ferguson rom (1)

Upload: kaps2385

Post on 14-Apr-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    1/16

    POST-MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORYCOMES OF AGE

    Brian M. RomKathleen W. FergusonSponsor-Software Systems, Inc.

    It has been a generation since Harry Markowitz laid the foundations and built much of thestructure of what we now know as Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT). The greatestcontribution of MPT is the establishment of a formal risk/return framework for investmentdecision-making. By defining investment risk in quantitative terms, Markowitz gave investorsa mathematical approach to asset selection and portfolio management.But as Markowitz himself and William Sharpe, the other giant of MPT, acknowledge, thereare important limitations to the original MPT formulation.

    Under certain conditions, the mean-variance approach can be shown to lead tounsatisfactory predictions of behavior. Markowitz suggests hat a model basedon the semi-variance would be preferable; in light of the formidablecomputational problems, however, he bases his analysis on the variance andstandard deviation.

    The causesof these unsatisfactory aspectsof MPT are the assumptions that 1) variance ofportfolio returns is the correct measureof investment risk, and 2) that the investment returnsof all securities and assetscan be adequately represented by the normal distribution. Statedanother way, MPT is limited by measuresof risk and return that do not always represent therealities of the investment markets.Fortunately, recent advances n portfolio and financial theory, coupled with todays increasedcomputing power, have overcome these limitations. The resulting expanded risk/returnparadigm is known as Post-Modern Portfolio Theory (PMPT). MPT thus becomes nothingmore than a special (symmetrical) case of the PMPT formulation.This article discusses eturn and risk under MPT and PMPT and demonstratesan approach toassetallocation basedon the more general rules permitted by PMPT.

    349

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    2/16

    La theorie du portefeuille post-moderneatteint Ibge de raison

    Brian M. RomKathleen W. Ferguson

    Sponsor-Software Systems, Inc.Une generation sest Bcoulee depuis que Harry Markowitz a Btabli les fondations etconstruit une grande partie de la structure de ce que nous appelons a Iheure actuelleN MPT )) (ThBorie du portefeuille moderne). La plus grande contribution faite par laMPT est letablissement dun cadre officiel de risque/rendement pour la prise dedecisions dinvestissement. En definissant le risque de Iinvestissement en termesquantitatifs, Markowitz a mis B la disposition des investisseurs une methodemathematique pour la selection des avoirs et pour la gestion du portefeuille.Mais, comme le reconnaissent Markowitz lui-m6me ainsi que William Sharpe, Iautre

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    3/16

    POST-MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY COMES OF AGE 351

    RISK MEASURES: DISTINGUISHING BETWEENBAD AND GOOD VARIAIBLITYIn MPT, risk is defined as the total variability of returns around the mean return and ismeasuredby the variance, or equivalently, standard deviation.* MPT treats all uncertaintythe same--surprises i.e., variability) on the upside are penalized identically to surprises onthe downside. In this sense,variance is a symmetric risk measure, which is counter-intuitivefor real-world investors. In fact, intuition argues ust the opposite--in a bull market weshould seek as much volatility as possible; only in a bear market should volatility be avoided!Furthermore, it is well known that individuals are more concerned with avoiding loss thanwith seeking gain. In other words, from a practical standpoint, risk is not symmetrical--it isseverely skewed, with the greatest concern going to the downside.While variance captures only the risks associatedwith achieving the average return, PMPTrecognizes that investment risk should be tied to each investors specific goals and that anyoutcomes above this goal do not represent economic or financial risk. PMPTs downsiderisK measure makesa clear distinction between downside and upside volatility. In PMPTonly volatility below the investors target return incurs risk; all returns above this target causeuncertainty, which is nothing more than riskless opportunity for unexpectedly high returns(Figure 1).In PMPT this target rate of return is referred to as the minimum acceptable return (MAR). Itrepresents the rate of return that must be earned to avoid failing to achieve some importantfinancial objective. Examples of MARs for pension funds include the actuarial interest rate,the return required to eliminate an underfunded position, and the return required to reducecontributions to a specified level. For individuals, a typical MAR could be the returnrequired to purchase a retirement annuity sufficient to replace a specified proportion of pre-retirement income. As this last example illustrates, the MAR can act as an explicit linkbetween investors financial requirements and their assets.Because he MAR is explicitly included in the calculation of PMPT efficient frontiers, there isa unique efficient frontier for each MAR. In other words, for any given set of risk, returnand covariance assumptions, there is an infinite number of efficient frontiers, eachcorresponding to a particular MAR. This stands n contrast to MPT efficient frontiers, inwhich the investors goals are never explicitly considered.Another appealing attribute of PMPT is that the downside risk statistic6 can be split into twoindependent components hat can then be separately analyzed. In PMPT these two componentstatistics are known as downside probability7 and average downside magnitude. Downsideprobability measures he likelihood of failure to meet the MAR. The average downsidemagnitude measures he average shortfall below the MAR, for only those instances when theMAR is not achieved. It is thus a measureof the consequencesof failure. These twostatistics provide useful additional perspectives on the nature of the investment risk for aportfolio or asset.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    4/16

    4TH AFIR INTERNATIONAL COLLOQUIUM

    SYMMETRICAL vs. ASYMMETRICAL RETURN DISTRIBUTIONS:NOT ALL DISTRIBUTIONS ARE NORMALTo represent the underlying uncertainty of asset forecasts, optimization procedures in bothMPT and PMPT require a statistical return distribution to be specified for each asset. WhileMPT permits only the two-parameter normal or lognormal distributions, PMPT utilizes abroader class of asymmetrical distributions. For the analysis presented here, we use the four-parameter lognormal distribution.The question then arises as to how much asymmetry, or skewness, s observed in the realworld. Table 1 shows skewness atios for several major assetclassesover different timeperiods. Ratios greater than 1 O indicate distributions with more returns occurring above themedian return (positive skewness); the converse is true for ratios less than 1.0 (negativeskewness).All the major assetclasses n Table 1 have skewness atios significantly different from 1.0 forall time periods analyzed. This is compelling evidence that the MPT requirement that allassetshave symmetrical return distributions is inappropriate and likely to lead to incorrectresults.The PMPT formulation significantly reduces this problem. BecausePMPT provides a moreaccurate representation of an assets true shape, PMPT optimization studies will generallyprovide more accurate results. In addition, PMPT can accommodateseverely skewedinvestment strategies such as portfolio insurance, option-writing, nuclear decommissioningtrusts and other derivative-based programs.9

    POST-MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORYAND PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATIONHarlow succinctly states he appeal and benefits of using the downside risk framework forportfolio optimization:

    (The downside risk framework) . . . view accords with most investmentmanagers perception of risk. Downside risk offers an attractive approach toasset allocation decisions. Theoretically more general than the traditionalmean-variance technique, it also promises signtjicant improvement n the risk-reward trade-offs to the investor.. . . That is, a downside risk approach canlower risk while maintaining or improving upon the expected return ofleered ymean-variance approaches.To illustrate the differences between the downside risk and mean-variance approaches, wecompare the results using the most general assumptionspermitted by each method. Theanalysis is performed using historical data as proxies for expectations of future asset behavior.Although the results vary according to changes n the ex ante assumptions, the process ofusing historical data to assist in the formulation of future expectations is common. In anycase, our focus is on exploring the usefulness of an alternative portfolio constructiontechnique rather than on producing return forecasts.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    5/16

    POST-MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY COMES OF AGE 353

    Our example is fairly typical for a U.S.-based investor. There are five asset choices: large-capitalization stocks, small-capitalization stocks, non-U.S. stocks, bonds, and cash. Thereturns used n this example cover the 15year period from January, 1978 to December, 1992and are presented n Table 2.* Efficient portfolios of these assetsare constructed using thePMPT and MPT techniques described below, a 10% MAR, and a five-year holding period.The PMPT efficient frontier is calculated using an algorithm for downside risk developed byThe Pension Research nstitute applied to the expected return, standard deviation andskewnessvalues shown in Table 2. Figure 2 shows the downside risk efficient frontier andidentifies the reference portfolios described below.The MPT efficient frontier is calculated using standard Markowitz optimization techniquesapplied to the expected returns and standard deviations shown in Table 2. Figure 3 shows theMPT mean-variance efficient frontier and identifies the reference portfolios.To assist in comparisons of portfolios generated from optimizations under the techniques, thefollowing benchmark portfolios are used: (1) the minimum-risk efficient portfolio torepresent the most risk-averse investor; (2) the maximum-efficiency portfolio to represent thepurely rational investor; and (3) the Brinson Partners Global Securities Normal Portfolioi torepresent the typical global investor.

    DOWNSIDE RISK vs. MEAN-VARIANCE OPTIMIZATIONThe Minimum-Risk PortfoliosMinimum-risk portfolios are shown in Table 3. Under mean-variance, the minimum-riskportfolio is practically an all-cash portfolio. As an indication of the limitations of mean-variance optimization, this portfolio is identified as the least risky; yet with certainty it willfail to deliver the 10% required return ! This illustrates how mean-variance analysis canrecommend llogical investment strategies and is a direct result of using standard deviation asthe investment risk measure. The inefficiency of the mean-variance minimum risk portfolio isobvious in that it is located substantially below the downside risk efficient frontier in Figure2.Contrast this with the downside risk minimum-risk portfolio which has a substantial non-cashcomponent. This diversification into higher-return, higher-volatility assets eflects the 10%MAR requirement which cannot be achieved by the low-return, low-volatility cash componenton its own.Table 4 shows the two components of downside risk--downside probability and averagedownside magnitude. These provide additional insights into how the riskiness of cash isviewed by the two optimization methods. For example, the low downside risk of cash isprimarily a consequenceof this assets ow average downside magnitude, despite therelatively high downside probability. Nonetheless, the downside risk minimum-risk portfolioholds substantially less cash than its mean-variance counterpart because he risk-reductionproperties are significantly less under downside risk than under mean-variance. This isshown in Table 5, which displays the risk of each asset relative to cash. Notice, for example,that the mean-variance risk of large-cap stocks s 19 times greater than that of cash, but only1.3 times greater using downside risk at a 10% MAR. This explains the disparity betweenthe two optimization methods n the allocation to large-cap stocks.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    6/16

    354 4TH AFIR INTERNATIONAL COLLOQUIUM

    A comparison of columns 2 and 3 in Table 5 shows how in the downside risk framework theMAR can change an assets risk relative to cash. Notice the rapid climb in riskiness of theassets elative to cash when the MAR falls to 8% from 10%. This is a direct reflection ofthe sharp decline in the downside risk of cash as the lower MAR moves into its range ofpossible outcomes.The Maximum-Efficiency PortfoliosTable 6 shows the downside risk and mean-variance maximum-efficiencyI portfolios. Thedifferences between these portfolios are explained by the efficiencies of the respective assetsshown in Table 7.16 Under mean-variance, cash is so much more efficient than the otherassets hat it dominates the maximum-efficiency portfolio with a 97% allocation. On theother hand, under downside risk, large-cap stocks are most efficient, which explains the 81%allocation to this asset. As noted previously, an assets efficiency relative to other assetswould be expected to change as the MAR changes.The inefficiency of the mean-variance maximum-efficiency portfolio is obvious in that it islocated substantially below the downside risk efficient frontier in Figure 2.The Equivalent-Risk PortfoliosWe define an equivalent-risk portfolio as an efficient portfolio with the same risk as aspecified reference portfolio, for which we use the Brinson Partners Global Securities NormalPortfolio. Table 8 shows the mean-variance and downside risk equivalent-risk portfolios.Notice that the downside risk portfolio has a higher allocation to large-cap stocks and lowerweightings to foreign stocks and bonds than the mean-variance portfolio. These differencesare attributable primarily to the assets skewness. For example, the positive skewnessoflarge-cap stocks makes this asset more appealing in the downside risk optimization (where theskewness s recognized) than in the mean-variance case (where the skewness s ignored).Similarly, the negative skewnessof foreign stocks and bonds explains the relativeunderweighting in these assetsunder downside risk.Importantly, this example illustrates the impact of ignoring asset skewnesswhen performingmean-variance optimization: for large-cap stocks, mean-variance gnores some of the goodreturns on the upside, resulting in an overestimation of the actual risks inherent in this asset;for foreign stocks and bonds, mean-variance gnores some of the bad returns on thedownside, resulting in an underestimation of the actual risks of these assets. This means thatthe mean-variance equivalent-risk portfolio is neither efficient nor optimal.

    CONCLUSIONS

    Recent advances n portfolio theory and computer technology today provide investors withcapabilities unheard of even a few years ago. Among these s Post-Modern Portfolio Theory(PMPT), which uses downside risk and asymmetrical return distributions, providinganalysts with flexibility and accuracy in constructing efficient portfolios unavailable undertraditional Markowitz mean-variance methodology.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    7/16

    POST-MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY COMES OF AGE 355

    Examples of policy decisions using these two optimization techniques show how mean--variance analysis can produce illogical and counter-intuitive results and how PMPT canrectify these problems.By providing a more accurate and robust framework for constructing optimal portfolio mixes,Post-Modern Portfolio Theory has made much needed mprovements to the fundamental workdone by Markowitz and Sharpe on portfolio theory.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    8/16

    356 4TH AFIR INTERNATIONAL COLLOQUIUM

    ENDNOTES:Sharpe, W.F., (1964) Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium underConsiderations of Risk, TheJournal XIX, 425. Markowitz recognized theselimitations and proposed downside risk (which he called semi-variance) as the preferredmeasure of investment risk. However, due to the complex calculations and the limitedcomputational resources at his disposal, practical implementation of downside risk wasimpossible. He therefore compromised and stayed with variance.*In Modern Portfolio Theory, the terms variance, variability, volatility, and standard deviationare often used interchangeably to represent investment risk.Why Investors Make the Wrong Choices, Fortune Magazine, January, 1987.qhere are many references to downside risk in the literature. The following is a partial listof those we feel are most relevant to our article. (See Bawa, V.S., Stochastic Dominance: AResearch Bibliography, Management Science, June, 1982, for a complete bibliography.)Fishburn, P.C., Mean-Risk Analysis with Risk Associated with Below-Target Variance, TheAmerican Economic Review, March, 1977; Sortino, Frank and v.d. Meer, Robert, DownsideRisk: Capturing Whats at Stake, The Journal of Portfolio Management, Summer, 1991;Clarkson, R.S., A Presentation to The Faculty of Actuaries (British), February 20, 1989.See Table 5 for an illustration. For example, notice in the downside risk framework therapid climb in relative risk of each asset when the MAR falls to 8% from 10%. This isexplained by the sharp decline in the downside risk of cash as the MAR moves into the cashrange of possible outcomes.jDownside risk is measured by target semi-deviation, the square root of target semi-variance.Downside risk is an asymmetric risk measure hat calculates the probability-weighted squareddeviations of those returns falling below a specified target rate of return (the MAR).7Downside probability is also known as shortfall risk. See Leibowitz, M.L. and I-angetieg,T.C., Shortfall Risks and the Asset Allocation Decision, Salomon Brothers, January, 1989.*The additional parameters permit independent shifting of the left and right tails of thelognormal distribution. For many years financial theorists and practitioners have recognizedthat, for many common asset classes, traditional methods of representing return distributionsdo not adequately capture empirically observed results. The lognormal distribution used forthe analysis here overcomes many of these objections.Lewis, A.L., Semivariance and the Performance of Portfolios with Options, FinancialAnalvsts Journal, July-August, 1990; Study on CTA Managers, Sponsor-Software Systems,Inc., February, 1993; Post-Modern Portfolio Theory Spawns Post-Modem Optimizer, MoneyManaeement Letter, February 15, 1993.Barlow, W.V., Asset Allocation in a Downside Risk Framework, mAnalvstsSeptember-October, 1991.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    9/16

    POST-MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY COMES OF AGE 357

    Although our examples utilize PMPTs most general capabilities--asymmetric returndistributions and downside risk--we emphasize that the benefits of downside risk describedstill apply if symmetrical return distributions are used. Space imitations preclude us fromincluding further examples to illustrate this point. These are available from the authors onrequest.*Throughout this article, the following market indexes are used as proxies for major assetclasses: Standard & Poors 500 Stock Index for large-cap stocks; Russell 2000 Stock Indexfor small-cap stocks; MSCI Europe, Australia, Far East Stock Index for foreign stocks;Lehman Brothers Aggregate Bond Index for bonds; 90-Day Treasury Bills for cash.

    i3The not-for-profit Pension Research Institute at San Francisco State University wrote thefirst commercial downside risk optimizer. This algorithm is used by The Asset AllocationExpert, a PC-basedoptimization software system developed and distributed by Sponsor--Software Systems, Inc. This system is used to generate the results described in this article.14We se a summarized form of this portfolio: 39% large-cap stocks, 17% small-cap stocks,19% foreign stocks, 20% bonds, and 5% cash. See Investment Review, Brinson Partners,Inc., 1992; page 7.151n ownside risk, the maximum-efficiency portfolio is the efficient portfolio with the highestSortino ratio: (rate of return-MAR)/(downside risk). In mean-variance, the maximum-efficiency portfolio is the efficient portfolio with the highest modified Sharpe ratio: (rate ofreturn)/(standard deviation).i6Covariancesbetween assetsalso will affect the results. This information is available fromthe authors on request.

    AUTHORS:Brian M. Rom is president of Sponsor-Software Systems, Inc. in New York, which hefounded in 1987. Prior to this, he was principal and New York region manager ofinvestment consulting at Mercer-Meidinger-Hansen, Inc., and a senior manager in PeatMarwicks Investment Consulting Group. He has also been adjunct associateprofessor offinance at the Columbia Graduate School of Business. Mr. Rom holds M.B.A. degrees fromColumbia University and the University of Cape Town in South Africa, as well as an M.S. incomputer science and mathematics.Kathleen W. Ferguson has been a principal of Sponsor-Software Systems, Inc. since 1990.She was previously vice president and manager of consulting services at Prudential-BatheSecurities, and senior investment analyst at The Equitable Life Assurance Society. Ms.Ferguson holds a B.B.A. in finance cum laude from Adelphi University and an M.B.A. infinance from New York University.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    10/16

    358 4TH AFIR INTERNATIONAL COLLOQUIUM

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    11/16

    15.5

    5 13.5c;

    2* 11.5.--G2

    2

    MPT EFFICIENT FRONTIERS-Year Holding PeriodDR Maximum---.-Efficiency Portfolio

    DR Equivalent-Risk PortfolioReferencePortfolio*

    9.5 - Risk PortfolioMV Minimum-Risk PortfolioMV Maximum-Efficiency Portfolio I I I I2.0 4.0 6.0 8.0 10.0 12.0 14.0

    Annualized Standard Deviation (%)DR=Downside Risk; MV=Mean-VarianceBrinson Partners Global Securities Normal Portfolio.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    12/16

    16.0

    14.0

    8.0f

    PMPT EFFICIENT FRONTIER5Year Holding Period10.0% Minimum Acceptable ReturnDR Maximum-

    Risk Portfolio l f----V Equivalent.Risk Portfolio

    ReferencePortfolio*

    MV Minimum-f +--- DR Minimum-Risk Portfolio

    Risk Portfolio

    I

    I1.0

    +. NV MaximumEfficiency PortfolioI I I I I I1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0 2.2

    Annualized Downside Risk (%)

    0cn0

    DR=Downside Risk; MV=Mean-VarianceBrinson Partners Global Securities Normal Portfolio.

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    13/16

    POST-MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY COMES OF AGE 361Table 1

    Skewness of Major Asset Classes and Inflation*&gtLarge-Cap StocksSmall-Cap StocksForeign StocksBondsCashInflation

    Periods Ending 12/31/9210 Yrs 20 Yrs 30 Yrs1.80 1.23 0.891.07 1.22 1.140.92 1.10 NA0.83 0.94 0.970.64 1.25 1.110.82 1.35 3.03

    *Skewness equals (High 10th Percentile Return - MedianReturn)/(Median Return - Low 10th Percentile Return)

    Table 2Return and Risk Assumptionsfor Optimizations*Expected Standard&f&t Return Deviation Skewness**Large-Cap Stocks 15.45% 15.80% 1.22Small-Cap Stocks 15.44 20.50 1.20Foreign Stocks 15.30 18.26 0.85Bonds 10.59 7.49 0.92Cash 8.45 0.83 1.19

    *Actual data from 1978 to 1992.**Skewness equals (High 10th Percentile Return - MedianReturn)/(Median Return - Low 10th Percentile Return)

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    14/16

    362 4TH AFIR INTERNATIONAL COLLOQUIUM

    Table 3Comparison of Minimum-Risk PortfoliosFive-Year Holding Period, 10.0% MAR

    Mean-Portfolio Mix VarianceLarge-Cap Stocks 0%Small-Cap Stocks 0Foreign Stocks 1Bonds 2Cash 91Portfolio CharacteristicsExpected Return 8.55%Risk:Downside Risk 1.51%Standard Deviation 0.80%Downside Prob 100.0%Avg Downside Mag 1.51%

    DownsideRisk11%041867

    9.86%

    0.96%2.84%55.4%1.29%

    Diff-erence+ll%0+3+16-30

    +1.31%

    -0.55 %+2.04%-44.6%-0.22%

    Table 4Components of Downside Riskfor Individual AssetsFive-Year Holding Period, 10.0% MARAverage

    Downside Downside Downside&Qi.@ Risk Probability MapnitudeLarge-Cap Stocks 2.09% 23.2% 4.35%Small-Cap Stocks 3.36 29.2 6.22Foreign Stocks 4.49 27.1 8.64Bonds 1.85 40.8 2.90Cash 1.62 100.0 1.62

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    15/16

    POST-MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY COMES OF AGE 363

    Table 5Risk for Individual AssetsRelative to CashFive-Year Holding Period

    Mean- Downside RiskAsset Variance* 10% MAR 8% MARLarge-Cap Stocks 19.0 1.3 14.2Small-Cap Stocks 24.7 2.1 25.7Foreign Stocks 22.0 2.8 37.6Bonds 9.0 1.1 10.3Cash 1.0 1.0 1.0*Standard deviation

    Table 6Comparison ofMaximum-Efficiency PortfoliosFive-Year Holding Period, 10.0% MAR

    Mean- Downside Diff-Portfolio Mix Variance Risk erenceLarge-Cap Stocks 0% 81% +81%Small-Cap Stocks 0 0 0Foreign Stocks 1 17 +16Bonds 2 1 -1Cash 97 1 -96Portfolio CharacteristicsExpected Return 8.55% 15.30% +6.75%Risk:Downside RiskStandard Deviation 1.51% 1.97% +0.46%0.80% 14.93% +14.13%Efficiency Ratio:Downside Risk*Mean-Variance** -0.96 2.70 +3.6610.71 2.48 -8.23*The Sortino ratio = (Expected Return - MAR)/Downside Risk**The Sharpe ratio = Expected Return/Standard Deviation

  • 7/30/2019 Ferguson Rom (1)

    16/16

    364 4TH AFIR INTERNATIONAL COLLOQUIUM

    Table 7Efficiency Measures and Rankingsfor Individual Assets

    Mean-VarianceEfficiencyAsset Ratio* &g&Large-Cap Stocks 1 O 3Small-Cap Stocks 0.8 5Foreign Stocks 0.8 4Bonds 1.4 2Cash 10.0 1

    Downside RiskatEfficiencyRatio** Rank2.6 11.6 21.2 30.3 4-0.9 5

    *The Sharpe ratio = Expected Return/Standard Deviation**The Sortino ratio = (Expected Return - MAR)/Downside Risk

    Table 8Comparison ofEquivalent-Risk PortfoliosS-Year Holding Period, 10.0% MAR

    Portfolio MixLarge-Cap StocksSmall-Cap StocksForeign StocksBondsCash

    Mean- DownsideVariance Risk50% 65%0 029 1821 170 0

    ReferencePortfolio*39%1719205Portfolio CharacteristicsExpected Return 14.38% 14.60% 14.10%Risk:Downside Risk 1.75% 1.77% 1.77%Standard Deviation 11.86% 13.00% 12.23%Efficiency Ratio:Downside Risk** 2.50 2.61 2.32Mean-Variance*** 1.21 1.12 1.15

    *Brinson Partners Global Securities Normal Portfolio**The Sortino ratio = (Expected Return - MAR)/Downside Risk***The Sharpe ratio = Expected Return/Standard Deviation