exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

45
Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee and Scott W. Hegerty The University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee, Milwaukee, Wisconsin, USA Abstract Purpose – Since the last review article by McKenzie, the literature has experienced a surge in the number of empirical articles. These new contributions, coupled with those that were overlooked by McKenzie, set the stage for this review. Many of the recent studies have been empirical in nature and these deserve specific attention. Thus, this paper aims to survey and review all of the studies by paying attention to the attributes outlined in the text. Design/methodology/approach – This paper examines the vast empirical literature, up to 2005, to assess the main trends in modeling and estimating these trade flows at the aggregate, bilateral, and sectoral levels. Findings – The increase in exchange-rate volatility since 1973 has had indeterminate effects on international export and import flows. Although it can be assumed that an increase in risk may lead to a reduction in economic activity, the theoretical literature provides justifications for positive or insignificant effects as well. Similar results have been found in empirical tests. While modeling techniques have evolved over time to incorporate new developments in econometric analysis, no single measure of exchange-rate volatility has dominated the literature. Originality/value – An argument put forward by the opponents of the floating exchange rates is that such rates introduce uncertainty into the foreign exchange market, which could deter trade flows. However, a theoretical argument is put forward by some to show that uncertainty could also boost trade flows if traders increase their trade volume to offset any decrease in future revenue due to exchange rate volatility. The empirical literature reviewed in this paper supports both views. Keywords Exchange rates, International trade Paper type Case study I. Introduction After the post-war Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates collapsed in 1973, the relative prices of currencies began to fluctuate. These fluctuations brought increased uncertainty to traders; this risk may influence the volume of international trade. Since the beginning of the current float, numerous theoretical papers have been written to explain the effects of increased exchange-rate volatility on trade, and even more have been published evaluating these ideas empirically. These studies have applied different methods and obtained different results, but no consensus has been reached regarding how to model, or even how to properly measure, exchange-rate volatility. Since the last review article by McKenzie (1999), the literature has experienced a surge in the number of empirical articles. These new contributions, coupled with those that were overlooked by McKenzie, set the stage for this review. Many of the recent studies have been empirical in nature and these deserve specific attention. Thus, this paper aims to survey and review all of the studies by paying attention to their following attributes. First, in section II we provide a brief overview of the theoretical literature that outlines the reasoning behind why increased exchange-rate volatility might hurt – or help – the volume of trade. Next, in section III the question of finding The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0144-3585.htm Exchange rate volatility 211 Journal of Economic Studies Vol. 34 No. 3, 2007 pp. 211-255 q Emerald Group Publishing Limited 0144-3585 DOI 10.1108/01443580710772777

Upload: scott-w

Post on 27-Jan-2017

224 views

Category:

Documents


5 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Exchange rate volatility and tradeflows: a review article

Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee and Scott W. HegertyThe University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee, Milwaukee, Wisconsin, USA

Abstract

Purpose – Since the last review article by McKenzie, the literature has experienced a surge in thenumber of empirical articles. These new contributions, coupled with those that were overlooked byMcKenzie, set the stage for this review. Many of the recent studies have been empirical in nature andthese deserve specific attention. Thus, this paper aims to survey and review all of the studies bypaying attention to the attributes outlined in the text.

Design/methodology/approach – This paper examines the vast empirical literature, up to 2005, toassess the main trends in modeling and estimating these trade flows at the aggregate, bilateral, andsectoral levels.

Findings – The increase in exchange-rate volatility since 1973 has had indeterminate effects oninternational export and import flows. Although it can be assumed that an increase in risk may lead toa reduction in economic activity, the theoretical literature provides justifications for positive orinsignificant effects as well. Similar results have been found in empirical tests. While modelingtechniques have evolved over time to incorporate new developments in econometric analysis, no singlemeasure of exchange-rate volatility has dominated the literature.

Originality/value – An argument put forward by the opponents of the floating exchange rates isthat such rates introduce uncertainty into the foreign exchange market, which could deter trade flows.However, a theoretical argument is put forward by some to show that uncertainty could also boosttrade flows if traders increase their trade volume to offset any decrease in future revenue due toexchange rate volatility. The empirical literature reviewed in this paper supports both views.

Keywords Exchange rates, International trade

Paper type Case study

I. IntroductionAfter the post-war Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates collapsed in 1973,the relative prices of currencies began to fluctuate. These fluctuations broughtincreased uncertainty to traders; this risk may influence the volume of internationaltrade. Since the beginning of the current float, numerous theoretical papers have beenwritten to explain the effects of increased exchange-rate volatility on trade, and evenmore have been published evaluating these ideas empirically. These studies haveapplied different methods and obtained different results, but no consensus has beenreached regarding how to model, or even how to properly measure, exchange-ratevolatility.

Since the last review article by McKenzie (1999), the literature has experienced asurge in the number of empirical articles. These new contributions, coupled with thosethat were overlooked by McKenzie, set the stage for this review. Many of the recentstudies have been empirical in nature and these deserve specific attention. Thus, thispaper aims to survey and review all of the studies by paying attention to theirfollowing attributes. First, in section II we provide a brief overview of the theoreticalliterature that outlines the reasoning behind why increased exchange-rate volatilitymight hurt – or help – the volume of trade. Next, in section III the question of finding

The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at

www.emeraldinsight.com/0144-3585.htm

Exchange ratevolatility

211

Journal of Economic StudiesVol. 34 No. 3, 2007

pp. 211-255q Emerald Group Publishing Limited

0144-3585DOI 10.1108/01443580710772777

Page 2: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

an “appropriate” measure of exchange-rate volatility is addressed. In section IV, V, andVI, the empirical literature is assessed at the aggregate, bilateral, and sectoral levels.Concluding remarks for future research are outlined in section VII.

II. Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: theory and empiricsThe theoretical backgroundThe first theoretical papers that explained the effects of exchange-rate riskhypothesized that, in the absence of any mechanism to reduce this risk, volatilitywill reduce the volume of trade. Ethier (1973) shows that, if traders were uncertain as tohow the exchange rate affects their firms’ revenue, the volume of trade will be reduced.This uncertainty could be alleviated, however: Clark (1973) notes that whilerisk-aversion among traders might depress the volume of a country’s exports, perfectforward markets might reduce this effect. Baron (1976) finds that forward markets maynot be sufficiently developed, and traders may still be unsure of how much foreignexchange they want to cover. Hooper and Kohlhagen (1978) further outline the theorybehind risk aversion in assessing the effects of exchange-rate volatility on trade pricesand quantities, incorporating both supply and demand effects. Gagnon (1993) putsforth a theoretical “upper bound” to the size of this negative effect.

Other theoretical papers, however, show that increased exchange-rate volatilitymight have the opposite effect and increase the volume of trade. Viaene and de Vries(1992) note that, because importers and exporters are on opposite sides of a riskytrading relationship, their respective roles are reversed, leading to a positive coefficienton a volatility variable for one partner. Franke (1991) demonstrates that, under verygeneral conditions, a firm might benefit from increased volatility and thus increase thevolume of its exports in response. Sercu (1992) also shows that volatility can increasetrade, as it increases the probability that the price a trader receives might exceed tradecosts. Sercu and Vanhulle (1992) theorize that increased volatility increases the value ofexporting firms, thus encouraging exports. Dellas and Zilberfarb (1993) use anasset-market approach to explain a positive effect. Broll and Eckwert (1999) concludethat volatility increases the value of a trader’s option to export; since this risk increasesthe potential gains from trade, the volume of trade will increase accordingly.

Still other papers conclude that volatility has no discernible impact on the volume ofinternational trade. Willett (1986), noting that the empirical evidence up to that timehad not revealed the expected reduction of trade, hypothesizes that this had beenbecause international risk increased in the floating period, but international anddomestic risk had behaved differently. He called for analyses of specific industries todetermine the specific industry-level risk effects. At the aggregate level, this adds tothe large body of theoretical literature that predicts that volatility will have a negativeeffect, a positive effect, or no effect at all on trade flows.

Estimation procedures: an overviewIt was not long before these theories were put to the test. Early empirical studies reliedon simple methods such as Ordinary Least Squares to evaluate the effects of exchangerate volatility. Over time, the techniques were refined, incorporating distributed lags tocapture dynamic effects; instrumental variables to account for endogeneity; andvarious procedures to control for autocorrelation. As time series analysis, rather thansimple regression, became more popular, such techniques as the Vector Autoregression

JES34,3

212

Page 3: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

(VAR) were applied to this area of research. Once co-integration analysis wasintroduced to time-series econometrics, economists were able to avoid many of theproblems – such as “spurious correlations” – created by relying on an overly simpletechnique such as OLS. Thus, the progressive refinement of econometric technique isapparent as the literature incorporates more and more complicated techniques.

While there are still different models of the determinants of trade flows – such asthose based on gravity models and those based on income and substitution effects –recent literature has employed simpler models than were used in older papers. Manypapers focus on export volumes as a function of the importer’s income, some measureof relative prices of export goods and competing domestic goods, and exchange-ratevolatility. Likewise, import volume is often modeled as a function of domestic income,relative prices, and exchange-rate volatility. While some agreement has been reachedregarding the basic empirical specifications, there has been no consensus as to a singlemeasure of volatility.

III. Measuring exchange rate volatilityThe methods of measuring volatility have evolved over time to reflect new advances ineconometric techniques. Nonetheless, there has not yet emerged a clearly dominantapproximation for uncertainty. The most common is some measure of variance, but theexact construction of this measure differs from study to study. The volatility variablemay be constructed as the standard deviation of a rate of change, or the level, of avariable; a moving standard deviation, or a within-period one; or employ the nominal,or the real, exchange rate.

Whether the nominal or the real exchange rate is used differs among studies. On theone hand, the real exchange rate captures the true relative price of a traded good; sincethe real exchange rate incorporates the price levels of the trading countries, however, itcaptures volatility in these price levels as well. Thus, nominal exchange rate volatilitywas often preferred at first. Akhtar and Hilton (1984) were among the first to measurethe effects of uncertainty, measuring the standard deviation of daily observations ofthe nominal exchange rate during each three-month period. Later papers have usedeither the nominal or real rate, or both rates with the aim of comparing the measures.Here, neither rate dominates the literature.

Also important are the properties of the method used to approximate volatilityitself. Later estimates involved using the moving standard deviation of the monthlychange in the exchange rate. Kenen and Rodrik (1986) brought attention to this method,which has the advantage of being stationary. Before the advent of co-integrationanalysis, this was a very desirable property. Such authors as Bleaney (1992) performeda similar analysis, using the level rather than the rate of change in the exchange rate.Some authors have introduced other methods of measuring volatility, which often tookadvantage of newer time-series methods. Autoregressive ConditionalHeteroskedasticity (ARCH), developed by Engle and Granger (1987) as a measure ofvolatility in time-series errors, is a popular measure of exchange-rate volatility in muchof the literature surveyed below. This procedure models the variance of each period’sdisturbance term as a function of the errors in the previous period(s), with the simpleARCH(1) modeled as follows:

s 2ð1tÞ ¼ a0 þ a112t21 ð1Þ

Exchange ratevolatility

213

Page 4: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

This model can be extended to an ARCH(p) model with the addition of more lags,where p indicates the number of total lags in the model:

s 2ð1tÞ ¼ a0 þ a112t21 þ :::þ ap1

2t2p ð1bÞ

A further extension is Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity(GARCH), which incorporates moving-average processes. Pattichis (2003), described inmore detail below, shows that for his sample, an ARCH-based volatility measure isstationary.

Other proxies have also been used. Thursby and Thursby (1987) use the deviationof the log real exchange rate from its predicted value based on the trend of the variable:

lnRijt ¼ fi

0 þ fi1t þ fi

2t2 þ 1ijt ð2Þ

The measure of volatility is the standard deviation of the actual minus the fitted value,using monthly data. Asseery and Peel (1991) use the squared residuals from anARIMA process to form another proxy for volatility; they find this measure to besuperior to ARCH, and the authors’ estimate had the desirable property of stationarity.Some papers have introduced their own measures of volatility as well. Table I outlinesthe main proxies for exchange-rate volatility:

While some measures are more popular than others, none stands out as the standardvolatility proxy.

Stochastic properties of the measureCertain studies have focused specifically on evaluating the properties of exchange-ratevolatility itself, rather than solely on its effects. Although these have brought to lightthe fact that volatility may not be modeled using simple methods, these conclusionshave not been applied in the empirical literature. Rana (1981) compares differentmeasures of risk for eight Asian countries and concludes that these variables conformto a non-normal probability distribution. The author thus questions whether the“conventional” volatility measures gave correct results. Pritchett (1991) examines realexchange-rate volatility for 56 developing countries and finds that the stochasticproperties of volatility, while often overlooked, are key in understanding uncertainty’seffects on trade flows. While the standard deviation (the second moment of thevariable) is the most-common basis for measures of volatility, Pritchett finds thatskewness and kurtosis (the third and fourth moments, respectively) are equallyimportant. The study also indicates that the non-normality of the volatility variablelimited the effectiveness of the standard-deviation-based volatility measure. Thus,these authors have found that exchange-rate volatility may not be correctly proxied inthe bulk of the literature, but later papers have not heeded their conclusions. Theycontinue to rely on the variance, rather than the higher moments of the variable.

Authors have also drawn attention to proper model specification as well as to thestochastic properties of the volatility term. Bini-Smaghi (1991) makes the case thatspecial attention should be paid to the precise methods of modeling both exchange-ratevolatility and the economic relationship itself. Using OLS to perform his analysis, headdresses problems that were apparent using this particular specification. Still, manyof his comments were insightful: He calls for the use of disaggregated, sectoral data; ameasure of competitors’ prices (rather than the WPI or GNP deflator) that is not

JES34,3

214

Page 5: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Ty

pe

ofm

easu

reU

sed

in:

Wit

hin

-per

iod

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

:

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffi1

n2

1

Xn i¼1

x2

� x½

�2

!

v u u t,

wh

ere

the

nu

mb

erof

sub

-per

iod

sw

ith

inth

ep

erio

du

nd

erin

ves

tig

atio

n

Ab

ram

s(1

980)

Ak

hta

ran

dH

ilto

n(1

984)

De

Vit

aan

dA

bb

ott

(200

4a)

Got

ur

(198

5)H

oop

eran

dK

ohlh

agen

(197

8)K

um

aran

dD

haw

an(1

991)

Med

hor

a(1

990)

Mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

:

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

ffiffiffiffi1 n

Xn i¼1

x tþi2

12

x tþi2

2

�� 2

"#

v u u t wh

ere

nis

the

nu

mb

erof

per

iod

sen

com

pas

sed

by

the

mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

Th

ism

easu

rem

ayu

seth

ele

vel

orth

era

teof

chan

ge

ofa

var

iab

le

Level:

Ari

ze(1

995)

Ari

ze(1

996)

Ari

ze(1

997)

Ari

ze(1

998)

Cor

bo

and

Cab

alle

ro(1

989)

Cu

shm

an(1

988)

De

Vit

aan

dA

bb

ott

(200

4b)

Dog

anla

r(2

002)

Kor

ayan

dL

astr

apes

(198

9)K

um

aran

dD

haw

an(1

991)

Las

trap

esan

dK

oray

(199

0)

Rate

ofchange

Ari

stot

elou

s(2

001)

Ari

stot

elou

s(2

002)

Ari

zean

dG

hos

h(1

994)

Ari

zeet

al.

(200

0)A

rize

etal.

(200

3)B

ahm

ani-

Osk

ooee

(199

6)B

ahm

ani-

Osk

ooee

(200

2)B

ahm

ani-

Osk

ooee

and

Lta

ifa

(199

2)B

ahm

ani-

Osk

ooee

and

Pay

este

h(1

993)

Bai

leyet

al.

(198

7)B

lean

ey(1

992)

Bre

din

etal.

(200

3)C

han

and

Won

g(1

985)

Ch

owd

hu

ry(1

993)

Ch

oet

al.

(200

2)C

ush

man

(198

6)D

eG

rau

we

and

De

Bel

lefr

oid

(198

7)D

eV

ita

and

Ab

bot

t(2

004a

)G

iorg

ion

ian

dT

hom

pso

n(2

002)

Gro

bar

(199

3)G

rub

ean

dS

aman

taK

enen

and

Rod

rik

(198

6)K

um

aran

dD

haw

an(1

991)

Per

idy

(200

3)

(continued

)

Table I.Measures of

exchange-rate volatility

Exchange ratevolatility

215

Page 6: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Ty

pe

ofm

easu

reU

sed

in:

Poo

net

al.

(200

5)P

ozo

(199

2)R

app

and

Red

dy

(200

0)S

auer

and

Boh

ara

(200

1)S

tok

man

(199

5)T

enre

yro

(200

4)T

hu

rsb

yan

dT

hu

rsb

y(1

985)

Usm

anan

dS

avv

ides

(199

4)V

erg

il(2

002)

AR

CH

mod

els:

s2ð1

tÞ¼

a0þ

a11

2 t21þ

:::þ

ap1

2 t2p

wh

ere

pis

the

nu

mb

erof

lag

sin

the

AR

CH

(p)

mod

el.

Als

oin

clu

ded

inth

isli

star

eG

AR

CH

mod

els

Ari

zean

dG

hos

h(1

994)

Ari

zean

dM

alin

dre

tos

(199

8)A

rize

etal.

(200

5)C

apor

ale

and

Dor

ood

ian

(199

4)C

hou

(200

0)C

ush

man

(198

3)D

eV

ita

and

Ab

bot

t(2

004a

)D

oroo

dia

n(1

999)

Doy

le(2

001)

Gro

bar

(199

3)

Hol

ly(1

995)

Kro

ner

and

Las

trap

es(1

993)

Lee

(199

9)M

cKen

zie

and

Bro

oks

(199

7)P

atti

chis

(200

3)P

erid

y(2

003)

Poz

o(1

992)

Qia

nan

dV

aran

gis

(199

4)S

auer

and

Boh

ara

(200

1)S

uk

aran

dH

assa

n(2

001)

Lon

g-r

un

mod

elof

max

imu

man

dm

inim

um

val

ues

ofth

en

omin

alex

chan

ge

rate

:

max

Xt t2

k2

minX

t t2k

minX

t t2k

þ1þ

Xt2

Xp t

jj

Xp

hi 2

Ch

oet

al.

(200

2)P

eree

and

Ste

inh

err

(198

9)

AR

IMA

resi

du

als

Ari

zean

dS

hw

iff

(199

8)A

ssee

ryan

dP

eel

(199

1)G

rob

ar(1

993)

Sau

eran

dB

ohar

a(2

001)

Du

mm

ies

for

fix

ed/fl

oati

ng

per

iod

sA

rist

otel

ous

(200

1)B

rad

aan

dM

end

ez(1

988)

(continued

)

Table I.

JES34,3

216

Page 7: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Ty

pe

ofm

easu

reU

sed

in:

Dev

iati

onar

oun

dtr

end

,fo

rex

amp

le,

the

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofth

eac

tual

val

ue

min

us

the

fitt

edv

alu

eob

tain

edb

y

lnRi jt¼

fi 0þ

fi 1tþ

fi 2t2

þ1i jt

Ari

zean

dG

hos

h(1

994)

De

Gra

uw

e(1

987)

Gro

bar

(199

3)T

hu

rsb

yan

dT

hu

rsb

y(1

987)

Ab

solu

tep

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

:

x t2

x t2

1

x t2

1

� � � �� � � �

Wh

ere

tis

the

curr

ent

per

iod

Bai

leyet

al.

(198

7)

Non

-par

amet

ric

tech

niq

ues

Bel

ang

eret

al.

(199

2)

Dif

fere

nce

bet

wee

nth

ed

aily

aver

age

ofth

em

onth

lyp

red

icte

dsp

otan

dfo

rwar

dra

tes

(nom

inal

risk

):

Espot2

Eforw

ard

� �� �

E

Plu

sd

iffe

ren

ceb

etw

een

pre

dic

ted

and

actu

alin

flat

ion

risk

:

INFpredþ

INFactual

Mas

ku

s(1

986)

Un

clea

rK

lein

(199

0)

Inst

rum

enta

lv

aria

ble

sB

ini-

Sm

agh

i(1

991)

Del

l’Ari

ccia

(199

9)

Table I.

Exchange ratevolatility

217

Page 8: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

correlated with volatility; proper specification that controls for autocorrelation; andapplying the best proxy for exchange-rate risk. Bini-Smaghi states that the nominal,rather than real, exchange rate should be used as the basis of this proxy, becausefluctuations in relative prices represent an additional, separate risk to traders. Theauthor calls for an instrumental variable method of constructing the volatility term,because of the potential problems associated with many of the popular proxies in theliterature. The Akhtar-Hilton within-period standard deviation, for example, fails tocapture long-run shifts in the exchange rate. The moving standard deviation ofpercentage changes in the exchange rate, used by Kenen and Rodrik, is “moresatisfactory,” (p. 933) but has stochastic properties that make it potentially flawed.Thus, Bini-Smaghi suggests further research into model specifications that couldcapture significant effects of exchange-rate volatility. West and Cho (1994) test thepredictive ability of a number of volatility measures and find that, for time horizonslonger than one week, it is difficult to choose between the various models.

Seabra (1995) tests several measures of exchange rate uncertainty in his study ofpurchasing power parity in Latin America. After conducting tests for PPP for 11 LatinAmerican countries, Seabra evaluates many of the volatility proxies that are prevalentin the literature. He concludes that ARCH-based methods are most efficient. Pattichis(2003) generates an ARCH-based measure of nominal and real exchange-rateuncertainty for the 15 EU countries to test whether it is stationary. Using this method,he performs the Dickey-Fuller test and finds that for the countries in his sample,exchange-rate volatility is I(0), or stationary. Thus, the author concludes that if tradeflows are I(1), there can be no co-integration between these flows and exchange-ratevolatility[1]. However, this need not be the case, as has been shown by the “boundstesting” approach to co-integration of Pesaran et al. (2001). In this relatively newapproach, there is no need for unit-root testing, and variables in a model can be I(1), I(0)or some combination of the two. Even though these studies have maderecommendations as to the “best” volatility proxies, the empirical analyses in thisarea have not settled on a single measure. Table I gathers all different measures ofvolatility and identifies studies that have used each measure.

Given what has been said about these different measures, where does the literaturestand in terms of the impact of exchange-rate volatility on trade flows? We turn to thisquestion we turn to next. For ease of exposure, we classify all existing empiricalstudies into three categories. Those that have used aggregate trade data between onecountry and the rest of the world; those that have used trade data between twocountries, (bilateral trade); and those that have disaggregated the bilateral trade databy sectors or by industries.

IV. Empirical studies using aggregate dataAggregate data measures the trade flows of a nation to all its trading partners or to therest of the world. Early studies used Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) to evaluate thesensitivity of the aggregate trade flows to a measure of exchange-rate uncertainty;more recent papers have applied newer, more sophisticated techniques, includingtime-series and panel-data methods. For convenience, we classify the studies in thisgroup by the type of method used in estimating their models.

JES34,3

218

Page 9: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

OLS-based studiesThe earliest studies performed basic regressions of trade flows on their determinants.While there are a variety of functional forms to choose from, the most basic structure isto set exports as a function of world GDP, relative prices, and a volatility term. Initialstudies, however, incorporated a number of additional variables.

Akhtar and Hilton (1984) employ a polynomial distributed lag method in their OLSestimate of the effects of exchange-rate volatility. These lags allow for delayed effects;traders might respond to volatility from a previous period just as they might react tocurrent conditions. Using a within-period volatility measure, the authors set exportvolume as a function of foreign income, foreign capacity utilization (to capturenon-price rationing), and relative prices. Likewise, they model import volume as afunction of domestic income, the ratio of foreign to domestic capacity utilization, andrelative prices. Using data for the USA and Germany, they estimate their models usingquarterly data over the period 1974-1981. The authors find that volatility had asignificantly negative effect on German exports, German imports, and US imports, butno effect on US exports. Thus, their conclusions conform to the theory that increasedrisk reduces trade flows.

This was quickly challenged by Gotur (1985), who re-specifies the equations toarrive at drastically different results. Using the same methodology as Akhtar andHilton, she re-works the study with certain modifications. First, she includes France,the UK, and Japan in his sample and repeats Akhtar and Hilton’s analysis. Germanexports and imports are found to have been negatively impacted, and Japanese exportsare shown to be positively affected, but the other seven trade flows register no effect.Next, Gotur assesses the robustness of the earlier paper’s results. She charges thatAkhtar and Hilton had applied the Cochrane-Orcutt procedure to control forautocorrelation, even in the cases in which the problem was not even present; Goturthus applies the procedure only when the Durbin-Watson statistic calls for it. Inaddition, she changes the sample period under investigation to account for lagstructure; imposes a polynomial lag; and adapts the volatility measure to use adifferent definition of the effective exchange rate, as well as to incorporate the rate ofchange, rather than the level, of the exchange rate. She thus finds that most resultswere insignificant, repudiating the results of Akhtar and Hilton’s paper. Thus, modelspecification seems to spell the difference between finding significant or insignificantresults for the same data. However, given the evidence of unit root in most macrovariables, the findings of both studies should be discounted since none accounted forintegrating properties of the variables, leaving the results to suffer from spuriousregression problem.

OLS studies that incorporate lag effects often find more significant effects thanthose that ignore them. The next major analysis, by Kenen and Rodrik (1986), uses OLSwith an Almon lag to estimate the following equation:

logVt ¼ a0 þk

Xak logRm

t2k þ a2 logYt þ a3T þ a4I1Amt ð3Þ

where V is import volume, R is the (lagged) real effective exchange rate, T is a trendterm, and the final term is one of the six measures of volatility described below. Theauthors’ choice of deterministic variables is admittedly simpler than that used byothers, most notably the bilateral study by Hooper and Kohlhagen (1978), but a

Exchange ratevolatility

219

Page 10: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

variation of this simple model has been used in the bulk of the studies that havefollowed. Still, debate about the best volatility measure led Kenen and Rodrik, likemany authors, to test the model with various proxies and then choose the one thatproduced the best results. The authors use three different standard deviation measures:the standard deviation of monthly percentage changes in the real effective exchangerate (REER) for 24- and 12-month periods are denoted as I1A and I1B, respectively; ofthe REER from a log-linear trend equation (I2A and I2B); and of the REER from theresiduals of an AR(1) process (I3A and I3B). The sample includes the G-7 countries plusBelgium, The Netherlands, Sweden, and Switzerland, using quarterly data over theperiod 1979-1984. The authors find that volatility had a negative impact on exportflows. Once again, given recent advances in time-series analysis, such aserror-correction modeling, the main criticism of specification (3) is that the dynamicsonly includes the lagged value of the exchange rate. Had they included the laggedvalues of other variables, their results could have been different. Furthermore, theresults could be, again, spurious because Kenen and Rodrik (1986) did not account forthe unit-root properties of the variables.

Using OLS (with corrections for serial correlation, but without lags) to estimateexport volumes as a function of foreign income, relative price, volatility and the exportearnings of oil-producing countries, Bailey et al. (1987) survey the theoreticalfoundations behind potential negative or positive effects of uncertainty on tradevolume, and empirically test them for 11 OECD countries. They find little support foreither hypothesis. The authors use four measures of volatility: absolute percentagechanges in the nominal and effective real exchange rates, as well as a moving standarddeviation of both rates. Of the 33 regressions they ran for the G-7 countries, volatilitycarried a significantly negative coefficient in only three. Still, without lags it may bequestioned whether the model specification itself led to a lack of significant results.

Rather than concentrating on modeling techniques, economists at this point stilltended to focus on finding an approximation that best captured uncertainty – ofteninventing their own. Peree and Steinherr (1989) devise a unique measure of long-termvolatility (see Table I) for their OLS estimate of the export volume of the UK, Belgium,Germany, Japan, and the USA, using annual data over the period 1960-1985. Theyincorporate two measures of relative price in their formulation of the following theequation:

Et ¼ a0 þ a1Y*

t þ a2Rt þ a3Wt þ a4Tt þ jt; ð4Þ

where export volume is a function of world demand (Y *), the real exchange rate (Rt),volatility (W), and the terms of trade (relative prices, T). The authors find that theirown volatility measure works no better than any other measure; thus, the mostaccurate proxy for uncertainty remained elusive. They also find that, with theexception of the United States, exchange-rate volatility has a significant negative effecton trade volume. Thus, for all its problems, OLS was able to capture significant effects.Most often, these were negative.

Most studies surveyed up to this point examine the exports of the developed world,but the range of countries studied began to be extended to less-developed countries.These analyses also led to mixed results. Corbo and Caballero (1989) surmise that arisk-neutral firm might benefit from increased risk as marginal return rises, but that arisk-averse firm may react negatively to uncertainty. The authors then apply this

JES34,3

220

Page 11: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

theory to less-developed countries in Asia and South America. Approximatingvolatility as a four-quarter moving standard deviation of the real exchange rate, theauthors use OLS and instrumental variables to estimate the export demand functionsof Chile, Colombia, Peru, Philippines, Thailand, and Turkey. In addition to otherdeterminants, they include lagged exports to capture learning by doing. The authorsstate that OLS will result in a downward bias for price elasticities. Therefore, the logsof the relative CPIs of DCs and LDCs, world demand, lagged exports, and time, as wellas the standard deviation of the log real exchange rate, were chosen as instruments.They find that when they use IV estimation, volatility is shown to have a clear,negative effect on export volumes.

Medhora (1990) applies OLS on the pooled import volume of the countries of theWest African Monetary Union: Benin, Cote d’Ivoire, Niger, Senegal, Togo, and BurkinaFaso. The author notes that the Union’s exports follow a completely differentspecification, which depends on such factors as government policies and weather.Volatility is measured using the Akhtar-Hilton definition: the standard deviation of thenominal effective exchange rate (NEER) within each year – testing various ranges ofpossible sub-periods (weekly, monthly, and quarterly). Estimating what has become apopular, yet simple model, of export volume as a function of world income, relativeprices, and volatility, the author sets up what has become a much-used equation:

lnXt ¼ b0 þ b1 lnWt þ b2 lnPt þ b3Ext ð5Þ

An analysis of the period 1976-1984 finds that not only did volatility have nosignificant effect, but there was no difference between the choice of sub-periods whenformulating a volatility proxy.

Bahmani-Oskooee and Ltaifa(1992) include additional variables in their OLSanalysis that included both developed and less-developed countries. They estimate thefollowing equation using annual data over the period 1973-1980:

logXi ¼ aþ b logYi þ c log Popi þ dDEVi þ e logsi þ 1i ð6Þ

where X ¼ export volume, Y ¼ foreign income, s ¼ the standard deviation ofpercentage changes in the REER, Pop¼population, and DEV¼the rate of devaluationrelative to the US dollar. The population variable was drawn from the gravity model ofBrada and Mendez (1988), but here it is used to proxy potential excess labor that couldbe embodied in exports. Assessing 86 countries (19 developed and 67 LDCs),Bahmani-Oskooee and Ltaifa find that LDCs are more sensitive to exchange-ratevolatility.

Bahmani-Oskooee and Payesteh (1993) continue this look at less-developedcountries, this time analyzing both imports and exports for Greece, Korea, Pakistan,the Philippines, Singapore, and South Africa from 1973-1990. Testing numerousspecifications of relative prices and dynamic effects, they incorporate an Almon Laginto some of their specifications. Trade flows are specified as functions of income,relative prices (lagged REER, or ratio of import prices to domestic prices), andvolatility (measured by the standard deviation of percentage changes in the REER).The authors find that for half of the cases, volatility had depressed trade flows, butwhen they apply co-integration (time-series) analysis, they find no long-runrelationship between trade flows and their determinants. This study was followedby Bahmani-Oskooee (1996), who uses the Johansen co-integration procedure to

Exchange ratevolatility

221

Page 12: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

evaluate the same countries that were covered in the 1993 paper, only using log ratherthan level variables. Using these transformed variables, as well as a time-seriesapproach, the results are significantly negative for both exports and imports.

Modern time-series studiesWhile the Ordinary Least Squares is widely used to estimate time-series,cross-sectional, and panel models, eventually modern and specific time-seriesanalysis began to surpass OLS as the main econometric tool in this part of theliterature. The main goal of these relatively new techniques is to account forintegrating properties of the variables so that the results are not considered spurious.ARCH has become a popular method of approximating volatility, and VAR andespecially error-correction models have become the most commonly utilized estimationtechniques. These methods, however, were not conclusive at first. Lastrapes and Koray(1990) apply the Vector Autoregression to their analysis of US trade. At the time, theyviewed the VAR to be superior because the procedure does not require the specificationof exogenous variables. Their VAR incorporates eight variables: export volume,import volume, volatility (measured as the 12-month moving standard deviation of theREER), the M1 money supply, the three-month T-bill rate, income, and the ConsumerPrice Index). Using monthly data (1973-1987), the authors find no effect on exports ofexchange rate volatility, but they find a small negative effect on imports.

Co-integration analysis continued to make inroads during the early 1990s. Asseeryand Peel (1991), in an often-cited study, adopt this method to evaluate the exports ofJapan, West Germany, the USA, the UK, and Australia over the period 1972-1987.Assessing export volume as a function of income and relative prices, they use quarterlydata and a measure of volatility that is based on the residuals from an ARIMA processfitted to the log real exchange rate. They find a positive effect of exchange ratevolatility for most countries.

Chowdhury (1993) incorporates co-integration analysis as well – and finds theopposite result. Export volume is determined by foreign GDP and relative prices, andvolatility is approximated by an eight-quarter moving standard deviation of thegrowth rate in the REER. For the G-7 countries over the quarterly period from1973-1990, volatility is shown to have a significant negative effect for all countries.Chowdhury concludes that past time-series models had not detected the same effectbecause of the properties of the models themselves, which had not takennon-stationarity into account. Thus, co-integration analysis corrected the flaws ofprevious models, and only refined techniques were able to capture relationships thatother studies had overlooked.

Kroner and Lastrapes (1993) find similar results using monthly data for the sameperiod, using additional variables in their specification as well as a multivariateGARCH proxy for volatility. The authors incorporate not only the exchange rate andthe relative price as determinants of the quantity of exports, but also labor costs, andthree lags of export volume itself. They find that exchange-rate uncertainty had asignificantly negative impact on the export volume of the USA, UK, and positiveimpact in the results for France and Germany. It had no significant impact on Japaneseexports. Also assessing the impact of volatility on export prices, they find that priceswere affected even more than export quantities.

JES34,3

222

Page 13: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Qian and Varangis (1994) also use ARCH to approximate volatility. They estimatethe short-run effects of exchange-rate uncertainty by using the lagged differencedvariables in the following export equation, which is an extension of a long-run versionof equation (5):

DXt ¼ a0 þ a1DSt þ a2DP*

t þ a3DWt þ a4rt þ a5f ðhtþ1Þ þX12

i¼1

dxiDXt2i

þX12

i¼1

lxiDPt2i þ 1xt ð7Þ

where S ¼ nominal exchange rate, P* is the foreign price level, W is the real wage rate,r is the real interest rate, f(h) is the ARCH measure of volatility, and P is the domesticprice level. The model is estimated using OLS for Canada, Australia, Japan, the UK,The Netherlands, and Sweden, using monthly data over the period 1973-1990. Themodel is also extended to look at bilateral relationships. While these had manysignificant coefficients for volatility, only Sweden has a significant (positive) aggregateresult (although Japan-USA and Canada-USA exports are negatively affected at thebilateral level). These findings should be viewed with caution, due to the fact that thedynamics of many variables have been ignored in (7).

Arize and Ghosh (1994) use not only ARCH, but three additional measures ofvolatility in their study: a five-quarter moving-average standard deviation ofexchange-rate growth; the recursive residuals from an AR(4) model of exchange-rategrowth; and the residuals of an ARIMA (1,1,0) process fitted to the log of the exchangerate. The model incorporates income and relative price as additional determinants ofUS exports during the period 1970-1997, and finds that volatility had a negative andsignificant coefficient. Most importantly, after performing a number of structuralstability testes, the authors conclude that the general export flow equation, often usedwithout volatility in other studies, is unstable without a volatility term.

With the advent of error-correction modeling, economists have been further able toanalyze both the short-run and long-run effects of uncertainty. Increased volatility mayproduce a temporary effect, but this may be reduced or eliminated over time asequilibrium is again reached. Using this approach, Arize (1995) models export volumeas a function of income, relative price, and volatility which is approximated as aneight-quarter moving standard deviation of the log of the REER. An analysis of theThe Netherlands, Sweden, Denmark, and Switzerland over the period 1973:II-1992:IVfinds that volatility has had a significant negative effect for all countries for both theshort- and the long-run. Additional papers by this author, which generally use a verysimilar empirical specification as the 1995 paper, have provided a wealth ofinformation about numerous countries, the trade flows of most of which appear to havebeen depressed by exchange-rate volatility. These studies use either the Engle-Grangermethod of co-integration, which tests for stationarity in the residuals of an OLSestimation of stationary variables, or the Johansen approach, which tests for thepresence of one or more co-integrating vectors. Those studies that employ theEngle-Granger method of co-integration include Arize (1996), who assesses UK exportsand concurs with Arize and Ghosh (1994) that the trade-flow equation is incorrectlyspecified if it omits volatility. Arize (1997) obtains different results from previous

Exchange ratevolatility

223

Page 14: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

studies of G-7 trade flows, obtaining significantly negative results for all countries.Arize and Malindretos (1998) look at Australia and New Zealand, using ARCH as wellas a recursive method to capture volatility. They find mixed results: Volatility is shownto have had a positive effect for Australia, and a negative one for New Zealand. Arizeand Shwiff (1998) re-examine the import flows of the G-7 countries, per Kenen andRodrik (1986), using two additional measures of volatility: the log deviation of theREER from expected value given by an AR(4) process, as well as predicted changes inthe REER. They show positive results for Canada and insignificant results forGermany. Arize et al. (2003), who perform the classic study for Turkey, Korea,Malaysia, Indonesia, and Pakistan, obtaining negative results. Those papers thatemploy the Johansen co-integration procedure include Arize (1998), who analyzes theeffects of volatility on the import volume of Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France,Greece, The Netherlands, Spain, and Sweden; and Arize et al. (2000), who study theexport volume of 13 LDCs[2]. While most results support the adverse effect ofexchange-rate volatility, Finland’s volatility coefficient was shown to be insignificant;and Greece and Sweden showed positive and significant coefficients.

This body of literature outlined here shows mixed, but mostly negative, effects ofexchange-rate volatility on trade flows. It is important to note that these models, likemuch of the literature of the past ten years, also use simple specification – oftenemploying only income, relative prices, and volatility as determinants of trade flows.Most recent literature also makes use of similar methods of time-series analysis (eitherthe Engle-Granger or the Johansen method of co-integration), and similar modelspecifications that use income and relative prices, even if there is no single, consistentmeasure of volatility. Using the Engle-Granger method, Doroodian (1999) measuresvolatility with both ARMA residuals and a GARCH-based measure to study theexports of India, Malaysia, and South Korea over the period 1973:II-1996:III. Theauthor finds significantly negative effects of exchange-rate volatility on trade flows.Sukar and Hassan (2001) used a GARCH-based measure as well, and find a similarnegative result for U.S. exports from 1975:I to 1993:II. Doganlar (2002), approximatingvolatility as a four- or eight-quarter moving standard deviation of the real exchangerate, also finds that volatility depressed the exports of Turkey, South Korea, Malaysia,Indonesia, and Pakistan. Poon et al. (2005) achieves mixed results: Modeling the exportvolume of Indonesia, Japan, South Korea, Singapore, and Thailand as functions ofworld income, the REER, the terms of trade and volatility (approximated by the12-period moving standard deviation of the log REER) over the quarterly span from1973:II to 2002:II, the authors find that volatility depressed the exports for Japan, SouthKorea, and Singapore, and had a significantly positive effect on those of Thailand.

One study measures the effects of exchange-rate volatility using an entirelydifferent exchange rate. Using the Johansen method, Bahmani-Oskooee (2002)evaluates both the exports and imports of Iran. Rather than using the official exchangerate for his volatility proxy, he uses the black-market rate – noting that the gapbetween the two rates had become quite large. Employing a four-year moving standarddeviation of percentage changes in the black-market exchange rate as his volatilityproxy, Bahmani-Oskooee finds that black-market exchange-rate volatility hasdiscouraged Iranian trade flows. In the absence of any other study that uses blackmarket exchange rate volatility, this is one area where future research needs toconcentrate.

JES34,3

224

Page 15: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Panel studiesNot all papers have used time-series analysis to estimate their models. Sauer andBohara (2001) use a panel-data model to evaluate volatility’s influence on the exports of91 developed and less-developed countries. Three measures of volatility are tested: oneis ARCH-based, the second uses the eight-quarter moving standard deviation of theerrors from an AR(1) process on the log RER, and the third uses an eight-quartermoving standard deviation. Employing both the fixed- and random-effect models, theauthors model export volume as a function of world income, and one or both of tworelative-price measures: the real effective exchange rate (RER) and each country’sterms of trade (TOT) as in (8):

logXit ¼ ao þ a1 logY*

it þ a2 logRERit þ a3 logTOTit þ a4 logVOLit þ uit ð8Þ

The terms of trade measure of relative price appears to have been significant in allspecifications, but the real exchange rate – or both terms together – is also significantin most cases. When the countries are evaluated together, the effect of volatility issignificantly negative; when the countries are separated by region, the developedcountries and Asia register no effect, but Africa and Latin America show asignificantly negative effect. The authors attribute this regional disparity to thediffering opportunities for currency hedging in different countries. Thus, panel dataapproaches arrive at the same conclusion as purely time-series analyses. Table IIprovides summary and main features of all studies that have relied upon aggregatetrade data.

V. Empirical studies using bilateral dataWhile studies of countries’ aggregate trade flows produced important results – thatexchange-rate volatility generally depressed trade flows – there was still a possibilitythat significant results might be concealed. The well-known “aggregation bias” was apotential problem if a country’s bilateral trade flows with different partners producedoffsetting positive and negative effects that cancelled each other out at the aggregatelevel. Thus, bilateral studies may provide a more accurate analysis, as they evaluatethe bilateral exchange rate – which is the rate that is actually used by exporters andimporters. Just as has been shown to be the case with aggregate studies, over time theempirical methods used in bilateral studies have improved, but the results they havebeen consistent. These studies differ in another aspect, however – the modelspecification employed by has incorporated a wide range of explanatory variables.While the first studies made use of more variables than more recent ones have, gravitymodels are also popular in studies of exchange-rate uncertainty. In addition, otherpapers have measured the growth rates, rather than the levels, of the variables inquestions to make them stationary.

Early model specificationsThe first bilateral analyses of the effects of exchange-rate volatility also incorporatemore economic variables than do later studies. Hooper and Kohlhagen (1978)performed one of the first bilateral studies, using OLS (with a Cochrane-Orcuttcorrection) to assess the trade flows of the USA and Germany with their tradingpartners over the 1966I-1975IV. Volatility is proxied three different ways: using thestandard deviation of the 13 weekly spot and forward exchange-rate observations

Exchange ratevolatility

225

Page 16: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

ime

span

Res

ult

s/re

mar

ks

Ak

hta

ran

dH

ilto

n(1

984)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eIm

por

tv

olu

me

Sta

nd

ard

dev

iati

onof

dai

lyob

serv

atio

ns

ofN

ER

inth

ree-

mon

thp

erio

d

For

eig

nin

com

e,F

orei

gn

cap

acit

yu

tili

zati

on,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

s

Ger

man

y,

US

AQ

uar

terl

y:

1974

-198

1S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

for

all

bu

tU

Sim

por

ts

Ari

ze(1

995)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Eig

ht-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

log

ofR

EE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sT

he

Net

her

lan

ds,

Sw

eden

,D

enm

ark

,S

wit

zerl

and

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73:2

-199

2S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

for

all

shor

tru

nan

dlo

ng

run

Ari

ze(1

996)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

2:b

oth

EE

Rs

eig

ht-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

on

Rea

lex

chan

ge

rate

,E

xp

ort

pri

ces,

Wor

ldp

rice

s

UK

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73:2

-199

2:4

Neg

ativ

eef

fect

s;eq

uat

ion

wit

hou

tv

olat

ilit

yn

eed

sv

olat

ilit

yte

rmto

be

stab

leA

rize

(199

7)T

ime

seri

esG

ran

ger

met

hod

ofco

inte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Eig

ht-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

log

ofR

EE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sG

-7co

un

trie

sQ

uar

terl

y:

1973

:2-1

992:

4S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

for

all

Ari

ze(1

998)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Imp

ort

vol

um

e2:

log

ofei

gh

t-p

erio

dm

ovin

gav

erag

ed

evof

RE

ER

min

us

pre

dic

ted

val

ue,

rep

eate

du

sin

gw

ith

dif

fere

nce

bet

wee

nq

uar

ters

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sB

elg

ium

,D

enm

ark

,F

inla

nd

,F

ran

ce,

Gre

ece,

Th

eN

eth

erla

nd

s,S

pai

n,

Sw

eden

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73:2

-199

5:1

Fin

lan

d:

neg

ativ

e,b

ut

non

-sig

nifi

can

t;G

reec

e,S

wed

en:p

osit

ive

and

sig

nifi

can

t;ot

her

s:n

egat

ive

and

sig

nifi

can

tA

rize

and

Gh

osh

(199

4)T

ime

seri

esG

ran

ger

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

4:fo

ur-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gav

erag

est

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

qu

arte

rly

exch

ang

e-ra

teg

row

th;

AR

CH

;re

curs

ive

resi

du

als

from

AR

(4)

ofex

-rat

eg

row

th;

resi

du

als

ofA

RIM

A(1

,1,0

)fi

tted

tolo

gof

exch

ang

era

te

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sU

SA

1970

-199

7N

egat

ive

sig

nifi

can

t;g

ener

aleq

uat

ion

nee

ds

vol

atil

ity

term

tob

est

able

Ari

zean

dM

alin

dre

tos

(199

8)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

coin

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

2:A

RC

H,

recu

rsiv

em

eth

od:

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofer

rors

onla

gg

eder

rors

,R

EE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sA

ust

rali

a,N

ewZ

eala

nd

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73-1

992

Pos

itiv

efo

rA

ust

rali

a,n

egat

ive

for

New

Zea

lan

d

(continued

)

Table II.Aggregate studies of theeffects of exchange-ratevolatility

JES34,3

226

Page 17: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

ime

span

Res

ult

s/re

mar

ks

Ari

zean

dS

hw

iff

(199

8)T

ime

seri

esG

ran

ger

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Imp

ort

vol

um

e2:

log

dev

iati

onof

RE

ER

from

exp

ecte

dv

alu

eg

iven

by

anA

R(4

)p

roce

ss,

pre

dic

ted

chan

ges

inR

EE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sG

-7Q

uar

terl

y:

1973

:2-1

995:

1S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

for

5/7

ofth

eco

un

trie

sst

ud

ied

Ari

zeet

al.

(200

5)T

ime

seri

esG

ran

ger

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

AR

CH

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sB

oliv

ia,

Col

omb

ia,

Cos

taR

ica,

Dom

inic

anR

epu

bli

c,E

cuad

or,

Hon

du

ras,

Per

u,

Ven

ezu

ela

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73-2

004

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

ein

shor

tru

nan

dlo

ng

run

for

all

cou

ntr

ies

Ari

zeet

al.

(200

0)T

ime

seri

esJo

han

sen

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Eig

ht-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

log

RE

ER

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

s13

LD

C’s

:E

cuad

or,

Ind

ones

ia,

Kor

ea,

Mal

aysi

a,M

alaw

i,M

auri

tiu

s,M

exic

o,M

oroc

co,

Ph

ilip

pin

es,

Sri

Lan

ka,

Tai

wan

,T

hai

lan

d,

Tu

nis

ia

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73-1

996

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

ein

shor

tru

nan

dlo

ng

run

for

all

Ari

zeet

al.

(200

3)T

ime

seri

esJo

han

sen

met

hod

ofco

inte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Eig

ht-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onin

log

RE

ER

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sB

urk

ina

Fas

o,C

olom

bia

,C

osta

Ric

a,Jo

rdan

,K

eny

a,K

orea

,M

yan

mar

,P

akis

tan

,S

.A

fric

a,V

enzu

ela

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73:2

-199

8:1

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

ral

l

Ass

eery

and

Pee

l(1

991)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Res

idu

als

from

AR

IMA

pro

cess

fitt

edto

log

RE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sA

ust

rali

a,Ja

pan

,W

est

Ger

man

yJa

pan

,U

SA

,U

K

Qu

arte

rly

:19

72-1

987

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

ral

l

Bah

man

i-O

skoo

ee(1

996)

Tim

ese

ries

Joh

anse

nm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Imp

orts

Ex

por

tslo

gv

ersi

onof

Bah

man

i-O

skoo

eean

dP

ayes

teh

(199

3)

Lag

ged

RE

ER

,In

com

e,tr

end

Gre

ece,

Kor

ea,

Pak

ista

n,

Ph

ilip

pin

es,

Sin

gap

ore,

Sou

thA

fric

a

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73-1

990

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

e

Bah

man

i-O

skoo

ee(2

002)

Tim

ese

ries

Joh

anse

nm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Imp

ort

vol

um

e

Fou

r-y

ear

mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

inR

ER

RE

R,

Inco

me,

Tre

nd

term

Iran

Qu

arte

rly

:19

74:1

-199

4:4

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

e

(continued

)

Table II.

Exchange ratevolatility

227

Page 18: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

ime

span

Res

ult

s/re

mar

ks

Bah

man

i-O

skoo

eean

dL

taif

a(1

992)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eS

tan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

inR

EE

R

Pop

ula

tion

,d

eval

uat

ion

,In

com

e86

cou

ntr

ies:

19d

evel

oped

,67

LD

Cs

Yea

rly

:19

59-1

989

LD

Cs

are

mor

ese

nsi

tiv

eto

exch

ang

e-ra

tev

olat

ilit

yB

ahm

ani-

Osk

ooee

and

Pay

este

h(1

993)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Imp

ort

vol

um

eE

xp

ort

vol

um

e

Sta

nd

ard

dev

iati

onof

qu

arte

rly

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

esin

RE

ER

Lag

ged

RE

ER

,In

com

e,T

ren

dG

reec

e,K

orea

,P

akis

tan

,P

hil

ipp

ines

,S

ing

apor

e,S

outh

Afr

ica

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73-1

990

No

sig

nifi

can

tre

lati

onsh

ipb

etw

een

var

iab

les

Bai

leyetal.

(198

7)O

LS

Ex

por

tV

olu

me

4:A

bso

lute

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

es,

mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofb

oth

NE

ER

and

RE

ER

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

s,E

xp

ort

earn

ing

sof

oil-

pro

du

cin

gco

un

trie

s

G-7

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73:1

-198

4:3

3/33

reg

ress

ion

ssi

gn

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive,

rest

un

affe

cted

Cor

bo

and

Cab

alle

ro(1

989)

OL

S/I

VE

xp

ort

vol

um

eF

our-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

RE

R

RE

wor

ldin

com

e,L

agex

por

ts,

Tim

eC

hil

e,C

olom

bia

,P

eru

,P

hil

ipp

ines

,T

hai

lan

d,

Tu

rkey

Yea

rly

,T

ime

not

spec

ified

Neg

ativ

eef

fect

Ch

owd

hu

ry(1

993)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Eig

ht-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

gro

wth

rate

inR

EE

R

For

eig

nin

com

e,re

lati

ve

pri

ces

G-7

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73-1

990

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

ral

l

De

Vit

aan

dA

bb

ott

(200

4b)

Tim

ese

ries

AR

DL

Bou

nd

sT

esti

ng

app

roac

hto

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Six

-qu

arte

rm

ovin

gav

erag

est

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

log

lev

elof

RE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sU

SA

Qu

arte

rly

:19

87:1

-200

1:2

No

sig

nifi

can

tre

lati

onsh

ip

Dog

anla

r(2

002)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tV

olu

me

Fou

ror

eig

ht-

qu

arte

rM

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

RE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sT

urk

ey,

Kor

ea,

Mal

aysi

a,In

don

esia

,P

akis

tan

Qu

arte

rly

:B

egin

s19

80S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

Dor

ood

ian

(199

9)T

ime

seri

esA

RM

AE

xp

ort

vol

um

eG

AR

CH

Ex

por

tp

rice

s,p

d,

yIn

dia

,M

alay

sia,

Sou

thK

orea

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73:2

-199

6:3

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

e

Got

ur

(198

5)O

LS

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Sam

eas

Ak

hta

r-H

ilto

nE

xp

orts

sig

nifi

can

tfo

rU

SA

and

Ger

man

yw

ith

up

dat

e,b

ut

insi

gn

ifica

nt

for

imp

orts

and

all

oth

ertr

ade

flow

s

(continued

)

Table II.

JES34,3

228

Page 19: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

ime

span

Res

ult

s/re

mar

ks

Hol

ly(1

995)

*T

ime

seri

esJo

han

sen

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

GA

RC

HW

orld

exp

orts

,rel

ativ

ep

rice

sU

KM

onth

ly:

1980

-199

6S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

onsu

pp

ly,n

otd

eman

d

Ken

enan

dR

odri

ck(1

986)

OL

Sw

/lag

sIm

por

tv

olu

me

3:st

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

mon

thly

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

ein

RE

ER

I24-

and

12-m

onth

;st

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

RE

ER

from

log

-lin

ear

tren

deq

uat

ion

;st

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

RE

ER

from

AR

(1)

pro

cess

Inco

me,

Lag

ged

RE

X,

Tre

nd

term

G-7

plu

sB

elg

ium

,T

he

Net

her

lan

ds,

Sw

eden

,Sw

itze

rlan

d

Qu

arte

rly

:v

arie

s,19

79-1

984

Neg

ativ

e

Kro

ner

and

Las

trap

es(1

993)

GA

RC

H-i

n-M

ean

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

GA

RC

HE

xch

ang

era

te,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

s,L

abor

cost

s,In

com

e,th

ree

lag

sof

exp

orts

US

A,

UK

,Ja

pan

,G

erm

any

,F

ran

ceM

onth

ly:

1973

-199

0S

ign

ifica

nt

imp

act

for

all

Las

trap

esan

dK

oray

(199

0)T

ime

seri

es8£

8V

AR

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Imp

ort

vol

um

e

12-m

onth

mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofR

EE

R

Mon

eysu

pp

ly,

thre

e-m

onth

T-b

ill

rate

,In

com

e,P

rice

s

US

AM

onth

ly:

1973

:3-1

987:

12S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

for

imp

orts

,n

otex

por

ts–

bu

tsm

all

Med

hor

a(1

990)

OL

SIm

por

tv

olu

me

Sta

nd

ard

dev

iati

onof

NE

ER

w/i

nea

chy

ear

–w

eek

ly,

mon

thly

,an

dq

uar

terl

y

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sW

AM

U:

Ben

in,

Cot

ed

’Iv

oire

,N

iger

,S

eneg

al,

Tog

o,B

urk

ina

Fas

o

Yea

rly

:19

76-1

984

No

sig

nifi

can

tre

lati

onsh

ip

Pat

tich

is(2

003)

Tim

ese

ries

–co

-in

teg

rati

onon

lyG

AR

CH

EU

15M

onth

ly:

Ter

mv

arie

sV

olis

I(0)

Per

eean

dS

tein

her

r(1

989)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eT

wo

bas

edon

dis

par

itie

s(l

ong

-ter

m)

Inco

me,

RE

R,T

erm

sof

Tra

de

UK

,B

elg

ium

,G

erm

any

,Ja

pan

,U

SA

Yea

rly

:19

60-1

985

Poo

net

al.

(200

5)T

ime

seri

esJo

han

sen

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

12-p

erio

dm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

log

RE

ER

Inco

me,

RE

ER

,T

erm

sof

Tra

de

Ind

ones

ia,

Jap

an,

S.

Kor

ea,

Sin

gap

ore,

Th

aila

nd

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73:2

-200

2:Q

2S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

Jap

an,

S.

Kor

ea,

Sin

gap

ore;

Sig

nifi

can

tly

pos

itiv

efo

rT

hai

Ian

d (continued

)

Table II.

Exchange ratevolatility

229

Page 20: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

ime

span

Res

ult

s/re

mar

ks

Qia

nan

dV

aran

gis

(199

4)O

LS

Fir

std

iffe

ren

ces

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

AR

CH

NE

X,

For

eig

np

rice

s,R

eal

wag

era

te,

Lag

ged

exp

orts

,L

agg

edp

rice

s

Can

ada,

Au

stra

lia,

Jap

an,

UK

,T

he

Net

her

lan

ds,

Sw

eden

Mon

thly

:19

73-1

990

Sig

nifi

can

tfo

rb

ilat

eral

–n

egat

ive

(ag

gre

gat

ed

ata

show

edth

atS

wed

enw

asp

osit

ivel

yaf

fect

ed)

Sau

eran

dB

ohar

a(2

001)

Pan

elF

ixed

and

ran

dom

effe

cts

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

3:A

RC

H,e

igh

t-q

uar

ter

mov

ing

SE

from

AR

(1)

oflo

g(R

EE

R),

eig

ht-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gS

Eof

reg

ress

ion

oflo

g(R

EE

R)

ont,

t^2

Inco

me,

RE

R,T

erm

sof

trad

e91

cou

ntr

ies:

25L

atin

Am

eric

an,

25A

fric

an,

12A

sian

,22

LD

Cs

Yea

rly

:19

73-1

993

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

rL

atin

Am

eric

a,A

fric

a,n

otD

Cs

orA

sia;

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

rte

rms

oftr

ade

Su

kar

and

Has

san

(200

1)T

ime

seri

esG

ran

ger

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

GA

RC

HIn

com

e,R

elat

ive

pri

ces

US

AQ

uar

terl

y:

1975

-199

3S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

Table II.

JES34,3

230

Page 21: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

within each period, and the absolute average difference over the 13-week period. Theauthors choose to limit the risk proxy to capture only exchange-rate risk and not othertypes of risk; they thus focus on the variance of the expected future spot rate. Afterattempting a nonlinear estimation technique, they choose a linear one, which ismodeled as follows:

q* ¼ d0 þ d1UC* þ d2UC þ d3PD þ d4Y þ d5CU þ d6EH * þ d7EH

þ d8d*s1=R1þ d9dsR1

ð9Þ

where asterisks denote the exporting country’s variables, UC is the unit cost ofproduction, PD represents domestic prices, Y is income, CU is capacity utilization, EHis an exchange-rate adjustment factor, s1=R1

is exchange-rate risk for the exportingfirm, and sR1

is exchange-rate risk for the importing firm. The authors find thatvolatility had no significant effect on the volume of trade; they conclude that their focuson short-run volatility may have neglected certain effects on quantity that may havebeen caused by long-run volatility. In addition, their study also formulates a priceequation that showed that exchange-rate volatility has had a significant impact onprices.

Similar, although somewhat simpler, specifications had different results in laterpapers. Cushman (1983), following Hooper and Kohlhagen (1978), models exportvolume as a function of the home and foreign unit cost of production (UC and UC*,respectively), nominal GNP (Y), the importer’s manufacturing capacity utilization (CU),the importers’ weighted real exchange rate (R), uncertainty (S), recent percentagechanges in R (M), and a dummy to capture the trade disruptions caused by a dockstrike (D):

Q ¼ a0 þ a1Y þ a2CU þ a3UC þ a4UC* þ a5R þ a6M þ a7S þ a8D ð10Þ

Volatility is approximated as a four-quarter standard deviation of the expected growthrate of the nominal exchange rate relative to inflation, and 14 trade flows – of the USAwith the UK, France, Germany, Canada, and Japan, and Germany with the UK, France,and Japan – over the quarterly period 1965-1977 are considered. Of these,exchange-rate risk has positive effect on trade flows (including two French flows)and negative effects on seven cases. In another paper, Cushman (1986) again uses OLSto test a similar specification for the export volume of the USA to the UK, TheNetherlands, France, Germany, Canada, and Japan over the floating period. The modeladds third-country risk, however – incorporating external effects. Cushman concludesthat these effects are necessary when formulating a trade model, in order to captureindirect as well as direct risk. Thus, those studies that had omitted this factor mayhave overstated the effects of direct (bilateral) risk. While Cushman finds that thenegative impact of uncertainty had been growing over the floating period,third-country effects need to be included. Few recent studies, however, do so;third-country effects are generally omitted.

Finally, Cushman (1988) tests a number of different volatility measures using thespecification of equation (10). They include: the four-quarter standard deviation ofpercentage changes in R, the 12-month moving standard deviation of the samemeasure, the nominal three-month exchange-rate expectations based on the forward

Exchange ratevolatility

231

Page 22: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

rate, and the 12-month moving standard deviation based on expectations. Quarterlydata for the floating period for the UK, The Netherlands, France, Germany, Canada,and Japan demonstrate negative results for ten of the 12 flows, and those volatilitymeasures based on the forward rate and assuming a “time-varying risk premium”appear to have a slightly better significance level. Trade flows to Japan show a positiveeffect. Thus, these early analyses find that exchange-rate uncertainty had had mixedresults.

Gravity models of bilateral tradeWhile these early models of bilateral trade used a number of purely economicvariables, gravity models use a more geographic approach. Trade might take placebecause of two countries’ proximity to each other, the size of their markets, commonborders, or common language between the two. Thus, favorable prices and exchangerates (substitution effects) may not matter as much as being right next door. This typeof model generally captures imperfect competition rather than completely free trade.Abrams (1980) uses a gravity-type model to assess the value (rather than the volume)of the bilateral exports of 19 countries using pooled OLS. He utilizes the standarddeviations of both the levels and the rate of change of the 12 monthly exchange-ratevalues within each year to proxy risk, in order to capture two types of risk: that basedon recent changes and that based on trend. Abrams formulates export value as afunction of the importing and exporting countries’ GDPs, the distance between eachpair of countries, the percentage difference in each pair’s real per capita incomes, anddummies for membership in the European Economic Community. Annual data overthe period 1973-1976 show that uncertainty had a significantly negative effect for thepooled sample for equations using both proxies for volatility.

A different gravity specification is used by Thursby and Thursby (1987), who studythe export values of 17 countries using annual data over the period 1974-1982[3]. In thismodel, the value of trade flows is broken into a price component and a quantitycomponent. The determinants of trade flows are both countries’ CPIs and GDPs; avariable that captures consumer tastes; relative export and import prices, transportcosts; tariff rates (proxied by dummies for membership in trade blocs; the nominalexchange rate, and hedging opportunities. The estimate of volatility used is thestandard deviation of the spot rate around a predicted trend; the estimation techniqueis OLS with lagged variables. The authors find that in the majority (10 of 17) of cases,uncertainty depressed trade flows. In addition, Thursby and Thursby test the “LinderHypothesis,” which states that, because producers design their goods to matchdomestic tastes, they export those goods mainly to countries that have similar income– which corresponds to similar tastes. They find strong support for this hypothesis aswell.

Additional papers have incorporated gravity models in their bilateral analyses.Brada and Mendez (1988) test the export values of 30 developed and less-developedcountries as a function of foreign income, population, distance, and the existence ofpreferential trade agreements between each pair of nations. In order to avoid a relianceon a specific measure of volatility, simple dummy variables are applied to representfixed and floating exchange-rate regimes between each pair of countries. Many of thecountries evaluated in the study were members of cooperative agreements such as theEuropean Monetary system; many of the countries’ currencies were pegged to the US

JES34,3

232

Page 23: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

dollar, and other currencies were allowed to float to some degree. Using OLS for annualdata over the time span 1973-1977, which includes both “tranquil” and volatile periods,the authors’ results confirm the results of past research: that volatility reduces trade.Nevertheless, they conclude that this reduction is not as bad as the reduction of tradebrought on by the restrictive trade policies of countries that maintain fixed exchangerates.

Dell’Ariccia (1999) applies pooled OLS as well as fixed- and random effects paneldata and two-stage least squares models to study the 15 countries of the EuropeanUnion, plus Swizterland, over the annual period from 1975-1994. He tests the followinggravity model:

logðTRADEijtÞ ¼ gt þ aij þ b1 logðGDPitGDPjtÞ þ b2 logðDISTijÞ

þ b3 logð popitpopjtÞ þ b4BORDijt þ b5EUijt þ b1LANGijt

þ b7nijt þ 1ijt

ð11Þ

where between every pair of countries i and j, the total trade (bilateral exports plusimports, TRADE) is a function of the product of the countries’ incomes, the distancebetween the two countries (DIST), the product of the countries’ populations, anddummies to signify the presence of a common border (BORD), a common language(LANG), and membership in the European Union (EU). The variable aij is a shiftdummy to capture individual effects for each pair of countries; nijt representsexchange-rate volatility, proxied four different ways as the standard deviations of thefirst differences of the log nominal and real exchange rates; the sum of squares of theforward errors in the exchange rate; and the percentage difference between themaximum and minimum of the nominal spot rate; all of the measures use monthlyobservations within each year. For every measure of volatility employed, and for everymodel specification, the effect of uncertainty is consistently significantly negative. Theother deterministic variables are significant as well, and show the expected signs.Dell’Ariccia suggests that future studies use more disaggregated data. In addition, hedraws attention to the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM), which was designed toreduce uncertainty between the European currencies, and thus promote increasedtrade. When the volatility variables were included in the model, the ERM coefficientwas significant – but had a negative sign. While the author offers a number of possibleexplanations, this outcome remains a mystery.

Tenreyro (2004) addresses a number of the problems associated with the gravitymodel of bilateral trade, including properties of the error term, and potentialendogeneity – volatility may be partially determined by the level of trade. Using apseudo-maximum likelihood procedure, she corrects for the relevant biases. Likewise,an instrumental variable method – modeled as a logit procedure – is used to eliminateendogeneity. Volatility is modeled as the standard deviation using the movingstandard deviation method on the nominal exchange rate, and a gravity modelexamines exports as a function of distance, per capita GDP, population, area, anddummies for free-trade agreements, contiguity, common language, and colonialheritage. Analyzing 104 countries over the period from 1970-1997 using this nonlinearmethod, Tenreyro finds that nominal exchange-rate volatility has no effect on trade.

Exchange ratevolatility

233

Page 24: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Studies using growth rates of variablesA few early papers realized that trend may play a role in time-series models, possiblyproducing misleading results. To de-trend the data, these studies employ the growth oftrade rather than at the level or log level of these flows. Thursby and Thursby (1985),applying pooled time series OLS for the years 1973-1977, examine the followingequation:

Xij ¼ a1 þ a2ADGij þ a3Vij þ a4MEij ð12Þ

where Xij, the rate of change of bilateral exports, is expressed as a function of ADGij,the absolute difference between the two countries’ GDPs growth rate, volatility(standard deviation of absolute percentage changes in the monthly nominal and realexchange rate), and MEij, the mean percentage change in the monthly exchange rate.The sample, which consists of the countries of the G-7 as well as Austria, Belgium,Denmark, Finland, Greece, The Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, South Africa, Spain,Sweden, Switzerland, and Turkey, shows an insignificant result at the aggregate level,but produced significant results – both positive and negative – at the bilateral level.Thus, exchange-rate volatility is shown not to reduce the level of trade, but rather toaffect the pattern of trade.

De Grauwe (1987) and De Grauwe and de Bellefroid (1987) find that the measure ofvolatility is important when assessing its impact on trade flows. The basic methodcommon to both papers is a regression of the average yearly growth rate of bilateralexports on a measure of trade integration, the growth rate of world income, the rate ofchange of the real bilateral exchange rate, and a volatility term. De Grauwe and deBellefroid (1987) pointed out that most previous studies evaluated the effects ofshort-run rather than long-run exchange-rate volatility by focusing on weekly ormonthly fluctuations. For this reason, they measure volatility by the standarddeviation of the yearly growth rates of the nominal and real exchange rates around themean. De Grauwe (1987) performs a Seemingly Unrelated Regressions (SUR) analysisfor the G-7 countries plus Belgium, The Netherlands, and Switzerland over the periods1960-1969 (fixed exchange-rate system) and 1973-1984 (floating period). The result:volatility has led to a slowdown in the growth of trade, but the coefficient wassignificant only if real, not nominal volatility is used. Other factors may be moreimportant in contributing to the slowdown in world trade, however, including theslowdown in trade integration during the 1970s and the decline in the growth rate inworld output. De Grauwe and de Bellefroid (1987) employ the same specification for thesame sample of countries over the same period, and add as an additional term thevariable of each country’s effective exchange rate. The coefficients are significant inreducing trade flows, especially when the real effective exchange rate is used; at thesame time, the effects of exchange-rate volatility are reduced when the new variable isadded. Thus, introducing third countries to the analysis gives significant results.

Third-country effects are included in Kumar and Dhawan (1991), who study theless-developed country of Pakistan using a bilateral specification similar to equation(5), in which export volume can be expressed as a function of importer’s income,relative prices, the nominal exchange rate, and uncertainty. The authors also payattention to the exchange rate employed in their volatility measure, which is proxied bythe within-period standard deviation, the coefficient of variation and Gini’s meandifference of the nominal and real exchange rates; as well as measures of third-country

JES34,3

234

Page 25: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

effects (including other countries’ volatilities). The authors find that volatility in thenominal, but not the real, exchange rate is significantly negative; that a linear, ratherthan a log-linear, specification provides significant results; and that third-country riskis important in explaining the reduction in trade flows.

Models using income and substitution effectsMost bilateral studies, however, use the simple income/relative price specification thatis common in the more recent aggregate studies surveyed earlier. This can begeneralized as:

Xt ¼ b0 þ b1Yt þ b2RPt þ b3VOLt þ 1t; ð13Þ

but it often includes trend terms, dummies, and other additions. The relative price maybe either a ratio of price levels or the real exchange rate. This is a reduced-formequation that captures supply and demand effects.

The earliest studies employed Ordinary Least Squares as the estimation technique.Chan and Wong (1985) use the four-quarter moving average of the percentage changein the real bilateral exchange rate as a proxy for volatility, performing an OLSregression of the volume of Hong Kong’s exports to the USA, the UK, and WestGermany. The determining variables are foreign income, the real exchange rate,seasonal dummies, and a trend term, including lags of all variables over the period1977-1984. The authors find that volatility had no effect on these trade flows.Extending the model to use the first differences, rather than the levels of the variables,did not change the results.

Other papers that follow this general specification have found that volatility hashad a significant effect. Peree and Steinherr (1989), creating a specific measure of“medium-term” exchange-rate volatility (see Table I), perform a bilateral study as wellas an aggregate one, and find that volatility had reduced trade flows. Bleaney (1992)analyzes German exports to Japan, Switzerland, UK, the USSR, Italy, The Netherlands,Belgium, and France using quarterly data from 1979-1990 and a standarddeviation-based volatility measure; volatility was shown to have had a significantlynegative effect. Bleaney notes the difference between volatility and “misalignment,”where a real exchange rate deviates from its equilibrium value. Pozo (1992) examinesbilateral exports from the UK to the USA from 1900-1940 using both GARCH- andstandard-deviation-based volatility proxies. The results support the adverse impact ofvolatility on trade flows. However, hedging opportunities may have alleviated thiseffect over certain sub-periods.

Studying US imports from Canada from 1974 to 1992, Caporale and Doroodian(1994) model uncertainty with a GARCH process, and find that these trade flows werealso hurt by volatility. These studies did not always find adverse effect on trade flowsof exchange rate volatility. McKenzie and Brooks (1997), using ARCH and analyzingUS-German trade from 1973:4-1992:9, arrive at significantly positive effects, regardlessof whether they used the real or the nominal exchange rate. Thus, the authors come to adifferent conclusion than those previous studies that had not captured any effect due toexchange rate volatility. McKenzie and Brooks also attain the opposite outcome asKumar and Dhawan (1991) – again, the literature had not arrived at even a universallyvalid choice of nominal versus real exchange rates.

Exchange ratevolatility

235

Page 26: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

As time-series methods were refined, bilateral studies began to apply them just asaggregate ones had. Various macroeconomic variables have been incorporated intomodels of trade and volatility. Koray and Lastrapes (1989) apply a VAR of the bilateralimports of the UK, France, Germany, Japan, and Canada from 1959-1985. The otherseven variables in the 8 £ 8 VAR are the interest rate, the money supply, prices,income, the nominal exchange rate, and a moving standard deviation-based volatilityproxy. The authors reveal a weak relationship, but concluded that, permanentvolatility shocks depress imports.

In more recent studies, co-integration and error-correction models have been appliedto bilateral studies of the effects of exchange-rate volatility. These methods have alsoarrived at mixed conclusions. Aristotelous (2001) employs the Engle-Granger methodof co-integration to evaluate British exports to the USA over the period 1889-1999,using annual data. His model, called a gravity model, uses income and substitutionvariables that are similar to those used in the other papers of this sub-section. Proxyingvolatility with dummies for the fixed and floating periods, as well as the standarddeviation of growth in the REER, Aristotelous models exports as a function of bothcountries’ total and per capita income, relative prices, and a war dummy. He finds thatneither volatility nor regime shifts had any effect on export flows. Aristotelous (2002)finds a different result in his co-integration analysis of US exports to Canada, Japan,Germany an the UK over the period 1959:1-1997:4. He estimates a model similar toequation (13) with an additional dummy for the post-1972 floating period, and uses themoving standard deviation proxy for risk. He finds that volatility has significant short-and long-run effects, and that the shift dummy was significantly negative in the case ofUS exports to Japan and Germany. Thus, the floating exchange-rate regime is shown tohave had a detrimental effect on US trade. Vergil (2002), also using the Engle-Grangermethod, analyzes Turkish exports to the USA, Germany, France, and Italy, using thesimple price-income specification. The effect of volatility is significant in the long runto all countries but Italy. One advantage of the ECM methodology is that it reveals theshort run-effects: Vergil finds a significantly negative short-run effect for Germany.

The volatility measure in most models (aggregate or bilateral) is based on standarddeviation of the real exchange rate, which is suspected to be a stationary variable.Since other variables in trade models are non-stationary, this introduces a problem inapplying Engle-Granger or Johansen’s co-integration technique. These techniquesrequire that all variables to be non-stationary; but the linear combination proxied bythe residuals of the trade model must be stationary. The introduction of theAutoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) or “bounds testing” approach toco-integration by Pesaran et al. (2001) has solved this problem. In this relatively newapproach, the variables in any time-series model could be I(1) or I(0). Anotheradvantage of the approach is that one could infer the short-run as well as the long-runeffects of one variable on the other at the same time. Indeed, De Vita and Abbott(2004b) employ the bounds testing approach in their study of US exports. They modelexport volume (ex) as a function of relative prices ( p), income (ic) and volatility (V) inthis popular long-run equation, which is the log version of (13):

ext ¼ b0 þ b1pt þ b2ict þ b3Vt þ ut ð14Þ

where V is the moving-average standard deviation of the log level of the real-exchangerate, for US exports to Canada, Mexico, Germany, Japan, and the UK over the period

JES34,3

236

Page 27: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

1987:I-2001:II. This equation is then extended to incorporate short-run and long-runeffects of the left-hand side variables (labeled in the paper as y) and the right-hand sidevariables (labeled as x):

Dyt ¼ c0t þ pyyt21 þ pxxt21 þXp21

i¼1

wtDyt2i þXq21

j¼1

d 0tDxt2j þ g 0Dxt þ 1t ð15Þ

Modeling the differences and the level variables together allows an analysis of bothdisequilibrium (short-run) and equilibrium (long-run) relationships. In addition, the testfor co-integration is conducted with an F-test of the joint significance of the coefficientspy and px in which the critical values were tabulated by Pesaran et al. If the F-valuefalls above the upper bound, the variables are shown to be co-integrated; if the statisticfalls below the lower bound, they are shown not to be co-integrated; and if the valuefalls in between, the test is inconclusive. The results are mixed in De Vita and Abbott’sstudy: The authors find significantly negative effects of volatility for Germany, the UK,and Mexico; and significantly positive results for Japan. As newer papers adopt thismethod, they offer the opportunity to assess short- and long-run effectssimultaneously, while allowing the presence of co-integration to be tested moreeasily than can be done by older methods. Table III provides a summary and mainfeatures of all studies in this group.

VI. Empirical studies that use sectoral dataSince this disaggregation of total trade data by trading partners resulted in no changein the mixed conclusion produced by aggregate studies, some authors havedisaggregated bilateral trade data between pairs of countries by either sector or bycommodity with a hope that some significant results could be discovered. In doing so,these studies have relied on recent advances in time-series analysis. Because differentsectors face different levels of risk, this disaggregation helps isolate specific effects onspecific goods. These studies can be broken down into two groups: Those thatdisaggregate trade into as many diverse sectors as possible, and those that focus on asingle sector and investigate its specific properties.

Multi-sector studiesWhereas the first aggregate and bilateral studies concentrated on the exports ofdeveloped countries, this is not the case for sectoral analyses. Coes (1981) performedone of the first sectoral studies, examining the effects of uncertainty in Brazil.Analyzing a wide range of manufactured goods (13 in all, including mineral products,rubber products, transportation equipment, and textiles), as well as nine primaryproducts, he formulates the following equation, which shows export volume as a linearfunction of level and lagged uncertainty, relative prices and foreign income as in (15):

ðX=QÞ ¼ b0 þX3

j¼0

b1jð1=U Þ þX3

j¼0

b2jP þ b3Y ð15Þ

The polynomial lag has a maximum of three years; uncertainty is proxied using ameasure of variance of the monthly real exchange rate; and the model is estimated withOLS. Estimating over the period 1957-1974, Coes finds that all manufactured goods

Exchange ratevolatility

237

Page 28: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

imes

pan

Res

ult

s

Ab

ram

s(1

980)

OL

SE

xp

ort

val

ue

2:S

tan

dar

dd

evia

tion

of12

-mon

thst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

esin

exch

ang

era

te

Inco

me,

For

eig

nin

com

e,D

ista

nce

,P

erce

nta

ge

dif

fere

nce

inre

alp

erca

pit

ain

com

es,

EE

C,

EF

TA

du

mm

ies

19co

un

trie

sY

earl

y:

1973

-197

6S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

Ari

stot

elou

s(2

001)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Du

mm

ies-

fix

ed,

Flo

at;

Mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofg

row

thin

RE

ER

Inco

me,

For

eig

nG

DP

,R

elat

ive

pri

ces,

War

du

mm

y

Bri

tain

toU

SA

Yea

rly

:18

89-1

999

No

effe

ct

Ari

stot

elou

s(2

002)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Du

mm

ies-

fix

ed,

Flo

at;

Mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofch

ang

esin

RE

ER

Inco

me,

For

eig

nG

DP

,R

elat

ive

pri

ces,

du

mm

yfo

rfl

oati

ng

per

iod

US

Ato

Can

ada,

Jap

an,

Ger

man

yU

KQ

uar

terl

y19

59:1

-199

7:4

Sig

nifi

can

tef

fect

for

vol

atil

ity

,si

gn

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

for

reg

ime

du

mm

yB

ini-

Sm

agh

i(1

991)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eS

tan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofp

erce

nta

ge

wee

kly

chan

ges

inE

ER

For

eig

nG

DP

,E

xp

ort

pri

ces,

Imp

ort

pri

ces

Ger

man

y,

Fra

nce

,It

aly

toE

MS

1976

-198

4,y

earl

yan

dq

uar

terl

y

Dif

fere

nt

spec

ifica

tion

sg

ive

dif

fere

nt

resu

lts

Ble

aney

(199

2)O

LS

Mea

suri

ng

vol

atil

ity

–n

eed

sto

cap

ture

mea

nre

ver

sion

,et

c.

Sta

nd

ard

dev

iati

onof

lev

elof

RE

Rov

ersi

x-y

ear

per

iod

Ger

man

yto

Jap

an,

Sw

itze

rlan

d,

UK

,U

SA

shor

tru

n,

Ital

y,

Th

eN

eth

erla

nd

s,B

elg

ium

,F

ran

ce

Qu

arte

rly

:19

79-1

990

Bra

da

and

Men

dez

(198

8)

OL

SE

xp

ort

val

ue

Du

mm

ies

for

fix

ed,

floa

tin

gp

erio

dIn

com

e,P

opu

lati

on,

dis

tan

ce,

Du

mm

ies

for

pre

fere

nti

altr

ade

agre

emen

ts

30D

Cs

and

LD

Cs

Yea

rly

:19

73-1

977

Flo

atin

gb

oost

str

ade,

bu

tv

olat

ilit

yd

oes

red

uce

it

Cap

oral

ean

dD

oroo

dia

n(1

994)

OL

SIm

por

tv

olu

me

GA

RC

HIn

com

e,R

EX

US

Afr

omC

anad

aM

onth

ly:

1974

:1-1

992:

4S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

Ch

anan

dW

ong

(198

5)O

LS

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Fou

r-q

uar

ter

ofp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ge

ofR

ER

Inco

me,

RE

X,

Sea

son

ald

um

mie

s,T

ren

d,L

ags

ofal

lth

ree

US

A,

UK

,W

est

Ger

man

y19

77-1

984

No

effe

ct

Cu

shm

an(1

983)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eF

our-

qu

arte

rst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

exp

ecte

dg

row

thra

teof

the

NE

Rre

lati

ve

toin

flat

ion

Un

itco

stof

pro

du

ctio

n(H

ome

and

For

eig

n),

Inco

me,

imp

orte

rsm

anu

fact

uri

ng

cap

acit

yu

tili

zati

on,

imp

orte

rs’

wei

gh

ted

RE

R,

doc

kst

rik

ed

um

my

US

Aw

ith

UK

,F

ran

ce,

Ger

man

y,

Can

ada,

Jap

an;

Ger

man

yw

ith

UK

,F

ran

ce,

Jap

an(1

4fl

ows)

Qu

arte

rly

:19

65-1

977

3/16

pos

itiv

e,7/

16n

egat

ive

(continued

)

Table III.Bilateral studies of theeffects of exchange-ratevolatility

JES34,3

238

Page 29: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

imes

pan

Res

ult

s

Cu

shm

an(1

986)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eF

our-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

RE

R

Inco

me,

Cap

acit

yu

tili

zati

on,

Rea

lu

nit

cost

s(h

ome

and

fore

ign

);R

EX

,M

ovin

gm

ean

ofR

EX

,C

ovar

ian

ceof

exch

ang

era

tes

US

Ato

UK

,T

he

Net

her

lan

ds,

Fra

nce

,G

erm

any

,C

anad

a,Ja

pan

Qu

arte

rly

:19

65-1

977,

1973

-198

3

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

e,p

osit

ive;

nee

dto

incl

ud

eth

ird

-cou

ntr

yef

fect

s

Cu

shm

an(1

988)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

e5:

Fou

r-q

uar

ter

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

inR

EX

,12

-mon

thm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

on,

Ex

pec

tati

ons

bas

edon

forw

ard

rate

:n

omin

alth

ree-

mon

thex

-rat

eex

pec

tati

ons,

12-m

onth

mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

,m

onth

lyav

erag

edto

qu

arte

rly

Inco

me;

imp

orte

r’s

cap

acit

yu

tili

zati

on,

Imp

orte

r’s

real

un

itla

bor

cost

,R

EX

,F

our-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gav

erag

eof

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

esin

RE

X,

Doc

kst

rik

ed

um

my

UK

,T

he

Net

her

lan

ds,

Fra

nce

,G

erm

any

,C

anad

a,Ja

pan

Qu

arte

rly

:19

74-1

983

10/1

2b

ilat

eral

flow

sw

ere

neg

ativ

e

De

Gra

uw

e(1

987)

SU

RG

row

thra

teof

exp

orts

Sta

nd

ard

dev

iati

onof

yea

rly

gro

wth

rate

sof

RE

Xar

oun

dth

em

ean

Tra

de

inte

gra

tion

,G

row

thra

teof

wor

ldin

com

e,P

erce

nta

ge

rate

ofch

ang

ein

RE

X,P

erio

dd

um

mie

s

Bel

giu

m,

Can

ada,

Fra

nce

,W

est

Ger

man

y,

Ital

y,

Jap

an,

Th

eN

eth

erla

nd

s,S

wit

zerl

and

,U

K,

US

A

Qu

arte

rly

/yea

rly

:19

60-1

969,

1973

-198

4

Neg

ativ

eef

fect

ong

row

thof

trad

e

De

Gra

uw

ean

dd

eB

elle

froi

d(1

987)

OL

SA

ver

age

yea

rly

gro

wth

inex

por

ts2:

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofy

earl

yg

row

thra

tes

(RE

R,

NE

R)

mea

nab

solu

tep

erce

nta

ge

chan

ge

ofra

tes

Inco

me,

Tra

de

inte

gra

tion

G-7

plu

sB

elg

ium

,T

he

Net

her

lan

ds,

Sw

itze

rlan

d

Yea

rly

:19

60-1

969,

1973

-198

4

Neg

ativ

e,U

sual

lysi

gn

ifica

nt

De

Vit

aan

dA

bb

ott

(200

4a)

Tim

ese

ries

:A

RD

Lb

oun

ds

test

ing

app

roac

hto

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Six

-qu

arte

rm

ovin

gav

erag

est

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

log

lev

elof

RE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sU

SA

toC

anad

a,M

exic

o,G

erm

any

,Ja

pan

,U

KQ

uar

terl

y:

1987

:1-2

001:

2S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

for

Ger

man

y,

UK

,M

exic

o;S

ign

ifica

nt

pos

itiv

efo

rJa

pan

Del

l’Ari

ccia

(199

9)P

anel

:P

oole

d,

fix

edef

fect

s,ra

nd

omef

fect

sE

xp

orts

þIm

por

tsF

un

ctio

nof

trad

esh

ares

:st

and

ard

dev

iati

onfo

rN

ER

and

RE

R,

forw

ard

erro

r,ra

ng

e

Pro

du

ctof

cou

ntr

ies’

Inco

mes

,P

rod

uct

ofco

un

trie

s’p

opu

lati

ons,

Dis

tan

ce,

Bor

der

,E

U,

Lan

gd

um

mie

s

EU

15þ

Sw

itze

rlan

dY

earl

y:

1975

-199

4A

llsi

gn

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

(continued

)

Table III.

Exchange ratevolatility

239

Page 30: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

imes

pan

Res

ult

s

Hoo

per

and

Koh

lhag

en(1

978)

OL

SIm

por

tv

olu

me

3:S

tan

dar

dd

evia

tion

of13

wee

kly

obse

rvat

ion

sin

each

qu

arte

rof

spot

and

forw

ard

NE

R,

Av

erag

e.ab

s.d

iffe

ren

ceov

er13

wee

ks

w/l

agg

edv

alu

e

Un

itco

stof

pro

du

ctio

n(h

ome

and

fore

ign

),D

omes

tic

pri

ces,

inco

me,

Man

ufa

ctu

rers

’ca

pac

ity

,U

tili

zati

on,

Imp

orte

rs’

wei

gh

ted

exch

ang

era

te,

Ex

por

ters

,ex

chan

ge

rate

adju

stm

ent

fact

or

US

A,

Ger

man

yQ

uar

terl

y:

1966

:4-1

975

Ris

kre

du

ced

exp

orts

infl

oati

ng

per

iod

;al

son

eg.

imp

act

onp

rice

Kor

ayan

dL

astr

apes

(198

9)

Tim

ese

ries

VA

RIm

por

tv

olu

me

12-m

onth

mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

inlo

gR

ER

Mon

eysu

pp

ly,

Bon

dy

ield

,P

rice

s,In

com

e,N

ER

UK

,F

ran

ce,

Ger

man

y,

Jap

an,

Can

ada

Mon

thly

:19

59-1

985

Wea

kre

lati

onsh

ip,

per

man

ent

vol

atil

ity

shoc

ks

dep

ress

imp

orts

Ku

mar

and

Dh

awan

(199

1)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eW

ith

inp

erio

dst

and

ard

dev

iati

on,

Mov

ing

-av

erag

est

and

ard

dev

iati

on,

Coe

ffici

ent

ofv

aria

nce

(For

RE

X,

NE

X,

and

chan

ges

inR

EX

)G

ini

Mea

nD

iffe

ren

ce,

3rd

cou

ntr

yri

sk

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

s,N

EX

Pak

ista

nQ

uar

terl

y:

1974

-198

5S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

ifu

sin

gN

EX

,not

RE

X;3

rdco

un

try

risk

imp

rov

esex

pla

nat

ion

McK

enzi

ean

dB

rook

s(1

997)

OL

SE

xp

orts

(Im

por

ts)

AR

CH

US

Inco

me

and

pri

ces,

Ger

man

inco

me

and

pri

ces,

NE

X

US

A,

Ger

man

yM

onth

ly:

1973

:4-1

992:

9S

ign

ifica

ntl

yp

osit

ive

No

dif

fere

nce

bet

wee

nu

sin

gR

EX

,N

EX

Per

eean

dS

tein

her

r(1

989)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eT

wo

bas

edon

dis

par

itie

s(l

ong

-tem

)In

com

e,R

ER

,T

erm

sof

trad

eU

K,

Bel

giu

m,

Ger

man

y,

Jap

anto

US

AY

earl

y:

1960

-198

5S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

for

all

bu

tU

SA

Poz

o(1

992)

OL

SR

eal

exp

ort

vol

um

e2:

GA

RC

H,

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofm

onth

lyp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

inR

EX

US

inco

me,

RE

X,

du

mm

ies

for

reg

ime

shif

ts

Bri

tain

toU

SA

Yea

rly

:19

00-1

940

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

e

Ten

rey

ro(2

004)

Pan

elP

seu

do-

max

imu

mli

kel

ihoo

dIn

stru

men

tal

var

iab

le

Ex

por

tsS

tan

dar

dd

evia

tion

offi

rst

dif

fof

log

ofm

onth

lyex

chan

ge

rate

Dis

tan

ce,

Du

mm

ies,

per

cap

ita

GD

P,

Pop

ula

tion

,ar

ea

104

cou

ntr

ies

1970

-199

7N

oef

fect

(continued

)

Table III.

JES34,3

240

Page 31: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

imes

pan

Res

ult

s

Th

urs

by

and

Th

urs

by

(198

7)

OL

S(l

ags)

Ex

por

tv

alu

eS

tan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofsp

otra

tear

oun

dp

red

icte

dtr

end

Pri

ces,

Inco

me,

For

eig

nG

DP

,T

aste

s,R

elat

ive

exp

ort

and

imp

ort

pri

ces,

Tra

nsp

ort

cost

s,N

EX

,D

edg

ing

opp

ortu

nit

ies

Au

stri

a,B

elg

ium

,D

enm

ark

,F

inla

nd

,F

ran

ce,

Ger

man

y,

Gre

ece,

Ital

y,

Th

eN

eth

erla

nd

s,N

orw

ay,

Sw

eden

,S

wit

zerl

and

,U

K,

Can

ada,

Sou

thA

fric

a,U

SA

Yea

rly

:19

74-1

982

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

rm

ost

Th

urs

by

and

Th

urs

by

(198

5)

OL

S:

poo

led

tim

ese

ries

,C

ross

-sec

tion

Ex

por

tv

alu

eS

tan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofab

solu

tep

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

inN

ER

and

RE

R

Ab

solu

ted

iffe

ren

ceb

etw

een

the

two

cou

ntr

ies’

GD

Ps,

mea

np

erce

nta

ge

chan

ge

inth

em

onth

lyex

chan

ge

rate

G-7

þA

ust

ria,

Bel

giu

m,

Den

mar

k,

Fin

lan

d,

Gre

ece,

Th

eN

eth

erla

nd

s,N

orw

ay,

Por

tug

al,

Sou

thA

fric

a,S

pai

n,

Sw

eden

,S

wit

zerl

and

,T

urk

ey

Yea

rly

:19

73-1

977

Insi

gn

ifica

nt

atag

gre

gat

ele

vel

,P

osit

ive

and

neg

ativ

esi

gn

ifica

nt

effe

cts

atb

ilat

eral

lev

el

Ver

gil

(200

2)T

ime

seri

esG

ran

ger

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

2:v

aria

nce

oftr

end

equ

atio

n,

12-m

onth

mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

Inco

me,

RE

RT

urk

eyto

US

A,

Ger

man

y,

Fra

nce

,It

aly

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73:2

-199

1:3

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

eto

all

bu

tIt

aly

,S

ign

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

shor

tru

nfo

rG

erm

any

Table III.

Exchange ratevolatility

241

Page 32: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

registered significant effects of exchange rate volatility, most of which are positive.Only the volatility coefficients for Beverages and Rubber Products are negative.Agricultural goods, which had showed signs of autocorrelation and thus are correctedfor serial correlation with the Cochrane-Orcutt procedure, have been affected less: Sixhave significantly positive coefficients at the 10 percent level, four of which are so atthe 5 percent level – and none are significantly negative. Thus, although Coes admitspotential data and specification errors, he shows that agricultural and manufacturedgoods face different effects due to exchange-rate uncertainty.

Developed countries are not neglected, however. Maskus (1986) models the volumeof US bilateral exports to Japan, the UK, Germany, and Canada as a function of foreignincome, labor costs, and capacity utilization; home labor costs; a measure of risk thatincludes both inflation and nominal exchange rate uncertainty; and the “sectoral realexchange rate” in a simplified version of (9). Using OLS and quarterly data from theperiod 1974-1984, Maskus finds that 58 of the 64 sectoral flows studied were negativelyaffected; for 26 of these, the impact was significant. Germany’s trade has been mostaffected. The volume of trade has been reduced in machinery, transport, chemicals, andmiscellaneous manufactures; the sector most negatively affected by exchange-ratevolatility is that of agriculture. The author speculates that this might be because of thelevel of concentration or internationalization of the industry, or the length of contracts.Nonetheless, this provides an important benchmark for future disaggregatedstudies[4].

Klein (1990) provides another sectoral study that finds mixed results. Examiningthe value of US bilateral exports to the G-7 as a function of foreign income and the realexchange rate, he arrives at positive as well as negative results. His model applies OLSto a regression of exports on current and lagged income, real exchange rate, andvolatility – as well as five country-specific dummy variables, and interaction variablesbetween the dummies and volatility. Evaluating six bilateral trade flows for nine1-digit SITC categories over the annual period 1978-1986, Klein’s study generated 54regressions – of which three are significantly negative and seven are significantlypositive. Most flows are thus shown to be unaffected by real exchange-rate volatility.Two of the three sectors that are hurt by uncertainty were to France (food andmanufactured goods), and four of the positively affected industry trade flows were toCanada; perhaps there is a country-specific effect at work.

Belanger et al. (1992) look further into the US relationship with Canada, this timeevaluating US imports from its main trading partner. Utilizing a novel nonparametricapproach to measure volatility, the authors examine the import volume of five sectors(food, industrial supplies, capital goods, automotive goods, and consumer goods) as afunction of a substitution effect (relative prices), a trade composition effect, a scalevariable (output), and the volatility proxy. OLS (with lags and seasonal dummies) isapplied to quarterly data over the period 1974-1983. The authors do not find anysignificant effect with the possible exception of capital goods.

Grobar (1993) applies a pooled and fixed-effects panel approach to the sectors ofchemicals, machinery and transport equipment, manufactures, and miscellaneousmanufactures (SITC categories 5-8) for ten LDCs. Using four proxies for uncertainty,Grobar models exports over the period 1963-1985 as a function of uncertainty, the realexchange rate, manufacturing’s proportion of the country’s GDP, and a premium thatis based on the level of misalignment of the official and black market exchange rate.

JES34,3

242

Page 33: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Chemicals and manufactures are negatively affected by volatility across all fourproxies; miscellaneous manufactures have been depressed by three of the four (all butthe one modeled from the trend equation); and machinery has not been significantlyaffected.

Stokman (1995) extends previous studies of European trade to account for sectoraltrade, using OLS. Stokman applies OLS to a simple income/relative price/volatilitymodel with a seasonal dummy over the period 1980:IV-1990:IV, measuring volatility asthe standard deviation of weekly percentage changes in the NEER. The authoranalyzes the export volume of Germany, France, Italy, Belgium, and The Netherlandsto the European Community, for the grouped SITC categories 0 and 1, 2 and 4, 5, 6, and7. Stokman concludes that because exchange-rate volatility depresses trade acrosscountries and sectors, the countries of the EC have benefited by the reduction of riskbrought on by economic integration. He further concludes that disaggregating the dataat the sectoral level proved to be a fruitful exercise.

Many of the sectoral studies use co-integration methods for their analysis. Theseanalyses often model exports as a simple linear function of income, relative prices, anduncertainty. Rapp and Reddy (2000) apply the Johansen procedure to a study ofmonthly US export value to its G-7 partners from 1978-1995, (eight sectors, 1-digitSITC groupings), with risk proxied by the moving standard deviation of the rate ofchange of the real exchange rate. Their estimated equation is as follows:

DXt ¼ c0 þ c1jt21 þX

diDXt2i þX

f iDYt2i þX

giDPt2i þX

kiDVt2i

þ et ð16Þ

where c1jt21 is the lagged error correction term (ECM). This analysis produces mixedresults. Most Canadian trade showed no evidence of co-integration among thevariables; most US trade with other countries did show evidence. Of the 39co-integrating vectors that resulted, 18 have significantly negative volatilitycoefficients, and 14 have significantly positive ones. These effects vary acrosscountries and sectors. French trade appears to be positively influenced by uncertainty;Japanese trade shows negative effects across sectors. Across countries, the food sectorseems to be positively affected in the long run – contradicting the conclusion ofMaskus (1986) in sign – but the machinery, crude, and chemical sectors showednegative effects.

Two papers, applying the Engle-Granger method of co-integration, focusedspecifically on Irish exports and find positive results across sectors. Doyle (2001), usinga GARCH-based proxy for nominal and real exchange-rate volatility, examines Irishexports to the UK using monthly sectoral data at the SITC 2-digit level from 1979-1992.The volatility variable is found to be I(0) for seven sectors and I(1) for the rest; it is alsoshown to carry significantly positive coefficient not only for the aggregate data, butalso for most sectors. This effect is present for both nominal and real exchange ratebased uncertainty measure. Doyle surmises that as a small, open economy, Irishtraders have no choice but to accept exchange-rate risk. Multinational corporations,however, may be able to diversify away from risk, thus reducing the impact ofuncertainty. Bredin et al. (2003) examine Irish sectoral exports to the European Union,over the period 1978:III-1998:IV. A moving standard deviation volatility proxy is used;the authors analyze the pooled 1-digit SITC commodity groupings 0-4, 5-8, and 0-8. The

Exchange ratevolatility

243

Page 34: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

authors note that multinational corporations (MNCs) dominate sectors 5-8, but that thesectors where locally based firms are more prominent show similar effects due touncertainty. Again, these results are positive, perhaps because volatility increases afirm’s expected profits.

The papers described above make use of the Engle-Granger and Johansen methodsof co-integration analysis, but the bounds testing approach is also applied to sectoraldata. One of the first studies to use this approach was Chou (2000), who applies theapproach as well as the Johansen error-correction method to study Chinese exportsfrom 1981-1986. These two approaches produce different results for the four sectors offoodstuffs, fuels, industrial materials, and manufactured goods (SITC categories 0 and1, 2 and 4, 3, and 5-9, respectively). While the error-correction method signifies thatexchange-rate volatility had a negative impact on all sectors except foodstuffs, thebounds testing approach registered a positive effect for industrial goods.

De Vita and Abbott (2004a) also achieve fewer significant results in their boundstesting analysis of the volume of UK exports to other European Union countries.Testing four uncertainty proxies (the sample and moving standard deviations ofweekly percentage changes in the log nominal exchange rate, as well as ARCH usingthe nominal and real exchange rates), the authors evaluate the four sectors ofmanufactures, food, basic materials, and services. The authors compare their volatilityproxies with a “tournament” in which the two standard-deviation proxies “competed”against each other, with the winner chosen via the log-maximizing Akaike InformationCriterion (AIC) and Schwarz Bayesian Criterion (SBC). The two ARCH proxies face offas well; the winners of the two semifinals are then compared against each other. Theauthors find that while the best risk proxy varied by the market of destination, theMoving Average Standard Deviation proxy dominated for sectoral trade. Thevolatility term itself has varying results at these levels of aggregation. At theaggregate level, the volatility coefficient was significantly positive only for exportflows to Germany, Denmark, and Sweden. At the sectoral level, pooled acrossimporting countries, only the service sector registers any significant effect. Theauthors speculate that exporters in different industries have different levels of riskaversion.

Just as was the case for aggregate and bilateral studies, analyses of sectoral tradeare not confined to time-series analysis. Panel data approaches are also fairly common,and often arrive at similar results. Peridy (2003) chooses a fixed-effects model, as wellas SUR and GMM models, to assess the export demand and supply of each G-7country’s exports to their main partners[5]. The author notes that such characteristicsas competition, pricing strategy, and costs are specific to each industry; therefore, eachindustry must have a different reaction to exchange-rate volatility. Peridy capturesthese factors by using a number of explanatory variables: employment, productivity,returns to scale, foreign income, product differentiation, and lagged exports. While theresults are significantly negative for all countries, they vary across sectors andgeographic areas, especially when a GARCH-based proxy is used for exchange-ratevolatility. Peridy thus calls attention to an “aggregation bias,” both sectorally andgeographically. While some fuels, natural products, and textiles are strongly affectedby risk, such manufactured goods as machinery are not. Peridy suggests that productdifferentiation might cushion these goods against swings in prices. Nonetheless, somecountries show positive effects for certain industries. France, for example, registers a

JES34,3

244

Page 35: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

significantly positive volatility effect in such industries as electrical machinery,communication equipment, pharmaceuticals, and medical equipment; this seems toconcur with the results of Rapp and Reddy (2000). Other countries, such as Japan, showsignificantly positive coefficients as well. Peridy also examines the geographicdestination of trade and concludes that developed countries’ exports to LDCs arenegatively affected; but their exports to other DCs are either positively affected or notaffected at all. Thus, aggregate data – both across sectors and across countries – maygive misleading results.

Specific sectorsBesides the studies reviewed above, a few studies have focused specifically on a singlegood or sector. Usman and Savvides (1994) examine the export and import volume ofcocoa and coffee for the CFA franc zone in Africa. The goods are treated asdifferentiated according to their market of destination. Using OLS (Parks method),Usman and Savvides model trade volume as a function of relative prices, the totalcoffee or cocoa import volume, a dummy for membership in the CFA, and volatility,which is proxied as the 12-year standard deviation of the percentage change in the realexchange rate. Using annual data from the period 1973-1984, they show a significantlynegative impact for most countries. In addition, the authors find that for two countries,membership in the CFA had a positive effect on their coffee and cocoa exports, eventhough the rigid peg to the French franc has exposed these countries to volatility.

While studies that evaluate the performance of manufactured goods often can becategorized with bilateral or aggregate analyses, it is also possible to treat them asstudies of a specific sector. Holly (1995) incorporates both supply and demand effects,rather than the more simple reduced form that has dominated empirical studies onexchange-rate volatility. Making use of the Johansen method of co-integration analysis,and using a GARCH approximation of volatility, his study find that volatility has had anegative effect on the supply, but not the demand, of UK manufacturing exports overthe period from 1980-1996.

Many of these papers used different empirical methods. Lee (1999) focuses on thevalue of US imports of durable goods from its G-7 partners, Belgium, Sweden, andSwitzerland over the period 1973-1992. Employing a vector autoregression thatincludes durable-goods prices, the real exchange rate, US income, and a GARCH-basedmeasure of volatility, Lee finds that uncertainty has had no discernible impact onimports.

Agriculture is another sector that is worthy of analysis. Cho et al. (2002) choose afixed-effects gravity model to study the total agricultural trade (exports plus imports)of the G-7 countries plus Belgium, The Netherlands, and Switzerland. Using not only astandard-deviation based volatility proxy, but also the Peree-Steinherr method, theauthors estimate the specification used by Dell’Ariccia (1999) and find that agriculturehas been hurt more by exchange-rate volatility than other sectors had been.

Giorgioni and Thompson (2002) examine an agricultural good as well, noting thatwheat requires high storage costs. They note however, that there are other types ofvolatility besides that of the exchange rate. Using pooled, fixed, and random-effectspanel data models, the authors evaluate the value of US wheat exports to Egypt, Israel,Italy, Japan, Korea, Morocco, Pakistan, the Philippines, and Venezuela. Income,substitution, and volatility effects are captured for each bilateral relationship with the

Exchange ratevolatility

245

Page 36: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

following deterministic variables: the total wheat imports of the importing country; thereal bilateral exchange rate; the REER of each of the USA’s main competitors in thewheat market; exchange-rate volatility, proxied by the 12-month moving standarddeviation of the percentage changes in the real exchange rate; and the volatility of theimporting country’s imports, measured by a three-year moving standard deviation.The authors find that it is the volatility of total imports, not of the real exchange rate,that depresses exports. Once again, Table IV collects all relevant information for eachpaper in this section in one place.

VII. New directions and conclusionsAn argument put forward by the opponents of the floating exchange rates is that suchrates introduce uncertainty into the foreign exchange market, which could deter tradeflows. However, a theoretical argument is put forward by some to show thatuncertainty could also boost trade flows if traders increase their trade volume to offsetany decrease in future revenue due to exchange rate volatility. The empirical literaturereviewed in this paper supports both views. In this study, we have classified theempirical studies into three categories. The first includes studies that used aggregatetrade data between one country and the rest of the world. The second category includesstudies that used disaggregate data at the bilateral level, i.e. trade flows between twocountries. Finally, the third category includes those studies that disaggregated thetrade data further by commodities or by sectors between two countries. For each groupa table is provided which summarizes each paper by its main features. For futureresearch the following recommendations are in order.

First, while the general trend in evaluating the effects of exchange-rate volatility hasbeen toward disaggregated and even sectoral data, no clear consensus has beenreached regarding a single measure of uncertainty. Coric and Pugh (2006) areperforming a meta-regression analysis, currently as a working paper, to determine thegeneral characteristics of this large body of literature. While statistical analyses havebeen performed to determine the stochastic properties of various volatility measures,their conclusion – such as that the higher-order properties of the volatility variable(skewness and kurtosis), have not been integrated into the body of literature. Whilesome early studies tested multiple proxies and then selected the one that best fits acertain criterion, this practice seems to be less common in more recent papers. For now,it seems that there is no optimal measure of uncertainty, and that authors are morecomfortable choosing one or two and concentrating on the results they provide. Futureresearch that concentrates on introducing new measures of volatility or refining theexisting measures, are recommended.

Second, certain modifications of the determinants of trade flows, such asincorporating third-country effects, also have not been incorporated in the majority ofstudies. Thus, simplified models are most common, often using income, relative price,and exchange rate volatility as determinants. Rather than focusing on specification,authors have recently used these specifications either to investigate countries that hadnot been studied, or to disaggregate the data so that specific effects may be uncovered.Future studies could advance our knowledge if they include third-country effects.

Third, because of foreign exchange controls in many less-developed countries, thereis a black market for foreign currencies in these countries. Not much attention is paid tothe effects of black-market exchange rate volatility on trade in developing countries,

JES34,3

246

Page 37: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

ime

span

Sec

tors

/res

ult

s

Bel

ang

eret

al.

(199

2)O

LS

Lag

sIm

por

tv

olu

me

For

ecas

ter

rors

/non

-par

amet

ric

met

hod

Su

bst

itu

tion

,T

rad

eco

mp

osit

ion

,S

cale

var

iab

le

US

Afr

omC

anad

aQ

uar

terl

y:

1974

-198

7F

ood

,In

du

stri

alsu

pp

lies

,C

apit

alg

ood

s,A

uto

mot

ive

goo

ds,

and

Con

sum

erg

ood

sN

osi

gn

ifica

nt

effe

ctex

cep

tp

ossi

bly

cap

ital

goo

ds

Bre

din

etal.

(200

3)T

ime

seri

esG

ran

ger

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

on

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Eig

ht-

qu

arte

rm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

log

ofg

row

thra

teof

RE

ER

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sIr

elan

d-E

UQ

uar

terl

y:

1978

-199

8S

ITC

0-4

poo

led

,5-

8p

oole

d,

0-8

poo

led

Sig

nifi

can

tly

pos

itiv

efo

ral

lin

lon

gru

nC

hoet

al.

(200

2)P

anel

:F

ixed

effe

cts

Tot

altr

ade

(Xþ

M)

2:T

en-y

ear

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

;P

eree

-Ste

inh

err

met

hod

G7

plu

sB

elg

ium

,T

he

Net

her

lan

ds,

Sw

itze

rlan

d

Yea

rly

:19

74-1

995

Ag

ricu

ltu

ral

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

e,m

ore

sig

nifi

can

tth

anot

her

sect

ors

Ch

ou(2

000)

Tim

ese

ries

:G

ran

ger

met

hod

ofco

-in

teg

rati

onA

RD

Lb

oun

ds

test

ing

app

roac

h

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

GA

RC

Hof

RE

ER

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sC

hin

aQ

uar

terl

y:

1981

-199

6F

our

sect

ors:

Foo

dst

uff

s,In

du

stri

alm

ater

ials

,M

iner

alfu

els,

Man

ufa

ctu

red

goo

ds:

Usi

ng

EC

M:

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

ral

lb

ut

food

Usi

ng

AR

DL

:P

osit

ive

for

ind

ust

rial

mat

eria

lsC

oes

(198

1)O

LS

wit

hla

gs

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Ind

exIn

com

e,R

elat

ive

pri

ces

Bra

zil

Mon

thly

:19

57-1

974

13m

anu

fact

uri

ng

,nin

ep

rim

ary

sect

ors

All

man

ufa

ctu

rin

gsi

gn

ifica

ntl

yp

osit

ive

Six

agri

cult

ura

lg

ood

ssi

gn

ifica

ntl

yp

osit

ive

(continued

)

Table IV.Sectoral studies of the

effects of exchange-ratevolatility

Exchange ratevolatility

247

Page 38: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

ime

span

Sec

tors

/res

ult

s

De

Vit

aan

dA

bb

ott

(200

4)

Tim

ese

ries

:A

RD

Lb

oun

ds

Tes

tin

gap

pro

ach

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

4:S

amp

lest

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

wee

kly

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

esin

log

NE

R;

Mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofw

eek

lyp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

inlo

gN

ER

(AIC

-max

imiz

ing

of2,

4,6,

8);A

RC

Hon

NE

R;

AR

CH

onR

ER

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sU

Kto

the

rest

ofth

eE

U14

Mon

thly

:19

93-2

001

Man

ufa

ctu

rers

,F

ood

,B

asic

mat

eria

ls,

Ser

vic

esO

nly

serv

ices

sig

nifi

can

tly

effe

cted

Pos

itiv

eto

Ger

man

y,

Den

mar

k,

Sw

eden

;in

sig

nifi

can

t,fo

rot

her

s

Doy

le(2

001)

Tim

ese

ries

Gra

ng

erm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

GA

RC

HIn

com

e,R

elat

ive

pri

ces

Irel

and

-UK

Mon

thly

:19

79-1

992

15S

ITC

2-d

igit

sect

ors

Sig

nifi

can

tly

pos

itiv

efo

rm

ost

sect

ors

and

tota

lG

iorg

ion

ian

dT

hom

pso

n(2

002)

Pan

el:

Poo

led

,F

ixed

effe

cts,

Ran

dom

effe

cts

Ex

por

tv

alu

e12

-mon

thm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

esin

RE

R

Tot

alim

por

ts,

RE

R,

Ter

ms

oftr

ade,

RE

ER

ofU

SA

’sco

mp

etit

ors,

Imp

ort

vol

atil

ity

US

Ato

Eg

yp

t,Is

rael

,It

aly

,Ja

pan

,K

orea

,M

oroc

co,

Pak

ista

n,

Ph

ilip

pin

es,

Ven

ezu

ela

1980

-199

6W

hea

tIm

por

tv

olat

ilit

yim

por

tan

t,E

xch

ang

era

tev

olat

ilit

yn

otsi

gn

ifica

nt

Gro

bar

(199

3)P

anel

:P

oole

d,

Fix

edef

fect

s

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

4:S

tan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofq

uar

terl

yp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ge

inR

ER

,S

tan

dar

der

ror

ofR

ER

fitt

edto

atr

end

,S

tan

dar

der

ror

ofR

ER

from

AR

(1),

AR

CH

RE

R,

risk

pre

miu

m,

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g’s

shar

eof

GD

P

10L

DC

s19

63-1

985

SIT

Cca

teg

orie

s5-

8S

ome

sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

e

Kle

in(1

990)

OL

S:

Poo

led

wit

hla

gs

US

exp

ort

val

ue

Tra

de-

wei

gh

ted

aver

age,

Rea

lb

ilat

eral

Inco

me,

RE

X,

tren

dU

Sex

por

tsto

G-7

Yea

rly

:19

78-1

986

1-d

igit

SIT

Cca

teg

orie

sse

ven

pos

itiv

ean

dth

ree

neg

ativ

eou

tof

54L

ee(1

999)

Tim

ese

ries

:V

AR

Imp

ort

val

ue

GA

RC

HR

elat

ive

pri

ces,

RE

X,

Inco

me

US

from

G-7

and

Th

eN

eth

erla

nd

s,B

elg

ium

,S

wed

en,

Sw

itze

rlan

d

Qu

arte

rly

:19

73-1

992

Man

ufa

ctu

rers

No

sig

nifi

can

tre

lati

onsh

ip(continued

)

Table IV.

JES34,3

248

Page 39: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Au

thor

(yea

r)M

eth

odD

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

Mea

sure

ofv

olat

ilit

yO

ther

ind

epen

den

tv

aria

ble

sC

oun

trie

sT

ime

span

Sec

tors

/res

ult

s

Mas

ku

s(1

986)

OL

SE

xp

ort

vol

um

eP

rice

risk

(in

flat

ion

)p

lus

NE

Rri

skIn

com

e,C

apac

ity

uti

liza

tion

,Lab

orco

sts,

RE

R

US

Aw

ith

Jap

an,

UK

,G

erm

any

,C

anad

aQ

uar

terl

y:

1974

:2-1

984:

41-

dig

itS

ITC

cate

gor

ies

Tra

de

red

uce

din

mac

hin

ery

,tr

ansp

ort,

chem

ical

s,m

isc.

man

ufa

ctu

rers

.P

erid

y(2

003)

Pan

el:

SU

R,G

MM

,Fix

edef

fect

s

Ex

por

td

eman

dan

dsu

pp

ly

2:G

AR

CH

,12

-per

iod

mov

ing

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofN

ER

Em

plo

ym

ent,

Pro

du

ctiv

ity

,R

TS

,F

orei

gn

GD

P,

Dif

fere

nti

atio

n,

Lag

ged

exp

orts

G7-

each

mem

ber

’sm

ain

par

tner

s:B

elg

ium

,L

ux

emb

ourg

,S

wit

zerl

and

,D

enm

ark

,S

pai

n,

Th

eN

eth

erla

nd

s,M

exic

o,C

hin

a,H

ong

Kon

g,

Kor

ea,

Mal

aysi

a,S

ing

apor

e,T

hai

lan

d,

Tai

wan

,A

ust

rali

a,B

razi

l

1975

-200

021

ind

ust

ries

,T

hre

eg

rou

ps

58/6

4N

egat

ive,

26S

ign

ifica

nt

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

ral

lco

un

trie

s,v

arie

sac

ross

sect

ors

and

geo

gra

ph

icar

eas

Rap

pan

dR

edd

y(2

000)

Tim

ese

ries

Joh

anse

nm

eth

odof

co-i

nte

gra

tion

Ex

por

ts12

-mon

thm

ovin

gst

and

ard

dev

iati

onof

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

esin

RE

R

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sU

SA

toG

-7M

onth

ly:

1975

-199

5E

igh

tse

ctor

s:1-

dig

itS

ITC

cate

gor

ies

18/3

9si

gn

ifica

ntl

yn

egat

ive

at10

per

cen

t14

sig

nifi

can

tly

pos

itiv

eS

tok

man

(199

5)O

LS

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Sta

nd

ard

dev

iati

onof

wee

kly

per

cen

tag

ech

ang

esin

NE

ER

Inco

me,

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

sG

erm

any

,F

ran

ce,

Ital

y,

Bel

giu

m,

Th

eN

eth

erla

nd

sto

EC

Qu

arte

rly

:19

80-1

990

SIT

Cca

teg

orie

s0

and

1,2

and

4,5,

6,7

Neg

ativ

eef

fect

Usm

anan

dS

avv

ides

(199

4)

OL

S:

Par

ks

met

hod

Ex

por

tv

olu

me

Imp

ort

vol

um

e

12-y

ear

stan

dar

dd

evia

tion

ofp

erce

nta

ge

chan

ges

inR

ER

Rel

ativ

ep

rice

s,T

otal

coff

ee/c

ocoa

imp

ort

vol

um

e,D

um

my

for

CF

Am

emb

ersh

ip

CF

Afr

anc

zon

eco

un

trie

sto

maj

orim

por

tin

gco

un

trie

s

Yea

rly

:19

73-1

984

Coc

oa,

Cof

fee

Sig

nifi

can

tly

neg

ativ

efo

rm

ost

cou

ntr

ies

Table IV.

Exchange ratevolatility

249

Page 40: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

nor on the impact of the black-market premium as a measure of exchange ratemisalignment.

Finally, it is shown that while all variables in a given trade flow model arenon-stationary, most measures of exchange rate volatility are stationary. The onlyco-integration and error-correction method that allows some of the variables to benon-stationary and some to be stationary is the bounds testing approach by Pesaranet al. (2001). It is highly recommended that future studies rely on this method. It shouldbe indicated that the other advantage of the bounds testing approach is that theshort-run and the long-run effects of exchange rate volatility on trade flows could beassessed simultaneously, using one model specification[6].

Notes

1. If a time-series variable is stationary at its level, it is said to be an I(0) variable. However, if itachieves stationarity after being differenced once, then it is said to integrated of order one,denoted by I (1).

2. Ecuador, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Malawi, Mauritius, Mexico, Morocco, Philippines, SriLanka, Taiwan, Thailand, and Tunisia.

3. Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Japan, TheNetherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, Canada, South Africa, the UK, and the USA.

4. One recommendation for future study is to repeat Maskus’ analysis for disaggregated datausing cointegration and error-correction modeling, since he did not engage in unit-roottesting or co-integration analysis.

5. Belgium, Luxembourg, Switzerland, Denmark, Spain, The Netherlands, Mexico, China, HongKong, Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, Thailand, Taiwan, Australia, and Brazil.

6. For more on the bounds testing approach see Bahmani-Oskooee and Goswami (2004) orBahmani-Oskooee and Ardalani (2006).

References

Abrams, R.K. (1980), “International trade flows under flexible exchange rates”, Economic Review,Vol. 65 No. 3, pp. 3-10.

Akhtar, M.A. and Hilton, R.S. (1984), “Effects of uncertainty on German and US trade”, FederalReserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review, pp. 7-16.

Aristotelous, K. (2001), “Exchange-rate volatility, exchange-rate regime, and trade volume:evidence from the UK-US export function (1889-1999)”, Economics Letters, Vol. 72 No. 1,pp. 87-94.

Aristotelous, K. (2002), “The impact of the post-1972 floating exchange rate regime on USexports”, Applied Economics, Vol. 34 No. 13, pp. 1627-32.

Arize, A.C. (1995), “Trade flows and real exchange-rate volatility: an application of cointegrationand error-correction modeling”, North American Journal of Economics & Finance, Vol. 6No. 1, pp. 37-51.

Arize, A.C. (1996), “A reexamination of the demand for UK exports: evidence from an errorcorrection model”, International Trade Journal, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 501-25.

Arize, A.C. (1997), “Foreign trade and exchange-rate risk in the G-7 countries: cointegration anderror-correction models”, Review of Financial Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1, pp. 95-112.

JES34,3

250

Page 41: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Arize, A.C. (1998), “The long-run relationship between import flows and real exchange-ratevolatility: the experience of eight European economies”, Interational Review of Economicsand Finance, Vol. 7 No. 4, pp. 417-35.

Arize, A.C. and Ghosh, D.K. (1994), “Exchange rate uncertainty and recent US export demandinstability”, International Trade Journal, Vol. 8 No. 3, p. 347.

Arize, A.C. and Malindretos, J. (1998), “The long-run and short-run effects of exchange-ratevolatility on exports: the case of Australia and New Zealand”, Journal of Economics andFinance, Vol. 22 Nos 2-3, pp. 43-56.

Arize, A.C. and Shwiff, S.S. (1998), “Does exchange-rate volatility affect import flows in G-7countries? Evidence from cointegration models”, Applied Economics, Vol. 30, pp. 1269-76.

Arize, A.C., Osang, T. and Slottje, D.J. (2000), “Exchange-rate volatility and foreign trade:evidence from thirteen LDCs”, Journal of Business & Economics Statistics, Vol. 18,pp. 10-17.

Arize, A.C., Malindretos, J. and Kasibhatla, K.M. (2003), “Does exchange-rate volatility depressexport flows: the case of LDCs”, International Advances in Economic Research, Vol. 9 No. 1,pp. 7-19.

Arize, A.C., Osang, T. and Slottje, D.J. (2005), “Exchange-rate volatility in Latin America and itsimpact on foreign trade”, working paper.

Asseery, A. and Peel, D.A. (1991), “The effects of exchange rate volatility on exports: some newestimates”, Economics Letters, Vol. 37, pp. 173-7.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M. (1996), “Exchange rate uncertainty and trade flows of LDCs: evidence fromJohansen’s cointegration analysis”, Journal of Economic Development, Vol. 21 No. 1,pp. 23-35.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M. (2002), “Does black-market exchange rate volatility deter the trade flows?”,Applied Economics, Vol. 34, pp. 2249-555.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Ardalani, Z. (2006), “Exchange rate sensitivity of US trade flows:evidence from industry data”, Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 72, pp. 542-59.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Goswami, G. (2004), “Exchange rate sensitivity of Japan’s bilateraltrade flows”, Japan and the World Economy, Vol. 16, pp. 1-15.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Ltaifa, N. (1992), “Effects of exchange rate risk on exports:cross-country analysis”, World Development, Vol. 20 No. 8, pp. 1173-81.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Payesteh, S. (1993), “Does exchange-rate volatility deter trade volumeof LDCs?”, Journal of Economic Development, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 189-205.

Bailey, M.J., Tavlas, G.S. and Ulan, M. (1987), “The impact of exchange-rate volatility on exportgrowth: some theoretical considerations and empirical results”, Journal of Policy Modeling,Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 225-43.

Baron, D.P. (1976), “Fluctuating exchange rates and the pricing of exports”, Economic Inquiry,Vol. 14, pp. 425-38.

Belanger, D., Gutierrez, S. and Raynauld, J. (1992), “Exchange rate variability and trade flows:preliminary sectoral estimates for the US-Canada case”, Ecole des Hautes EtudesCommerciales: Cahiers de Recherche, Vol. 89 No. 1.

Bini-Smaghi, L. (1991), “Exchange rate variability and trade: why is it so difficult to find anyempirical relationship?”, Applied Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 927-36.

Bleaney, M. (1992), “Comparisons of real exchange rate volatility across exchange rate systems”,Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 54 No. 4, pp. 557-65.

Exchange ratevolatility

251

Page 42: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Brada, J.C. and Mendez, J. (1988), “Exchange rate risk, exchange rate regime and the volume ofinternational trade”, Kyklos, Vol. 41 No. 2, pp. 263-80.

Bredin, D., Stilianos, F. and Murphy, E. (2003), “An empirical analysis of short-run and long-runIrish export functions: does exchange-rate volatility matter?”, International Review ofApplied Economics, Vol. 17 No. 2, pp. 193-208.

Broll, U. and Eckwert, B. (1999), “Exchange rate volatility and international trade”, SouthernEconomic Journal, Vol. 66 No. 1, pp. 178-85.

Caporale, T. and Doroodian, K. (1994), “Exchange rate variability and the flow of internationaltrade”, Economics Letters, Vol. 46 No. 1, pp. 49-54.

Chan, P.K.L. and Wong, J.H.Y. (1985), “The effect of exchange rate variability on Hong Kong’sexports”, Hong Kong Economic Papers, Vol. 1985 No. 16, pp. 27-39.

Cho, G., Sheldon, I.M. and McCorriston, S. (2002), “Exchange rate uncertainty and agriculturaltrade”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 84 No. 4, pp. 931-42.

Chou, W.L. (2000), “Exchange rate variability and China’s exports”, Journal of ComparativeEconomics, Vol. 28 No. 1, pp. 61-79.

Chowdhury, A.R. (1993), “Does exchange rate volatility depress trade flows? Evidence fromerror-correction models”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 75, pp. 700-6.

Clark, P.B. (1973), “Uncertainty, exchange risk, and the level of international trade”, WesternEconomic Journal, Vol. 6, pp. 302-13.

Coes, D. (1981), “The crawling peg and exchange rate uncertainty”, in Williamson, J. (Ed.),Exchange Rate Rules: The Theory, Performance, and Prospect of the Crawling Peg,St Martins Press, New York, NY.

Corbo, V. and Caballero, R.J. (1989), “How does uncertainty about the real exchange rate affectexports?” The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series: 221.

Coric, B. and Pugh, G. (2006), “The effects of exchange rate variability on international trade: ameta regression analysis”, Working Papers: Centre for Research on Emerging Economies,Staffordshire University, Stoke on Trent.

Cushman, D.O. (1983), “The effects of real exchange rate risk on international trade”, Journal ofInternational Economics, Vol. 15 Nos 1-2, pp. 45-63.

Cushman, D.O. (1986), “Has exchange risk depressed international trade? The impact ofthird-country exchange risk”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 5 No. 3, pp. 361-79.

Cushman, D.O. (1988), “US bilateral trade flows and exchange risk during the floating period”,Journal of International Economics, Vol. 24 Nos 3/4, pp. 317-30.

De Grauwe, P. (1987), “Exchange rate variability and the slowdown in growth of internationaltrade”, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, Vol. 35 No. 1, pp. 63-84.

De Grauwe, P. and De Bellefroid, B. (1987), “Long run exchange rate variability and internationaltrade”, in Arndt, S.W. and Richardson, J.D. (Eds), Real Financial Linkages Among OpenEconomics, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Dell’Ariccia, G. (1999), “Exchange rate fluctuations and trade flows: evidence from the EuropeanUnion”, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 46 No. 3, p. 5.

Dellas, H. and Zilberfarb, B.-Z. (1993), “Real exchange rate volatility and international trade: areexamination of the theory”, Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 59 No. 4, pp. 641-7.

De Vita, G. and Abbott, A. (2004a), “The impact of exchange rate volatility on UK exports to EUcountries”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 51 No. 1, pp. 62-81.

De Vita, G. and Abbott, A. (2004b), “Real exchange rate volatility and US exports: an ARDLbounds testing approach”, Economic Issues, Vol. 9, Pt 1, pp. 69-78.

JES34,3

252

Page 43: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Doganlar, M. (2002), “Estimating the impact of exchange rate volatility on exports: evidence fromAsian countries”, Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 9, pp. 859-63.

Doroodian, K. (1999), “Does exchange rate volatility deter international trade in developingcountries?”, Journal of Asian Economics, Vol. 10, pp. 465-74.

Doyle, E. (2001), “Exchange rate volatility and Irish-UK trade, 1979-1992”, Applied Economics,Vol. 33, pp. 249-65.

Engle, R.F. and Granger, C.W.J. (1987), “Co-integration and error-correction: representation,estimation and testing”, Econometrica, Vol. 55, pp. 1251-76.

Ethier, W. (1973), “International trade and the forward exchange market”, American EconomicReview, Vol. 63 No. 3, pp. 494-503.

Franke, G. (1991), “Exchange rate volatility and international trading strategy”, Journal ofInternational Money and Finance, Vol. 10, pp. 292-307.

Gagnon, J. (1993), “Exchange rate variability and the level of international trade”, Journal ofInternational Economics, Vol. 34, pp. 269-340.

Giorgioni, G. and Thompson, J.L. (2002), “Which volatility? The case of the exports of wheat”,Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 9 No. 4, pp. 681-4.

Gotur, P. (1985), “Effects of exchange rate volatility on trade: some further evidence”,International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, Vol. 32 No. 3, pp. 475-512.

Grobar, L.M. (1993), “The effect of real exchange rate uncertainty on LDC manufacturedexports”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 41 No. 2, pp. 367-76.

Holly, S. (1995), “Exchange rate uncertainty and export performance: supply and demandeffects”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 42 No. 4, pp. 381-91.

Hooper, P. and Kohlhagen, S.W. (1978), “The effects of exchange rate uncertainty on the pricesand volume of international trade”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 8, pp. 483-511.

Kenen, P.B. and Rodrik, D. (1986), “Measuring and analyzing the effects of short-term volatilityin real exchange rates”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 68, pp. 311-5.

Klein, M.W. (1990), “Sectoral effects of exchange rate volatility on United States exports”, Journalof International Money and Finance, Vol. 9, pp. 299-308.

Koray, F. and Lastrapes, W.D. (1989), “Real exchange rate volatility and US bilateral trade:a VAR approach”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 71, pp. 708-12.

Kroner, K.F. and Lastrapes, W.D. (1993), “The impact of exchange rate volatility on internationaltrade: reduced form estimates using the GARCH-in-mean model”, Journal of InternationalMoney and Finance, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 298-318.

Kumar, R. and Dhawan, R. (1991), “Exchange rate volatility and Pakistan’s exports to thedeveloped world, 1974-85”, World Development, Vol. 19, pp. 1225-40.

Lastrapes, W.D. and Koray, F. (1990), “Exchange rate volatility and US multilateral trade flows”,Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 341-62.

Lee, J. (1999), “The effect of exchange rate volatility on trade in durables”, Review of InternationalEconomics, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 189-201.

McKenzie, M. and Brooks, R.D. (1997), “The impact of exchange rate volatility on German-UStrade flows”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions &Money, Vol. 7 No. 1,pp. 73-87.

McKenzie, M.D. (1999), “The impact of exchange rate volatility on international trade flows”,Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 13 No. 1, pp. 71-104.

Maskus, K.E. (1986), “Exchange rate risk and US trade: a sectoral analysis”, Economic Review,Vol. 71 No. 3, pp. 16-28.

Exchange ratevolatility

253

Page 44: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Medhora, R. (1990), “The effect of exchange rate variability on trade: the case of the West Africanmonetary union’s imports”, World Development, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 313-24.

Pattichis, C. (2003), “Conditional exchange. rate volatility, unit roots, and international trade”,International Trade Journal, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 1-17.

Peree, E. and Steinherr, A. (1989), “Exchange rate uncertainty and foreign trade”, EuropeanEconomic Review, Vol. 33, pp. 1241-64.

Peridy, N. (2003), “Exchange rate volatility, sectoral trade, and the aggregation bias”, Review ofWorld Economics, Vol. 139 No. 3, pp. 389-418.

Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y. and Smith, R.J. (2001), “Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of levelrelationships”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 16, p. 326.

Poon, W.C., Choong, C.-K. and Habibullah, M.S. (2005), “Exchange rate volatility and exports forselected East Asian countries: evidence from error correction model”, ASEAN EconomicBulletin, Vol. 22 No. 2, pp. 144-59.

Pozo, S. (1992), “Conditional exchange-rate volatility and the volume of international trade:evidence from the early 1900s”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 74, pp. 325-9.

Pritchett, L. (1991), “Measuring real exchange rate instability in developing countries: empiricalevidence and implications”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series: 791.

Qian, Y. and Varangis, P. (1994), “Does exchange rate volatility hinder export growth?Additional evidence”, Journal Empirical Economics, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 371-96.

Rana, P.B. (1981), “Exchange rate risk under generalized floating: eight Asian countries”, Journalof International Economics, Vol. 11 No. 4, pp. 459-66.

Rapp, T.A. and Reddy, N.N. (2000), “The effect of real exchange rate volatility on bilateral sectorexports”, The Journal of Economics, Vol. 26, pp. 87-103.

Sauer, C. and Bohara, A.K. (2001), “Exchange rate volatility and exports: regional differencesbetween developing and industrialized countries”, Review of International Economics,Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 133-52.

Seabra, F. (1995), “Short-run exchange rate uncertainty in Latin America”, Applied Economics,Vol. 27 No. 5, pp. 441-50.

Sercu, P. (1992), “Exchange risk, exposure, and the option to trade”, Journal of InternationalMoney and Finance, Vol. 11, pp. 579-93.

Sercu, P. and Vanhulle, C. (1992), “Exchange rate volatility, international trade, and the value ofexporting firms”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 16, pp. 155-82.

Sukar, A.-H. and Hassan, S. (2001), “US exports and time varying volatility of real exchangerate”, Global Finance Journal, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 109-19.

Tenreyro, S. (2004), “On the trade impact of real exchange rate volatility”, Federal Reserve Bankof Boston, Working Papers: 03-2.

Thursby, J.G. and Thursby, M. (1985), “The uncertainty effects of floating exchange rates:empirical evidence on international trade flows”, in Arndt, S.W., Sweeney, R.J. and Willett,T.D. (Eds), Exchange Rates, Trade and the US Economy, Ballinger, Cambridge, MA.

Thursby, J.G. and Thursby, M.C. (1987), “Bilateral trade flows, the Linder hypothesis, andexchange risk”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 69, pp. 488-95.

Usman, A.A. and Savvides, A. (1994), “A differentiated good model of coffee and cocoa exportswith reference to the CFA franc zone”, Applied Economics, Vol. 26 No. 6, pp. 583-90.

Vergil, H. (2002), “Exchange rate volatility in Turkey and its effect on trade flows”, Journal ofEconomic and Social Research, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 67-80.

JES34,3

254

Page 45: Exchange rate volatility and trade flows: a review article

Viaene, J.-M. and de Vries, C.G. (1992), “International trade and exchange rate volatility”,European Economic Review, Vol. 36, pp. 1311-22.

West, K.D. and Cho, D. (1994), “The predictive ability of several models of exchange ratevolatility, NBER Technical Working Papers 0152.

Willett, T.D. (1986), “Exchange-rate variability, international trade and resource allocation:a perspective on recent research”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 5,pp. S101-12.

Further reading

Cushman, D.O. (1992), “The effects of real exchange rate risk on international trade”, Journal ofInternational Economics, Vol. 15, pp. 45-63.

Goldstein, M. and Khan, M.S. (1985), “Income and price effects in foreign trade”, in Kenen, P.B.and Jones, R.W. (Eds), Handbook of International Economics,Vol. II, North Holland,Amsterdam.

Corresponding authorMohsen Bahmani-Oskooee can be contacted at: [email protected]

Exchange ratevolatility

255

To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: [email protected] visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints