre-

    sented in the SHARE is relatively small. In particular, former Socialist

    societies are yet missing. Future studies of the division of housework

    among older couples should not only aim at an extension of the spatial and

    time dimensions of their analyses, though. They should, third, also try at the

    microlevel to account for complementary productive activities of elders

    inside and outside their own homes (see Hook, 2004) and at the macrolevel

    to include indicators that allow development of a better grasp of the cultural

    factors contributing to the persistence of the gendered division of (house-

    hold) labor.8 Although some suggestions in this latter regard have alreadybeen put forward (such as national cohabitation rates, used by Batalova &

    Cohen, 2002), much more systematic work needs still to be done.

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    19/24

    416

    Appendix

    DeterminantsofCouplesDivisio

    nofHousework:ResultsofHierarchicalLinearModels,WithSeparate

    EstimationsforMaleandF

    emaleRespondents

    Model3:Male

    Model3:Female

    SE

    SE

    Intercept

    .2317**

    .0054

    .2031**

    .0083

    GEM

    .1236**

    .0165

    .1119**

    .0251

    Maleincomefemaleincomea

    .0265*

    .0109

    .0241**

    .0102

    GEM

    .0215

    .0311

    .0053

    .0288

    Maleinlaborfor

    ceb

    .0457**

    .0138

    .0501*

    .0142

    GEM

    .0250

    .0238

    .0231

    .0241

    Femaleinlaborforceb

    .0591**

    .0113

    .0644**

    .0120

    GEM

    .0282

    .0300

    .0021

    .0317

    Unmarriedcoupl

    e

    .0678**

    .0203

    .0411

    .0237

    GEM

    .0155

    .0690

    .0635

    .0786

    Couplesmeanage

    .0027**

    .0005

    .0019**

    .0006

    Malefemaleage

    difference

    .0007

    .0007

    .0004

    .0007

    Male,higheduca

    tionaldegree

    .0138

    .0077

    .0163*

    .0081

    Female,highedu

    cationaldegree

    .0131

    .0088

    .0192*

    .0092

    Householdincom

    e,1stquintile

    .0094

    .0098

    .0163

    .0102

    Householdincom

    e,2ndquintile

    .0065

    .0096

    .0121

    .0100

    Householdincom

    e,4thquintile

    .0015

    .0096

    .0137

    .0100

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    20/24

    417

    Householdincom

    e,5thquintile

    .0100

    .0099

    .0091

    .0104

    Maleretiredfrom

    laborforceb

    .0117

    .0137

    .0175

    .0142

    Femaleretiredfromlaborforceb

    .0266**

    .0085

    .0217*

    .0091

    Numberofchildren

    .0091**

    .0024

    .0129**

    .0025

    Malecaresforgrandchildren

    .0104

    .0100

    .0145

    .0104

    Femalecaresfor

    grandchildren

    .0180

    .0096

    .0139

    .0100

    Malelimitedbyhealthproblems

    .0057

    .0065

    .0054

    .0068

    Femalelimitedb

    yhealthproblems

    .0179**

    .0064

    .0094

    .0066

    Variancecompon

    ents

    Intercept

    .0018**

    .0005**

    Maleincome

    femaleincome

    .0005

    .0004

    Maleinlaborforce

    .0002

    .0002

    Femaleinlabo

    rforce

    .0004

    .0004

    Unmarriedcou

    ple

    .0013

    .0024

    Level1

    .0337

    .0369

    Note:GEM=

    Un

    itedNationsgenderempower

    mentmeasure.

    a.Referencecate

    gory:maleincome=femalein

    come.

    b.Referencecate

    gory:males(females,respectively)whoareneitheremployed

    norretired.

    significantat10%.

    *significantat5%.

    **signific

    antat1%.

    Source:SHARE

    2004(Release1),authorscalc

    ulations.

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    21/24

    418 Journal of Family Issues

    Notes

    1. For details on survey participation, item nonresponse, and imputations in the Survey ofHealth, Ageing and Retirement in Europe (SHARE), see de Luca and Peracchi (2005) and

    Kalwij and van Soest (2005).

    2. In 95 percent of our observations, both partners chose the same or a neighboring answer

    category. Values indicating that the male partner does the main share or even all of the house-

    work are observed for less than 2 percent of our sample.

    3. Missing values are a particular concern in the case of income variables. In our study we

    use imputed information about income provided from the data by the SHARE group. See

    Brugiavini, Croda, Paccagnella, Rainato, and Weber (2005) for a detailed description of the

    applied imputation procedures.

    4. The proportion of older French couples with an equal division of household labor (asestimated from the SHARE data) is 16 percent, that is, slightly above the average of the nine

    countries included in our full analysis.

    5. To ease the interpretation of the size effect of the United Nations gender empowerment

    measure, we rescaled the values published by the UN so that the country in our sample with

    the lowest score has value zero and the country with the highest score has value one.

    6. The coefficients of the variables for participation in the labor force and retirement are

    significantly different from each other (both for males and for females). Although this provides

    some indication for postretirement changes in the division of household labor, these changes

    are obviously too small to affect the basic distribution of work between men and women.

    7. A closely related issue concerns cross-national variations in equity points. An unequal(i.e., not 5050) distribution of household labor need not necessarily be perceived as unfair.

    However, only since the 1990s has research begun to isolate conditions associated with label-

    ing divisions of housework as fair or unfair (Coltrane, 2000). Recent work by Davis (2004) not

    only reveals cross-national differences in womens average perceptions of fairness of the divi-

    sion of household labor, but also shows that these differences are affected by a countrys polit-

    ical and economic history as well as by womens overall empowerment.

    8. This is not to say that economic factors contributing to greater gender material equality

    would be irrelevant (cf. Breen & Cooke, 2005).

    References

    Batalova, J. A., & Cohen, P. N. (2002). Premarital cohabitation and housework: Couples in

    cross-national perspective.Journal of Marriage and Family, 64, 743-755.

    Baxter, J. (1997). Gender equality and participation in housework: A cross-national perspec-

    tive. Comparative Family Studies, 28, 220-248.

    Becker, G. S. (1981).A treatise on the family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Bianchi, S. M., Milkie, M. A., Sayer, L. C., & Robinson, J. P. (2000). Is anyone doing the

    housework? Trends in the gender division of household labor. Social Forces, 79, 191-228.

    Bittman, M., England, P., Sayer, L., Folbre, N., & Matheson, G. (2003). When does gendertrump money? Bargaining and time in household work. American Journal of Sociology,

    109, 186-214.

    Blumberg, R. L. (1984). A general theory of gender stratification. Sociological Theory, 2, 23-101.

    Brsch-Supan, A., Brugiavini, A., Jrges, H., Mackenbach, J., Siegrist, J., & Weber, G. (Eds.).

    (2005).Health, ageing and retirement in EuropeFirst results from the Survey of Health,

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    22/24

    Hank, Jrges / Division of Household Labor 419

    Ageing and Retirement in Europe. Mannheim, Germany: Mannheim Research Institute for

    the Economics of Aging. Available at http://www.share-project.org.

    Brsch-Supan, A., & Jrges, J. (Eds.). (2005). The Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirementin EuropeMethodology. Mannheim, Germany: Mannheim Research Institute for the

    Economics of Ageing. Available at http://www.share-project.org.

    Breen, R., & Cooke, L. P. (2005). The persistence of the gendered division of domestic labour.

    European Sociological Review, 21, 43-57.

    Brines, J. (1993). The exchange value of housework.Rationality and Society, 5, 302-340.

    Brugiavini, A., Croda, E., Paccagnella, O., Rainato, R., & Weber, G. (2005). Generated income

    variables in SHARE Release 1. In A. Brsch-Supan & H. Jrges (Eds.), The Survey of

    Health, Ageing and Retirement in EuropeMethodology (pp. 105-113). Mannheim,

    Germany: Mannheim Research Institute for the Economics of Aging.

    Bryk, A. S., & Raudenbush, S. W. (1992).Hierarchical linear models: Applications and dataanalysis methods. Newbury Park: Sage.

    Caro, F. G., & Bass, S. A. (1995). Increasing volunteering among older people. In S. A. Bass

    (Ed.), Older and active: How Americans over 55 are contributing to society. New Haven:

    Yale University Press, 71-96.

    Chang, M. L. (2000). The evolution of sex segregation regimes. American Journal of

    Sociology, 105, 1658-1701.

    Coltrane, S. (2000). Research on household labor: Modeling and measuring the social embed-

    dedness of routine family work.Journal of Marriage and Family, 62, 1208-1233.

    Coverman, S. (1985). Explaining husbands participation in domestic labor. Sociological

    Quarterly, 26, 81-97.Croda, E., & Gonzalez-Chapela, J. (2005). How do European older adults use their time? In

    A. Brsch-Supan, A. Brugiavini, H. Jrges, J. Mackenbach, J. Siegrist, & G. Weber (Eds.),

    Health, ageing and retirement in EuropeFirst results from the Survey of Health, Ageing

    and Retirement in Europe (pp. 265-271). Mannheim, Germany: Mannheim Research

    Institute for the Economics of Aging.

    Cunningham, M. (2005). Gender in cohabitation and marriage: The influence of gender ideol-

    ogy on housework allocation over the life course.Journal of Family Issues, 26, 1037-1061.

    Davis, S. N. (2004). Is justice contextual? A cross-national analysis of womens perceptions

    of fairness of the division of household labor. Unpublished manuscript, Carolina

    Population Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.Davis, S. N., & Greenstein, T. N. (2004). Cross-national variations in the division of house-

    hold labor.Journal of Marriage and Family, 66, 1260-1271.

    de Luca, G., & Peracchi, F. (2005). Survey participation in the first wave of SHARE. In

    A. Brsch-Supan & H. Jrges (Eds.), The Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in

    EuropeMethodology (pp. 88-104). Mannheim, Germany: Mannheim Research Institute

    for the Economics of Aging.

    de Ruijter, E., Treas, J. K., & Cohen, P. N. (2005). Outsourcing the gender factory: Living

    arrangements and service expenditures on female and male tasks. Social Forces, 84, 305-322.

    Dorfman, L. T. (1992). Couples in retirement. Division of household work. In M. Szinovacz,

    D. J. Ekerdt, & B. H. Vinick (Eds.), Families and retirement: Conceptual and method-ological issues. Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 159-173.

    Elder, L. (2004). Why women dont run: Explaining womens underrepresentation in

    Americas political institutions. Women & Politics, 26, 27-56.

    Erlinghagen, M., & Hank, K. (2006). Participation of older Europeans in volunteer work.

    Ageing & Society, 26, 567-584.

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    23/24

    420 Journal of Family Issues

    Fuwa, M. (2004). Macro-level gender inequality and the division of household labor in 22

    countries.American Sociological Review, 69, 751-767.

    Gauthier, A., & Smeeding, T. (2003). Time use at older ages: Cross-national differences.Research on Aging, 25, 247-274.

    Geist, C. (2005). The welfare state and the home: Regime differences in the domestic division

    of labour.European Sociological Review, 21, 23-41.

    Greenstein, T. N. (1996). Husbands participation in domestic labor: Interactive effects of

    wives and husbands gender ideologies.Journal of Marriage and Family, 58, 585-595.

    Greenstein, T. N. (2000). Economic dependence, gender, and the division of labor in the home:

    A replication and extension.Journal of Marriage and Family, 62, 322-335.

    Hayslip, B., & Kaminski, P. L. (2005). Grandparents raising their grandchildren: A review of

    the literature and suggestions for practice. The Gerontologist, 45, 262-269.

    Herzog, A. R., & Morgan, J. N. (1992). Age and gender differences in the value of productiveactivities.Research on Aging, 14, 169-198.

    Hook, J. L. (2004). Reconsidering the division of household labor: Incorporating volunteer

    work and informal support.Journal of Marriage and Family, 66, 101-117.

    Huber, J. (1990). Macro-micro links in gender stratification.American Sociological Review,

    55, 1-10.

    Jacobs, J. A. (1996). Gender inequality in higher education.Annual Review of Sociology, 22,

    153-185.

    Kalwij, A., & van Soest, A. (2005). Item non-response and alternative imputation procedures.

    In A. Brsch-Supan & H. Jrges (Eds.), The Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in

    EuropeMethodology (pp. 128-150). Mannheim, Germany: Mannheim Research Institutefor the Economics of Aging.

    Kamo,Y. (2000). He said, she said: Assessing discrepancies in husbands and wives reports

    on the division of household labor. Social Science Research, 29, 459-476.

    Lee, Y.-S., & Waite, L. J. (2005). Husbands and wives time spent on housework: A compar-

    ison of measures.Journal of Marriage and Family, 67, 328-336.

    Mason, K. O. (1997). Gender and demographic change: What do we know? In G. W. Jones,

    R. M. Douglas, J. C Caldwell, & R. M. DSouza (Eds.), The continuing demographic tran-

    sition (pp. 158-182). Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.

    Morrow-Howell, N., Hinterlong, J., & Sherraden, M. (Eds.). (2001). Productive aging: A con-

    ceptual framework. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.OReilly, P., & Caro, F. G. (1994). Productive aging: An overview of the literature.Journal of

    Aging and Social Policy, 6, 39-71.

    Orloff, A. (1996). Gender in the welfare state.Annual Review of Sociology, 22, 51-78.

    Pebley, A. R., & Rudkin, L. L. (1999). Grandparents caring for grandchildren: What do we

    know?Journal of Family Issues, 20, 218-242.

    Sanchez, L. (1993). Womens power and the gendered division of domestic labor in the third

    world. Gender & Society, 7, 434-459.

    Sanchez, L. (1994). Material resources, family structure resources, and husbands housework

    participation: A cross-national comparison.Journal of Family Issues, 15, 379-402.

    Sarkisian, N., & Gerstel, N. (2004). Explaining the gender gap in help to parents: The impor-tance of employment.Journal of Marriage and Family, 66, 431-451.

    Shelton, B. A., & John, D. (1996). The division of household labor. Annual Review of

    Sociology, 22, 299-322.

    Solomon, C. R., Acock, A. C., & Walker, A. J. (2004). Gender ideology and investment in

    housework: Postretirement change.Journal of Family Issues, 25, 1050-1071.

    by maria monalisa on October 15, 2012jfi.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/http://jfi.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Gender and the Division of Household Labor in Older Couples

    24/24

    Hank, Jrges / Division of Household Labor 421

    South, S. J., & Spitze, G. (1994). Housework in marital and nonmarital households.American

    Sociological Review, 59, 327-347.

    Stier, H., & Lewin-Epstein, N. (2005, May). Policy effects on the division of housework. Paperpresented at the spring meeting of the ISA Research Committee 28, Oslo, Norway.

    Stoller, E. P., & Cutler, S. J. (1993). Predictors of use of paid help among older people living

    in the community. The Gerontologist, 33, 31-40.

    Sundstrm, M., & Duvander, A.-Z. (2002). Gender division of child care and the sharing of

    parental leave among new parents in Sweden.European Sociological Review, 18, 433-447.

    Szinovacz, M. E. (2000). Changes in housework after retirement: A panel analysis.Journal of

    Marriage and Family, 62, 78-92.

    Teachman, J. D., & Crowder, K. D. (2002). Multilevel models in family research: Some con-

    ceptual and methodological issues.Journal of Marriage and Family, 64, 280-294.

    Thompson, L., & Walker,A. J. (1989). Gender in families: Women and men in marriage, work,and parenthood.Journal of Marriage and Family, 51, 845-871.

    United Nations Development Program (UNDP). (2004). Human development report. New

    York: UNDP.