final-sol.pdf

Upload: simeon-koffi

Post on 02-Mar-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/26/2019 final-sol.pdf

    1/8

    Econ 202a Spring 2000

    Suggested Final Exam Solutions

    1 Rational and Near Rational Wage Setting

    Firms

    Each firm faces a commodity demand ofqd = 1nMp

    pp

    , where >1. Labor

    productivity is given by T(w) = A+B wwR

    +Cu. So, the production

    function is qs = T(w)L and the cost function must take the form C(qs) =w

    T(w)qs

    . Hence, the profit function can be written as

    i = piqsi C(q

    si ) =

    pi

    wiT(wi)

    qdi (1)

    for a monopolist. There are two types of firms, rational and near-rationalones. Label them i = r, nr, respectively.

    1.1 Price choice of firm i

    Firmi chooses it price by maximizing (1) with respect to pi. The first order

    condition for this problem is

    qdi

    pi

    wiT(wi)

    qdipi

    = 0,

    which is a sufficient condition since revenues are concave in pi. Rearrangingyields

    pi =

    1

    wiT(wi)

    . (2)

    1.2 Wage choice of firm i

    Similarly, maximizing (1) with respect towi yields the first order condition

    T(wi) T(wi)wi

    T(wi)2

    = 0

    1

  • 7/26/2019 final-sol.pdf

    2/8

    so that, in optimum, the Solow condition

    wi = T(wi)

    T(wi) (3)

    must be satisfied. By the definition ofT(), this implies that

    w=A+B

    wiwRi

    +Cu

    BwiwRi

    1w

    .

    Equivalently,

    wi = A Cu

    (1 )B

    1

    w

    R

    i . (4)

    1.3 Relative profits

    Given the facts that wRr = wR = w1(1 +e) for the rational firms and

    wRnr = w1 for the near rational firms, the two wage choices are equal for= e = 0:

    wRr =wRnr =

    A Cu

    (1 )B

    1

    wR if = e = 0.

    Hence, the productivity levels must be equal, too: T(wr) = T(wnr) for =

    e = 0. Then, however, price choices must be equal: pr = pnr. Therefore,we can conclude that profits r and nr must be identical if =

    e = 0 andrelative profits (the ratio of profits) must be equal to one: r/nr = 1.

    Suppose these relative profits could be expressed as a function of inflation. Then, by the arguments above, at zero inflation =e = 0 the optimalchoice ofpi and wi are the same for both firms. Therefore, the change inprofits is the same by the envelope theorem so that the ratio of profits remainsat one after the change. This means, however, that the derivative of the ratior/nr with respect to must be zero.

    1 This argument suffices to answerthe question.

    1In general,

    r

    nr

    =r

    nr nr

    r

    (nr)2 = 0

    for r = nr and r/ = nr/.

    2

  • 7/26/2019 final-sol.pdf

    3/8

    The same results could, of course, also be derived explicitly. This was not

    required. For completeness, relative profits could be derived by noting that

    i =

    pi

    wiT(wi)

    qdi

    =

    1

    wiT(wi)

    wi

    T(wi)

    1

    n

    M

    p

    pip

    = 1

    1

    1

    Mn

    1

    p

    1 wiT(wi)

    1,

    and hence

    rnr =

    wrT(wr)wnr

    T(wnr)

    1= w

    Rr

    wRnrA+B(wr/wR)+CuA+B(wnr/wR)

    +Cu

    1

    by (4) and the fact that true productivity is given byT(wi) = A +B

    wi/wR

    +

    Cu for both firms (where wR = w1(1 +e)). Setting = e = 0 immediately

    yields r/nr = 1. Taking the derivative with respect to and evaluating the

    resulting term at = e = 0 yields zero.

    1.4 Short-run wage Phillips curve

    If we suppose that denotes the share of near-rational firms, we can obtain

    the wage level at period 0 as

    w0 = wnr+ (1 )wr

    =

    A Cu

    (1 )B

    1

    [w1+ (1 )w1(1 +e)] . (5)

    Subtractingw1/w1 from both sides of (5) yields

    w0 w1w1

    =

    A Cu

    (1 )B

    1

    [1 + (1 )e] 1. (6)

    1.5 Long-run Phillips curve

    Since = e = 0 and = (w0 w1)/w1 in the long-run, (6) implies

    1 +LR = a [1 + (1 )LR] (7)

    3

  • 7/26/2019 final-sol.pdf

    4/8

    Figure 1: Phase Diagram for Tobins q

    fora [(A Cu)/(1 )B] 1 . Thus,

    LR= 1 a

    1 a(1 ). (8)

    2 Temporary Technological Progress and To-

    bins q

    A temporary rise in the technology parameterA shifts the qt= 0-scheduletemporarily to the East. Thus, between time t0, when productivity unexpect-

    edly rises, and time T > t0, when it expectedly falls back to its initial level,the new dynamic system with qt = 0 and Kt = 0 temporarily governsthe dynamics of the capital stock and Tobins q.

    The capital stockKt0 cannot adjust immediately and thus remains at itsinitial steady-state level for one period. However, the shadow price of capital,

    4

  • 7/26/2019 final-sol.pdf

    5/8

    Tobinsq, has to jump to a new level which is such that the subsequent levels

    of bothqs andKs (s t0) will be back at a point on the initial saddle path.So, att0Tobinsqjumps discretely to point 2 in figure 1 and it will reach point3 exactly at date T. Between timet0 andT, both variables qs andKs mustfollow the dynamics of the shifted system which take them first to the southeast and then (once the Kt = 0-schedule is surpassed) to the south westof the system. Note that the shadow price must not change discontinuously(jump) at any time after t0, otherwise the capital stock cannot have beenchosen optimally. Between time t0 and T, the capital stock first increasesand then falls while Tobins qkeeps falling until T. Once timeT is reached,the system is again governed by the old qt = 0 and Kt = 0-schedulesand the capital stock continues to fall smoothly while the shadow price of

    capitalqs now continuously rises.

    3 Central Bank with Superior Knowledge

    3.1 Linear optimal monetary rule

    Given aggregate supply

    yt = (pt Et1[pt]) +ut, (9)

    and aggregate demand

    mdt =pt+ vt, (10)

    output can be written as

    yt = mst vt Et1[m

    st vt] +ut

    = mst vt Et1[mst ] +ut1+ t. (11)

    The second step follows from the assumptions on the stochastic processes.Since the conditional expectations over the linear monetary rule mst = a+but1+ct+dvt1 are Et1[m

    st ] =a+but1+d vt1, it follows that

    mst Et1[mst ] =ct.

    Hence, output can be written as

    yt = (c+ 1)t vt+ut1. (12)

    5

  • 7/26/2019 final-sol.pdf

    6/8

    For c = 1, the disturbance of aggregate supply is completely offset by

    the monetary rule so that the variance of output will be minimized. Theparameters a, b, d are irrelevant since their impact is entirely anticipatedby the private sector. This arguments can be made formal by minimizingV(yt) = E[(ct vt+ ut1+ t)

    2] with respect to a, b, c, d (a, b, d dontenter the minimization problem).

    3.2 Non-linear optimal monetary rule

    Allowing for higher order terms such as in a rule like mst = a+ but1 +ct+dvt1+ b(ut1)2 +c(t)2 +d(vt1)2 will result in minimizing V(yt) =E[(ct+ c(t)2 vt+ ut1+ t)2]. Now neithera, b, d nor a, b, d enter,

    and settingc = 1 is still optimal. Since the noise t is completely offset bythe choice ofc = 1 already, anything else but c = 0 would add noise backin. The same is true for any higher order polynomial.

    3.3 Stochastic process ofut

    The process

    ut= ut1+t1+ t (13)

    is an ARMA(1,1) process. Using lag operators, (13) can be rewritten as

    1 L

    1 +Lut= t (14)

    or

    (1 L)(1 L +2L2 3L3 +4L4 . . . ) ut = t (15)

    (1 L L +L2 +2L2 2L3 3L3 +. . . ) ut = t

    (1 (+)L + (+)L2 (+)2L3 +. . . ) ut = t. (16)

    Without going through any further derivations, the first step (15) immedi-

    ately shows that we found an AR(

    ) process with

    ut=s=1

    ksuts+ t

    6

  • 7/26/2019 final-sol.pdf

    7/8

    for some ks. The (not required) further steps show that

    ut = (+)s=1

    ()s1uts+ t

    in fact.

    3.4 New optimal monetary rule

    The optimal monetary rule does not change at all. Both the Central Bankand the Private Sector know all (infinitely many) past realizations ofuts(s = 0, 1, 2, . . . ). So it is still the case that the Private Sector rationally

    foresees that the expected deviation of the money supply from its mean isequal to the unknown part of the money rule, mst Et1[m

    st ] =ct+ c

    (t)2.Thus, including any past realizations ofuts orvts is entirely irrelevant. Itis still optimal for the central bank to set c = 1 and c = 0.

    4 Microfoundations of Money Demand

    4.1 Interpretation of budget constraint

    The individual can choose to allocate her current income Yt to three different

    uses: to savingsAt+1, or to money holding Mt, or to consumption Ct. Themore money Mt she chooses to put aside today (at t), the more of todaysincome Yt becomes useful. In the limit (

    MtPt

    ), income is fully useful.In optimum, the individual will choose some intermediate amount of moneyholdings.

    4.2 Choice variables

    The individual can choose Ct, At+1, and Mt. Since she is restricted by thebudget constraint, choosing any two of the three implies her choice of thethird. Thus, two intertemporal first-order conditions (Euler equations) will

    be enough to pin the optimal consumption, savings and money holdings pathsdown.

    7

  • 7/26/2019 final-sol.pdf

    8/8

    4.3 First-order conditions

    Intertemporal utilityUt =

    s=tstu(Cs)2 can be rewritten as

    Ut = u(Ct) +Ut+1= u(Ct) +u(Ct+1) +2Ut+2. (17)

    Then, plugging the consumption choice Ct = (1 +r)At+Mt1Pt

    +g(MtPt )Yt

    At+1 MtPt

    into (17) fort and t + 1, and maximizing (17) with respect toAt+1andMt yields the two first-order conditions

    u(Ct) +(1 +r)u(Ct+1) = 0 (18)

    and

    1Pt

    u(Ct)

    1 g

    MtPt

    Yt

    + 1

    Pt+1u(Ct+1) = 0. (19)

    Using (18) in (19) yields

    1 g

    MtPt

    Yt=

    1

    1 +r

    PtPt+1

    . (20)

    4.4 Money demand under specific functional form for

    g()

    Given (20) andYs= Y, and usingg(MtPt ) = 1k e

    Mt

    Pt so thatg(MtPt ) =k e

    Mt

    Pt,we find

    k Y eMt

    Pt = 1 1

    1 +r

    PtPt+1

    .

    Observe that the nominal interest rate must be related to the real interestrate through 1 +it+1= (1 +r)

    Pt+1Pt

    . Then, taking logs of both sides yields

    MtPt

    = ln kY ln it+11 +it+1

    . (21)

    This function is increasing in income and decreasing in the nominal interestrate, just as any LM-function should be.

    2This relationship is correct for 1. All the following derivations hold for the more common case where