evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 a. groth, m. ghil, s. hallegatte and p....

22
Submitted to Econometrica EVIDENCE FOR GENUINE PERIODICITY AND DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES Andreas Groth a,b , Michael Ghil a,b,c,d , St´ ephane Hallegatte e,f and Patrice Dumas b,e AbstractWe apply the advanced time-and-frequency-domain method of singular spectrum analysis to study cyclical behavior in U.S. macroeconomic data for a 52- year interval (1954–2005). This method bridges the gap between the multivariate but merely qualitative definition of the business cycle used by the U.S. National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) and the quantitative but univariate analyses in the econometric literature. The multivariate data set represents a total of nine aggregate indicators, including but not restricted to gross domestic product (GDP). We address the problem of spurious cycles generated by the use of detrending filters with fixed, prescribed weights and present a Monte Carlo test to extract significant oscillations in the presence of colored noise. The self-consistent analysis of multiple variables and of their comovements greatly improves the robustness of our business cycle analysis. Finally, we demonstrate that the behavior of the U.S. economy changes significantly between episodes of growth and recession; these variations cannot be generated by random shocks alone, in the absence of endogenous variability. Keywords: Advanced spectral methods, Comovements, Frequency domain, Monte Carlo testing, Time domain. 1. INTRODUCTION Business cycles, their causes and characteristics have been extensively studied since the beginnings of modern economic theory. Research to characterize their regularities and stylized facts has, therewith, a long history (Burns and Mitchell, 1946; Kydland and Prescott, 1998). Besides a long-term upward drift, macroeco- nomic time series exhibit short-term fluctuations. A number of approaches have been proposed to separate the fluctuations from the trend (Canova, 1998; Baxter and King, 1999); the Hodrick-Prescott filter (HP filter) is the most commonly used tool to do so (Hodrick and Prescott, 1997). Since there is no fundamental theory — and hence no generally accepted definition — of the trend, the re- sulting residuals have to be analyzed very critically, in order to avoid spurious results due merely to the detrending procedure (Nelson and Kang, 1981; Harvey and Jaeger, 1993; Cogley and Nason, 1995). [email protected] (A. Groth), [email protected] (M. Ghil), [email protected] (S. Hallegatte), [email protected] (P. Dumas) a Laboratoire de M´ et´ eorologie Dynamique (CNRS and IPSL), Ecole Normale Sup´ erieure, Paris, France b Environmental Research & Teaching Institute, Ecole Normale Sup´ erieure, Paris, France c Geosciences Department, Ecole Normale Sup´ erieure, Paris, France d Department of Atmospheric & Oceanic Sciences and Institute of Geophysics & Planetary Physics, University of California, Los Angeles, USA e Centre International de Recherche sur l’Environnement et le D´ eveloppement, Nogent-sur- Marne, France f Ecole Nationale de la M´ et´ eorologie, M´ et´ eo France, Toulouse, France 1

Upload: others

Post on 05-Apr-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

Submitted to Econometrica

EVIDENCE FOR GENUINE PERIODICITY AND DETERMINISTICCAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES

Andreas Grotha,b , Michael Ghila,b,c,d , Stephane Hallegattee,f and

Patrice Dumasb,e

AbstractWe apply the advanced time-and-frequency-domain method of singularspectrum analysis to study cyclical behavior in U.S. macroeconomic data for a 52-year interval (1954–2005). This method bridges the gap between the multivariate butmerely qualitative definition of the business cycle used by the U.S. National Bureauof Economic Research (NBER) and the quantitative but univariate analyses in theeconometric literature. The multivariate data set represents a total of nine aggregateindicators, including but not restricted to gross domestic product (GDP). We addressthe problem of spurious cycles generated by the use of detrending filters with fixed,prescribed weights and present a Monte Carlo test to extract significant oscillationsin the presence of colored noise. The self-consistent analysis of multiple variables andof their comovements greatly improves the robustness of our business cycle analysis.Finally, we demonstrate that the behavior of the U.S. economy changes significantlybetween episodes of growth and recession; these variations cannot be generated byrandom shocks alone, in the absence of endogenous variability.

Keywords: Advanced spectral methods, Comovements, Frequency domain, MonteCarlo testing, Time domain.

1. INTRODUCTION

Business cycles, their causes and characteristics have been extensively studiedsince the beginnings of modern economic theory. Research to characterize theirregularities and stylized facts has, therewith, a long history (Burns and Mitchell,1946; Kydland and Prescott, 1998). Besides a long-term upward drift, macroeco-nomic time series exhibit short-term fluctuations. A number of approaches havebeen proposed to separate the fluctuations from the trend (Canova, 1998; Baxterand King, 1999); the Hodrick-Prescott filter (HP filter) is the most commonlyused tool to do so (Hodrick and Prescott, 1997). Since there is no fundamentaltheory — and hence no generally accepted definition — of the trend, the re-sulting residuals have to be analyzed very critically, in order to avoid spuriousresults due merely to the detrending procedure (Nelson and Kang, 1981; Harveyand Jaeger, 1993; Cogley and Nason, 1995).

[email protected] (A. Groth), [email protected] (M. Ghil), [email protected](S. Hallegatte), [email protected] (P. Dumas)

aLaboratoire de Meteorologie Dynamique (CNRS and IPSL), Ecole Normale Superieure,Paris, France

bEnvironmental Research & Teaching Institute, Ecole Normale Superieure, Paris, FrancecGeosciences Department, Ecole Normale Superieure, Paris, FrancedDepartment of Atmospheric & Oceanic Sciences and Institute of Geophysics & Planetary

Physics, University of California, Los Angeles, USAeCentre International de Recherche sur l’Environnement et le Developpement, Nogent-sur-

Marne, FrancefEcole Nationale de la Meteorologie, Meteo France, Toulouse, France

1

Page 2: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from thetrend in several distinct macroeconomic variables (Burns and Mitchell, 1946;Lucas, 1977). It is imperative, therefore, to analyze business cycle propertiesas a multivariate process, as suggested even by their definition due to the U.S.National Bureau of Economic Reserach (NBER), namely that “a recession is asignificant decline in economic activity spread across the economy, lasting morethan a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment,industrial production, and wholesale-retail sales.”

The purpose of this paper is to apply the advanced methodology of singularspectrum analysis (SSA) — more specifically both univariate and multivariateSSA (M-SSA) — to the analysis of macroeconomic time series in order to helpunderstand the origin and behavior of business cycles. Both methods rely on theclassical Karhunen-Loeve spectral decomposition of time series and random fields(Karhunen, 1946; Loeve, 1945, 1978). Broomhead and King (1986a,b) proposedto use SSA and M-SSA in the context of nonlinear dynamics for the purpose ofreconstructing the attractor of a system from measured time series, thus pro-viding an extension and a more robust application of the Mane-Takens idea ofreconstructing dynamics from a single time series (Mane, 1981; Takens, 1981;Sauer, Yorke, and Casdagli, 1991). Ghil, Vautard and associates (Vautard andGhil, 1989; Ghil and Vautard, 1991; Vautard, Yiou, and Ghil, 1992) noticed thatSSA can be used as a time-and-frequency domain method for time series analysis— independently from attractor reconstruction and including cases in which thelatter may fail.

We rely here on M-SSA for the analysis of oscillatory modes and comovementsof several time series that reflect the time evolution of a single economy. M-SSAcombines two useful approaches of statistical analysis: (1) it determines majordirections in the system’s phase space that are spanned by the multivariatetime series with the help of principal component analysis; and (2) it extractsmajor spectral components by using data-adaptive filters. In particular, M-SSAcan separate distinct spectral components in a multivariate data set of limitedlength and in the presence of relatively high noise levels. In order to get reliableinformation about oscillatory modes, we perform exhaustive statistical tests bymeans of Monte Carlo SSA (Allen and Smith, 1996); these tests allow us tohandle the problem of spurious oscillations highlighted in the economic literatureby Nelson and Kang (1981) and by Cogley and Nason (1995).

M-SSA has already proven its advantages in a variety of applications, suchas climate dynamics, meteorology and oceanography, as well as the biomedi-cal sciences. Ghil, Allen, Dettinger, Ide, Kondrashov, Mann, Robertson, Saun-ders, Tian, Varadi, and Yiou (2002) provide an overview and a comprehensiveset of references to both the theory and applications of SSA and M-SSA; freesoftware for implementation is provided by the SSA-MTM Toolkit at http:

//www.atmos.ucla.edu/tcd/ssa. M-SSA has also shown its ability to reducethe effect of noise in order to help predict future exchange rates (Lisi and Medio,1997). The present paper, however, goes beyond mere denoising and describes

Page 3: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 3

in much greater detail how to use M-SSA in order to quantify the properties ofthe underlying macroeconomic system.

The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the SSA andM-SSA methodology: starting from single-channel SSA, we discuss the extensionto multi-channel time series. We summarize the properties of the methodologyin terms of spectral decomposition, as well as of time-domain reconstruction.In Section 3, we apply single-channel SSA to the U.S. gross domestic product(GDP) and M-SSA to the full data set, and discuss the reliability of the results interms of Monte Carlo testing. Section 4 analyzes the temporal variability of theU.S. business cycles, and we draw conclusions about the underlying dynamics inSection 5.

2. DECOMPOSITION AND RECONSTRUCTION

2.1. Data and pre-processing

We apply M-SSA to U.S. macroeconomic data from the Bureau of EconomicAnalysis (BEA; see http://www.bea.gov). The nine variables analyzed are GDP,investment, employment rate, consumption, total wage, change in private in-ventories, price, exports, and imports; all monetary variables are in constant2005 dollars, while the employment rate is in percent. The time series of thesenine variables are available on a quarterly basis, and cover 52 years, from thefirst quarter of 1954 to the last of 2005.

We first remove the trend of each time series separately, by using the Hodrickand Prescott (1997) filter with the parameter value λ = 1600, as recommendedby these authors for quarterly data. Employment is the only one of the ninevariables that does not exhibit an upward trend, being bounded between 0 and100%; still we detrend it, in order to remove periods that are much longer than10 years and thus are not relevant to our analysis. This approach to obtainingthe (raw–trend) residuals provides a common basis for comparison with previousstudies. As stated already in the Introduction, we are fully aware of the danger ofobtaining spurious cyclical behavior due to inadequate detrending (Nelson andKang, 1981; Harvey and Jaeger, 1993; Cogley and Nason, 1995), and will discussin Section 3 the ability of Monte Carlo M-SSA to justify the results obtained inthe present paper.

Next, we nondimensionalize each time series by dividing the residuals by thetrend, i.e. we concentrate on relative values. Each time series of relative values isnormalized to possess standard deviation one, i.e. we divide the relative valuesby their standard deviation. Finally, we divide the normalized time series by(DM)1/2 — where D = 9 is the number of variables (“channels”) and M = 24 isthe window width — so that the sum of the partial variances equals one (see thenext two subsections). Figure 1a shows the results of this pre-processing. TheU.S. recessions, as defined by the NBER, are indicated by shaded vertical barsin this figure.

Page 4: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

4 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

(a) Pre−processed time series

−0.2

−0.1

0

0.1

0.2

(b) RCs 1−32 of M−SSA

1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

−0.2

−0.1

0

0.1

0.2

Figure 1.— The nine time series of U.S. macroeconomic data: pre-processingand multivariate singular spectrum analysis (M-SSA); raw data from the U.S.Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), 1954–2005. (a) Detrended and standard-ized time series. (b) Reconstruction of the entire data set with the first 32 com-ponents of M-SSA, which capture 90% of the total variance; the window width isM = 24 quarters. The shaded vertical bars in both panels indicate NBER-definedrecessions.

Page 5: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 5

2.2. Singular spectrum analysis (SSA)

Before introducing the full multivariate SSA, we first discuss the univariateversion of SSA and present the main properties and capabilities of this analysismethod. The classical approach to describe cyclical behavior of a single timeseries is to decompose it into its spectral components by some version of Fourieranalysis. This approach works well for fairly long time series {x(t) : t = 1 . . . N},with N large, and relatively low noise levels; it works less well when N is smalland the noise is large, which is often the case in economic time series, as well asin geophysical ones.

Ghil, Vautard and several associates first proposed to apply the SSA method-ology to handle the problem of describing cyclical behavior in short and noisytime series, for which standard methods derived from Fourier analysis do notwork well (Vautard and Ghil, 1989; Ghil and Vautard, 1991; Vautard, Yiou, andGhil, 1992). This methodology provides insight into the unknown or partiallyknown dynamics of the underlying system that has generated the time series.Applying SSA to reconstruct the entire attractor of a nonlinear dynamical sys-tem from limited data, as originally proposed by Broomhead and King (1986a),may fail, however, even in relatively simple cases (Mees, Rapp, and Jennings,1987; Vautard and Ghil, 1989).

The key idea of Vautard and Ghil (1989) and Ghil and Vautard (1991) wasto only reconstruct the “skeleton of the attractor”, i.e. the most robust, albeitunstable limit cycles embedded in it. Following Mane (1981) and Takens (1981),the starting point of SSA is to embed the time series {x(t) : t = 1 . . . N} into anM–dimensional phase space X, by using M lagged copies

(1) x(t) = (x(t), x(t+ 1), . . . , x(t+M − 1)),

with t = 1 . . . N −M + 1.

The SSA procedure starts by calculating the principal directions of the attrac-tor in this embedding phase space X from the vector sequence x(t). The firststep is then to compute the auto-covariance matrix C of x, whose elements ci,jare given by

(2) ci,j =1

N − |i− j|

N−|i−j|∑t=1

x(t)x(t+ |i− j|).

Vautard and Ghil (1989) observed that the M ×M matrix C has Toeplitz struc-ture with constant diagonals; that is, its entries ci,j depend only on the lag|i− j|.

The eigenvalues λk and eigenvectors ρk, k = 1 . . .M , of C are obtained bysolving

(3) Cρk = λkρk.

Page 6: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

6 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

The eigenvectors, which are pairwise orthonormal, span a new coordinate systemin the M–dimensional embedding space X, and each eigenvalue λk indicates thevariance of x in the corresponding direction ρk. This computation helps us findmajor directions in x that carry a large variance, and therefore describe majorcomponents of the system’s dynamical behavior. Usually, this decomposition ofC determines its directions of greatest variance successively, from the largestto the smallest eigenvalues, subject to the condition that each new direction beorthogonal to all the preceding ones.

By convention, the eigenvalues {λk, k = 1 . . .M} are arranged in descendingorder, thus representing the directions ρk in x in order of importance, from thelargest to the smallest variance. In the so-called “scree diagram” plot of λk vs.k, one often looks for a clear break in the slope in order to distinguish “signal”from “noise.” Such a break, however, occurs mostly when the noise is actuallywhite, with no temporal correlations at all. The signal-to-noise separation testhas, therefore, to be modified in the presence of colored noise. We will discussthis problem in greater detail when introducing the appropriate significance testin Sec. 3.

Projecting the time series x onto each eigenvector ρk yields the correspondingprincipal component (PC)

(4) Ak(t) =

M∑j=1

x(t+ j − 1)ρk(j), k = 1 . . .M.

Note that the sum above is not defined close to the end of the time series, whereN −M ≤ t ≤ N . It is customary, therefore, to consider the PCs as defined foronly N −M + 1 indices, which could start at t = M , rather than at t = 1, andend at N , or start at t = 1 but end at N −M + 1; most commonly they areplotted centered for M/2 ≤ t ≤ N −M/2, with M even (Ghil, Allen, Dettinger,Ide, Kondrashov, Mann, Robertson, Saunders, Tian, Varadi, and Yiou, 2002).

We can now reconstruct that part of the time series that is associated with aparticular eigenvector by convolving the PC with the corresponding eigenvector

(5) rk(t) =1

Mt

Ut∑j=Lt

Ak(t− j + 1)ρk(j), k = 1 . . .M.

The values of the triplet of integers (Mt, Lt, Ut) for the central part of the timeseries, M ≤ t ≤ N −M + 1, are simply (M, 1,M); for either end they are givenin Ghil, Allen, Dettinger, Ide, Kondrashov, Mann, Robertson, Saunders, Tian,Varadi, and Yiou (2002). Thus the reconstructed component (RC) rk(t) associatedwith the variance λk has a complete set of N indices, but our confidence in itsvalues decreases as we approach either end of the time series, since fewer valuesof the original time series are averaged over the window M to obtain these valuesof the RC.

Page 7: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 7

Given any subset K of eigenelements {(λk,ρk) : k ∈ K}, we obtain the corre-sponding reconstruction rK(t) by summing the RCs rk over k ∈ K,

(6) rK(t) =∑k∈K

rk(t).

Typical choices of K may involve (i) K = {t : 1 ≤ t ≤ S}, where S is the statis-tical dimension of the time series, cf. Vautard and Ghil (1989), i.e., the numberof statistically significant components, commonly referred to as the signal, asopposed to the noise; (ii) a pair of successive components (k0, k0 + 1) for whichλk0≈ λk0+1, which might capture, as we shall see, a possibly cyclic mode of

behavior of the system (see Section 3); or (iii) K = {k : 1 ≤ k ≤ M}, i.e. thecomplete reconstruction of the time series. The latter case simply corresponds tothe counterpart, for SSA, of the Parseval theorem for a Fourier series (or inte-gral) or to wavelet reconstruction. The common, less mathematical notation forthe reconstructed component rk is RC k, and for a sum of several, consecutiveRCs — from index k to index k′ — it is RCs k–k′.

From the viewpoint of signal processing, the RCs can be considered as filteredtime series, where the filtering is data adaptive, being given by the projection ontothe eigenvectors. Eq. (4) can be interpreted as a finite-impulse response (FIR)filter (Oppenheim and Schafer, 1989), with ρk being an FIR filter of length M .Next, the PCs Ak(t) obtained in Eq. (4) are time-reversed, cf. Eq. (5), and theFIR filter is run again through them. After this second filter pass, the correctchronological order is restored by reversing the filtered result rk(t) once more.This procedure is called forward-backward filtering, and it is known to preservethe phase relations.

The filtering by projection onto each eigenvector ρk is thus neutral in phaseand acts only on the amplitudes. Hence, each RC rk(t) and the original timeseries x(t) are in phase. In designing an appropriate band-pass filter, Baxter andKing (1999) require, in particular, that this “filter should not introduce phaseshifts.” Unlike their band-pass filter, with its data-independent weights givena priori, SSA is data adaptive, since the M filters are simply the eigenvectorsof the auto-covariance matrix. These eigenvectors extract a certain frequencyband of the time series, and we thus assign to each pair (λk,ρk) a frequency,given by the maximum of the Fourier transform of ρk (cf. Vautard, Yiou, andGhil (1992)). Instead of plotting each eigenvalue vs. its rank, we plot it vs. itsdominant frequency.

This approach provides a complementary perspective on SSA in terms of ananalogy with classical spectral analysis; still, the eigenvector pairs associatedwith oscillatory modes are more flexible than the fixed pairs of sine and cosinefunctions that appear in Fourier analysis. Indeed, the MUSIC algorithm (MUl-tiple SIgnal Classification, Schmidt (1986)) builds on this analogy in order toestimate the frequency spectrum.

When analyzing the trend residuals of GDP alone, we observe a maximum inthe spectrum of eigenvalues at the usually reported mean business cycle length of

Page 8: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

8 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

0 0.5 1 1.5 20

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

(a) Spectrum of eigenvalues

f in 1/year

λ

0 0.5 1 1.5 20

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

f in 1/year

(b) Power spectral densityP

SD

−20 0 20−0.02

0

0.02

0.04Covariance function

Time lag in quarters

Figure 2.— Univariate spectral analysis of U.S. GDP. (a) Eigenvalue spec-trum of λk (circles) vs. dominant frequency of the associated eigenvector ρk,with window width M = 24 quarters; the error bars indicate the confidencelevel (cf. Sec. 3.1). (b) Power spectral density (PSD) estimate (solid lines) usingWelch’s averaged periodogram method, with a Hamming window of length 128quarters and 75% overlap (Priestley, 1991); the dashed lines indicate the signif-icance levels. Inset: Covariance estimates and significance levels. The upper andlower significance levels in both panels and in the inset are derived from the 2.5%and 97.5% percentiles of 1000 surrogate time series; see Sec. 3.1.

Page 9: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 9

5–6 years (Figure 2a). This result is in agreement with those of classical spectraldensity analysis (Figure 2b), which also exhibit a maximum around the sameperiod, for various power spectral density (PSD) estimation algorithms that wehave tested. At this point, though, the trend residuals are subject to the Nelsonand Kang (1981) critique of spurious cycles and we have to perform additionaltests before relying on the results; see Sec. 3.1.

2.3. Multivariate SSA (M-SSA)

M-SSA extends univariate SSA to multivariate time series. Broomhead andKing (1986b) proposed the use of an M-SSA version in the context of Mane–Takens-style attractor reconstruction for nonlinear, deterministic dynamical sys-tems. Once again, complete reconstruction is problematic, especially for largesystems and in the presence of substantial amounts of noise. The more modestgoal of reconstructing only the robust skeleton of the attractor led Kimoto, Ghil,and Mo (1991), Keppenne and Ghil (1993), and Plaut and Vautard (1994) toformulate the algorithm described briefly herein; see also Ghil, Allen, Dettinger,Ide, Kondrashov, Mann, Robertson, Saunders, Tian, Varadi, and Yiou (2002).In this section, we present the advantages of applying M-SSA to the data set athand.

Instead of a single time series x(t), we now observe multiple quantities simul-taneously. Let x(t) = {xd(t): d = 1 . . . D, t = 1 . . . N} be now a D–channel,vector time series of length N . In the generalization of (2) we consider, besideall D auto-covariances Cd,d, also all cross-covariances Cd,d′ to yield the grand

covariance matrix C:

(7) C =

C1,1 C1,2 . . . C1,D

C2,1 C2,2 . . . C2,D

...... Cd,d′

...CD,1 CD,2 . . . CD,D

,

where C is of size DM × DM and the entries of the individual matrices Cd,d′

are given by

(8) (ci,j)d,d′ =1

N

min{N,N+i−j}∑t=max{1,1+i−j}

xd(t)xd′(t+ i− j).

The denominator N depends on the range of summation, namely N = min{N,N+i− j} −max{1, 1 + i− j}+ 1.

As in the univariate case of Eq. (3) in Section 2.2, we now diagonalize the

grand matrix C to yield its eigenvalues λk and eigenvectors ρk,

(9) Cρk = λkρk.

Page 10: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

10 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

By solving this equation, we get DM pairs (λk, ρk), where each eigenvector ρk

of length DM is composed of D consecutive segments ρdk, d = 1 . . . D, each of

length M . The associated PCs are single-channel time series that are computedby projecting the multivariate time series (x1, x2, . . . , xD) onto ρd

k,

(10) Ak(t) =

M∑j=1

D∑d=1

xd(t+ j − 1)ρdk(j), k = 1 . . .M.

In addition to the summation j over time as in the univariate SSA in Eq. (4),we have here a second summation with respect to the distinct channels d, repre-senting a principal component analysis. In the geophysical applications reviewedby Ghil, Allen, Dettinger, Ide, Kondrashov, Mann, Robertson, Saunders, Tian,Varadi, and Yiou (2002), these channels often represent sample time series of thesame variable, e.g. temperature, at distinct spatial locations; here they representdistinct variables for the same economy.

Convolving the PCs with the eigenvectors,

(11) rdk(t) =1

Mt

Ut∑j=Lt

Ak(t− j + 1)ρdk(j), k = 1 . . .M, d = 1 . . . D,

yields the RCs, as in the univariate case of Eq. (5). Like in single-channel SSA,the M-SSA result of Eq. (11) provides us with a set of M RCs, but it does sofor each of the D time series xd(t). Depending on the information containedin the cross-covariances Cd,d′ , the RCs of different channels may or may notbe correlated. In this way, M-SSA helps extract common spectral componentsfrom the multivariate data set, along with comovements of the channels. Pastexperience has shown, moreover, that M-SSA does not induce artificially morecoherent behavior in the filtered data set, i.e. no spurious correlations betweenchannels arise from to the M-SSA treatment of the data, when choosing theparameters of the analysis, such as D and M , with due care.

To illustrate the power of M-SSA to help extract behavior that is shared acrossthe complete data set, we compare in Figure 1 the pre-processed time series (Fig-ure 1a) and the M-SSA reconstruction (Figure 1b). The overall picture of theM-SSA filtered time series (Figure 1b) exhibits a smoother and more coherentbehavior of the nine economic variables. The reconstruction with the 32 leadingRCs captures already 90 % of the total variance and only small, high-frequencyfluctuations with a period shorter than one year are removed. It is obvious fromthe comparison with Figure 1a that the M-SSA treatment improves the ex-traction of common phase-space behavior and helps gain additional informationabout the underlying dynamics. Still, we have to be very critical in interpret-ing the behavior in Figure 1b as a set of oscillations. In the next section, wepursue therefore the single- and multi-channel SSA analysis of the U.S. aggre-gate indicators, while paying great attention to the statistical significance of theresults.

Page 11: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 11

3. OSCILLATORY BEHAVIOR AND ITS STATISTICAL SIGNIFICANCE

The trend residuals in Figure 1 exhibit obviously more structure than purewhite noise; we need, therefore, a stringent test to decide whether the visuallyapparent cyclical behavior can be attributed to random fluctuations or to amore regular oscillatory behavior, of possibly intrinsic origin. Cogley and Na-son (1995), among others, have discussed in detail the effect of detrending andthe generation of spurious cycles; their discussion was placed in the context ofthe detrending effect on a standard real business cycle (RBC) model, with nooscillatory dynamics. These authors showed, in particular, that the PSD of anHP-filtered random walk has a peak at a period of 7.6 years.

Our key idea here is very similar to that of Cogley and Nason (1995) and it is awell-established, standard tool in the geosciences: To verify the statistical signif-icance of oscillations, we test against autoregressive processes of order one. SuchAR(1) processes exhibit greater variance at low frequencies, with a maximum atzero frequency, while detrending with the HP filter — even when applied to thesimulations of an RBC model with no oscillatory dynamics — yields a maximumin the spectral density around the reported business cycle length of five years.

We fit an AR(1) process to the detrended and standardized BEA data setand pass the output through an HP filter, in such a way as to preserve certainstylized facts, including the auto- and cross-correlations of the data. By meansof Monte Carlo simulation we test whether oscillatory modes exist that cannotbe explained by the fluctuations of the surrogate time series. This method —introduced and discussed in detail by Allen and Smith (1996) — is referred toas Monte Carlo SSA. In the univariate case, we compare the Monte Carlo SSAresults with those of standard spectral density estimation to verify further thatthe two approaches are consistent (Sec. 3.1). Next, we present the advantagesof a full, multivariate SSA in finding robust oscillatory modes (Sec. 3.2), whosecharacteristics are less obvious in a univariate analysis.

3.1. Univariate time series: the GDP

We consider here the simple case of a univariate time series, where we do nothave to take comovements into account. The analysis focuses on GDP, which isusually considered to be the most import macroeconomic variable.

First off, we have to find an appropriate null hypothesis of a stochastic processthat captures the typical “stylized facts” of our original data set, but in whichwe know that no oscillations are present. The natural choice is to fit an AR(1)process to the time series,

(12) X(t) = aX(t− 1) + σ0 ε(t),

with ε(t) being Gaussian white noise of variance σ = 1. In the case of GDP resid-uals, we estimate the regression coefficient to be a = 0.78, while the estimated

Page 12: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

12 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

variance is σ0 = 0.38. We have used as surrogate data 1000 realizations of theAR(1) process in Eq. (12), with the same length of 52 years as the data set.

Next, we have to consider the influence of the HP filter on the null hypothesis.We filter, therefore, the AR(1) output with exactly the same HP filter as theactual GDP data.

In Figure 2b, we have estimated the PSD of the GDP residuals displayed inFigure 1a. The PSD estimate (solid line) is clearly much higher around a five-year period. On the other hand, we have also estimated the PSD for each of thesurrogate time series and derived significance levels for each frequency from the2.5% and 97.5% percentiles (dashed lines). These significance levels also showhigh power around five years, and the PSD estimate falls entirely between them.

We have applied several PSD estimation methods and conclude that, in thisunivariate analysis, the GDP residuals cannot be distinguished from the nullhypothesis of an HP-filtered AR(1) process, and the high PSD values aroundfive years could be due to the detrending of an otherwise stable model withexogenous excitation. Such a detrending effect is in complete agreement withthe findings of Cogley and Nason (1995) and Nelson and Kang (1981). The sameholds — as expected from the Wiener-Khinchin theorem that links the PSD andthe lag-covariance function of a time series — for the latter (see the small inset inFigure 2b ): the swing below zero for the surrogate time series comes again fromthe HP filter’s effect; note that the auto-correlation function of a pure AR(1)process would be proportional to 1/τ2, with τ being the time lag, and thus onlytake positive values (Blackman and Tukey, 1958). The preliminary conclusionis that, for the univariate GDP time series at hand, we cannot falsify the nullhypothesis of an AR(1) process.

This negative finding can also be confirmed by Monte Carlo SSA (Allen andSmith, 1996). This method tests whether an eigenvalue λk captures more partialvariance in the direction of the corresponding eigenvector ρk than present in thenull hypothesis. To derive the significance level in the eigenvalue spectrum, weproject the covariance matrix CS, estimated for each surrogate time series xS(t)as in Eq. (2), onto the eigenvectors ρk of the original time series

(13) ΛS = EᵀCSE,

where the ρk are the columns of E, and (·)ᵀ denotes the transpose of a vectoror a matrix.

Since Eq. (13) is not the eigen-decomposition of the particular realizationCS, the matrix ΛS is not necessarily diagonal, as it would be for C. Instead,ΛS provides a measure of the discrepancy between the surrogate time seriesxS(t) and the original time series x(t). By computing the percentiles of thediagonal-element distribution, we derive significance levels for each eigenvalueλk. In Figure 2a, these levels of significance are indicated as vertical bars andwe see, as in the case of the PSD, that all the eigenvalues λk fall within theseerror bars. This is not surprising, given the already stated analogy between SSA

Page 13: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 13

TABLE I

Null-hypothesis parameters

Variable AR(1) parameters Time lag behind GDPad σd ∆d (quarters)

GDP 0.78 0.38 0Investment 0.90 0.19 1Employment 0.88 0.23 0Consumption 0.81 0.34 0Total wage 0.83 0.31 0∆(Inventories) 0.56 0.67 0Price 0.94 0.12 7Exports 0.80 0.36 1Imports 0.73 0.46 1

and PSD, although SSA is more flexible, due to the data-adaptive eigenvectorsit uses as a basis. In the following subsection, we will demonstrate nonethelessthat, by including additional information from other macroeconomic indicators,it is still possible to reject a reasonable multivariate null hypothesis.

3.2. Multivariate time series

In the multivariate case, the hypothesis that we test against has to be modified.Allen and Robertson (1996) have proposed to fit an independent AR(1) process toeach separate time series. A simple inspection of the trend residuals in Figure 1a,though, suggests comovements that should be taken into account in formulat-ing the null hypothesis. An alternative would be to use a vector AR(1) model.When testing for significant oscillations, we need, however, a null-hypothesismodel that does not support oscillations. Vector AR models, though, supportoscillations even for order one; when present, these are referred to as principaloscillation patterns (von Storch, Burger, Schnur, and von Storch, 1995; Penlandand Matrosova, 2001). We keep, therefore, the idea of fitting individual AR(1)processes, but build characteristics of the auto- as well as the cross-correlationsof the given time series into each one of the fits.

We thus start by fitting a scalar AR(1) process to each of the time series, asin the univariate case:

(14) Xd(t) = adXd(t− 1) + σd εd(t).

The estimated parameters for each macroeconomic indicator are listed in Table I,and the cross-covariances between the indicators are plotted in Figure 3.

Next, we include information on these cross-covariances into the null hypoth-esis by coupling the noise residuals εd(t) of the individual AR(1) processes Xd(t)in Eq. (14). Namely, we allow for temporal lags ∆d between the GDP, denotedby x1(t), and the other variables, xd6=1(t), and set each lag ∆d to equal the oneat which the cross-covariance function between x1(t) and xd(t) reaches its max-

Page 14: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

14 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

imum. Such a lag is especially necessary for the price, for which the maximalcross-covariance with GDP occurs at about seven quarters (cf. Figure 3).

The covariance matrix R that we take into account for the coupling of theinnovation processes εd(t) has elements Rd,d′ given by

(15) Rd,d′ =1

Nd,d′

min{N,N+∆d′−∆d}∑t=max{1,1+∆d′−∆d}

xd(t)xd′(t+ ∆d′ −∆d) ;

the denominator Nd,d′ here depends on the range of summation, namely Nd,d′ =min{N,N + ∆d′ − ∆d} − max{1, 1 + ∆d′ − ∆d} + 1, cf. Eq. (8). Cholesky de-composition yields R = LᵀL and we derive correlated innovation processes from

(16) (ε1(t), . . . , εd(t+ ∆d), . . . , εD(t+ ∆D))ᵀ

= Lᵀ(ξ1(t), . . . , ξd(t), . . . , ξD(t))ᵀ,

with the ξd being independent white-noise processes. We thus build certain time-lag patterns found in the given data set into the set of D = 9 individual AR(1)processes. Finally, we pass the time series so generated through the HP filter toremove low frequencies, normalize it to the same standard deviation as the dataset, and thus obtain the surrogate time series we test against.

Figure 3 compares the auto- and cross-covariance functions with respect toGDP of the original and the surrogate time series. We observe that the lead-lag relations among economic indicators that are associated with typical stylizedfacts of business cycles (Zarnowitz, 1985; Hallegatte, Ghil, Dumas, and Hourcade,2008) are reproduced by the null-hypothesis model, and that the covariancefunctions of the data set lie almost, but not quite, within the fluctuations of themultivariate AR(1) model. As in the univariate case, the HP filter introduces aswing below zero, whose minimum is at approximately five quarters and whichwould lead to spurious cycles with a length of roughly 20 quarters.

To derive significance levels for the M-SSA eigenvalues, we determine again —from Eq. (7) and for each surrogate time series — the grand covariance matrix

CS and project it onto the eigenvectors of the original time series, ΛS = EᵀCSE,as in Eq. (13). From the distribution of the elements on the main diagonal of ΛS,we derive as before the significance levels for each eigenvalue {λk : 1, . . . , DM}.These, along with the actual eigenvalues associated with the original data set,are plotted in Figure 4.

As in the case of GDP in Figure 2a, we observe also in this figure higher levelsof surrogate eigenvalues near a five-year period (Figure 4). But this time theoscillatory five-year mode in the data set clearly exceeds the significance levelof the null hypothesis and can no longer be explained by spurious cycles thatwould be induced by inappropriate detrending.

We have also tested the robustness of the present results by using differentvalues of the window width, M = 20, 30, 40 and 50: it turns out that the leadingpair of eigenvalues always describes a significant oscillatory mode at a period of

Page 15: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 15

−2

0

2

4

x 10−3

(a) GDP − GDP (b) GDP − Investment (c) GDP − Employment

−2

0

2

4

x 10−3

(d) GDP − Consumption (e) GDP − Total wage (f) GDP − ∆(Inventories)

−20 −10 0 10 20

−2

0

2

4

x 10−3

(g) GDP − Price

Time lag in quarters−20 −10 0 10 20

(h) GDP − Exports

−20 −10 0 10 20

(i) GDP − Imports

Figure 3.— Auto- and cross-covariance functions of the nine U.S. economicindicators with respect to GDP (solid lines). Given as dashed lines are the sig-nificance levels (2.5% and 97.5%), as well as the median from the realization of1000 surrogate time series; see text for details.

Page 16: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

16 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 20

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

Spectrum of eigenvalues

f in 1/year

λ

Figure 4.— Spectrum of eigenvalues (circles) from M-SSA of all nine timeseries with M = 24. The error bars indicate the level of significance, which arederived from the 2.5% and 97.5% percentiles of 1000 multivariate surrogate timeseries.

about five years (not shown). On the other hand, the three-year oscillation thatis reflected in the second pair of eigenvalues in Figure 4 is less robust.

We have performed additional, exhaustive tests — as proposed by Allen andSmith (1996) — to cope with the problem of overestimating large eigenvalues inSSA and have found further evidence that the five-year oscillatory pair is indeedstatistically significant at the 95% level. We focus, therefore, in the next sectionon this oscillatory mode and investigate its role in business cycle dynamics.

4. TEMPORAL VARIABILITY OF BUSINESS CYCLE DYNAMICS

The existence of an oscillatory pair indicates that the trajectory of the systemthat produced the time series is attracted by a limit cycle in phase space; inthis case, the cycle has a period of about five years. But this limit cycle doesnot explain the full dynamical behavior, as the first two eigenvalues capture only40% of the total variance.

In order to better understand the role of the five-year oscillatory mode inthe processes of expansion and recession, we study the evolution of its variancethroughout the cycle. Plaut and Vautard (1994) have introduced the concept oflocal variance fraction VK(t),

(17) VK(t) =

∑k∈KAk(t)2

DM∑k=1

Ak(t)2

,

Page 17: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 17

which quantifies how much of the total variance is captured by the set K ofPCs at a given time t. This index is especially useful in measuring the relativeamplitude of an oscillatory activity, described here by PCs 1–2, within a timewindow of width M . The PCs are used in Eq. (17), rather than the RCs, sinceit is the former that give us the projection of the multivariate time series ontothe eigenvector pairs; as already noted in connection with Eq. (4), we considerthe PCs as centered, i.e. starting at M/2.

Figure 5 shows this index, along with the NBER-defined recessions, for PCs1–2 in panel (a) and for PCs 3–100 in panel (b). The sum of both (dash-dottedline in panel (a)) captures 99% of the total variance; the missing 1% is due tothe “leakage” near the endpoints. Starting after 1970, it is quite remarkable thatthe fraction of the five-year oscillatory mode in PCs 1–2 is high during recessionsand low during expansions. This shows that during the recessions, the trajectoryof the U.S. economy described by the BEA data set stays closer to a possiblefive-year limit cycle — like the one in the Non-Equilibrium Dynamic Model(NEDyM) of Hallegatte and Ghil (2008) or in other endogenous business cyclemodels (Chiarella, Flaschel, and Franke, 2005) — while this trajectory revealsmore complex behavior during expansions.

Furthermore, Figure 5 suggests a change in the system’s dynamics in the 1980s.During the 1970s, PCs 1–2 capture roughly 50% of the variance or more overthe full decade, while from 1980 on, PCs 1–2 play a significant role only duringrecessions. This change falls into the same period as the “great moderation,”during which volatility in GDP growth diminished markedly (Kim and Nelson,1999; McConnell and Perez-Quiros, 2000; Stock and Watson, 2002).

There has been considerable debate on the cause of this shift, as well as onthe duration of the new functioning mode of the U.S. economy ; in particularit has been proposed that this moderate behavior terminated in 2007, i.e. be-fore and during the “great recession” of 2008-2009. In any case, our results areat least consistent with the hypothesis of structural changes in the 1980s, andour M-SSA methodology can help provide sophisticated analysis tools to deter-mine whether and when the great moderation ended, once additional BEA databecome available.

In order to assess whether the variability of the local variance fraction VK(t)can be explained by the random fluctuations of the null hypothesis, we examineits significance by the same type of procedure as for the eigenvalues in Eq. (13).To wit, we project each surrogate set K of PCs — e.g., PCs 1–2, 3–100 and 1–100— onto the data eigenvectors ρ, in the same way as for the data set in Eq. (10).The resulting time series are again not orthogonal, and their covariance matrixΛS is not diagonal, but it allows us — as in the case of the significance levels forthe eigenvalues — to assess the distance from the data PCs.

We calculate, for each set of surrogate time series K, the local variance fractionVK(t), in the same way as for the data set in Eq. (17), and derive for each epocht the significance levels from the percentiles (Figs. 5a,b, dashed lines). Since theAR(1) processes are stationary, these levels are supposed to be constant; this

Page 18: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

18 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

(a) Local variance fraction of PCs 1−2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

(b) Local variance fraction of PCs 3−100

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 20050

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Figure 5.— Local variance fraction V (t): (a) for PCs 1-2 (solid line) andPCs 1–100 (near-total variance, dash-dotted line); and (b) for PCs 3–100 (solidline). The dashed lines in both panels indicate the 2.5%, 25%, 50%, 75%, and97.5% percentiles based on 1000 surrogate time series. The shaded vertical barsindicate NBER-defined recessions.

stationarity is seen in fact in Figure 5, except near the end of the time series,i.e. starting at t ' N −M , where M = 24 quarters.

In contrast to the approximate constancy of V (t) for the AR(1) processes,the five-year oscillatory mode in the BEA data exhibits much greater variabilityduring the recessions, when it does exceed the 97.5% significance level. The vari-ability in PCs 3–100 is also larger than can be explained by the null hypothesis,with V (t) values that are significantly larger than the 97.5% percentile duringexpansions and smaller than the 2.5% percentile during recessions, respectively.We have further examined the variability of V (t) during the whole 1954–2005interval by using other quantities, such as standard deviation and interquartilerange (not shown here). All these estimates confirm that the U.S. data set ex-hibits larger variability than can be explained by the random fluctuations of ourcarefully and conservatively formulated null hypothesis.

5. CONCLUDING REMARKS

In this article, we proposed a novel methodology — namely singular spectrumanalysis (SSA) and its multivariate extension (M-SSA) — to study businesscycles in a consistent and multivariate way, which allowed us to reconcile and

Page 19: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 19

combine the NBER definition of recessions with quantitative analysis tools. Weapplied this methodology to nine U.S. macroeconomic indicators available fromthe BEA for 52 years (1954–2005); see Section 2.1 and Figure 1 there.

This analysis leads to three major conclusions that concern, respectively:(i) the presence of genuine periodicity in macroeconomic behavior and its de-terministic causes; (ii) the essential role of comovements of economic aggregatesin the proper definition of business cycles; and (iii) the dependence of economic“volatility” on the phase of the business cycle. We describe these conclusions ingreater detail below.

Genuine periodicity and its deterministic causes. In their work about the “realfacts” and monetary myths of business cycles, Kydland and Prescott (1998)discussed the origin of business cycles in terms of the Slutzky (1937) theory ofrandom shocks. In the simplest RBC models, cyclicity originates exclusively fromproductivity shocks that can be modeled by a simple random walk. Cogley andNason (1995) have, moreover, argued that the spurious appearance of businesscycle dynamics can be generated by the HP filter even if none is present, evenin a random walk.

Indeed, in agreement with the findings of Cogley and Nason (1995), a simpleunivariate analysis of GDP does not reveal any significant oscillatory modes (seeFigure 2). The multivariate, M-SSA version of our analysis, however, permits thesystematic, self-consistent use of a larger amount of information about macroe-conomic behavior; it allows us, therewith, to identify a five-year oscillatory modewith high statistical confidence (see Figure 4). This mode cannot be explainedby artificial effects due to detrending by the HP filter, and a random-walk–drivenmodel of business cycles has to be questioned in the light of the results obtainedin the present investigation.

It is well known, as already mentioned at the beginning of Section 3.2, thatvector AR(1) processes can posses oscillatory solutions, due to the presence of

pairs of complex conjugate eigenvalues (λk, λk+1) = (λ(r)k ± λ

(i)k ) in the spectrum

of the matrix A = (aij) that characterizes such a process,

(18) X(t) = A X(t− 1) + Σ ε(t) ;

here Σ is a covariance matrix multiplying the noise vector ε. For a stationary

AR(1) process, all the real parts λ(r)k of the eigenvalues of A must be negative,

and the damped oscillations are maintained at a statistically constant amplitudeby the noise ε.

In practice, such a stochastically driven oscillator might be hard to distinguishfrom a purely deterministic, possibly chaotic one. But the term A X(t−1) in theformer case, on the right-hand side of Eq. (18), still captures the manifestationof a coupled pair of deterministic feedbacks, one positive, the other negative,whether linear or nonlinear, noise-driven or not, as the ultimate cause of any

complex conjugate pair of eigenvalues (λ(r)k ± λ

(i)k ).

A major result of our M-SSA study thus points rather unambiguously to the

Page 20: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

20 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

presence of such deterministic effects in the business cycles of the U.S. economy.We conclude, therefore, that business cycles cannot be explained by exogenousshocks alone and arise from complex interactions between endogenous dynamicsand exogenous perturbations.

Comovements of macroeconomic aggregates. The role of the additional infor-mation provided by the M-SSA analysis emphasizes the need to understandbusiness cycles as a phenomenon that is not limited to GDP variations, but in-volves all aspects of the economy; it is reflected, therefore, in the comovements ofseveral macroeconomic aggregates. In the present study, we have performed aninnovative, quantitative analysis of the BEA data set that is consistent with theNBER definition of the business cycle, inasmuch as it is entirely multivariate andtakes into account the lead-and-lag relationships between the various indicatorspresent in the data (see Table I and Figure 3).

State-dependent fluctuations. M-SSA also allowed us to provide further insightinto the underlying macroeconomic dynamics, and especially into the crucialquestion of the complex interplay between endogenous dynamics and exogenousshocks. We showed that the U.S. economy changes its behavior from one phase ofthe business cycle to another: the recession phase is dominated by the five-yearmode, while the expansion phase exhibits more complex dynamics, with higher-frequency modes coming into play (see Figure 5). This type of behavior cannotbe explained by the random fluctuations that drive a simple RBC model, in theabsence of endogenous oscillatory dynamics.

Pursuing further the implications of our results, let us assume that the dy-namics of the U.S. economy can indeed be decomposed into a five-year cycleand more complex, higher-frequency behavior superimposed on this cycle: thelatter suggests a higher volatility of the business cycle during expansions. Thisinference is consistent with intuition, since recessions are phases of underutilizedproduction capacities; hence economic variables, such as GDP and employment,are likely to be less sensitive to exogenous shocks, be it natural disaster (Halle-gatte and Ghil, 2008), monetary or fiscal policy shocks, or productivity shocks.During expansions, on the other hand, production is closer to saturation, andexogenous shocks — whether positive or negative —are likely to have a biggerimpact.

The next step in our research program is thus to investigate whether thechange in the economy’s dynamical behavior between boom and bust also leadsto different types of response to exogenous shocks. This question is fundamentalin attempting to evaluate the efficiency of economic policy in different phases ofthe business cycle.

Acknowledgments. It is a pleasure to thank J.-C. Hourcade for informative andstimulating discussions. This work was supported by a CNRS post-doctoral fel-lowship to AG, the Groupement d’Interet Scientifique (GIS) Reseau de Recherchesur le Developpement Soutenable (R2DS) of the Region Ile-de-France, and theChaire Developpement Durable of the Ecole Polytechnique.

Page 21: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

DETERMINISTIC CAUSES OF U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES 21

REFERENCES

Allen, M. R., and A. W. Robertson (1996): “Distinguishing modulated oscillations fromcoloured noise in multivariate datasets,” Climate Dynamics, 12(11), 775–784.

Allen, M. R., and L. A. Smith (1996): “Monte Carlo SSA: Detecting irregular oscillationsin the presence of colored noise,” Journal of Climate, 9, 3373–3404.

Baxter, M., and R. G. King (1999): “Measuring business cycles: Approximate band-passfilters for economic time series,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(4), 575–593.

Blackman, R. B., and J. W. Tukey (1958): The Measurement of Power Spectra. Dover.Broomhead, D. S., and G. P. King (1986a): “Extracting qualitative dynamics from experi-

mental data,” Physica D, 20(2-3), 217–236.(1986b): “On the qualitative analysis of experimental dynamical systems,” in Nonlin-

ear Phenomena and Chaos, ed. by S. Sarkar, pp. 113–144. Adam Hilger, Bristol, England.Burns, A. F., and W. C. Mitchell (1946): Measuring Business Cycles. NBER, New York

City, New York.Canova, F. (1998): “Detrending and business cycle facts,” Journal of Monetary Economics,

41(3), 475–512.Chiarella, C., P. Flaschel, and R. Franke (2005): Foundations for a Disequilibrium The-

ory of the Business Cycle. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Cogley, T., and J. M. Nason (1995): “Effects of the Hodrick-Prescott filter on trend and

difference stationary time series: Implications for business cycle research,” Journal of Eco-nomic Dynamics and Control, 19(1-2), 253–278.

Ghil, M., M. R. Allen, M. D. Dettinger, K. Ide, D. Kondrashov, M. E. Mann, A. W.Robertson, A. Saunders, Y. Tian, F. Varadi, and P. Yiou (2002): “Advanced spectralmethods for climatic time series,” Reviews of Geophysics, 40(1), 1–41.

Ghil, M., and R. Vautard (1991): “Interdecadal oscillations and the warming trend in globaltemperature time series,” Nature, 350(6316), 324–327.

Hallegatte, S., and M. Ghil (2008): “Natural disasters impacting a macroeconomic modelwith endogenous dynamics,” Ecological Economics, 68(1–2), 582–592.

Hallegatte, S., M. Ghil, P. Dumas, and J.-C. Hourcade (2008): “Business cycles, bifur-cations and chaos in a neo-classical model with investment dynamics,” Journal of EconomicBehavior & Organization, 67(1), 57–77.

Harvey, A. C., and A. Jaeger (1993): “Detrending, Stylized Facts and the Business Cycle,”Journal of Applied Econometrics, 8(3), 231–247.

Hodrick, R. J., and E. C. Prescott (1997): “Postwar U.S. business cycles: An empiricalinvestigation,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29(1), 1–16.

Karhunen, K. (1946): “Zur Spektraltheorie stochastischer Prozesse,” Ann. Acad. Sci. Fenn.Ser. A1, Math. Phys., 34.

Keppenne, C. L., and M. Ghil (1993): “Adaptive filtering and prediction of noisy multivari-ate signals: An application to subannual variability in atmospheric angular momentum,”International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos, 3, 625–634.

Kim, C.-J., and C. R. Nelson (1999): “Has the U.S. economy become more stable? A Bayesianapproach based on a Markov-switching model of the business cycle,” Review of Economicsand Statistics, 81, 608–616.

Kimoto, M., M. Ghil, and K.-C. Mo (1991): “Spatial structure of the extratropical 40-dayoscillation,” in Eighth Conf. Atmos. & Oceanic Waves and Stability (Denver, Colo.), pp.115–116. American Meteorological Society, Boston, Mass.

Kydland, F. E., and E. C. Prescott (1998): “Business cycles: Real Facts and a Mone-tary Myth,” in Real Business Cycles: A Reader, ed. by K. D. S. James E. Hartley, KevinD. Hoover, pp. 231–247. Routledge.

Lisi, F., and A. Medio (1997): “Is a random walk the best exchange rate predictor?,” Inter-national Journal of Forecasting, 13(2), 255–267.

Loeve, M. (1945): “Fonctions aleatoires de second ordre,” Comptes Rendus de l’Academie dessciences Paris, 220, 380.

(1978): Probability Theory, Vol. II, 4th ed., vol. 46 of Graduate Texts in Mathematics.

Page 22: Evidence for genuine periodicity and deterministic …...2 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS Business cycles are understood as comovements of the deviations from the trend

22 A. GROTH, M. GHIL, S. HALLEGATTE AND P. DUMAS

Springer-Verlag.Lucas, R. E. (1977): “Understanding business cycles,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series

on Public Policy, 5(1), 7–29.Mane, R. (1981): “On the dimension of the compact invariant sets of certain non-linear maps,”

in Dynamical Systems and Turbulence, vol. 898 of Lecture Notes in Mathematics, pp. 230–242. Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

McConnell, M. M., and G. Perez-Quiros (2000): “Output fluctuations in the United States:What has changed since the early 1980’s?,” American Economic Review, 90(5), 1464–1476.

Mees, A. I., P. E. Rapp, and L. S. Jennings (1987): “Singular-value decomposition andembedding dimension,” Physical Review A, 36(1), 340–346.

Nelson, C. R., and H. Kang (1981): “Spurious Periodicity in Inappropriately DetrendedTime Series,” Econometrica, 49(3), 741–751.

Oppenheim, A. V., and R. W. Schafer (1989): Discrete-time signal processing. Prentice-Hall,Inc. Upper Saddle River, NJ.

Penland, C., and L. Matrosova (2001): “Expected and actual errors of linear inverse modelforecasts,” Monthly Weather Review, 129, 1740–1745.

Plaut, G., and R. Vautard (1994): “Spells of low-frequency oscillations and weather regimesin the Northern Hemisphere,” Journal of the Atmospheric Sciences, 51(2), 210–236.

Priestley, M. (1991): Spectral Analysis and Time Series. Academic Press.Sauer, T., J. A. Yorke, and M. Casdagli (1991): “Embedology,” Journal of Statistical

Physics, 65(3-4), 579–616.Schmidt, R. O. (1986): “Multiple emitter location and signal parameter estimation,” IEEE

Transactions on Antennas and Propagation, 34, 276–280.Slutzky, E. (1937): “The summation of random causes as a source of cyclic processes,” Econo-

metrica, 5, 105–146.Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson (2002): “Has the business cycle changed and why?,” in

NBER Macroeconomics Annual, ed. by M. Gertler, and K. S. Rogoff, pp. 159–218. MITPress, Cambridge, Mass.

Takens, F. (1981): “Detecting strange attractors in turbulence,” in Dynamical Systems andTurbulence, vol. 898 of Lecture Notes in Mathematics, pp. 366–381. Springer, Berlin.

Vautard, R., and M. Ghil (1989): “Singular spectrum analysis in nonlinear dynamics, withapplications to paleoclimatic time series,” Physica D, 35(3), 395–424.

Vautard, R., P. Yiou, and M. Ghil (1992): “Singular-spectrum analysis: A toolkit for short,noisy chaotic signals,” Physica D, 58(1-4), 95–126.

von Storch, H., G. Burger, R. Schnur, and J.-S. von Storch (1995): “Principal oscillationpatterns : a review,” Journal of Climate, 8(3), 377–400.

Zarnowitz, V. (1985): “Recent work on business cycles in historical perspective: A review oftheories and evidence,” Journal of Economic Literature, 23(2), 523–580.