game of brains - algebris...for tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): jacopo bassetto francesco filippucci...

24
Game of Brains 21st century Italian emigration. MAY 2019 RESEARCH COLLAB | APRF + TORTUGA |

Upload: others

Post on 17-Aug-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Game of Brains21st century Italian emigration.

M A Y 2 0 1 9

R E S E A R C H CO L L A B |A P R F + TO R T U G A |

Page 2: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The
Page 3: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

R E S E A R C H CO L L A B

Brain Drain: quick review

Brain drain is a well-documented and researched phenomenon – asso-

ciated with the migration of high-skilled and well-educated individuals in

pursuit of higher remuneration1, better work opportunities2, better living

standards, or fleeing from places where unfavourable social conditions

prevail, including areas with low levels of civic spirit3.

The phenomenon presents challenges and opportunities. A negative

‘brain balance’ is typical of developing economies4, which often risk ‘lo-

sing’ their talents. This eventuality creates a disincentive for the countries

of emigration to invest in the development of high-level human capital.

Brain drain also impacts recipient countries, in several ways. First, inflows

of high-skilled migrants – often concentrated in the STEM fields – may

increase specialization as well as the potential for radical innovation in

the receiving labour market. There is also evidence of high-skilled mi-

grants displaying a higher tendency to become entrepreneurs than na-

tives5, thus boosting productivity and profitability in the receiving eco-

nomies. Moreover, the mobility and circulation of high-skilled individuals

may help share technology and knowledge6. For the countries of emi-

gration, the balance hangs on whether re-attracting and retaining talent

is possible. Absent flows of return migration, or inflows of high-skilled

foreigners, brain drain could ignite a vicious circle between low growth

potential and inability to accumulate much needed human capital7.

Importantly, global high-skilled migration has been increasing over the

past decades. Among OCED countries, the number of migrants with ter-

tiary education grew by almost 130% between 1990 and 2010. Over the

same period, low-skilled migration grew by 40% ‘only’. In part, this boom

in high-skilled migration has to be read within a context of greatly dee-

pened global interconnectedness. Between 1975 and 2008, in fact, the

population of international students (who often remain in the countries

where they pursue their studies and create a ‘network effect’ that further

attracts nationals of the countries of origin) has increased to 3.3 million.

1 Rosenzweig, Mark R. “Global Wage Differences And International Student Flows”. Brookings Trade Forum, vol 2006, no. 1, 2006, pp. 57-86. Project Muse

2 Mayda, Anna Maria. “International Migration: A Panel Data Analysis Of The Determinants Of Bilateral Flows”. Journal Of Population Economics, vol 23, no. 4, 2009, pp. 1249-1274. Springer Nature

Grogger, Jeffrey, and Gordon H. Hanson. “Attracting Talent: Location Choices Of Foreign-Born Phds In The United States”. Journal Of Labor Economics, vol 33, no. S1, 2015, pp. S5-S38. University Of Chicago Press

3 Casari, Marco, et al. “Civicness drain.” (2018) show how individuals from geographical areas within Italy characterized by a low “civic spirit” tend to migrate internally to the country, whereas individuals from areas that display a higher “civic spirit” tend to be more likely to move abroad.

4 Hanson, Gordon H. “The Economic Consequences Of The International Migration Of Labor”. Annual Review Of Economics, vol 1, no. 1, 2009, pp. 179-208. Annual Reviews.

5 Fairlie, Robert W., and Magnus Lofstrom. “Immigration and entrepreneurship.” Handbook of the economics of international migration. Vol. 1. North-Holland, 2015. 877-911.

6 Fairlie e Lofstrom (2015) and Hanson (2009)

7 Demange, Gabrielle, Robert Fenge, and Silke Uebelmesser. “Financing higher education in a mobile world.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 16.3 (2014): 343-371.

For Algebris Policy & Research Forum:

Silvia MerlerHead of Research

For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu):

Jacopo BassettoFrancesco Filippucci

Edoardo MagaliniFilippo Passerini

Sara Rabino

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

(“The Forum”) is a not-for-profit

advisory forum designed to pro-

mote and encourage a strong and

balanced economy, based on a

sound financial system supported

by a transparent regulatory and

fiscal environment for the benefit

of society as a whole.

The Forum aims to achieve its

mission by sharing expert know-

ledge and research with the ge-

neral public.

The Forum will publish expert re-

ports and recommendations on

financial topics that address the

stability of the global economy

and politics including European

integration, political issues (e.g.

immigration, trade policy), macro-

economic trends (e.g. wage stag-

nation, income inequality).

The Forum is entirely independent

of the commercial operations of

Algebris (UK) Limited.

3

Page 4: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Brain Drain in Europe during the Crisis

Within the European Union, emigration has occured in large numbers

and for some time from Eastern towards Western EU Member States, es-

pecially after the eastern enlargements. More recently, however, we have

witnessed important flows of emigration also across the Western Euro-

pean Members States, in the context of the Global Financial Crisis first,

and the Eurozone crisis later. The economic and financial turmoil that

dominated the Eurozone between 2009 and 2013 contributed to unveil

deep structural differences across countries.. Declining standards of li-

ving in what has since become known as the ‘Southern periphery’ were

associated with quickly growing unemployment and poverty incidence,

especially among the young generations.

What is perhaps even more important, when looking at push factors for

young skilled emigration, is the rapid increase in the duration of youth

unemployment. Figure 1 below shows that long-term unemployment

came to account for a larger and larger share of total youth unemploy-

ment, between 2008 and 2014. In Italy and Greece, 60% of all young

people who were unemployed in 2014 had been in such condition for

longer than 1 year. In both countries, the share is still around 50% today,

testifying to an important ongoing process of skills deterioration in these

countries

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

Figure 1 • Share of total youth unemployment lasting more than 1 year (%)

Source: Authors’ calculations based on OECD data on inciden-ce of unemployment by duration

“50% of unemployed

young people in Italy

today have been in such

state for 1 year or more”

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

4

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

France Germany Greece Italy Portugal Spain Ireland

Page 5: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Unsurprisingly, dire economic and social conditions were accompanied

by a widespread phenomenon of South-to-North migration, as young

people increasingly fled crisis countries in search for better opportunities.

The crude net migration rate turned negative – signalling net emigration

– in Ireland in 2009, in Greece in 2010, in Portugal in 2011 and in Spain in

2012. This dynamic is also visible in the substantial increase in inflows of

migrants from the Eurozone South to the Eurozone North (Figure, 2 left).

Emigration from Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain more than doubled

between 2007 and 2013. Emigration from Italy has increased significan-

tly since 2012. Only recently have these flows started to slowly level off,

though they continue to be much larger than prior to the crisis.

The counterpart to this massive Southern ‘exit’ has been a significant de-

terioration in the ability of Mediterranean countries to attract talent or

even just retain existing one. One way to measure this loss is through

the World Economic Forum’s ‘brain drain index’ (Figure 2, right). A look

at the time dynamics of this indicator suggest two considerations. First,

the sizeable (and potentially structural) effect of the crisis on those coun-

tries that underwent EU/IMF macroeconomic adjustment programmes

is strikingly evident. While ‘North’ and ‘South’ before the crisis were very

similar in terms of their capacity to attract and retain talent, today the gap

in attractiveness is large - with the periphery lagging far behind. Second,

Italy stands out as an outlier. Its ability to attract and retain talent was

structurally lower already before the crisis, and it has been on a declining

path since the mid-2000s.

Source: LeFT: Authors’ calcula-tions based on OECD internatio-nal migration database

NoTe: South = Greece, Portugal, Spain (no data for Ireland). North = Austria, Belgium, Finland, Germany, Netherlands (France is excluded due to missing data before 2012)

Source: rIGHT: Authors’ calcu-lations based on data from the World Economic Forum

NoTe: South = Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Spai); North = Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Netherlands

Figure 2 • South-to-North Migration (left) and Brain Drain (right)

“Italy is structurally

weak at retaining and

attracting talent”

5

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

Brain Drain Index (1=worst; 7=best)

North South Italy

0

20000

40000

60000

80000

100000

120000

140000

160000

180000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

South-to-North migration (th.)

South Italy

Page 6: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Brain Drain in Italy

Overview

Emigration of Italian citizens is nearing a five-decade high – at le-

vels that were last seen in the 1970s (IMF 2019). Italy is going back to

being a country of emigrants, and its structurally low ability to attract

and retain talent makes it an especially interesting case to investigate

the dynamics of brain drain in an advanced economy. The boom in e-

migration observed since 2008 is not physiological but pathological: while

during the previous decade emigration was fairly stable and insensitive to

unemployment dynamics, starting in 2008 they have been going hand in

hand (Figure 3).

The growing trend is mostly explained by emigration of Italians youn

ger than 45, while outflows have been increasing only slightly for the

45-64 cohort and have remained stable among those 65 years old or older.

Geographically, most of those who migrate come originally from the

north of Italy, which is perhaps unexpected in light of the historically high

migration from the south - both internally and abroad. The preferred de-

stination is by far Western Europe – in line with the easiness to travel

and relocate that EU citizens enjoy within the Schengen area. In terms

of gender, Italian emigration is composed mostly by men, although the

post- 2008 boom has also seen a significant increase in the number of

women emigrants (Figure 4).

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

Emigrants per 100 th inhabitants Unemployment rate

Figure 3 • Emigrants (LHS) and Unemployment (RHS)

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from Anelli & Peri (2017)

“The Italian boom in emigration since 2008 is not physiological but pathological”

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

6

Page 7: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

A negative skill balance

Most importantly, recent Italian emigration has been characterized by

‘brain drain’ features. The number of migrants holding at least a ba-

chelor degree more than tripled in ten years, while the increase is much

smaller among lower educated Italians. To understand who these mobile

emigrating graduates are, we exploit a survey conducted by ISTAT8. The

survey includes interviews collected in 2011 on a sample of 30 000 Ita-

lians who graduated in 2007, and again in 2015 on a sample who gradu-

ated in 2011 9. The results in Figure 5 below show that the share of gradu-

ate emigrants holding a bachelor degree doubled in about five years. The

share of people holding a master degree who emigrate is also significan

tly higher. By contrast, respondents who graduated in a 4 to 6 six years

degree remained constant across the two waves of the survey - probably

an effect of the phasing out of the old system of tertiary education.

Looking at the differences in educational levels of respondents by re-

sidency, it can be seen that 58% of those who are resident in Italy at-

tained a Bachelor degree in 2007, whereas among the respondents

living abroad the share is less than 50%. On the contrary, the share of

8 The Italian Insitute of Statistics

9 Methodological note: administrative data account for the number of people moving their residency and thus tend to underestimate the real number of emigrants, especially those moving (or intending to move) for short periods of time. The data from ISTAT survey of graduates allow for a better comparison with the population, although the risk of underestimation is still present – mostly due to non-responses.

Figure 4 • Emigration by age, gender, region of origin, and destination

0.00%

0.05%

0.10%

0.15%

0.20%

0.25%

0.30%

0.35%

0.40%

0.45%

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

0-24 25-44 45-64 >65

0.00%

0.05%

0.10%

0.15%

0.20%

0.25%

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Sud Centro Nord

0.00%

0.05%

0.10%

0.15%

0.20%

0.25%

0.30%

0.35%

0.40%

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

Maschi Femmine

0.00%

0.05%

0.10%

0.15%

0.20%

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

Western Europe Other

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from ISTAT

“Those who leave have on average a higher educational attainment than those who stay”

7

Page 8: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

those who attained a Master degree or equivalent is less than 17% among

the respondents resident in Italy, but it reaches 33% among those who

moved abroad. When looking at the 2015 cohorts, the share of Italians

resident abroad who hold a Master or equivalent is 43% - testifying to the

relevance of skilled movement in the context of the most recent wave of

Italian emigration (Figure 6).

Moreover, there seems to be a strong process of self-selection among

those who leave. Looking at the 2011 ISTAT survey cohort, the students

who graduated with the highest marks (honours, or ‘110 cum laude’ in

Italian) represent 40% of the graduates living abroad, but only less than

25% among those who stayed. In other words, not only is Italy losing a

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

Figure 5 • Emigration by education (LHS) Residents abroad by education (RHS)

Figure 6 • Educational attainment by residency, 2015 vs 2011

14.97%5.34%

28.37%42.98%

56.66%51.68%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Residents in Italy Residents abroad

2015

Bachelor (3 years) Master (2 years) Old system (4-6 year)

25.34%18.32%

16.58% 32.61%

58.08%49.06%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Residents in Italy Residents abroad

2011

Bachelor (3 years) Master (2 years) Old system (4-6 year)

-0.1%

0.0%

0.1%

0.2%

0.3%

0.4%

0.5%

0.6%

0.7%

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

Tertiary and post

Upper secondary

1.75%

7.03%

4.36%

1.71%

4.52%

1.99%

0% 2% 4% 6% 8%

Old system (4-6 year)

Master (2 years)

Bachelor (3 years)

Intervistati nel 2011 Intervistati nel 2015

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from ISTAT

“Graduates with honors are 40% among mov-ers, but only to 25% among stayers”

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

8

Page 9: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

relatively larger proportion of high-skilled young people compared to

low-skilled ones, but those who go are on the right tail of the distribution,

in terms of their academic achievement (the ‘best and brightest’).

Focusing on the fields of study prevalent among the emigrants, it emer

ges from Figure 7 above that the largest increase in emigration has oc-

curred among graduates in the STEM fields (science, technology, en-

gineering and mathematics). The share of graduates in economics and

statistics, scientific subjects, and engineering living abroad has more than

doubled between 2011 and 2015. In 2015, the graduates in scientific fields

represented the largest share among those residing abroad (7.4%), fol-

lowed by the engineers (6.7%) and architects (6.5%).

Another very worrying aspect of the recent Italian brain drain is the fact

that the emigration of Italian skilled workers described above is not com-

pensated by an inflow of foreign brains. Although the topic of immigration

has been growing in saliency in the Italian political discourse over the

past few years, the cumulated net migration balance shown in Figure 8

(left) suggests that Italy’s net migration has been growing increasingly

negative, especially for high skills. Moreover,Italy is the destination to one

of the lowest shares of foreign skilled immigrants among OECD countries

(Figure 8, right). These factors combine to determine a clear loss and a

potential disincentive to invest in human capital formation.

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from ISTAT, survey of graduates, weighted data

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from ISTAT,

Figure 7 • Italian graduates abroad by field of study

3.0%

2.2%

2.7%

3.5%

0.7%

3.2%

1.9%

0.6% 0.5%

4.6%5.0% 5.1%

7.4%

1.1%

6.7%6.5%

1.4%1.0%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

8%

2011 2015

“The largest increase in emigration has been taking place among STEM graduates”

9

Page 10: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Revamped dualism

Looking at the gender composition of emigration, we detect the signs of

a ‘new gender gap’ suggesting that women may be slightly less likely to

migrate. Women represent a clear majority (58%) among the 2007 gra-

duates living in Italy, but less so among those living abroad (52%). Across

the 2011 cohort, the share of women living in Italy reaches 59% whereas

it remains at 52% among the emigrants. This may be the side effect of a

gender-led selection into different areas of study – with men having a

higher tendency to enrol into those STEM fields that we have shown to

be the source of most high-skilled Italian emigration.

We also see evidence of a north-south gap. Those who pursue their stu-

dies in the north of Italy have a higher likelihood of moving abroad (Figure

9). This testifies to the stronger competitiveness of northern universities

in producing ‘exportable’ skills. If we look at where the movers come from

before enrolling in northern universities, the picture however changes

considerably. Many of the respondents who graduate from universities in

the north of the country and then move abroad is in fact originally from

the south of Italy. The emigrants who graduated from northern universi-

ties were 57% of the total in 2011 and 60% in 2015, but only 44% and 53%

respectively were from the north of Italy. This points to the existence of a

process of ‘two-steps-migration’, whereby young Italians from the more

disadvantaged southern regions move first to the north of Italy to build

their human capital, and then abroad, to further their education or work.10

10 A similar analysis has been conducted also on PhD graduates (taking advantage of two others ISTAT surveys), and the picture delineated so far remains fairly unchanged. Indeed, also Italian PhD graduates are deciding to reside abroad at increasing rates, and reflect the trends delineated for the other graduates

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from ISTAT, survey of graduates, weighted data

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

Foreign-born residents with tertiary education (% of total immigrants)

2005 2011

-180

-160

-140

-120

-100

-80

-60

-40

-20

02013 2014 2015 2016 2017

Cumulated net migration balance

Up to lower secondary Tertiary

Figure 8 • An uncompensated loss

“Bran Drain is part of a two-step-migration process that revives the North-South divide”

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

10

Page 11: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from ISTAT, survey of graduates, weighted data

42.85%

59.52%

25.52%

24.05%

31.63%

16.42%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Residents in Italy Residents abroad

Italian graduates resident in Italy and abroad, based on where they studied (2015)

North Centre South

35.36%

52.54%

15.60%

20.45%

49.04%

27%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Residents in Italy Residents abroad

Italian graduates resident in Italy and abroad, geographical origin (2015)

North Centre South

Figure 9 • Emigration by origin (right) and place of study (left)

11

Page 12: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Why we care

Losing out on the future

The severity of the recent Italian brain drain wave is even more com-

pelling if the phenomenon is examined in the context of Italy’s stru-

ctural weakness in accumulating human capital. The recent OECD report

‘Education at a Glance 2018’ delivers a sobering picture of Italy in terms

of educational and labour market outcomes. In 2017, the country was se-

cond to last for the share of the population attaining tertiary education,

with only 18.7%. This figure is significantly lower than the OECD average

(35%) and only 1.3 percentage points better than the worst performer

(Mexico). Among those aged 25 to 34, the share with tertiary education

increases to 27%, which is again below average (44%). .

.

Among those who do attain tertiary education, the largest share pur-

sues degrees in the STEM fields (23.8%). This is significantly below the

35.2% of the best performer (Germany) but not too far from OECD ave-

rage (25%). More interesting is the breakdown into STEM subfields. While

Italy tops the OECD ranking in natural sciences, mathematics and sta-

tistics (8% against an OECD average of 4.7%), it is second to last in infor-

mation and communication technologies (with 1.3%) and in the left tail

of the distribution in engineering, manufacturing and construction (14 %).

Source: Authors’ calculations based on OECD data

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

Figure 10 • Skills under-supply and high/tech manufacturing production

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

1992 1997 2002 2007 2012 2017

High-Tech ManufacturingVolume Index of Production (1992=100)

DE ES FR IT

0 10 20 30 40 50

ItalySweden

NetherlandsChile

Cyprus¹Ireland

Jakarta (Indonesia)Norway

SingaporeCanadaFinlandAustria

Northern Ireland (UK)Australia

Flanders (Belgium)FranceTurkey

United StatesOECD average

GreeceEngland (UK)

EstoniaGermany

KoreaSlovenia

New ZealandDenmark

SpainLithuania

PolandIsrael

Russian Federation²Japan

Czech RepublicSlovak Republic

% of mismatched workers, by type of mismatch

Under-qualified Over-qualified

“Italy has the second lowest share of population with tertiary education (18.7%)”

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

12

Page 13: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Italy thus seems to be structurally under-producing skills in those fields

that will drive industrial development and production in the future (ICTs).

This is the case despite the unemployment rate for 25-34 years old ICTs

graduates is the lowest (7.4%) across all tertiary sub-fields

In light of this data, the recent spike in brain drain – which we have shown

to be concentrated in STEMs – is even more concerning. It deprives the

country of key but already scarce skills, leaving it badly equipped to face

the process of technological deepening in industry and manufactu-

ring. Building and retaining more STEM skills – but especially ICT skills

- would be a key priority for Italy, particulalry in light of the fact that in-

dustrial production in high-tech manufacturing sectors11 has been sta-

gnating since the early Nineties (Figure 10, left).

The structural effects of this scarce accumulation of high skills is com-

pounded by mismatching on the labour market (Figure 10, right). Italy is

not significantly worse than the average OECD country in terms of overall

mismatch, but it has the highest share of under-qualified mismatched

workers (22%). The data from ISTAT’s survey of graduates rhyme with this

evidence (Figure 11 below). If we look at the occupation of respondents

by residency, we clearly see that the share of those employed in highly

specialized professions is much higher (51%) among the Italians resident

abroad than among those who remained in Italy (39%)

11 See the classification from the European Commission here: https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Glossary:High-tech_classification_of_manufacturing_industries. See also: https://docs.wixstatic.com/ugd/4b5846_67852ba0c1ee488c86fcc81b1b79e5c8.pdf?index=true

Source: calculations based on ISTAT data

0.94%

39.43%37.41%

12.31%

7.88%

0.61%1.42%

Residents in Italy 2015

High-level executive

Highly specialisedprofessions

Technical Professions

Executive office positions

Commercial/services

Artisans, factory workers,farmers

Military

1.10%

50.93%

28.82%

8.15%

10.52%0.47%

Residents abroad 2015

Figure 11 • Occupation of respondents by residency, 2015

“Italy under-produces ICT skills and has the highest share of under qualified mismatch workers in the OECD”

13

Page 14: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Immobility and radicalization

Why is tertiary education attainment so low, in italy? This dismal per-

formance may be related to the perceived return of on higher educa-

tion. One way to look at this is through the lens of the private inter-

nal rate of return (IRR), i.e. the real interest rate that would equalise

costs and benefits of investing in one’s own education .The IRR

can be interpreted as the interest rate on the investment made on

a higher level of education that an individual can expect to receive

every year during a working-age life: the higher the IRR, the stron-

gest the incentive should be. On average across OECD countries, the IRR

from attaining tertiary education as compared to upper secondary is 14%

for men and 16% for women. Figure 12 below shows that the private IRR

for male students in Italy is the second lowest in the OECD – at 8%, just

ahead of Turkey In other word, it appears that the pay-off from investing

in one’s own tertiary education in Italy is especially low.

The low return on education certainly does not help tackle anoth-

er worrying Italian feature, i.e. the very low degree of intergenerational

mobility along the educational ladder. Based on OECD data, Figure 13

shows that in 2012 – the latest available data for Italy – only 36% of Ita-

lians aged 25 to 64 attained an educational level higher than their pa-

rents did, in families where neither parent had attained upper secondary.

When looking at Italians with that same family background who succeed

in attaining tertiary education specifically, the share drops to 6%.

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

Figure 12 • Private Internal Rate of Return from tertiary education (men, %)

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

Nor

way

Italy

Port

ugal

Belg

ium

Aust

riaAu

stra

liaJa

pan

Esto

nia

Denm

ark

Uni

ted

King

dom

Czec

h Re

publ

icG

reec

eLa

tvia

Spai

nEU

22 a

vera

geFi

nlan

dSl

oven

iaLu

xem

bour

gG

erm

any

Fran

ceCa

nada

Slov

ak R

epub

licN

ew Z

eala

ndSw

itzer

land

OEC

D av

erag

ePo

land

Uni

ted

Stat

esHu

ngar

yIre

land

Kore

aIs

rael

Turk

eyCh

ile Source: calculations based on OCED data

“In Italy, the private Internal Rate of Return on tertiary education is the second lowest in the OECD”

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

14

Page 15: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Such a strong persistence suggests that the Italian education system is

ineffective at making sure that everyone has an equal chance to deve-

lop their knowledge and skills independently from their socio-economic

background, and therefore it risks reinforcing inequality dynamics. This

is even more evident when considering the fact that young Italians from

better-educated families are also significantly more likely to migrate in re-

sponse to unfavourable domestic economic conditions. Figure 14 below

shows that the share of Italians whose parents hold an university degree

is proportionally much higher among those living abroad than among

those living in Italy. Conversely, the share of Italians whose parents did

not attain upper secondary education is much lower among the migrants

than among those who stay.

0 20 40 60 80 100

LithuaniaEstonia

JapanFinlandPolandCanada

IsraelCzech Rep.

SwedenKorea

GermanyUSA

New ZealandDenmark

AustriaFrance

NorwaySlovak Rep.

AustraliaSlovenia

IrelandNetherlands

GreeceChileSpain

ItalyTurkey

% with higher education than parents

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40

New ZealandCanadaFinland

IsraelKorea

DenmarkEstonia

AustraliaJapan

NorwaySpain

NetherlandsSwedenIrelandFranceGreece

GermanyLithuania

USAChile

AustriaTurkeyPoland

SloveniaItaly

Slovak Rep.Czech Rep.

% with tertiary education

Figure 14 • Italians by residency and parents’ education

9.97%4.66%

28.36%

19.27%

41.68%

40.34%

1.84%

3.24%

18.15%

32.48%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Residents in Italy Residents abroad

Father's education, 2015

Primary or no education Lower secondary

Upper secondary Old system tertiary

Tertiary or post-tertiary

11.05%4.72%

26.97%

17.22%

43.66%

44.42%

2.94%

6.88%

15.39%26.75%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Residents in Italy Residents abroad

Mother's education, 2015

Tertiary or post-tertiary Old system tertiary

Upper secondary Lower secondary

Primary or no education

Figure 13 • Intergenerational mobility for Italians in families where neither parent attained secondary education

Source: calculations based on OECD data

Source: calculations based on OECD data

“Only 6% of Italians attain tertiary educa-tion when their parents did not complete upper secondary”

15

Page 16: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

A low intergenerational education mobility thus not only deprives indi-

viduals from disadvantaged backgrounds of an equal chance at studying,

but also significantly lowers their likelihood to escape an impoverishing

economic and social environment, in bad times. This dualism is likely

to produce political polarization and radicalization among the ‘stayers’,

as opposed to the ‘movers’. In fact, looking at political statements col-

lected in the European Social Survey (ESS) among respondents younger

than 30 from Mediterranean countries , some differences emerge (Figure

15 below). The most evident one is on the subject of immigration – whose

salience has heightened in Europe with the euro crisis first and especially

with the refugee crisis. On that, movers are unsurprisingly more liberal

than stayers.

Movers also trust the European Parliament more, and tend to be slight-

ly more emotionally attached to Europe. These differences are further

strengthened by evidence in the Eurobarometer survey, suggesting that

attitudes towards the EU are very different among ‘movers’ and ‘stayers’.

Figure 16 below shows answers to the question “what does the EU mean

to you personally?” for Italian movers and stayers specifically. The share

of people associating the EU with positive aspects such as ‘economic

prosperity,’ ‘democracy,’ and ‘social security’ is much higher among mo-

vers than among stayers. Conversely, the share of stayers who associate

the EU with ‘unemployment’ is higher than for movers.

Source: Authors’ calculations based on ESS data

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

Figure 15 • Movers vs. Stayers: political positions

4.91

6.806.71 6.76

5.13

4.70

7.26

4.61

6.19

4.34

3.5

4.0

4.5

5.0

5.5

6.0

6.5

7.0

7.5

Right-Left Positioning Government needs toreduce inequalities

Immigrationpositive/negative

Emotional attachment toEurope

Trust in the EuropeanParliament

movers stayers

“Movers and Stayers have different views of domestic and Europe-an political issues”

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

16

Page 17: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Source: Authors’ calculations based on Eurobarometer data

20122017

0

5

10

15

20

25

2007 2012 2017

The EU means ... Economic Prosperity(% mentioning)

Stayers Movers

0

5

10

15

20

25

2007 2012 2017

The EU means ... Unemployment(% mentioning)

Stayers Movers

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

2007 2012 2017

The EU means ... Democracy(% mentioning)

Stayers Movers

0

5

10

15

20

25

2007 2012 2017

The EU means ... Social Protection(% mentioning)

Stayers Movers

Figure 16 • What does the EU mean to you personally?Italian movers vs. stayers

17

Page 18: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Policy Implications

In a context of increased international mobility, brain circulation can be

an opportunity. However, as we have described at lenght in this report,

the recent Italian brain drain wave displays several pathological features,

which make it look more like an emergency evacuation than a balanced

exchange of human capital. Two aspects are particularly concerning:

• Negative skills balance. The outflow of skilled workers is not

compensated by an inflow of foreign brains. This translates into a loss,

and a potential disincentive to invest in human capital formation, in a

country that is structurally under-producing key skills.

• Emigration and inequality. Italian emigrants in the recent brain drain

wave are mostly a self-selected part of the population: the likelihood

to both attain tertiary education and emigrate is larger for young

Italians coming from more advataged socio/economic backgrounds..

Italy thus risks becoming locked into a self-fulfilling vicious circle of

emigration, low potential growth, high youth unemployment, and more

emigration. This eventuality has a monetary and a non-monetary cost.

A study from the General Confederation of Italian Industry (Confindustria)

estimates that Italian households spend in care and education about 165

thousand euro per child, from the birth till the 25th year of life. Based

on this, Confindustria estimates that the emigration of young Italians

between 2008 and 2015 has been equivalent to a 42.8 billion euro loss

in private human capital investment. For 2015 alone, when 51 thousands

Italians under the age of 40 moved their residency abroad, the private

loss can be estimated in the order of 8.4 billion, to which we would need

to add 5.6 billion of public investment in education12.

The non-monetary cost is no less dire. Italy suffers from very low

intergenerational education mobility. Italians from a less-advantaged

background are not only less likely to pursue higher education, but also

less likely to emigrate in bad times. For people who remain stuck in

economically and socially impoverished environments, the risk of political

radicalization is high, as is the temptation to support drastic responses to

emigration. A recent ECFR poll13, for example, shows that 52% of the Italian

respondents would support measures “preventing nationals from leaving

the country for long periods of time, as a policy response to migration”.

12 Estimates are contained in “Le Sfide della Politica Economica”, Settembre 2017, Centro Studi Confindustria http://www.bollettinoadapt.it/wp-content/uploads/2017/09/ScenariEconomici_settembre_2017.pdf

13 See https://www.ecfr.eu/specials/what_europeans_really_want_five_myths_debunked

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

18

Page 19: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Best European practices to retainin and attract talent can be gauged

by looking at the case of those countries in Europe that are a catalyst for

a large number of students, but have difficulties in retaining them once

they graduate: Switzerland, Denmark, the Netherlands. In Denmark, for

example, even graduates who do not immediately find a job can have

access to unemployment benefit, and can easily access residency rights.

A second successful practice in attracting foreign skilled migrants is the

creation of priority lists, which facilitate immigration of people holding

specific degrees (e.g. engineers). Such practices have been enacted in

Germany and Denmark, but also at the European level there through the

introduction of a ‘European blue Card’, in 2009. A third best practice to

improve skill inflow is the recognition of foreign certifications. In 2005,

a European directive14 standardized procedures for accessing regulated

labor markets (e.g. the profession of physicians) for EU citizens. Countries

such as Norway, Denmark and Germany have also established clear

procedures to recognize certifications held by non-EU citizens. We also

have examples of lower-income EU countries that suffered from sizeable

waves of mass emigration, but have enacted counter-measures. For

example, Poland implemented in 2007 a mix of tax incentives and service

provisions to stimulate return migration.

Italy has been experimenting with incentives for return migration since

2003. In both 2010 and 2019, governments of very different political

composition introduced substantial (50-90%) income tax exemptions

for returning emigrants. Another policy tool that has been deployed,

although more limitedly, has been the creation of hiring programs

specifically targeted at foreign researchers. As an example the ‘cattedre

Natta’ programme aimed at hiring 500 excelling Italian researchers and

professors from abroad, but the program was suspended before it could

reach full implementation. Finally, there is also a number of regional

programs, often consisting in scholarships and sponsorships for studying

or working abroad, conditional on the return of the recipient in the region

of origin for a certain period of time.

The best policies to favor a more even skill migration balance and a

more equal access to the opportunity of international mobility would

be those tackling the underlying structural problems of Italian economy.

These would include more investment in research, a public education

and university system that promotes the accumulation of key skills and

rewards merit, policies aimed at tackling the underlying intergenerational

education immobility that perpetuates social inequalities, a fiscal policy

that reliefs labor income and corporate investment in skills thus boosting

the resturn to education, a more efficient labor market that minimizes skill

mismatch. Although crucial, these are long-term structural actions. In this

final section we try to suggest some readily implementable measures.

14 2005-36-EC and successively 2013-55-EU

19

Page 20: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

1. Change the tax incentives system

Tax exemptions to returning migrants have promoted inflows from

abroad, with no cost for the state. On the other hand, tax incentives

schemes present criticalities. From an equity standpoint, exempting

returning skilled migrants means favouring a part of the population

that often comes from relatively more advantaged socio-economic

background (as shown). Political support for this may be slim, unless it is

explained very clearly that favouring the return of talent would eventually

benefit everyone in society, through higher growth in the longer term.

Secondly, incentives to return - if permanent - can have the short-term

consequence to act also as an incentive to leave. This is not necessarily

bad, because the return of people who pursue their education or part of

their work experience abroad can be beneficial through the diversification

that it spurs in the home labor market. But incentives should not become

a subsidy to emigration nor a dis-incentive for governement to invest in

the improvement of the local education system. Possible changes to the

incentive framework could include making the exemption more diluted in

time - smaller but longer - so as to favor long-term returns .Extending the

tax benefit to foreigners, trying not only to re-attract Italian emigrants but

also foreign skilled workers, would also be important.

2. Establish a system of ‘keep in touch’ programs

Introduce additional financing for Italian emigrants who commit to work

either part time or full time in the region of origin. This work requirement

might also be satisfied through participation in projects based in Italy

or creation of enterprises. A first step could be the coordination and

harmonization of different existing regional policies such as ‘Torno subito’

in Lazio, ‘Brain Back’ in Umbria or ‘Master Back’ in Sardinia.

3. Bilateral agreements on degrees recognition

Italy should adopt a system similar to the one adopted by Germany for the

recognition of degrees earned abroad. The system should be based on a

procedure delegated to professional associations (camere professionali)

and public employment centers, including on the subjecto of maximum

administrative costs and procedure duration.

4. Remunerate Skills

Establishing a minimum wage for researchers would prevent the

existence of unpaid PhDs and post-doc positions, pushing universities to

concentrate resources and to valorize their researchers.

R E S E A R C H C O L L A B

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

20

Page 21: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

5. Continue promoting the universities’ ‘third mission’

Since 2004, and more formally with the creation of ANVUR (the

national evaluation institute), universities have been evaluated based

on three ‘mandates’: (1) interaction with students, (2) with the scientific

communities, and (3) with the surrounding socio-economic environment.

For the business sector, the third mandate is of particular importance in

bridging the competences that students acquire with what they could

do in the surrounding region, preventing emigration after graduation or

severe skill mismatch. The ‘third mandate’ is not only being taken into

more and more consideration in the context of ANVUR’s activity, but it is

also the basis for initiatives such as the Innovative Doctoral Programme

and Excellent Departments, in which the excellent faculties are put in

better conditions for attracting best researchers.

6. Incentivize recruitment on international markets by public research institutions

Today, foreign researchers face a high fixed cost when applying for

jobs in Italy. these costs include bureaucratic procedures, network and

information investments that are crucial but often not transparent,

language barriers, the above-mentioned problems with recognition of

foreign-earned degrees et c.. Participation to the international job market

by universities should be promoted better. Actions could include:

• Creating universally applied standardized services, such as online

information and application platforms or counseling, in English.

• Simplify procedures for recruitment, career and tenure track

access. For example, easing the mechanism of National Scientific

Habilitation (Abilitazione Scientifica Nazionale), and allowing for

flexibility in using direct calls (chiamata diretta(, both for professors

and researcher posts

• Establish a target of recruitment of foreigners, which could

be enforced through quotas or incentives (currently, the

‘internationalization’ evaluation pillar by ANVUR considers the

share of foreign students and foreign language courses, but not

the share of foreign faculties).

• A similar requirement could be established for the recruitment of

Italians from abroad

21

Page 22: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

Algebris Policy & Research Forum

22

Page 23: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The

23

This document is issued by Algebris (UK) Limited. The information contained herein may not be re-produced, distributed or published by any recipi-ent for any purpose without the prior written con-sent of Algebris (UK) Limited.

Algebris (UK) Limited is authorised and Regulated in the UK by the Financial Conduct Authority. The information and opinions contained in this doc-ument are for background purposes only, do not purport to be full or complete and do not consti-tute investment advice. Under no circumstances should any part of this document be construed as an offering or solicitation of any offer of any fund managed by Algebris (UK) Limited. Any invest-ment in the products referred to in this document should only be made on the basis of the relevant Prospectus. This information does not constitute Investment Research, nor a Research Recommen-dation. Algebris (UK) Limited is not hereby arrang-ing or agreeing to arrange any transaction in any investment whatsoever or otherwise undertaking any activity requiring authorisation under the Fi-nancial Services and Markets Act 2000.

No reliance may be placed for any purpose on the information and opinions contained in this docu-ment or their accuracy or completeness. No rep-resentation, warranty or undertaking, express or implied, is given as to the accuracy or complete-ness of the information or opinions contained in this document by any of Algebris (UK) Limited , its directors, employees or affiliates and no liability is accepted by such persons for the accuracy or com-pleteness of any such information or opinions.

The distribution of this document may be restricted in certain jurisdictions. The above information is for general guidance only, and it is the responsibili-ty of any person or persons in possession of this document to inform themselves of, and to observe, all applicable laws and regulations of any relevant jurisdiction. This document is for private circulation to professional investors only.

© 2019 Algebris (UK) Limited. All Rights Reserved. 4th Floor, 1 St James’s Market, SW1Y 4AH.

Page 24: Game of Brains - Algebris...For Tortuga (tortugaecon.eu): Jacopo Bassetto Francesco Filippucci Edoardo Magalini Filippo Passerini Sara Rabino Algebris Policy & Research Forum (“The