evaluating!the!effects!of!certificationon!smallholders ......! i!...

115
i Evaluating the Effects of Certification on Smallholders’ Net Incomes, with a Focus on Cacao Farmers in Cooperatives in Côte d’Ivoire By MELISSA ANNE SCHWEISGUTH M.S. (University of California, Davis) B.S. (University of Delaware) THESIS Submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF SCIENCE in International Agricultural Development in the OFFICE OF GRADUATE STUDIES of the UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA DAVIS Approved: __________________________________________________________________ Richard Sexton, Chair ___________________________________________________________________ James Chalfant ____________________________________________________________________ Lovell Jarvis Committee in Charge 2015

Upload: others

Post on 19-Mar-2020

10 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

 

  i  

Evaluating  the  Effects  of  Certification  on  Smallholders’  Net  Incomes,  with  a  Focus  on  Cacao  Farmers  in  Cooperatives  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  

 By  

MELISSA  ANNE  SCHWEISGUTH  

M.S.  (University  of  California,  Davis)  B.S.  (University  of  Delaware)  

 THESIS  

Submitted  in  partial  satisfaction  of  the  requirements  for  the  degree  of  

 MASTER  OF  SCIENCE  

in  

International  Agricultural  Development  

in  the  

OFFICE  OF  GRADUATE  STUDIES  

of  the  

UNIVERSITY  OF  CALIFORNIA  

DAVIS  

 

Approved:    

__________________________________________________________________  

Richard  Sexton,  Chair  

___________________________________________________________________  

James  Chalfant  

____________________________________________________________________  

Lovell  Jarvis  

Committee  in  Charge  

2015  

 

  ii  

Melissa  Anne  Schweisguth  March  2015  

International  Agricultural  Development    

Evaluating  the  Effects  of  Certification  on  Smallholders’  Net  Incomes,  with  a  Focus  on  Cacao  Farmers  in  Cooperatives  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  

 Abstract  

This  thesis  evaluates  the  direct  effects  of  the  Fairtrade  International  (Fairtrade),  Rainforest  Alliance  (RA)  and  

UTZ  Certified  (UTZ)  certifications  on  smallholders’  net  incomes  (profit),  using  three  modes  of  inquiry:  a  

theoretical  evaluation  of  each  certifier’s  standards  and  activities,  a  literature  review,  and  econometric  

analyses  of  primary  data  from  cacao  producers  in  Côte  d’Ivoire.  It  seeks  to  inform  efforts  to  scale  up  these  

certifications,  particularly  in  the  West  African  cacao  sector,  the  primary  source  of  mass-­‐market  cacao,  and  

ensure  that  certification  benefits  producers.    

In  recent  years,  commodity  certifications  such  as  Fairtrade,  RA  and  UTZ  have  shown  robust  growth  

in  the  agricultural  sector,  and  cacao  in  particular.  Certifiers,  brand  owners  and  others  have  asserted  that  

certification  improves  farm-­‐level  profit,  via  factors  such  as  higher  prices,  and  better  farm  management  that  

increases  yield  and  reduces  expenditure.  However,  little  independent  research  has  explored  such  claims,  

particularly  for  cacao.  This  thesis  seeks  to  fill  gaps  in  understanding  using  a  comprehensive,  rigorous  

approach,  including  regressions  using  primary  data  from  certified  and  non-­‐certified  Ivorian  cacao  farmers.  

The  theoretical  evaluation,  literature  review  and  analyses  of  primary  data  indicate  that  certified  

producers’  profits  may  be  higher  than,  lower  than  or  equal  to  non-­‐certified  farmers,  depending  on  the  

context.  Certification  seems  to  impact  profit  largely  by  enabling  farmers  to  command  premiums  for  certified  

sales,  which  increase  average  farm  gate  price  for  total  output  sold.  Such  price  increases  may  be  small,  as  with  

the  Ivorian  sample.  The  theoretical  evaluation  and  literature  review  indicate  that  certification  is  associated  

with  varied  outcomes  for  yield  and  expenditures.  Regressions  using  the  primary  data  show  that  certification  

has  a  strong  effect  in  reducing  expenditures,  while  its  effect  on  yield  ranges  from  negative  to  positive.  

If  certifiers  and  their  partners  wish  to  improve  certified  producers’  profits,  they  can  take  numerous  

steps  to  address  factors  that  affect  farmers’  average  prices,  yields  and  expenditures,  and  certification  costs.  In  

some  cases,  this  will  require  broadening  the  scope  of  certification  training,  standards,  producer  services,  or  

implementation  partners  to  address  development  constraints  that  lie  beyond  the  scope  of  certifiers’  current  

requirements,  activities  and  capabilities.    

 

  iii  

Table  of  Contents,  Tables  and  Figures    

Abstract  ……………………………………….………………………………………………………….……………………………ii  Acknowledgments  …………………………………………………………………………………….…………………..………v  Acronyms  and  Abbreviations…………………………………………………………………….…………………………vii  

Chapter  1.  Introduction  ......................................................................................................................  1  

Chapter  2.  Certification  and  its  Potential  Effects  on  Smallholders’  Net  Incomes  ...........  5  2.1  Certification  Scope  ...................................................................................................................................  5  2.2  Certification  Standards  and  Processes  for  Smallholder  Groups  ..............................................  8  2.3  Theoretical  Effects:  Pricing,  Output  and  Expenditures  .............................................................  11  2.3.1  Theoretical  Effects:  Pricing  ............................................................................................................................  11  2.3.2  Theoretical  Effects:  Output  Produced  and  Sold  as  Certified  ...........................................................  16  2.3.3  Theoretical  Effects:  Costs  and  Expenditures  .........................................................................................  19  

2.4  Conclusion  ................................................................................................................................................  22  Chapter  3.  Literature  Review  .........................................................................................................  24  3.1  Literature  Scope  .....................................................................................................................................  24  3.2  Design  and  Methods  ..............................................................................................................................  26  3.3  Findings  From  Prior  Research  ...........................................................................................................  30  3.4  Conclusion  ................................................................................................................................................  34  

Chapter  4.  Côte  d’Ivoire  and  the  Cacao  Sector  ..........................................................................  36  4.1  Côte  d’Ivoire  .............................................................................................................................................  36  4.2  Cacao  Value  Chain    .................................................................................................................................  37  4.3  Cacao  Production  and  Processing  ....................................................................................................  38  4.4  Cacao  Price  Determination  .................................................................................................................  40  4.5  Market  Power  ..........................................................................................................................................  41  4.6  Supply  and  Demand  ..............................................................................................................................  42  4.7  Production  Constraints  ........................................................................................................................  44  4.8  Cacao  Development  Projects  ..............................................................................................................  45  4.9  Conclusion  ................................................................................................................................................  48  

Chapter  5.  Field  Research  ................................................................................................................  49  5.1  Design  and  Sample  .................................................................................................................................  49  5.2  Data  Collection  and  Survey  Instruments  .......................................................................................  52  5.3  Data  Analyses  ..........................................................................................................................................  53  5.3.1  Differences  in  Means,  and  Certification  Effects  on  Price  ..................................................................  53  5.3.2  Yield  and  Variable  Cash  Expenditure  Regressions  ..............................................................................  54  

5.4  Results  .......................................................................................................................................................  56  5.4.1  Differences  in  Means,  and  Certification  Effects  on  Price  ..................................................................  58  5.4.2  Yield  Regressions  ...............................................................................................................................................  64  5.4.3:  Variable  Expenditure  Regressions  ............................................................................................................  69  

5.5  Conclusion  ................................................................................................................................................  72  Chapter  6.  Conclusions  .....................................................................................................................  74  6.1  Effects  and  Limits  of  Certification  ....................................................................................................  74  6.2  Recommendations  for  Improving  Certification  Outcomes  ......................................................  77  

References  ...........................................................................................................................................................  80  Appendix  A:  Survey  Instruments  .................................................................................................................  88  

A1.  Producer  Survey  ....................................................................................................................................................  88  A2.  Co-­‐op  Management  Interview:  Certified  Co-­‐ops  .....................................................................................  96  

 

  iv  

A3.  Co-­‐op  Management  Interview:  Non-­‐Certified  Co-­‐ops  ...........................................................................  98  Appendix  B:  Additional  Data  .........................................................................................................................  99    Tables  Table  2.1:  Certifications:  Key  Attributes  for  Cacao  .....................................................................................................  8  Table  2.2:  Possible  Effects  of  Certification  on  Producer  Prices  ..........................................................................  11  Table  2.3:  Possible  Effects  of  Certification  on  Output  and  Certified  Sales  Volume  ....................................  16  Table  2.4:  Possible  Effects  of  Certification  on  Producer  Costs  and  Expenditures  ......................................  19  Table  3.1:  Literature  Reviewed  ........................................................................................................................................  25  Table  3.2:  Certification  Literature  Scope  ......................................................................................................................  26  Table  3.3:  Study  Design  and  Methods  ............................................................................................................................  27  Table  3.4:  Findings  on  Relationships  Between  Certification,  and  Net  Income  and  Its  Components  d  31  Table  4.1:  Côte  d’Ivoire  Country  Statistics,  2012  ......................................................................................................  37  Table  5.1:  Sample  Distribution  .........................................................................................................................................  50  Table  5.2:  Producer  Summary  Statistics,  Full  Sample,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season  ...........................................  57  Table  5.3:  Differences  in  Means  Between  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls,  Regression  Variables  and  

Economic  Outcomes,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season  ....................................................................................................  59  Table  5.4:  Differences  in  Means  Between  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls  By  Certification  Type,  

Economic  Outcomes,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season  ....................................................................................................  60  Table  5.5:  Summary  Statistics  for  Certified  and  Control  Co-­‐ops,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season  .......................  61  Table  5.6:  Yield  Regression  Models  ................................................................................................................................  65  Table  5.7:  Total  Intercept  Shift  for  Certification  Dummies,  Yield  Regressions  ...........................................  66  Table  5.8:  Estimated  Total  Effect  of  Certification  on  Yield,  Total  Intercept  Shift,  and  Difference  in  

Means  .................................................................................................................................................................................  67  Table  5.9:  Variable  Cash  Expenditure  Regression  Models  ....................................................................................  69  Table  5.10:  Total  Intercept  Shift  for  Certification  Dummies,  Expenditure  ....................................................  70  Table  5.11:  Estimated  Total  Effect  of  Certification  on  Expenditure,  All  Models  .........................................  70  

 Table  B1:  Summary  Statistics,  Certified  Producers  &  Controls,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season  .........................  99  Table  B2:  Means  For  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls  By  Region,  Agronomic  Inputs  and  Economic  Outcomes  ..................................................................................................................................................................................  101  Table  B3:  Differences  in  Means  Between  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls,  2012-­‐13  Season    .............  103  Table  B4:  Means  For  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls  By  Certification  Type  ..............................................  105  Table  B5:  Significant  Differences  Between  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls  By  Certification  Type,  Economic  Outcomes  and  Agronomic  Inputs  .............................................................................................................  107    Figures  Figure  2.4:  Demand  Curves  for  Differentiated  (Certified)  and  Conventional  Goods  ................................  12  Figure  2.5:  Fairtrade  Cacao  Price  with  Premium,  and  World  Price,  1993  to  2014    ...................................  15  Figure  4.1:  Cacao  Value  Chain  for  Côte  d’Ivoire  Smallholders  ............................................................................  38  Figure  4.2:  World  Cacao  Prices,  Yearly  Average,  1993  to  2014  .........................................................................  41  Figure  4.3:  Global  Cacao  Production  and  Grindings,  2005  to  2014  ..................................................................  43  Figure  5.1  Research  Sites  ....................................................................................................................................................  51    

   

   

 

  v  

Acknowledgments    Many  individuals  contributed  to  this  thesis,  and  to  them  I  am  indebted.  I  extend  my  deepest  

gratitude  to  Rich  Sexton,  my  thesis  chair.  He  offered  extensive,  invaluable  and  multi-­‐faceted  support  

in  all  phases  of  this  work,  from  ideation  through  completion.  Despite  his  many  commitments,  he  

was  extremely  generous  in  sharing  his  time  to  review  and  discuss  multiple  iterations  of  funding  

proposals,  survey  instruments,  data  analyses  and  thesis  chapters;  and  also  contributed  funding  for  

fieldwork.  Rich  provided  thorough,  thoughtful,  laser-­‐sharp  and  candid  feedback,  and  set  high  

standards,  driving  me  to  think  more  deeply  and  improve  my  work.  He  also  offered  moral  support  

and  inspiration  just  when  I  needed  it,  and  was  patient  through  my  learning  process.  I  could  not  

have  asked  for  a  better  chair.  

I  also  thank  my  other  committee  members,  Jim  Chalfant  and  Tu  Jarvis,  for  giving  their  time  

to  review  and  advise  on  multiple  rounds  of  data  analyses,  and  provide  incredibly  helpful,  

comprehensive  comments  on  draft  chapters.  Jim  is  a  fantastic  econometrician,  and  his  input  greatly  

advanced  the  regression  analyses  in  particular.  Tu  is  a  seasoned  developmental  economist  whose  

insightful  exchanges  helped  me  evaluate  and  articulate  many  concepts  much  better.  He  also  

suggested  alternate  yield  regression  models  to  explore  regional  effects.  Along  with  Rich,  they  were  

an  exceptional  team.  

Much  appreciation  goes  to  the  World  Agroforestry  Center  (ICRAF)  in  Côte  d’Ivoire,  

particularly  Christophe  Kouame,  Amos  Gyau,  Yao  Eric,  Colombe  Loba  and  Jean-­‐Noël.  ICRAF  hosted  

me  as  a  research  fellow  and  I  simply  could  not  have  done  my  fieldwork  without  them.  Christophe  

and  Amos  helped  refine  the  design  and  survey  instruments,  and  championed  the  work  throughout  

my  time  in  country.  Yao  Eric,  Colombe  and  Jean-­‐Noël  helped  with  logistics,  playing  key  roles  to  keep  

things  moving  under  a  tight  schedule.  ICRAF  also  contributed  significant  in-­‐kind  support,  including  

a  field  coordinator,  transportation,  and  surveyors  for  one  region,  greatly  improving  the  smoothness  

and  success  of  fieldwork.  

 

  vi  

The  field  research  team  deserves  special  commendation  for  their  tremendous  work.  Niava  

Landry,  the  field  coordinator,  has  extensive  expertise  in  cacao  surveys,  and  was  an  incredible  asset  

in  budgeting,  scheduling  surveys  and  managing  the  enumerators.  The  enumerators,  Abié  Cynthia  

Elodie,  Aka  Mel  Roland,  Anzan  Komenan  Yaya,  Assetou  Zitkoum,  Kouassi  Sainte  Sebastienne  Aya  

and  Niava  Eric,  are  well-­‐experienced  and  terrific  to  work  with.  I  am  extremely  grateful  to  have  had  

such  a  trustworthy,  skilled  team.  They  maintained  a  positive  attitude  and  delivered  high-­‐quality  

work  through  the  rigors  of  fieldwork.  

Additionally,  I  thank  the  representatives  of  certifiers  and  industry  members  who  took  time  

out  of  their  busy  schedules  for  interviews,  providing  essential  background  on  certification  and  the  

dynamic,  complex  context  in  which  it  operates.  IAD  alumna  Kaity  Smoot  was  a  vital  source  of  

information  as  I  was  formulating  my  thesis,  and  connected  me  to  ICRAF,  helping  me  obtain  the  

research  fellowship.  Despite  being  based  in  Côte  ‘Ivoire,  and  facing  sizeable  research  and  work  

commitments,  Kaity  was  always  quick  to  provide  detailed  information.  Having  such  a  

knowledgeable  on-­‐the-­‐ground  informant  was  invaluable.  

The  University  of  California,  Davis  provided  funding  for  fieldwork  via  a  Jastro  Research  

Grant.  Without  this  grant,  the  fieldwork  would  have  been  cost  prohibitive.  Thanks  to  Theresa  Costa  

and  Mary  Lieth  for  facilitating  the  funding  process.  Thanks  and  hugs  to  family  and  friends  who  

encouraged  me  along  the  way;  and  to  my  parents  for  cultivating  a  dedication  to  education,  curiosity,  

critical  inquiry,  hard  work  and  a  job  well  done.        

Last  but  not  least,  a  deep  merci  to  the  farmers  and  co-­‐op  representatives  who  took  time  

away  from  their  farms  and  work  to  participate  in  surveys  and  interviews,  and  for  the  hard  work  

they  do  in  order  to  provide  the  world  with  cacao.  They  welcomed  the  research  team  into  their  

offices,  villages  and  farms,  patiently  answered  many  questions,  and  provided  meals  on  occasion.  I  

hope  to  be  able  to  repay  their  generosity  through  work  that  fosters  lasting  livelihoods  

improvements  for  cacao  smallholders,  which  was  the  motivation  for  this  thesis.  

 

  vii  

Acronyms  and  Abbreviations    

ANADER   Ivorian  national  agricultural  extension  

CCC     Le  Conseil  du  Café-­‐Cacao  (Côte  d’Ivoire  coffee  and  cocoa  board)  

COSA       Committee  on  Sustainability  Assessment  

Fairtrade   Fairtrade  International  certification  

FLO     Fairtrade  International,  Fairtrade-­‐only  certification  

FTO     Fairtrade  and  Organic  dual  certified  

HDI     Human  Development  Index  

ICCO     International  Cocoa  Organization  

ICRAF     World  Agroforestry  Center  

IDH     IDH,  The  Sustainable  Trade  Initiative  

IITA     International  Institute  of  Tropical  Agriculture    

IPM       Integrated  Pest  Management  

PSM     Propensity  Score  Matching  

SAN     Sustainable  Agriculture  Network  

SPO     Small  Producer  Organization  (in  Fairtrade)  

STCP     Sustainable  Tree  Crops  Program  

RA     Rainforest  Alliance  

TCC     Tropical  Commodity  Coalition  

UN     United  Nations  

UNDP     United  Nations  Development  Program  

UTZ     UTZ  Certified  

 

 

  1  

Chapter  1. Introduction    

This  thesis  evaluates  the  direct  effects  of  the  Fairtrade  International  (Fairtrade),  Rainforest  Alliance  

(RA)  and  UTZ  Certified  (UTZ)  certifications  on  smallholders’  net  incomes  (profit).  It  considers  this  

question  using  three  methods:  a  theoretical  evaluation  of  each  certifier’s  standards  and  activities,  a  

literature  review,  and  econometric  analyses  of  primary  data  from  cacao  producers  in  Côte  d’Ivoire.  

It  aims  to  inform  efforts  to  scale  up  these  certifications,  particularly  in  the  West  African  cacao  

sector,  the  primary  source  of  mass-­‐market  cacao,  and  ensure  that  certification  benefits  producers.  

This  thesis  does  not  seek  to  analyze  the  economic  impacts  of  certification  that  result  from  producer  

group  management  training,  premium  investments  at  the  producer  group  and  community  levels,  or  

farm  management  practices  that  protect  and  restore  natural  resources.  As  such,  it  does  not  evaluate  

the  indirect  effects  that  farmers  may  realize,  or  total  welfare  more  broadly.  

In  recent  years,  sustainable  commodity  certifications  such  as  Fairtrade,  RA  and  UTZ  have  

shown  robust  growth  in  the  agricultural  sector,  and  cacao  in  particular  (Potts  et  al.  2014).  Such  

labels  have  moved  from  the  niche  to  the  mainstream  and  appear  to  be  on  a  continued  growth  

trajectory  in  cacao,  as  major  chocolate  companies  such  as  The  Hershey  Company,  Mars  and  Ferrero  

Rocher  have  committed  to  sourcing  100%  certified  sustainable  cacao  (Tropical  Commodity  

Coalition  2012).  As  of  2013,  UTZ  (2014a)  estimated  that  22  percent  of  global  cacao  supply  bore  at  

least  one  such  certification.    

Certifiers,  brand  owners  and  others  have  asserted  that  certification  helps  improve  

producers’  profits  via  factors  such  as  higher  prices,  better  agricultural  practices  that  boost  yield,  

and  more  efficient  farm  management  that  reduces  expenditure.  However,  little  independent  

research  has  explored  these  claims,  particularly  with  respect  to  cacao.  Moreover  there  is  no  single  

international  third-­‐party  agency  that  oversees  certifiers,  who  have  developed  their  standards  and  

gained  credibility  by  engaging  various  civil  society,  industry,  consumer  and  government  

 

  2  

stakeholders.  Given  that  certification  involves  added  costs  for  producers  and  buyers,  and  often  

consumers,  and  that  entities  across  the  value  chain  invest  in  certification  efforts  on  the  basis  of  its  

purported  benefits,  it  is  imperative  to  undertake  a  careful,  independent  evaluation  of  how  cacao  

certification  affects  farmers’  net  incomes.    

To  fill  this  gap,  this  thesis  evaluates  the  effects  of  the  Fairtrade,  RA  and  UTZ  certifications  

(“target  certifications”)  on  producers’  net  incomes,  on  a  broad  level,  and  with  specific  reference  to  

Ivorian  cacao  farmers  in  cooperatives,  by:1  

• Undertaking  a  theoretical  evaluation  of  how  certifiers’  standards  and  producer  engagement  

activities  could  affect  net  income  (profit)  and  its  components:  output,  price  and  expenditures  

• Synthesizing  empirical  research  that  has  focused  on  how  certification  modulates  net  income  

and  its  components  among  smallholders,  across  diverse  crops  and  countries  

• Comparing  farm-­‐level  outcomes  for  net  income  and  its  components,  across  certified  and  non-­‐

certified  cacao  producers  in  Côte  d’Ivoire,  to  determine  whether  certification  is  associated  with  

improved  outcomes  

• Comparing  performance  across  certified  and  non-­‐certified  Ivorian  cacao  farmers  in  factors  that  

may  affect  net  income  and  its  components  (e.g.,  input  use,  farm  management  practices),  to  

understand  how  groups  differ  for  such  explanatory  variables  

• Using  regressions  to  determine  how  certification  and  other  factors  contribute  to  differences  in  

yield  and  expenditures  among  Ivorian  cacao  farmers,  while  controlling  for  selection  bias  related  

to  certification  

This  thesis  uses  Cote  d'Ivoire  as  a  case  study  because  it  is  the  world's  number  one  cacao  

producer,  providing  about  36%  of  the  world's  supply  (ICCO  2014b),  and  has  seen  a  steady  increase  

in  cacao  certification.  The  country  has  about  900,000  cacao  farms,  predominantly  smallholdings  

                                                                                                                         1  Fair  Trade  USA,  an  independent  Fair  Trade  certifier,  was  a  member  of  FLO  through  12/31/11  then  became  independent.  It  is  not  included  here  because  it  was  still  using  FLO’s  standards  and  had  not  certified  any  new  producers  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  when  fieldwork  was  completed.    

 

  3  

averaging  3  hectares  (ICCO  undated).  Cacao  is  the  main  source  of  income  for  about  75  percent  of  

the  rural  population  and  provides  employment  for  over  four  million  people  (Hatløy  et.  al  2012).  

Approximately  43  percent  of  the  population  lives  below  the  poverty  line.  Given  the  significance  of  

cacao  for  rural  welfare,  and  the  extent  of  poverty,  there  is  value  in  evaluating  the  effects  of  

certification  on  cacao  farmers’  net  incomes.    

The  target  certifications  could  affect  producers’  prices,  output  produced  and  sold  as  

certified,  and  expenditures  in  different  ways,  making  it  difficult  to  predict  the  direction  or  

magnitude  of  net  income  effects.  For  most  commodities,  Fairtrade  has  mandatory  minimum  prices  

that  include  above-­‐market  premiums  (Fairtrade  International  2011b).  In  the  absence  of  price  

guarantees,  certified  commodities  are  differentiated  goods  that  can  command  a  premium  when  the  

market  places  added  value  on  their  attributes.  The  target  certifications  require  crop  management  

practices  that  can  improve  yields,  such  as  soil  fertility  management,  but  also  mandate  ecosystem  

conservation  measures  that  could  reduce  planted  area  (e.g.,  buffers  for  pesticide  application  and  

riparian  areas),  and  thus  total  output.    

On  the  expenditure  side,  certification  involves  expenses  for  audits,  management  systems  

and  record  keeping  at  the  group  level,  while  individual  producers  may  need  to  increase  farm-­‐level  

spending  and/or  family  labor  time  to  comply  with  certification  requirements  (e.g.,  more  labor  for  

pruning).  However,  producers  also  may  realize  expenditure  reductions  through  more  efficient  farm  

management  (e.g.,  pesticide  application)  as  a  result  of  certification  training.  This  thesis  explores  

how  certification  modulates  each  component  of  net  income  separately,  enabling  more  informed  

predictions  about  its  net  effects.  

This  research  is  novel  in  undertaking  an  independent  evaluation  of  how  different  

certifications  affect  net  income  and  its  components,  combining  a  theoretical  evaluation,  a  broad-­‐

based  literature  review,  and  econometric  analyses  of  primary  data  from  certified  farmers  and  

comparable  controls.  Much  of  the  initial  field  research  in  this  area  was  initiated  by  certifiers,  

 

  4  

focused  on  gross  revenue  or  prices  rather  than  cost-­‐benefit  measures  such  as  net  income,  and  often  

lacked  controls  (see  Arnould  et.  al.  2009,  CEval  2012).  Independent  studies  with  controls  have  since  

increased,  generally  utilizing  basic  statistical  methods  such  as  ANOVAS  and  t-­‐tests  to  compare  

price,  yield,  revenue  and  net  income  across  certified  and  non-­‐certified  producers  (Valkila  and  

Nygren  2008,  Giovannucci  and  Potts  2010,  Ruben  and  Zúñiga  2011).    

A  few  studies  have  used  higher-­‐level  statistical  approaches  to  control  for  selection  bias,  and  

quantify  the  effects  of  certification  and  other  attributes  on  net  income,  in  order  to  attain  more  valid  

conclusions.  Such  methods  include  propensity  score  matching  (Ruben  and  Fort  2012)  and  two-­‐

stage  regressions  using  the  Heckman  correction  (Becchetti  and  Costantino  2008).  Overall,  prior  

work  has  found  that  certified  producers’  relative  outcomes  vary  within  and  across  certifications,  

crops  and  regions,  indicating  the  need  for  further  inquiry.  Finally,  most  research  has  focused  on  

Fairtrade  coffee  in  the  Latin  American  specialty  sector  (Chan  and  Pound  2009).  This  thesis  fills  gaps  

in  geographic,  crop  and  market  coverage  by  assessing  the  Fairtrade,  RA  and  UTZ  certifications  in  

the  mainstream  cacao  sector  in  Côte  d'Ivoire.  It  uses  regressions  to  estimate  the  effects  of  

certification  and  other  variables  on  yield  and  expenditure,  while  controlling  for  selection  bias.  

Chapter  2  introduces  the  target  certifications  and  undertakes  a  broad  theoretical  evaluation  

of  their  potential  effects  on  the  components  of  smallholders’  net  incomes,  irrespective  of  crop  or  

region.  Chapter  3  presents  a  review  of  relevant  literature,  characterizing  the  scope,  methodologies,  

findings,  strengths  and  limitations  of  prior  research,  and  implications  for  further  studies.  Chapter  4  

offers  background  on  cacao  production  and  trade  with  a  focus  on  Côte  d’Ivoire,  providing  a  solid  

grounding  in  the  fieldwork  context.  Chapter  5  presents  the  results  of  fieldwork  in  Côte  d’Ivoire.  

Chapter  6  summarizes  conclusions  across  each  mode  of  inquiry,  and  offers  recommendations  for  

ways  that  certifiers  and  others  can  improve  economic  outcomes  among  certified  farmers.  

 

 

  5  

Chapter  2. Certification  and  its  Potential  Effects  on  Smallholders’  Net  Incomes  

The  analysis  of  the  effects  of  certification  on  smallholders’  net  incomes  begins  with  a  comparison  of  

their  scopes,  standards  and  certification  processes;  and  a  theoretical  evaluation  of  their  potential  

impacts  for  all  applicable  commodities  and  regions,  with  cacao  used  as  an  illustrative  example.  This  

discussion  focuses  on  smallholders  who  are  organized  in  groups  because  they  predominate  in  cacao  

and  were  the  focus  of  my  fieldwork.  Section  2.1  outlines  each  certification’s  scope,  and  identifies  

ways  in  which  they  overlap  and  differ.  Section  2.2  presents  a  broad  view  of  each  certification’s  

requirements  and  the  processes  that  producers  face  to  become  certified,  providing  background  for  

a  discussion  of  specific  criteria.  Section  2.3  identifies  specific  certification  requirements  and  

certifier  activities  (e.g.,  training)  that  could  affect  the  components  of  net  income:  farm  gate  price,  

output  produced  and  sold  as  certified,  and  farm-­‐level  expenditures,  and  discusses  possible  effects.  

As  a  point  of  clarification,  for  cacao,  this  thesis  defines  smallholders  as  family  farms  that  

rely  primarily  on  family  labor.  Additionally,  the  terms  producers  and  farmers  refer  to  individual  

smallholders,  while  producer  group  refers  to  a  collective  marketing  entity  that  sells  members’  

aggregated  production,  such  as  a  cooperative,  association  or  contract  production  scheme.  The  

terms  yield  and  productivity  are  used  interchangeably,  and  denote  crop  volume  per  land  unit,  while  

output  refers  to  a  farm’s  total  production.  

2.1  Certification  Scope    

Fairtrade  International  (FLO)  is  focused  on  improving  producer  livelihoods,  with  a  mission  “to  

connect  disadvantaged  producers  and  consumers,  promote  fairer  trading  conditions;  and  empower  

producers  to  combat  poverty,  strengthen  their  position  and  take  more  control  over  their  lives”  (FLO  

2011b).  Following  from  its  mission,  its  theory  of  change  asserts  that  its  floor  prices,  premiums,  

required  pre-­‐financing  from  buyers,  group  governance  criteria,  and  efforts  to  increase  Fairtrade  

market  access  and  demand,  are  the  means  by  which  it  improves  farmers’  incomes  (FLO  2013c).    

 

  6  

The  Fairtrade  label  (Figure  2.1)  applies  to  multiple  commodities  

including  bananas,  cacao,  coffee,  cotton,  fruit,  fruit  juices,  honey,  sugar,  

vegetables,  gold,  and  sports  balls  (FLO  2011a).  Democratically  run  

smallholder  groups,  contract  production  schemes  and  hired  labor  

operations  can  become  “certified  producer  organizations,”  with  

certification  limited  to  smallholder  groups  for  cacao,  coffee,  sugar  

and  tea.2  FLO  supports  producers  with  credit  via  its  “Fair  Trade  Access  Fund,”  and  provides  

technical  assistance  through  its  regional  producer  networks  (FLO  2014b).    

According  to  FLO’s  2013-­‐14  Annual  Report,  Fairtrade  certification  involves  1,210  certified  

producer  organizations  that  represent  over  1,400,000  farmers  and  workers  in  74  countries  (FLO  

2014b).  Fairtrade  certified  its  first  cacao  producer  group  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  in  2004  (Fair  Trade  USA  

2010).  As  of  2012,  Fairtrade  cacao  production  involved  166,900  farmers  from  122  producer  groups  

in  19  countries,  with  52  groups  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  (FLO  2013a).  That  year,  Fairtrade  cacao  production  

totaled  175,900  metric  tons  (MT),  representing  4.3  percent  of  global  supply.  Buyers  purchased  

68,300  MT  of  Fairtrade  certified  cacao,  amounting  to  39  percent  of  certified  output,  through  

Fairtrade  contracts.  This  represents  a  47  percent  increase  in  Fairtrade  cacao  sales  over  2011.3  

Rainforest  Alliance  (RA)  seeks  to  foster  market-­‐driven  

conservation,  with  a  mission  “to  conserve  biodiversity  and  ensure  

sustainable  livelihoods  by  transforming  land-­‐use  practices,  business  

practices  and  consumer  behavior”  (RA  2014c).  The  Rainforest  Alliance  

CertifiedTM  label  (Figure  2.2)  applies  to  over  100  agricultural  

commodities  including  bananas,  cattle,  coffee,  cacao,  flowers,  palm  oil  

                                                                                                                         2  For  cacao  and  other  crops  categorized  as  “less  labor  intensive”  (coffee,  herbs,  honey  and  spices),  FLO  defines  smallholders  as  those  who  rely  primarily  on  family  labor  and  do  not  hire  labor  year  round.  FLO  does  not  use  farm  size  to  determine  whether  producers  of  such  crops  are  smallholders  (FLO  2012).  3  Output  that  producers  do  not  sell  as  Fairtrade  may  be  sold  under  other  certifications  or  contracts,  or  on  the  conventional  market.  

Figure  2.1:  Fairtrade  Label  Source:  fairtrade.net  

Figure  2.2:  RA  Label  Source:  rainforest-­‐

alliance.org  

 

  7  

and  tea  (RA  2014a).  Individual  farms  and  groups  of  various  forms  (e.g.,  cooperative,  association,  

contract  production  schemes)  can  become  certified  (RA  2014b).  RA  assists  certified  producers  by  

connecting  them  with  lenders,  offering  guidance  on  business  and  financial  management,  and  

providing  technical  assistance.  As  of  2013,  900,000  farms  were  RA  certified  (RA  2013b).  That  year,  

RA-­‐certified  farms  produced  14.5  percent  of  the  world’s  cacao,  14  percent  of  tea  and  5.2  percent  of  

coffee.  In  2013,  RA-­‐certified  cacao  production  was  571,695  MT,  with  48  percent  sold  on  RA  terms  

(Nieberg  2014).    

UTZ  Certified’s  (UTZ)  mission  is  “to  create  a  world  where  sustainable  farming  is  the  norm”  

(UTZ  2014a).  Its  theory  of  change  posits  that  its  certification  criteria  on  

farm  management,  and  its  marketing  efforts  for  UTZ-­‐certified  goods,  lead  

to  improved  farm  yields,  revenues  and  profits  (UTZ  2014c).  Its  label  

(Figure  2.3)  applies  to  cacao,  coffee,  hazelnuts,  tea  and  rooibos  (UTZ  

2014b),  from  large,  individual  farms  (hired  labor)  and  various  types  of  

producer  groups.  UTZ  offers  technical  assistance  to  help  producers  meet  

specific  goals,  such  as  reducing  greenhouse  gas  emissions  and  conserving  water.  

UTZ  launched  its  cacao  certification  in  2007,  and  certified  its  first  Ivorian  cacao  co-­‐ops  in  

2009.  As  of  2013,  there  were  1,800  UTZ-­‐certified  entities  representing  over  500,000  farms  (UTZ  

2014c).  In  2013,  over  17.5  percent  of  global  cacao  supply  was  certified  to  UTZ  standards,  coming  

from  336,351  smallholders  and  40  estates  in  16  countries.  Buyers  purchased  295,084  MT  of  cacao  

under  UTZ  certified  contracts  that  year,  representing  42  percent  of  UTZ  production,  and  a  149  

percent  increase  in  certified  sales  over  2012  (Nieberg  2014,  UTZ  2014c).  

Table  2.1  summarizes  key  attributes  of  each  label’s  scope  with  respect  to  cacao.  While  

certification  criteria  overlap  in  many  ways,  Fairtrade  focuses  on  producer  empowerment  and  price  

in  particular,  RA  prioritizes  market-­‐driven  conservation,  and  UTZ  emphasizes  farmer  and  group    

Figure  2.3:  UTZ  Certified  label          

Source:  utzcertified.org  

 

  8  

Table  2.1:  Certifications:  Key  Attributes  for  Cacao  

  Fairtrade    (2012)  

Rainforest  Alliance  (2013)  

UTZ  Certified  (2013)  

Primary  focus   Improve  farmer  and  group  empowerment,  ensure  “fair”  prices  

Foster  environmental  conservation  and  sustainable  livelihoods  

Mainstream  sustainable  farming,  professionalize  farm  and  group  mgmt.    

Producers   166,900   N/R   336,351  Production  (MT)   176,000     571,695   691,491  Percent  traded  as  certified  

39%    

48%   42%  

Percent  of  Global  Supply  

4.3%   14.5%   17.5%  

Certified  entities   Democratic  smallholder  groups;  contract  production  schemes  in  SE  Asia  

Smallholder  groups  of  various  forms  (association,  co-­‐op,  contract  production  scheme,  multi-­‐farm  operation,  communal  lands),  large  farms  

Smallholder  groups  of  various  forms,  large  farms  

Required  Price   $2,000  floor  price  and  $200  premium  per  MT  

No   No  

Premiums  Paid  to  Certified  Org’s  a  

$11.8  mil  total,    Avg.  $71/producer    

Not  reported   ~  $49.9  mil  total,    Avg.  $150/producer  

a  FLO’s  reported  9,433,900  euros,  and  UTZ’s  reported  13,000,000  euros,  converted  to  USD  at  xe.com  using  5/28/12  exchange  rate  (middle  of  cacao  season).    Sources:  FLO  2013a,  FLO  2014b,  ICCO  2014b,  RA  2013,  Nieberg  2014,  SAN  2011b,  UTZ  2014b,  UTZ  2014c      professionalization.  UTZ  has  the  most  producers  and  output,  and  Fairtrade  has  the  least.  Overall,  

certified  producers  sell  less  than  half  of  their  output  at  certified  terms,  with  RA  farmers  having  the  

highest  rate  of  certified  sales.  Fairtrade  is  the  only  certifier  that  sets  prices  and  limits  certification  

to  democratic  smallholder  groups  for  the  most  part,  while  RA  and  UTZ  certify  more  diverse  entities.  

Due  to  the  fact  that  many  farms  hold  more  than  one  certification,  total  supply  of  cacao  produced  

under  at  least  one  of  the  target  certifications  is  estimated  to  be  22  percent  of  global  output  (UTZ  

2014a).  

2.2  Certification  Standards  and  Processes  for  Smallholder  Groups  

The  standards  documents  identified  here  were  used  to  characterize  certification  requirements,  and  

identify  criteria  with  material  effects  on  net  income.  Certification  content  overlaps  quite  a  bit  at  a  

 

  9  

broad  level,  though  specific  requirements  differ,  as  seen  in  Section  2.3.  Fairtrade  smallholders  must  

comply  with  the  Small  Producer  Organizations  (SPO)  Standard  (FLO  2011c),  which  defines  

requirements  for  groups  and  farmers  in  the  areas  of  labor,  safety,  farm  management,  

environmental  protection,  group  governance,  and  compliance  management;  and  crop-­‐specific  

standards  such  as  the  Fairtrade  Standard  for  Cocoa  for  SPOs  (FLO  2013b).4  RA  producers  must  

adhere  to  the  Sustainable  Agriculture  Network’s  (SAN)  Sustainable  Agriculture  Standard  (SAN  

2010),  which  states  farm-­‐level  requirements  for  labor,  safety,  crop  management,  environmental  

protection  and  community  relations;  the  Group  Certification  Standard  (2011a),  which  dictates  the  

group  administrator’s  responsibilities  for  training,  capacity  building,  risk  assessment  and  

compliance  management;  and  applicable  crop-­‐specific  modules.    

As  of  2014,  UTZ-­‐certified  producers  must  adhere  to  a  Code  of  Conduct  (UTZ  2014d)  that  

covers  all  crops  and  organizational  forms;  and  commodity-­‐specific  modules  such  as  the  Cocoa  

Module  (UTZ  2014e).  Prior  to  2014,  UTZ  used  a  self-­‐contained  Code  of  Conduct  for  each  commodity  

and  organizational  form  (e.g.,  group,  plantation),  such  as  the  Cocoa  Code  for  smallholder  groups  

(UTZ  2009).5  The  theoretical  analysis  considers  both  the  prior  and  current  Codes,  in  order  to  

provide  a  means  for  interpreting  prior  research  and  the  data  collected  for  this  thesis,  and  posit  

theoretical  effects  moving  forward.  The  Cocoa  Code  and  the  Core  Code  of  Conduct  combine  

requirements  for  producers  and  the  “certificate  holder”  (group  administrator),  and  cover  labor,  

safety,  crop  production,  environment,  compliance  management,  and  community  engagement.  The  

Cocoa  Module  addresses  farm  maintenance  and  post-­‐harvest  processing.  All  certifications  identify  

                                                                                                                         4  To  qualify  as  an  SPO,  at  least  half  of  the  group’s  traded  volume  must  come  from  smallholders,  and  smallholders  must  comprise  at  least  half  of  the  group’s  membership  (FLO  2011c).  5  For  some  crops,  SAN  also  has  developed  additional  modules  specific  to  a  given  crop  in  a  given  country,  such  as  cacao  in  Ghana.  

 

  10  

prohibited  agrochemicals,  following  from  international  conventions  banning  the  most  toxic  

substances.6    

The  certification  process  is  largely  similar  across  certifications.  Auditors  conduct  annual  

audits  of  group  operations  and  records,  and  a  subset  of  farms.7  Fairtrade  grants  certification  to  

groups  as  a  whole  only,  while  RA  and  UTZ  allow  groups  to  certify  only  a  subset  of  members  (Buyo  

2013,  Laan  and  Guilhuis  2014).  Thus,  RA  and  UTZ  producers  are  able  to  align  certified  supply  with  

demand,  and  avoid  paying  certification  fees  on  crop  they  will  sell  as  conventional,  while  Fairtrade  

producers  are  unable  to  do  so.  For  RA  and  UTZ,  the  certificate  holder  must  inspect  all  certified  

farms  before  an  external  audit  (SAN  2011a,  UTZ  2014d).  RA  and  UTZ  allow  third  parties  such  as  

buyers  to  hold  and  manage  the  certificate.  

Each  certification  has  a  set  of  minimum  criteria  needed  to  attain  certification,  and  increases  

the  number  of  criteria  needed  to  maintain  certification  over  time.  This  indicates  that  related  cost  

increases  may  be  spread  out  over  several  years,  and  thus  may  be  more  manageable  than  a  single  

up-­‐front  increase.  Fairtrade  producers  must  meet  all  “core”  requirements  for  a  given  year,  and  

attain  a  minimum  score  for  “development”  requirements  (FLO  2012).  The  number  of  requirements  

increases  through  the  first  six  years.  RA  producers  must  meet  all  “critical”  criteria,  50  percent  of  the  

criteria  under  each  principle,  and  80  percent  of  total  criteria  in  year  one  (SAN  2010,  SAN  2011a).8  

They  must  satisfy  at  least  85  percent  and  90  percent  of  total  criteria  in  the  second  and  third  years,  

respectively  (SAN  2010,  SAN  2011a).  UTZ  producers  must  satisfy  all  “mandatory”  criteria  and  a  

                                                                                                                         6  Prohibited  agrochemicals  includes  those  that  are  banned  or  severely  restricted  by  the  U.S.  Environmental  Protection  Agency  or  the  European  Union,  banned  per  the  Stockholm  Convention  on  Persistent  Organic  Pollutants,  included  in  the  Rotterdam  Convention  on  Prior  Informed  Consent  Annex  II,  listed  on  the  Pesticide  Action  Network  Dirty  Dozen  list,  or  not  registered  in  the  production  country.  7  FLO  uses  FLOCERT,  an  independent  subsidiary  of  FLO  (FLO  2011c),  RA  uses  accredited  auditors  that  may  be  SAN  members  (RA-­‐Cert  2012),  and  UTZ  uses  independent  auditors.  Thus,  auditor  independence  varies  across  certifications.  8  An  exception  to  this  is  that,  in  groups  with  more  than  17  members,  the  group  can  pass  the  audit  if  at  least  80  percent  of  farms  meet  80  percent  of  total  criteria  and  the  remaining  farms  meet  70  to  80  percent  (SAN  2011a).  

 

  11  

minimum  number  of  “additional”  criteria  in  year  one.  Many  criteria  that  are  initially  additional  

become  mandatory  over  the  first  four  years.  

2.3  Theoretical  Effects:  Pricing,  Output  and  Expenditures  

Table  2.2  summarizes  the  ways  in  which  each  certifier’s  standards  and  activities  could  theoretically  

affect  producer  prices.  Each  is  detailed  below.  

 

Table  2.2:  Possible  Effects  of  Certification  on  Producer  Prices    

  Fairtrade   Rainforest  Alliance  

UTZ  2009  and  2014  

Differentiates  product  as  higher  quality  along  social  and  environmental  attributes  

Yes   Yes   Yes  

Differentiates  product  as  higher  physical  quality    

Possibly,  by  encouraging  or  requiring  premium  use  for  quality    

No   Possibly,  via    post-­‐harvest  processing  criteria  

Sets  prices   Minimum  price  and  premium  for  producer  groups  

No  requirements   No  requirements  

 

2.3.1  Theoretical  Effects:  Pricing    

Certifications  can  affect  producer  prices  by  differentiating  products  based  on  attributes  that  are  

perceived  as  enhancing  quality  and  result  in  a  higher  willingness  to  pay.  As  such,  certification  

enables  vertical  differentiation  because  consumers  would  rank-­‐order  the  relevant  qualities  the  

same  way,  and  agree  they  add  value  over  conventional  goods  (see  Saitone  and  Sexton  2010).  

Consumers  differ  in  the  actual  value  they  place  on  these  qualities,  however.  Thus,  willingness  to  pay  

is  highest  among  those  who  value  the  relevant  qualities  the  most,  and  average  willingness  to  pay  

decreases  as  we  include  consumers  who  value  them  less.  Figure  2.4  illustrates  a  simple  set  of  

demand  curves  for  certified  (differentiated)  and  conventional  commodities,  assuming  that  the  

premium  that  buyers  are  willing  to  pay  decreases  as  the  quantity  demanded  increases.  This  figure  

 

  12  

indicates  that  one  would  expect  premiums  for  certified  cacao  to  be  lower  as  certification  moves  

from  the  niche  to  the  mainstream,  as  it  has  for  cacao.  

 

Figure  2.4:  Demand  Curves  for  Differentiated  (Certified)  and  Conventional  Goods  

 

 

Per  Saitone  and  Sexton  (2010),  buyers  define  quality  using  diverse  traits,  from  physical  

characteristics  to  worker  treatment  and  environmental  impacts.  Certifications  can  indicate  two  

types  of  quality:  social  responsibility  attributes,  and  physical  attributes  that  affect  flavor  and  

processing  efficiency.  The  target  certifications  identify  commodities  as  being  more  socially  and  

environmentally  responsible  than  conventional  goods,  in  ways  that  align  with  consumer  

preferences.  Cone  Communications/ECHO  (2013)  surveyed  10,287  consumers  in  ten  countries,  

who  ranked  the  environment,  poverty  and  human  rights  as  three  of  the  four  most  important  issues  

companies  should  address.  Each  certification  prohibits  the  worst  forms  of  child  labor,  and  requires  

practices  that  reduce  negative  environmental  impacts,  such  as  establishing  buffer  zones  to  protect  

waterways.  Additionally,  Fairtrade  requires  buyers  to  pay  prices  that  include  above-­‐market  

premiums  (FLO  2012).    

Conventional  Price  

Differentiated  Price  

Quantity  demanded  

 

  13  

Market  research  indicates  that  goods  that  are  seen  as  being  more  socially  responsible  may  

be  able  to  command  price  premiums.  The  Nielsen  Company  (2014)  polled  30,000  consumers  from  

60  countries,  and  found  that  55  percent  would  pay  more  for  products  from  socially  and  

environmentally  responsible  companies.  Additionally,  52  percent  look  at  packaging  for  indicators  

that  the  product  has  positive  social  and  environmental  impacts,  such  as  self-­‐stated  claims  or  third-­‐

party  labels.  Companies  with  products  that  meet  a  certifier’s  labeling  requirements  can  put  that  

label  on  applicable  products,  providing  third-­‐party  verification  of  relevant  marketing  claims.  

Certifiers  seek  to  increase  demand  through  consumer  marketing  campaigns  and  industry  outreach  

(see  FLO  2014b,  RA  2014b).  This  shifts  the  demand  curve  out  to  increase  prices  for  producers.  

The  target  certifications  seem  to  have  a  limited  effect  on  differentiating  goods  as  being  of  

higher  physical  quality.  None  of  the  certifications  specifies  physical  quality  requirements,  though  

FLO  and  UTZ  have  criteria  that  could  boost  physical  quality.  The  Fairtrade  Cocoa  standard  states  

that  groups  must  consider  whether  investing  their  premium  in  physical  quality  improvement  

would  enhance  producer  incomes,  and  encourages  groups  to  invest  “at  least”  25  percent  of  the  

premium  on  physical  quality  and  productivity  (FLO  2011a).9  This  is  not  binding,  so  its  effects  are  

uncertain.    

UTZ  specifies  criteria  that  would  help  producers  meet  market  requirements,  reducing  the  

amount  of  substandard  beans  that  are  rejected  or  sold  for  discounted  prices.  The  Core  Code  (UTZ  

2014d)  requires  farmers  to  harvest  their  crop  at  the  correct  time  and  use  post-­‐harvest  processing  

methods  that  “optimize”  quality.  The  Cocoa  Module  (UTZ  2014e)  and  the  Cocoa  Code  (UTZ  2009)  

require  farmers  to  use  the  “appropriate”  method  for  fermentation,  dry  and  store  beans  away  from  

flavor  contaminants  (e.g.,  smoke  and  fuel),  dry  beans  to  an  “appropriate”  moisture  level,  meet  

national/buyer  physical  quality  requirements,  and  sort  out  foreign  matter  and  “defective”  beans.    

                                                                                                                         9  FLO  requires  coffee  producers  to  allocate  25  percent  of  their  premium  toward  yield  and  quality  improvement,  but  does  not  mandate  a  minimum  percentage  they  must  spend  on  quality.  Thus,  producers  could  invest  solely  on  productivity,  leaving  quality  unaffected  (FLO  2011a).  

 

  14  

Such  criteria  would  drive  meaningful  change  if  market  failures  exist,  such  that  producers  

are  not  aware  of  physical  quality  standards,  do  not  know  how  to  meet  them,  or  do  not  have  

adequate  cost-­‐benefit  information  to  feel  confident  that  market  prices  will  sufficiently  compensate  

them  for  the  required  effort.  Insufficient  training,  technical  skills  and  financial  literacy,  are  widely  

cited  problems  in  agricultural  development  (Jessop  et  al.  2012).  Certification  criteria  and  training  

address  the  former  two  issues,  but  do  not  improve  financial  knowledge  or  analysis  skills.    

Knowing  that  certification  differentiates  commodities  in  ways  that  are  associated  with  a  

higher  willingness  to  pay,  we  must  also  consider  how  certifiers  seek  to  affect  price.  None  of  the  

target  certifications  mandates  a  floor  price  for  individual  smallholders.  RA  (2014a)  and  UTZ  

(2014d)  do  not  dictate  prices  at  the  group  level  either.  Thus,  for  these  certifications,  the  market’s  

willingness  to  pay  for  differentiated  goods  determines  group  prices.  In  contrast,  for  most  products,  

FLO  (2011b)  requires  buyers  to  pay  producer  organizations  a  Fairtrade  price,  consisting  of  a  floor  

price  (market  or  Fairtrade  minimum,  whichever  is  higher)  and  an  additional  premium,  if  the  buyer  

wishes  to  market  the  commodity  as  certified.  FLO  prohibits  groups  from  giving  members  the  entire  

premium  as  income  (FLO  2012).  It  audits  buyers  and  producers  to  ensure  compliance.  

The  magnitude  of  Fairtrade’s  impact  on  producer  group  prices  depends  on  the  differential  

between  the  Fairtrade  floor  price  and  the  market  price,  which  varies  across  commodities  and  time.  

Thus,  we  cannot  predict  the  exact  price  differential  across  Fairtrade  and  conventional  groups.  As  an  

example,  Figure  2.5  shows  the  Fairtrade  cacao  price  (teal  line)  and  minimum  price  (green  line)  

relative  to  the  world  price  (blue  line),  from  1993  to  2014.  Through  2006,  the  world  price  fell  below  

the  Fairtrade  floor,  giving  certified  producer  groups  a  differential  over  market  prices,  equal  to  the  

difference  between  the  world  market  and  the  Fairtrade  floor,  plus  the  premium.  Since  2007,  the  

world  price  has  exceeded  the  Fairtrade  floor,  making  the  premium  the  minimum  guaranteed  price  

differential  that  certified  organizations  receive,  above  world  prices.    

 

 

  15  

Figure  2.5:  Fairtrade  Cacao  Price  with  Premium,  and  World  Price,  1993  to  2014  a  

 

   a  From  1994-­‐2011,  the  Fairtrade  price  was  $1,750/MT.  In  2011,  Fairtrade  price  was  raised  to  $2,200/MT.  Data  sources:  FLO  Undated,  ICCO  2014a  

 

Regarding  how  pricing  at  the  group  level  translates  to  farmer  prices,  FLO  reports  that,  

across  commodities,  farmers  receive  20  percent  of  the  premium  as  a  direct  payment,  while  cacao  

farmers  receive  21  percent  of  the  premium  directly.  This  indicates  that  Fairtrade  sales  return  

above-­‐market  prices  to  farmers.  Among  certifications  without  set  prices,  RA  (2014a)  asserts  that  

farmers  typically  receive  above-­‐market  prices  but  does  not  publicize  prices  or  premiums.  Thus,  it  is  

not  possible  to  validate  the  magnitude  of  the  effect  of  RA  certification  on  producer  prices.  UTZ  does  

not  disclose  farmer  prices.  It  reported  that  groups  received  premiums  equating  to  $0.043  per  lb.  for  

coffee,  $159  per  MT  for  cacao  and  $26  to  $77  per  MT  for  tea  per  producer,  in  2013  (UTZ  2014c),  

which  represent  averages  of  total  group  premiums  across  all  producers.10  It  seems  reasonable  to  

assume  that  RA-­‐  and  UTZ-­‐certified  groups  will  return  some  portion  of  above-­‐market  prices  to                                                                                                                            10  UTZ  premium  figures  were  converted  from  122,  20  and  59  euros  respectively,  as  reported  by  UTZ  (2013c),  using  May  30,  2013  (middle  of  cacao  season)  exchange  rate  at  xe.com.  

$0  

$500  

$1,000  

$1,500  

$2,000  

$2,500  

$3,000  

$3,500  1993  

1994  

1995  

1996  

1997  

1998  

1999  

2000  

2001  

2002  

2003  

2004  

2005  

2006  

2007  

2008  

2009  

2010  

2011  

2012  

2013  

2014  

ICCO  Price  

Fairtrade  min.  price  

Fairtrade  price  (wloor  +  premium)  

 

  16  

farmers,  as  at  least  some  of  these  groups  are  democratically  run  by  farmers,  and  all  groups  must  

compete  with  Fairtrade  producer  organizations  that  are  clearly  paying  above-­‐market  prices.  

2.3.2  Theoretical  Effects:  Output  Produced  and  Sold  as  Certified  

Certifications  could  affect  a  farm’s  total  output  by  modulating  yield,  the  amount  of  land  cultivated,  

or  both.  Certifier  activities  can  also  impact  the  proportion  of  output  that  farmers  sell  through  

certified  contracts,  at  certified  prices.  The  latter  is  an  important  consideration  since  merely  being  

certified  does  not  ensure  farmers  receive  certified  prices.  Table  2.3  summarizes  the  possible  effects.  

 

Table  2.3:  Possible  Effects  of  Certification  on  Output  and  Certified  Sales  Volume  

  Fairtrade   Rainforest  Alliance  

UTZ  2009   UTZ  2014  

Requirements  and  training  that  can  increase  yield    

Report  fertility  improvement  activities.  Reuse  organic  matter  on  farm.  Encouraged  to  use  part  of  premium  for  productivity  (required  for  coffee)  

Develop  and  implement  fertility  and  IPM  plans.  Use  vegetative  cover  and  organic  waste  for  fertility.  

Certificate  holder  must  train  farmers  on  IPM  and  fertility  improvement,  and  recommend  suitable  varietals.  Farmers  must  understand  IPM  and  fertilization  practices,  and  prune  and  weed.  

Plant  suitable  varietals  (per  yield).  Establish  good  cropping  stand.  Improve  fertility.  Use  IPM  and  yield-­‐optimizing  practices.  Prune  and  weed.  Regenerate  unproductive  plants.    

Requirements  that  can  decrease  yield  

Prohibits  GMO/GE  crops  

Prohibits  GMO/GE  crops  

None  apparent    

Activities  that  increase  certified  sales  volume  

Marketing,  New  product  labeling  options  

Marketing   Marketing    

Requirements  that  can  decrease  planted  land  (crop)  area  

Buffers  between  farm  and  waterways,  protected  areas,  and  areas  of  human  activity.  Buffers  for  pesticide  application  

Buffers  as  with  Fairtrade.  No  expansion  onto  high-­‐value  ecosystems.  Maintain  at  least  40%  shade  cover.  

Buffers  as  with  Fairtrade.  No  expansion  onto  primary  forest.  Limits  expansion  in  native  forest.  No  production  in  protected  areas.  Plant  at  least  18  shade  trees/ha.  

Same  as  UTZ  2009  except  12  shade  trees/ha  required  (cacao)  

 

  17  

All  of  the  target  certifications  have  criteria  that  could  boost  yields  to  differing  degrees  (FLO  

2012,  SAN  2010,  UTZ  2009,  UTZ  2014d,  UTZ  2014e).  Each  requires  producers  to  improve  soil  

fertility  and  reuse  organic  waste  on  the  farm.  Fairtrade  organizations  must  evaluate  the  benefits  of  

spending  some  of  their  premiums  on  yield  improvement,  and  FLO  encourages  groups  to  use  at  least  

25  percent  of  the  premium  to  boost  yield  and  physical  quality  (coffee  groups  must  do  so;  FLO  

2013b).  This  criterion  lacks  a  mandate,  so  its  effects  are  questionable.  RA  and  UTZ  farmers  must  

implement  an  integrated  pest  management  (IPM)  program,  while  Fairtrade  requires  IPM  training.  

This  is  not  a  critical  requirement  for  RA,  so  it  is  not  certain  that  RA  producers  will  implement  it.    

UTZ  (2014d)  goes  further  in  mandating  that  producers  select  varietals  with  consideration  

to  yield,  control  weeds  (to  maximize  nutrient  uptake),  regenerate  unproductive  plants,  and  develop  

and  implement  a  yield  optimization  plan.11  The  prior  Cocoa  Code  (UTZ  2009)  requires  the  same  

practices  except  for  a  yield  improvement  plan,  and  does  not  explicitly  reference  yield  enhancement  

to  the  same  degree.  As  with  physical  quality,  such  criteria  will  have  a  tangible  impact  if  market  

failures  exist,  such  that  producers  lack  training  on  yield-­‐boosting  practices,  lack  information  to  

determine  if  they  are  profitable,  or  face  financial  constraints  that  leave  them  unable  to  implement  

them.  Insufficient  training,  technical  skills,  financial  literacy  and  access  to  credit  are  prevalent  

constraints  farmers  face  (Jessop  et  al.  2012).  Certification  criteria  rectify  the  two  former  issues.  FLO  

and  RA  help  groups  access  affordable  credit.  However,  gaps  in  farm-­‐level  credit  and  financial  

management  limit  producers’  abilities  and  motivations  to  invest  at  levels  that  may  be  optimal.  

Regarding  output,  certifiers’  marketing  efforts  can  increase  demand  for  certified  products,  

which  would  help  producers  increase  the  proportion  of  output  they  sell  under  certified  contracts,  

or  increase  the  price  they  receive.  Given  that  supply  continues  to  increase,  and  that  none  of  the  

certifiers  requires  producers  to  have  a  buyer  who  commits  to  purchasing  a  minimum  volume  at  

certified  terms,  the  net  effect  of  certifier  marketing  efforts  cannot  be  determined.    

                                                                                                                         11  The  stated  UTZ  criteria  become  mandatory  incrementally  over  four  years.  

 

  18  

FLO  also  has  worked  to  increase  purchasing  through  a  new  

“Fairtrade  Sourcing  Program”  labeling  option  (Figure  2.6)  for  cacao,  

sugar  and  cotton  (FLO  2014b).  Brand  owners  can  use  the  “Program”  

label  on  products  that  contain  several  ingredients  that  are  produced  

by  Fairtrade  organizations  if  they  source  only  one  of  these  ingredients  as  Fairtrade  (e.g.,  use  

Fairtrade  cacao  and  conventional  sugar  in  chocolate).  This  provides  a  lower-­‐cost  option  for  

marketing  products  as  Fairtrade,  as  companies  must  source  all  applicable  ingredients  as  Fairtrade  

to  use  the  regular  Fairtrade  label  (e.g.,  both  cacao  and  sugar  in  a  chocolate  bar  must  be  Fairtrade).  

Ten  chocolate  companies  have  signed  on  to  source  Fairtrade  through  the  program,  including  Mars  

and  Ferrero.    

Concerning  negative  effects  on  yield  and  output,  Fairtrade  and  RA  both  prohibit  the  use  of  

genetically  modified  (GM/GMO)  and  genetically  engineered  (GE)  planting  material,  a  criterion  

whose  effect  varies  geographically.  This  would  prevent  producers  from  attaining  maximum  

possible  yields  if  GE/GMO  options  have  a  higher  yield  potential  than  non-­‐GMO  varieties,  and  are  

approved  for  use.  GE  varieties  are  not  currently  available  for  cacao,  so  this  requirement  does  not  

affect  cacao  farmers.  All  of  the  target  certifications  require  producers  to  establish  buffer  zones  

around  waterways,  protected  areas,  areas  of  human  activity,  and  pesticide  application  sites,  and  

prohibit  farmers  from  expanding  onto  protected  ecosystems  (FLO  2012,  SAN  2010,  UTZ  2009,  UTZ  

2014d,  UTZ  2014e).  RA  and  UTZ  are  more  stringent,  also  prohibiting  expansion  onto  primary  

forest,  or  native  forest  that  is  not  used  for  timber  production,  and  requiring  producers  to  maintain  a  

shade  canopy  (12  trees  her  ha  for  UTZ,  and  a  40%  shade  cover  for  RA).  These  requirements,  which  

seek  to  control  negative  externalities,  could  reduce  planted  or  pesticide-­‐treated  area,  and  thus  total  

output.  Their  impacts  depend  on  local  regulations  for  buffer  zones  and  ecosystem  protection,  and  

local  norms  for  shade  cover.    

 

Figure  2.6:  Fairtrade  Cocoa  Sourcing  Program  Label.    Source:  fairtrade.net  

 

  19  

2.3.3  Theoretical  Effects:  Costs  and  Expenditures  

Certifications  can  increase  or  reduce  production  expenditures,  and  group  costs.  Farmers  ultimately  

bear  costs  that  occur  at  the  group  level,  via  higher  member  fees  or  lower  group  profits  that  reduce  

farmer  prices.  Table  2.4  outlines  potential  impacts.  

 

Table  2.4:  Possible  Effects  of  Certification  on  Producer  Costs  and  Expenditures    

  Fairtrade   Rainforest  Alliance  (RA)  

UTZ  2009  (Cacao)  

UTZ  2014  

Increased  farm  expenditures    

Restrictions  on  child  work.  Personal  protective  equipment  for  pesticide  use.  IPM  Training.  Use  non-­‐chemical  weed  control  preferentially.  Wastewater  management  and  record  keeping.  

Fairtrade  plus:  Ecosystem  restoration.  Shade:  40%  cover.  Measure  water  use.  Assess  fertility  and  wastewater  quality.  Site  for  chemical  storage.  Use  IPM.  Fertility  improvement.  

Fairtrade  plus:  Chemical  storage  site.  Pruning.  Use  IPM.  Dry  cacao  away  from  flavor  contaminants.    Plant  18  shade  trees/ha.  IPM.    

UTZ  2009,  with  only  12  shade  trees/ha,  plus:  Measure,  track  and  test  irrigation  water.  Monitor  and  test  soil  fertility.  Regenerate  unproductive  plants.  Use  yield  optimization  practices.  

Increased  producer  group  costs  and  expenditures  

Certification  fee.  Audit  fees.  Certification  management  system,  training  and  monitoring.  Product  traceability  and  segregation.  Record  keeping.  Democratic  mgmt.  

Same  as  Fairtrade  except  certification  fee  and  democratic  process,  plus:  Risk  planning.  Inspect  member  farms  

Same  as  RA  plus:  Technical  advising  staff.  Educate  members  on  numerous  social  topics.  Assess  crop  quality.  

Same  as  UTZ  2009  except  quality  analysis  and  member  education  on  social  topics,  plus:  Map  and  measure  production  area.  Risk  assessment.    

Reduced  farm  expenditures    

Training  on  IPM,  fertilizer  use,  water  use  efficiency  and  reusing  organic  matter  on  farm.  

Same  as  Fairtrade  plus:  Implement  IPM  

Same  as  RA  plus:  Apply  agrochemicals  efficiently  and  reuse  organic  waste  on  farm.    

Reduced  producer  group  costs  and  expenditures  

Pre-­‐financing  at  rate  buyer  could  obtain.  Efficient  business  mgmt.  

Efficient  business  management  

Efficient  business  management    

 

  20  

The  target  certifications  could  affect  farm-­‐level  expenditures  in  numerous  ways  (FLO  2012,  

SAN  2010,  UTZ  2009,  UTZ  2014d,  UTZ  2014e).  All  of  the  certifications  prohibit  the  Worst  Forms  of  

Child  Labor  as  defined  by  ILO  Convention  182,  such  as  having  children  under  the  age  of  18  handle  

pesticides  and  sharp  implements,  engage  in  other  unsafe  tasks  or  work  long  hours.  Additionally,  

each  requires  wastewater  management,  and  the  use  of  personal  protective  equipment  when  

spraying  pesticides.  RA  and  UTZ  producers  also  must  keep  farm  records,  establish  secure  

agrochemical  storage,  maintain  a  minimum  shade  cover,  analyze  and  improve  soil  fertility,  and  

measure  and  track  irrigation  water.    

Beyond  these  criteria,  RA  requires  farmers  to  restore  damaged  high-­‐value  ecosystems,  

inventory  wildlife  habitat,  treat  wastewater,  and  test  wastewater  quality,  while  UTZ  producers  

must  establish  crop  drying  and  storage  sites  away  from  flavor  contaminants,  prune  and  regenerate  

crops,  test  irrigation  water,  and  implement  yield  optimization  practices.  The  current  UTZ  Codes  

require  all  of  these  practices  while  the  prior  Codes  do  not.  These  criteria  could  all  increase  labor  

requirements  and  cash  expenditures,  depending  on  producers’  current  practices  and  the  crop.  

Many  also  seem  likely  to  boost  yield  or  physical  quality,  improving  revenue.  Certification  addresses  

gaps  in  technical  training  on  such  practices,  but  does  not  necessarily  convey  information  about  

their  profitability  to  motivate  adoption.  

On  the  expenditure  reduction  side,  all  certifications  require  training  on  water  efficiency.  

Additionally,  Fairtrade  and  RA  mandate  training  on  reusing  organic  farm  waste,  and  UTZ  requires  

farmers  to  apply  agrochemicals  efficiently  and  reuse  organic  waste  on  the  farm.  These  criteria  could  

help  producers  reduce  purchased  input  expenditures,  depending  on  pre-­‐certification  practices.  

Additionally,  FLO  (2014a)  reports  that  producers  receive  approximately  eight  percent  of  the  

premium  in  kind,  as  tools  and  inputs,  representing  an  expenditure  reduction  in  cases  where  

producers  would  have  purchased  the  items  themselves.  The  effects  of  weed  and  pest  control  

criteria  are  not  clear.  All  certifications  require  producers  to  use  non-­‐chemical  weed  control  

 

  21  

preferentially.  RA  and  UTZ  and  mandate  IPM  use,  and  Fairtrade  producer  groups  must  train  

members  on  this.  Both  approaches  involve  replacing  agrochemicals  with  labor,  and  using  less  toxic  

agrochemicals  when  they  are  needed.  Farmers  may  reduce  input  expenditures  while  increasing  

labor,  with  the  net  result  depending  on  relative  costs  and  amounts  used.    

Certification  involves  numerous  costs  at  the  group  level  (UTZ  2009,  SAN  2011a,  FLO  2012,  

UTZ  2014d,  UTZ  2014e).  Producers  must  pay  audit  fees  for  each  certification,  and  an  additional  

registration  fee  for  Fairtrade  (FLOCERT  2014).  RA  and  UTZ  allow  groups  to  certify  only  a  subset  of  

members,  and  thus  avoid  paying  to  certify  output  they  don’t  expect  to  sell  as  certified,  while  FLO  

does  not.  For  all  certifications,  groups  also  must  implement  a  compliance  program,  train  members  

on  requirements,  monitor  member  performance,  track  and  segregate  certified  commodities  from  

the  farm  to  the  first  buyer,  and  report  on  soil  fertility  improvement  efforts.12  Fairtrade  and  UTZ  

groups  must  track  and  report  premium  usage.  RA  and  UTZ  require  groups  to  inspect  member  farms  

prior  to  external  audits,  manage  compliance  agreements  with  members,  and  develop  a  compliance  

risk  management  plan.  UTZ  adds  demands  on  top  of  this,  such  as  mapping  and  measuring  certified  

crop  area,  and  analyzing  a  crop’s  physical  quality.    

All  of  these  requirements  increase  human  resources  demands,  and  many  require  higher-­‐

level  record  keeping,  planning  and  management  skills.  Groups  will  bear  these  costs  through  staff  

salaries  or  payments  to  external  entities  that  they  must  contract  to  fill  gaps  in  management  

capacity.  Fairtrade  also  requires  democratic  group  management,  including  assemblies  to  vote  on  

group  matters,  which  can  add  time  and  costs.  

Certified  groups  may  realize  expenditure  reductions  by  establishing  more  efficient  group  

management,  product  handling  and  financial  record-­‐keeping  systems,  as  a  result  of  improving  

relevant  processes  to  meet  certification  requirements.  Fairtrade  also  requires  buyers  to  provide  

producer  groups  with  pre-­‐financing  for  contracted  sales,  amounting  to  up  to  60%  of  the  contract  

                                                                                                                         12  FLO  allows  producers  to  commingle  certified  and  non-­‐certified  crops  if  the  buyer  is  approved  to  do  so,  under  FLO’s  “mass  balance”  system  (FLO  2012).  

 

  22  

value  (FLO  2011d).  The  interest  rate  must  not  exceed  the  rate  that  the  buyer  could  obtain  if  they  

took  out  a  loan  for  the  requested  amount.  A  buyer  might  be  expected  to  receive  a  lower  rate  than  a  

producer  group.  Groups  would  face  reduced  loan  costs  in  such  cases    

2.4  Conclusion  

A  review  of  certifiers’  standards  and  activities  indicates  that  certification  could  affect  the  

components  of  net  income  in  numerous  ways,  and  that  the  direction  and  magnitude  of  such  effects  

for  a  specific  producer  group  cannot  be  predicted  on  a  purely  theoretical  basis.  As  such,  the  positive  

outcomes  posited  in  certifiers’  theories  of  change  and  other  communications  are  not  guaranteed.  

Given  that  certifiers’  requirements  and  activities  are  similar  in  some  ways,  and  differ  in  others,  we  

would  expect  each  certification  to  have  different  sets  of  partially  overlapping  effects.  

Certification  seems  most  likely  to  have  a  positive  effect  through  prices,  by  differentiating  

commodities  in  terms  of  social  and  environmental  qualities  that  have  added  valued  in  the  market.  

Producers  will  receive  applicable  higher  prices  only  for  quantities  that  buyers  wish  to  market  as  

certified,  however.  Each  certification  includes  requirements  that  could  boost  yields,  particularly  

UTZ.  However,  each  also  involves  land  use  restrictions  that  could  reduce  output,  particularly  RA.  

There  is  evidence  that  certifiers  are  working  to  build  demand  that  would  help  producers  sell  larger  

volumes  at  certified  terms,  and  altering  labeling  requirements  to  achieve  the  same  end  in  the  case  

of  Fairtrade.  However,  it  is  not  clear  if  and  how  any  of  the  certifiers  are  working  to  manage  supply  

and  demand  growth  to  prevent  a  surplus  of  certified  output,  which  would  constrain  average  

producer  prices  and  certified  sales  volumes  for  a  given  group.    

On  the  cost  and  expenditure  side,  each  certification  entails  more  intensive  farm  

management  practices  that  could  increase  the  cost  of  production,  but  also  involves  training  that  

could  reduce  expenditures  through  efficient  input  use.  UTZ  seems  to  have  the  most  criteria  relevant  

to  this  area,  followed  by  RA.  Certified  groups  would  face  increased  costs  and  expenditures  to  

 

  23  

manage  and  implement  certification  requirements,  with  potential  savings  coming  from  efficiencies  

realized  through  improved  management,  and,  for  Fairtrade,  pre-­‐finance.    

Given  uncertainties  about  how  each  certification  would  affect  the  components  of  net  

income,  and  thus  net  income  overall,  field-­‐based  research  across  certifications,  crops  and  countries  

is  needed  to  make  informed  predictions.  The  following  chapter  will  discuss  relevant  research  to  

date,  identify  remaining  knowledge  gaps,  and  note  design  and  analyses  methods  that  are  required  

for  a  sound  assessment  of  certification  impacts.    

   

 

  24  

Chapter  3. Literature  Review  

The  literature  review  characterizes  the  scope,  methods,  designs,  and  findings  of  research  that  has  

evaluated  the  relationship  between  certification  and  smallholders’  net  incomes.  It  identifies  gaps  

warranting  further  inquiry,  and  methodological  best  practices,  which  informed  the  fieldwork  for  

this  thesis.  It  focuses  on  independent  research  that  used  primary  data  to  evaluate  the  relationship  

between  at  least  one  of  the  target  certifications,  and  price,  output,  yield,  crop  expenditure,  gross  

crop  revenue,  net  crop  revenue  and/or  household  income.  It  excludes  papers  that  used  only  

secondary  data,  are  purely  theoretical  or  that  certifiers  produced  (e.g.,  impact  assessments,  

monitoring  and  evaluation  reports).    

  The  literature  review  comprises  39  publications,  indicated  in  Table  3.1.  Of  these,  24  are  

independent  studies  by  academic  researchers  and  research  institutes,  or  peer-­‐reviewed  articles  

based  on  work  that  certifiers  or  partners  commissioned  from  such  entities.  The  remaining  15  are  

non-­‐peer-­‐reviewed,  quantitative  studies  commissioned  by  certifiers,  partners  (e.g.,  NGO)  or  others.  

Independent  and  commissioned  papers  are  evaluated  separately,  as  the  latter  may  be  subject  to  

more  bias.  Section  3.1  discusses  the  literature  scope,  section  3.2  characterizes  methods  and  design,  

section  3.3  summarizes  and  evaluates  findings,  and  Section  3.4  concludes.  Overall,  research  has  

focused  on  Latin  American  Fairtrade  coffee  and  prices,  used  mostly  cross-­‐section  designs  and  

methods  of  varied  strength,  and  reached  mixed  conclusions  on  certification’s  economic  impacts.    

3.1  Literature  Scope  

Table  3.2  summarizes  the  literature  coverage  by  certification,  crop  and  region.  Papers  may  cover  

more  than  one  item  in  these  categories.  Thus,  category  totals  may  exceed  the  number  of  studies.  

Researchers  have  focused  predominantly  on  Fairtrade  certification,  coffee  and  Latin  America,  

particularly  targeting  specialty  coffee  producers.  Thus,  much  of  our  current  understanding  of  

certification  outcomes  is  based  on  data  from  farmers  that  grow  a  single  certified  commodity  for  

niche  markets.  Certifier-­‐commissioned  works  are  more  balanced  in  scope  than  independent    

 

  25  

Table  3.1:  Literature  Reviewed  

Independent  Academic    and  Research  Inst.  Studies  

Certifier/Partner  Commissioned  Studies  

Afari-­‐Sefa  et  al.  (2010)   Bennett  et  al.  (2013)  Arnould,  Plastina  and  Ball  (2009)   Ceval  (2014)  Barham  and  Weber  (2011)   COSA  (2014)  Bassett  (2012)   Fort  and  Ruben  (2008a)  Becchetti  and  Constantino  (2008)   Fort  and  Ruben  (2008b)  Beuchelt  and  Zeller  (2011)   Giovannucci  and  Potts  (2008)  Blowfield  and  Dolan  (2010)   Ingram  et  al.  (2014)  Chiputwa,  Spielman  and  Qaim  (2014)   Jaffee  (2008)  de  Janvry,  McIntosh  and  Sadoulet  (2014)   KPMG  (2012)  Deppeler,  Fromm  and  Aidoo  (2014)   RA  (2012)  Fromm  and  Dubón  (2006)   Riisgard  et  al.  (2009)  Jena  et  al.  (2012)   Ruben  et  al.  (2008)  Kamau  et  al.  (2012)   Smith  (2010)  Lazaro,  Makindara  and  Kilima  (2008)   Waarts  et  al.  (2012)  Melo  and  Hollander  (2013)   Zúñiga-­‐Arias  and  Sáenz  Segura  (2008)  Méndez  et  al.  (2010)      

                               

Pinto  et  al.  (2014)  Ruben  and  Fort  (2011)  Ruben,  Fort  and  Zúñiga-­‐Arias  (2009)  Ruben  and  Zúñiga  (2010)  Rueda  and  Lambin  (2013)  Utting-­‐Chamorro  (2005)  Valkila  (2009)  Valkila  and  Nygren  (2008)    

research.  Numerous  studies  evaluate  multiple  certifications,  though  few  consider  different  crops  

and  regions.    

Of  the  studies  evaluating  Fairtrade,  58  percent  include  farmers  who  are  dually  certified  as  

Fairtrade  and  organic  (FTO).  Twelve  of  these  papers  include  both  Fairtrade-­‐only  (FLO)  and  FTO  

groups,  while  six  include  only  FTO  (Becchetti  and  Constantino  2008,  Fort  and  Ruben  2008a,  Jaffee  

2008,  Barham  and  Weber  2011,  Beuchelt  and  Zeller  2011,  Jena  et  al.  2012).  For  the  latter  six,  one  

cannot  separate  the  effects  of  Fairtrade  from  organic,  limiting  the  strength  of  any  conclusions.  

Overall,  there  is  a  knowledge  gap  regarding  the  economic  outcomes  associated  with  FLO,  RA  and  

UTZ  for  African  cacao  producers  who  grow  a  mass-­‐market  varietal  and  hold  only  one  certification.  

 

  26  

Table  3.2:  Certification  Literature  Scope  

  Independent  Academic  and  Research  Inst.  Studies  

Certifier/Partner  Commissioned  Studies  

 Total   24   15  

    N   %  of  Total   N   %  of  Total  Certifications  Covered  a    Fairtrade  (FLO)   15   63   10   67  FLO  +  Organic  multi-­‐certified  (FTO)   14   58   4   27  RA   7   29   6   40  UTZ   4   17   5   33  UTZ  +  Organic  multi-­‐certified   1   4   0   0  FLO,  RA  and/or  UTZ  multi-­‐certified   2   8   2   13  Other:  Organic,  Starbucks  Café,  SMBC  Bird  Friendly  

8   33   5   33  

 Evaluates  multiple  certifications   15   63   9   60  

 Crops  Covered    Banana   1   4   5   33  Cacao   3   13   6   40  Coffee   18   75   6   40  Cotton   1   4   1   7  Flowers   0   0   1   7  Fruit   1   4   0   0  Tea   1   4   3   20    Evaluates  multiple  crops   1   4   3   20  

 Geographic  Regions          Africa   9   38   8   53  Asia   0   0   2   13  Latin  America   15   63   9   60  

 Evaluates  multiple  regions   0   0   3   20  a  Some  studies  cover  multiple  crops,  certifications  and/or  regions.      

3.2  Design  and  Methods  

Table  3.3  indicates  design  and  methods  from  the  literature.  Totals  for  each  sub-­‐header  may  not  

equal  the  number  of  papers  due  to  missing  information,  and/or  the  use  of  multiple  designs  or  

methods.  The  overwhelming  majority  of  studies  used  a  cross-­‐section  design,  comprising  83  percent  

 

  27  

of  independent  research  and  71  percent  of  commissioned  works.  Only  five  used  a  panel,  with  four  

of  these  being  commissioned.  Three  papers,  all  independent  case  studies,  used  time-­‐series  data  

(Barham  and  Weber  2011,  de  Janvry,  McIntosh  and  Sadoulet  2014,  Melo  and  Hollender  2013).  

 

Table  3.3:  Study  Design  and  Methods  

  Independent  Academic    and  Research  Inst.  Studies  

Certifier/Partner  Commissioned  Studies  

 Total   24   15       N   %  of  Total   N   %  of  Total  Design    Cross  section     20   83   11   73  Panel     1   4   4   27  Case  Study   4  (3  time  series)   17   0   0  

 Controls    Used  non-­‐certified  controls   15   63   11   73  Certified  and  controls  in  same  organizational  form  a  

7   47   1   7  

 Sample  Diversity  b    One  group  per  type  (e.g.,  certification,  crop,  country)  

9   38   8   53  

Two  groups  per  type   2   8   1   7  Three  or  more  groups  per  type   11   46   2   13  

 Analysis  Methods    Descriptive  Statistics  Only   5   21   2   13  Correlations   1   4   0   0  Compare  unmatched  means    (t-­‐tests,  ANOVA)  

9   35   13   87  

Compare  means  via  Propensity  Score  Matching  

5   21   5   33  

Difference-­‐in-­‐Difference   0   0   3   20  Regression   3   13   2   13  Qualitative   7   29   3   20  Cost-­‐Benefit  Analysis   1   4   1   7  a  This  is  the  percentage  of  studies  with  controls.  Some  studies  did  not  state  organizational  form  for  controls.  b  The  number  of  groups  per  type  is  not  stated  in  all  studies.    

The  validity  of  cross-­‐sectional  findings,  and  our  ability  to  generalize  them,  rests  on  the  

diversity  of  the  sample,  and  the  use  of  appropriate  controls.  Here,  sample  diversity  is  defined  as  the  

 

  28  

number  of  distinct  groups  per  certification  status  that  a  study  included,  across  producers  and/or  

locations.  Among  independent  studies,  almost  half  used  three  or  more  groups  per  certification  

status  (e.g.,  four  certified  and  four  non-­‐certified  groups),  while  about  40  percent  used  only  one  (e.g.,  

one  certified  and  one  non-­‐certified  group,  or  one  certified  group  in  a  time-­‐series  study).  Certifier-­‐

commissioned  studies  have  much  lower  sample  diversity,  with  most  using  only  one  group.  As  such,  

the  results  of  most  studies  cannot  be  generalized  beyond  the  sampling  context  with  confidence.    

Using  a  counterfactual  enables  us  to  draw  valid  conclusions  about  how  certification  differs  

from  conventional  systems,  and  generalize  conclusions  to  comparable  populations  outside  the  

sample.  While  the  majority  of  studies  used  non-­‐certified  controls,  one  third  did  not.  In  the  absence  

of  controls,  researchers  have  evaluated  a  single  certification  using  time-­‐series  data  (Barham  and  

Weber  2011,  Melo  and  Hollender  2013,  de  Janvry  et  al.  2014)  or  producer  recall  (Ceval  2012),  or  

compared  performance  across  certifications  (Utting-­‐Chamorro  2005,  Fort  and  Ruben  2008c).  

Among  studies  using  time-­‐series  or  recall  data,  only  Barham  and  Weber  (2011)  include  pre-­‐

certification  data,  which  are  needed  to  determine  if  obtaining  certification  is  better  than  doing  

nothing.  Additionally,  recall  can  be  faulty.  Other  papers  without  controls  compare  certified  farmers’  

outcomes  to  sector  averages  (Utting-­‐Chamorro  2005,  Valkila  and  Nygren  2008,  Blowfield  and  Dolan  

2010,  Bassett  2012,  Pinto  et  al.  2014).  Such  averages  are  not  suitable  control  data  since  they  

represent  certified  and  non-­‐certified  farmers’  outcomes,  and  may  not  be  geographically  applicable.      

Where  studies  employ  controls,  the  majority  either  fail  to  state  organizational  form  (Fromm  

and  Dubón  2006,  RA  2012,  Waarts  et  al.  2012,  Bennett  et  al.  2013,  Rueda  and  Lambin  2013,  

Deppeler,  Fromm  and  Aidoo  2014)  or  do  not  control  for  it  because  they  use  certified  producers  

from  co-­‐ops,  and  independent  controls  (Becchetti  and  Constantino  2008,  Jaffee  2008,  Ruben,  Fort  

and  Zúñiga-­‐  Arias  2009,  Riisgard  et  al.  2009,  Ruben  and  Zúñiga  2010,  Chiputwa,  Speilman  and  Qaim  

2014).  Given  that  producer  organizations  have  greater  market  power  than  individual  smallholders,  

may  provide  goods  and  services  to  members  (FLO  2014a)  and  may  receive  training  and  support  

 

  29  

that  buyers  offer  to  groups  only  (Barry  Callebaut  2014),  group  affiliation  can  affect  economic  

outcomes  apart  from  certification.  When  researchers  do  not  state  or  control  for  organizational  

form,  and  use  only  simple  analyses  such  as  unmatched  group  means,  one  cannot  attribute  reported  

differences  across  certified  and  non-­‐certified  producers  to  certification  alone.    

Selection  bias  is  a  concern  in  evaluating  certification  impacts,  as  certification  has  not  

involved  random  selection  to  date.  Producers  may  choose  to  become  certified,  or  buyers  and  others  

may  initiate  the  process.  Certifier  and  trader  interviews  confirm  that  traders  approach  co-­‐ops  to  

become  certified  in  Côte  d’Ivoire,  and  have  selection  criteria  such  as  group  size  and  management  

capabilities  (Buyo  2013,  Sendjou  2014).  Larger  group  size  reduces  the  number  of  transactions  

traders  must  manage,  and  makes  certification  cost-­‐efficient  for  producers  (Pinto  et  al.  2014).  

Farmers  with  better  knowledge,  yields,  physical  quality  and  incomes,  and  co-­‐ops  with  better  

management,  could  also  find  it  easier  to  meet  requirements  and  costs,  and  be  more  likely  to  seek  

certification.  Alternately,  impoverished,  poorly  performing  farmers  may  pursue  certification,  or  be  

chosen  preferentially  for  certification  by  others,  as  a  way  to  improve  their  knowledge  and  incomes.    

Some  of  the  reviewed  studies  have  employed  data  analysis  methods  to  address  selection  

bias.  Five  independent  and  five  commissioned  works  utilized  propensity  score  matching  (PSM)  to  

compare  group  means.  In  PSM,  certified  and  non-­‐certified  producers  are  matched  based  on  a  

propensity  score  from  a  probit  regression  that  predicts  the  likelihood  of  being  certified.  Probit  

models  include  household,  farmer  and  farm  attributes  such  as  household  size,  farmer’s  age  and  

cropping  area  (see  Ruben  and  Fort  2011,  Bennett  et  al.  2012).  Three  such  studies  do  not  specify  the  

probit,  making  it  difficult  to  evaluate  the  validity  of  subsequent  tests  (Ruben,  Fort  and  Zúñiga-­‐Arias  

2009,  Kamau  et  al.  2010,  COSA  2014).  Some  probits  include  variables  that  may  be  affected  by  

certification  and  thus  may  not  reflect  the  pre-­‐certification  state,  such  as  current  cropping  area  

(Ruben  and  Zúñiga  2010,  Ruben  and  Fort  2011,  Bennett  et  al.  2013).  Chiputwa  et  al.  (2014)  use  

past  cropping  area  per  farmer  recall,  providing  a  pre-­‐certification  measure  but  risking  recall  error.    

 

  30  

  Three  papers,  all  commissioned,  utilized  a  difference-­‐in-­‐difference  (DiD)  analysis  with  panel  

data  to  compare  change  over  time  across  certified  and  non-­‐certified  groups  (RA  2012,  Waarts  et  al.  

2013,  Bennett  et  al.  2013).  This  is  said  to  be  a  stronger  method  of  analyzing  how  certification  may  

affect  outcomes,  with  the  difference  in  change  over  time  between  groups  defined  as  the  potential  

treatment  effect.  However,  analyses  that  compare  means  across  groups  only,  including  DiD,  PSM  

and  unmatched  t-­‐tests,  cannot  prove  that  certification  has  caused  observed  differences.  Such  

methods  also  do  not  quantify  certification’s  effects  relative  to  other  relevant  variables.  Regression  

analyses  serve  this  role.  Only  four  studies,  two  independent  and  two  commissioned,  used  

regressions  to  estimate  the  effect  of  certification  on  net  income  and/or  its  components.  The  

regressions  focused  on  coffee  price  (de  Janvry  et  al.  2014),  total  coffee  output  (Arnould  et  al.  2009),  

coffee  profit  (Riisgard  et  al.  2009),  and  cacao  yield  and  profit  (Ingram  et  al.  2014).  All  four  studies  

found  that  certification,  and  other  demographic,  economic  and  agronomic  variables,  had  significant  

positive  effects.  However,  Ingram  et  al.  (2014)  found  that  the  coefficient  for  certification  was  

significant  for  yield  and  not  profit.  Ingram  et  al.  (2014)  also  considered  the  effects  of  buyer  

affiliation  and  participation  in  other  training  programs,  the  only  study  to  do  so.  

3.3  Findings  From  Prior  Research  

 Table  3.4  summarizes  the  results  of  existing  research  on  the  relationship  between  certification,  and  

net  income  and  its  components.  It  includes  only  statistically  significant  findings,  with  an  exception  

for  descriptive  statistics  on  price  premiums  from  seven  studies  (Utting-­‐Chamorro  2005,  Lazaro    

et  al.  2008,  Valkila  and  Nygren  2008,  Valkila  2009,  Bassett  2012,  KPMG  2012,  Melo  and  Hollander  

2013).  The  percentages  for  each  finding  (e.g.,  higher,  lower)  are  based  on  the  number  of  studies  

evaluating  each  outcome.  Overall,  research  indicates  mixed  outcomes,  with  some  results  dependent  

on  time,  crop  and  geography,  or  partially  driven  by  factors  such  as  farm  size.  Findings  vary  within  

each  crop,  certification  and  region,  such  that  no  single  commodity,  certification  or  location  is  

associated  with  purely  positive  or  negative  outcomes.    

 

  31  

Table  3.4:  Findings  on  Relationships  Between  Certification,  and  Net  Income  and  Its  Components  a  

  Independent  Academic    and  Research  Inst.  Studies  

Certifier/Partner  Commissioned  Studies  

 Total   24   15       N   %  of  Relevant  Total     N   %  of  Relevant  Total  Price      Number  of  Relevant  Studies   19   79   8   53  Certified  Higher   15   79   5   62.5  Certified  Lower   0   0   0   0  No  Significant  Difference   2   10.5   2   25  Mixed  Results   2   10.5   1   12.5  

 Total  Output    Number  of  Relevant  Studies   4   17   5   33  Certified  Higher   1   25   4   80  Certified  Lower   0   0   0   0  No  Significant  Difference   1   25   0   0  Mixed  Results   2   50   1   20  

 Yield    Number  of  Relevant  Studies   8   33   9   60  Certified  Higher   1   13   4   45  Certified  Lower   3   37   1   11  No  Significant  Difference   0   0   2   22  Mixed  Results   4   50   2   22  

 Gross  Crop  Revenue    Number  of  Relevant  Studies   6   25   5   33  Certified  Higher   3   50   2   40  Certified  Lower   0   0   1   20  No  Significant  Difference   1   17   1   40  Mixed  Results   2   33   1   20  

 Total  Production  Expenditure    Number  of  Relevant  Studies   1   4   2   13  Certified  Lower   0   0   1   50  Certified  Higher   0   0   0   0  No  Significant  Difference   1   100   1   50  Mixed  Results   0   0   0   0  

 Net  Crop  Revenue  (Profit)    Number  of  Relevant  Studies   5   21   12   80  Certified  Higher   0   0   5   42  Certified  Lower   1   20   1   8  

 

  32  

No  Significant  Difference   2   40   3   25  Mixed  Results   2   40   3   25  

 Household  Income    Number  of  Relevant  Studies   6   25   5   33  Certified  Higher   0   0   3   60  Certified  Lower   1   17   1   20  No  Significant  Difference   1   17   0   0  Mixed  Results   4   66   1   20  a  The  percentages  for  each  finding  are  out  of  studies  evaluating  relevant  outcome.      

Price  is  the  most  widely  analyzed  outcome,  with  most  studies  measuring  the  certified  

contract  price  or  premium,  and  few  reporting  average  price  across  total  volume  sold.  Certification  

was  associated  with  higher  prices,  relative  to  controls  and  conventional  channels  (market  prices),  

in  79  percent  of  independent  research  papers  and  62.5  percent  of  commissioned  works.  Studies  

reporting  mixed  results  (positive,  negative  and  no  significant  difference)  used  time-­‐series  or  recall  

data  (Valkila  2008  and  Nygren),  or  evaluated  multiple  crops  and  geographies  (COSA  2014),  where  

more  variance  is  expected.  Those  reporting  no  significant  difference  focused  on  certifications  that  

do  not  set  prices  (Blowfield  and  Dolan  2010,  RA  2012)  or  used  PSM  to  compare  means  (Fort  and  

Ruben  2008a,  Ruben  and  Fort  2011).  While  there  is  strong  evidence  that  certified  sales  involve  

above-­‐market  prices,  there  is  little  data  on  how  certified  contract  prices  vary  across  time  or  

producers,  or  the  magnitude  at  which  average  price  across  total  output  differs  across  certified  and  

non-­‐certified  groups.    

  Fewer  studies,  nine  in  all,  assessed  total  crop  output.  Independent  research  reported  mostly  

mixed  or  equal  outcomes  under  certification,  while  commissioned  papers  largely  found  that  

certified  farmers  had  higher  output  than  controls.  In  four  cases,  differences  in  mean  crop  area  

across  certified  producers  and  controls  explain  differences  in  output  (Fort  and  Ruben  2008a,  

Arnould  et  al.  2009,  Riisgard  et  al.  2009,  Kamau  et  al.  2010).  Arnould  et  al.  (2009)  controlled  for  

crop  area  by  using  a  regression  with  crop  area  and  certification  as  explanatory  variables,  while  Fort  

 

  33  

and  Ruben  (2008a)  used  PSM  with  a  probit  that  included  crop  land.  However,  Riisgard  et  al.  (2009)  

did  not  control  for  land,  while  Kamau  et  al.  (2010)  used  PSM  but  did  not  state  the  probit,  making  it  

uncertain  if  they  accounted  for  land.  Thus,  the  validity  of  these  studies  is  uncertain.  Beyond  this,  

given  that  certification  could  affect  crop  area,  and  that  output  is  not  a  normalized  measure  that  

enables  an  even  comparison  across  different  farms,  it  is  not  an  ideal  metric  for  cross-­‐section  data.    

Yield  is  a  better  measure,  and  was  the  focus  of  about  44  percent  of  studies.  Only  one  

independent  study  found  that  certification  was  correlated  with  higher  yields  (Pinto  et  al.  2014),  

while  three  reported  that  it  was  associated  with  lower  yields  (Ruben  and  Zúñiga  2010,  Beuchelt  

and  Zeller  2011,  Jena  et  al.  2012).  Commissioned  studies  have  found  more  positive  results.  Across  

all  papers  evaluating  yield,  about  half  found  mixed  or  equal  outcomes.  Thus,  there  is  little  evidence  

that  certification  is  associated  with  higher  yields.    

  Eleven  studies  evaluated  crop  revenue,  with  most  using  total  farm  income  rather  than  a  per  

hectare  measure.  Three  independent  (Fromm  and  Dubón  2006,  Arnould  et  al.  2009,  Méndez  et  al.  

2009)  and  two  commissioned  papers  (Fort  and  Ruben  2008a,  Riisgard  et  al.  2011)  reported  higher  

revenue  among  certified  producers  than  controls.  One  found  that  certification  was  associated  with  

lower  revenue  (Fort  and  Ruben  2008c),  and  the  remainder  reported  mixed  or  equivalent  outcomes  

across  groups.  In  eight  studies  of  revenue,  average  farm  size  differed  significantly  across  certified  

producers  and  controls,  or  the  nature  of  this  difference  was  not  reported.  Three  of  these  did  not  

control  for  farm  size  (Fromm  and  Dubón  2006,  Riisgard  et  al.  2009,  Méndez  et  al.  2010),  while  

Kamau  et  al.  (2010)  used  PSM  without  specifying  the  probit,  making  it  unclear  if  they  accounted  for  

it.  Given  that  farm  size  is  a  determinant  of  output,  which  drives  total  revenue,  one  cannot  

confidently  attribute  observed  differences  to  certification  in  these  four  studies.  Overall,  findings  on  

revenue  have  mixed  conclusions  and  some  limitations  on  validity.  

  Only  three  studies  evaluated  the  relationship  between  certification  and  total  farm  

expenditure,  with  one  reporting  lower  spending  among  certified  producers  than  controls  (Ingram  

 

  34  

et  al.  2014)  and  two  finding  mixed  results  (Beuchelt  and  Zeller  2011,  Bennett  et  al.  2013).  Seven  

papers  assessed  individual  expenditures  such  as  labor  or  fertilizer,  but  such  piecemeal  findings  

cannot  be  extrapolated  to  total  spending.    

  Researchers  have  assessed  net  income  using  both  crop-­‐specific  and  household  income.  

Approximately  20  percent  of  independent  and  80  percent  of  commissioned  studies  evaluated  net  

crop  revenue,  with  independent  works  finding  that  certification  was  associated  with  negative,  

mixed  or  equal  outcomes  relative  to  controls.  Commissioned  papers  indicate  that  certified  

producers  had  higher  net  incomes  than  controls  42  percent  of  the  time,  and  mixed  or  equivalent  

outcomes  in  all  but  one  of  the  remaining  cases.  Household  income  was  addressed  in  25  percent  of  

independent  and  33  percent  of  commissioned  research,  with  the  overall  pattern  of  results  being  

similar  to  findings  on  net  crop  revenue.  Most  studies  do  not  report  the  percentage  of  household  

income  that  comes  from  certified  crops,  so  it  is  not  possible  to  determine  the  degree  to  which  

certification  status  might  modulate  household  income.    

3.4  Conclusion  

Overall,  the  literature  review  indicates  that,  for  economic  outcomes  other  than  price,  relative  

differences  between  certified  and  non-­‐certified  farmers  vary  across  time  and  geography.  The  

majority  of  studies  found  that  certification  was  associated  with  higher  prices,  higher  or  equal  total  

output  and  revenue,  lower  or  equal  farm  expenditure,  and  mixed  outcomes  for  yield  and  profit.  

Most  research  has  focused  on  evaluating  price,  Fairtrade,  and  Latin  American  coffee  farmers  who  

sell  through  specialty  channels,  particularly  independent  studies.  Thus,  there  is  a  need  for  further  

research  in  areas  with  less  coverage,  such  as  the  RA  and  UTZ  certifications,  Africa,  cacao,  mass-­‐

market  trade,  and  economic  measures  beyond  price.  This  thesis  seeks  to  fill  these  gaps  and  

complement  prior  work  by  evaluating  price,  yield,  revenue,  farm  expenditure  and  net  income  

among  Ivorian  farmers  who  produce  bulk  cacao  under  the  FLO,  RA  and/or  UTZ  certifications.  

 

  35  

An  analysis  of  methodologies  indicates  that  some  results  may  be  artifacts  of  designs  and  

analyses  that  had  limited  sampling  diversity,  used  only  multi-­‐certified  producers  (e.g.,  FTO),  did  not  

address  selection  bias,  or  did  not  control  for  factors  such  as  organizational  form  or  crop  area.  The  

latter  two  issues  are  largely  due  to  the  fact  that  most  studies  used  only  unmatched  comparisons  of  

group  means,  rather  than  PSM  or  regressions.  This  limits  the  validity  and  generalizability  of  the  

findings.  Additionally,  many  studies  evaluating  price  also  considered  only  the  certified  contract  

price  and  not  average  price  across  total  sales  volume,  such  that  results  represent  the  potential  of  

certification  rather  than  actual  outcomes.  Only  one  study  (Ingram  et  al.  2014)  considered  the  effect  

of  certification  relative  to  buyer  affiliation  and  participation  in  other  training  programs.  Given  that  

both  can  affect  agronomic  and  economic  outcomes,  one  cannot  confidently  attribute  observed  

differences  solely  to  certification,  in  analyses  that  do  not  consider  such  factors.  

This  thesis  seeks  to  adopt  methodological  best  practices  from  prior  research  by  using  

certified  producers  and  controls  that  are  both  from  co-­‐ops  only,  gathering  data  from  farmers  in  35  

co-­‐ops  in  three  regions,  and  using  regressions  to  control  for  other  relevant  variables  and  selection  

bias.  Regressions  also  provide  estimates  of  certification’s  effects,  enabling  stronger  conclusions  

than  the  group  means  comparisons  used  in  much  of  the  existing  literature.  To  permit  comparisons  

across  producers  of  different  farm  sizes,  this  thesis  uses  normalized  measures  such  as  yield,  and  

revenue,  expenditure  and  profit  per  hectare.  It  considers  both  average  price  across  sales  volume,  

and  certified  contract  prices,  to  understand  current  performance  and  best  case  outcomes.  

 

   

 

  36  

Chapter  4. Côte  d’Ivoire  and  the  Cacao  Sector  

This  chapter  characterizes  the  context  in  which  cacao  farmers,  buyers  and  certifiers  operate,  with  a  

focus  on  Côte  d’Ivoire.  It  serves  to  establish  an  understanding  of  how  certification  might  affect  

cacao  producers’  profits  in  general,  and  in  Côte  d’Ivoire,  where  fieldwork  took  place.  Section  4.1  

provides  background  on  Côte  d’Ivoire,  with  respect  to  factors  that  affect  cacao  smallholders’  

agronomic  and  economic  outcomes.  Section  4.2  outlines  value  chain  structure,  and  Section  4.3  

characterizes  cacao  production  and  processing.  Sections  4.4  through  4.6  discuss  pricing,  market  

power,  and  supply  and  demand  respectively.  Sections  4.7  and  4.8  cover  production  constraints  and  

development  efforts,  and  Section  4.9  presents  conclusions.  The  contextual  overview  indicates  that  

certification  operates  in  a  dynamic  environment  with  diverse  elements  that  may  constrain  or  

enhance  producers’  outcomes.  This  provides  insights  into  the  potential  of  certification  to  impact  

farmers’  profits  in  the  Ivorian  cacao  sector,  and  identifies  multiple  factors  that  may  explain  relative  

differences  in  economic  outcomes  between  certified  and  non-­‐certified  producers.  

4.1  Côte  d’Ivoire  

Côte  d’Ivoire  is  located  in  West  Africa,  with  Ghana  to  the  east,  Guinea  and  Liberia  to  the  west,  and  

Mali  and  Burkina  Faso  to  the  north.  It  faces  formidable  economic,  social  and  agricultural  challenges  

that  constrain  producers.  Table  4.1  presents  key  socioeconomic  and  agricultural  statistics.  

Approximately  43  percent  of  its  population  lives  below  the  poverty  line  (Hatløy  et  al.  2012).  Its  

Human  Development  Index  (HDI)  ranking  is  low,  at  168  out  of  187  countries  (United  Nations  

Development  Program  2013).  Since  1980,  Gross  National  Income  (GNI)  has  decreased  36  percent,  

though  its  HDI  score,  which  is  based  on  income,  educational  attainment  and  life  expectancy,  has  

improved  due  to  increases  in  the  latter  two  components.  Mean  education  is  4.2  years,  at  the  

primary  school  level.  Cacao  is  the  top  export  crop,  comprising  20  percent  of  GDP  (Agritrade  2012).  

It  is  the  main  source  of  income  for  about  75  percent  of  the  rural  population  (Hatløy  et.  al  2012).    

 

 

  37  

Table  4.1:  Côte  d’Ivoire  Country  Statistics,  2012  

GNI  per  capita  (2005  PPP$)   $  1,593  Life  expectancy  at  birth   56  Prevalence  of  Poverty  (2005)   43%  below  poverty  line  Schooling:  expected  years  (mean  years)   6.5  (4.2)  %  rural  population   47%  Top  export  commodities   cacao,  coffee,  timber,  petroleum,  cotton,  bananas,  

pineapples,  palm  oil,  fish  Population  in  agriculture   2.71  million  (36%  female);  35%  of  labor  force  Sources:  CIA  2013,  Hatløy  et  al.  2012,  UNDP  2013  

 

In  the  past  decade,  the  country  has  experienced  two  civil  wars,  negatively  affecting  the  

economy  and  social  systems.  The  first  civil  war  lasted  from  2002-­‐07.  A  second  civil  war  ensued  in  

March  2011,  which  lasted  five  weeks  and  directly  affected  the  cacao  sector.  The  president-­‐elect,  

Alassane  Ouattara,  enacted  an  export  ban  on  cacao  from  January  through  April  2011,  in  order  to  cut  

off  export  revenues  to  the  incumbent  who  refused  to  cede  office,  Laurent  Gbagbo  (Coulibaly  2011).    

4.2  Cacao  Value  Chain  13    

Cacao  beans  are  the  primary  ingredient  in  chocolate  and  the  source  of  cocoa  powder  and  butter,  

which  are  used  in  chocolate,  cocoa  drinks,  other  foods  and  beverages,  and  personal  care  products.  

The  value  chain  consists  of  input  suppliers,  credit  providers,  other  service  providers,  agricultural  

extension,  certifiers,  farmers,  buyers,  traders,  exporters,  grinders,  industrial  processors,  contract  

manufacturers,  brand  owners,  distributors  and  retailers.  Individual  entities  may  serve  multiple  

roles,  such  as  a  cooperative  that  purchases  and  exports  cacao  beans,  or  a  company  that  purchases  

beans  directly  from  farmers,  exports  them  and  makes  them  into  finished  chocolate.    

Figure  4.1  illustrates  the  cacao  value  chain  for  Côte  d’Ivoire,  applicable  to  both  certified  and  

non-­‐certified  producers  (i.e.,  certification  operates  within  the  conventional  value  chain).  Producers  

may  sell  to  traveling  buyers  (pisteurs)  or,  if  they  are  in  a  co-­‐op,  to  their  co-­‐op.  Co-­‐ops  may  sell  to  

                                                                                                                         13  “Value  chain”  refers  to  the  supply  chain  plus  input/service  providers  such  as  creditors,  while  “supply  chain”  refers  to  the  chain  of  buyers  and  sellers  from  farm  to  retail.  

 

  38  

regional  buyers  (traitants),  traders,  exporters,  grinders  or  brand  owners.  From  that  point,  cacao  

moves  through  the  rest  of  the  value  chain  to  consumers.  Certifiers  work  with  producers,  and  

industry  members  from  traders  through  brand  owners,  to  provide  certification,  licensing  and  

related  services.  

 Figure  4.1:  Cacao  Value  Chain  for  Côte  d’Ivoire  Smallholders  

 

Sources:  Field  surveys,  Hatløy  et  al.  2012,  TCC  2012  

4.3  Cacao  Production  and  Processing  

Cacao  beans  grow  in  pods  on  the  theobroma  cacao  tree,  which  grows  within  10  degrees  north  and  

south  of  the  equator.  There  are  three  main  types  of  cacao:  criollo,  forastero  and  trinitario  (a  cross  of  

the  other  two).  Forastero,  the  lowest-­‐valued  type,  predominates  in  West  Africa.  Trees  reach  peak  

production  around  their  tenth  year,  maintain  this  productivity  level  for  about  ten  years,  then  

decline  in  yields  (World  Cocoa  Foundation  2013).    

 

  39  

The  path  from  bean  to  bar,  baked  good  or  beauty  product  includes  crop  production,  post-­‐

harvest  processing,  crop  marketing,  roasting,  grinding,  semi-­‐finished  ingredients  manufacturing,  

finished  goods  production,  brand  marketing  and  retailing  (UNCTAD  2008).  The  World  Cocoa  

Foundation  (2013)  estimates  that  there  are  five  million  cacao  producers  globally.  The  Tropical  

Commodity  Coalition  (TCC  2012)  reports  that  about  98%  of  farms  are  five  hectares  or  less,  with  

these  farms  producing  about  90%  of  global  supply.  The  International  Cocoa  Organization  (ICCO  

Undated)  estimates  that  Côte  d’Ivoire  has  about  900,000  cacao  producers,  who  are  primarily  

smallholders.  Many  farmers  lack  sufficient  training  on  production  and  post-­‐harvest  processing,  face  

difficulties  accessing  inputs  and  credit,  and  have  aging,  low-­‐yield  trees,  all  of  which  constrain  

economic  outcomes  (World  Cocoa  Foundation  2013).    

Opoku-­‐Ameyaw  et  al.  (2010)  characterize  West  African  production.  Farmers  primarily  grow  

traditional  varietals  that  require  shade,  though  some  cultivate  higher-­‐yielding  sun-­‐grown  hybrids.  

Farmers  should  prune,  weed  and  fertilize  trees  to  maximize  yield.  They  must  manage  pests  that  can  

cause  crop  losses  of  up  to  30  percent,  particularly  Black  Pod,  a  fungus,  mirids,  an  insect,  and  cocoa  

swollen  shoot  virus.  The  main  harvest  lasts  from  October  to  March,  with  a  smaller  harvest  from  

May  to  August.  Fresh  cacao  beans  may  be  fermented  then  dried,  or  washed  and  dried  without  

fermentation.  Producers  may  ferment  and  dry  beans,  or  sell  wet  beans  or  pods  to  buyers.  

Saltini,  Akkerman  and  Frosch  (2013)  characterize  post-­‐harvest  processing.  Fermentation  is  

one  of  the  key  determinants  of  flavor  and  must  be  done  carefully.  Beans,  and  the  pulp  surrounding  

them,  are  placed  in  a  pile  or  container,  covered,  and  turned  every  day  or  two  to  ensure  an  even  

fermentation.  Natural  yeasts  digest  sugars  in  the  pulp,  causing  chemical  reactions  that  turn  the  

bitter,  purple  beans  into  brown,  chocolate  flavored  ones  in  about  three  to  five  days.  Producers  dry  

beans  for  up  to  12  days,  ideally  to  7.5  percent  or  less  moisture.  Sun  drying  is  preferred  for  flavor,  

but  rainy  weather  may  necessitate  wood-­‐  or  gas-­‐fired  driers,  which  can  mar  flavor.  Buyers  evaluate  

physical  quality  to  determine  whether  to  reject  any  beans,  and  what  price  they  will  pay.  They  

 

  40  

inspect  wet  beans  for  germinated  beans  and  foreign  matter,  and  cut  dry  beans  to  determine  the  

percentage  of  properly  fermented  (if  applicable)  and  defective  beans  (Opoku-­‐Ameyaw  et  al.  2010).    

The  ICCO  (Undated)  outlines  processing.  Beans  are  cleaned,  roasted,  cracked,  and  

winnowed  to  separate  the  nibs  (cacao  bean  pieces)  and  shell.  Processors  then  grind  the  nibs  into  

liquor.  Cacao  liquor  may  be  pressed  into  cacao  butter  and  powder,  or  refined  and  conched  (mixed)  

to  make  couverture  (industrial  chocolate),  which  is  tempered  and  formed  into  eating  chocolate.  

Most  processing,  and  almost  all  finished  goods  manufacturing,  is  done  by  multinationals  in  

consuming  countries  (UNCTAD  2008).  However,  Côte  d’Ivoire  is  the  world’s  second  largest  grinder,  

grinding  35  percent  of  its  production  and  representing  11.4%  of  global  grindings  (ICCO  2014b).  

4.4  Cacao  Price  Determination  

World  prices  for  the  “bulk”  cacao  that  predominates  in  West  Africa  are  based  on  two  futures  

markets,  in  New  York  (ICE)  and  London  (NYSE  Liffe)  (World  Cocoa  Foundation  2014a).  Figure  4.2  

charts  nominal  world  prices  for  bulk,  fermented  cacao  from  2002-­‐2014,  which  are  marked  by  

cyclical  increases  and  decreases  of  varied  magnitudes.  Physical  quality  and  varietal  determine  the  

actual  export  prices  that  a  producer  or  country  can  command.  For  example,  Ghana  earns  a  higher  

premium  over  world  prices  than  Côte  d’Ivoire  due  to  higher  physical  quality  standards  (Agritrade  

2012).  In  cases  where  export  prices  are  lower  than  the  world  price,  certifications  that  set  prices,  

such  as  Fairtrade,  would  help  groups  garner  above-­‐market  prices  for  output  sold  at  certified  terms.      

Farm  gate  prices  and  margins  vary  within  and  across  countries.  According  to  the  ICCO  

(2012),  from  2002-­‐11,  among  West  African  producers,  Ghana  received  the  highest  percentage  of  

the  world  price,  followed  by  Cameroon  and  Côte  d’Ivoire.  Côte  d’Ivoire  sets  farm  gate  price  floors  

through  its  cacao  and  coffee  board,  Le  Conseil  du  Café-­‐Cacao  (CCC)  (Agritrade  2012).  This  is  rare  in  

the  sector  and  a  recent  development.  The  CCC  was  formed  in  2012  as  part  of  cacao  sector  reform  

enacted  to  satisfy  the  terms  of  IMF  debt  relief.  The  country  had  a  cacao  board  with  price  controls  

from  1960  to  1999,  when  it  scuttled  it  as  part  of  liberalization  and  structural  adjustment.  To  date,  

 

  41  

farm  gate  floor  prices  have  amounted  to  60  percent  of  the  export  prices  that  the  CCC  negotiates.  

Côte  d’Ivoire  also  taxes  cacao  exports,  placing  an  added  economic  burden  on  producers.  It  has  

 

Figure  4.2:  World  Cacao  Prices,  Yearly  Average,  1993  to  2014  

 

 

Data  source:  ICCO  2014a  

 

agreed  to  reduce  and  cap  these  taxes  as  part  of  its  cacao  sector  reform  (Hatløy  et.  al  2012).  Ghana  

also  sets  floor  prices,  a  longstanding  practice,  as  it  did  not  eliminate  its  cacao  board  or  pricing  

regulations  when  it  went  through  structural  adjustment  (Agritrade  2012).      

4.5  Market  Power  

Within  countries,  there  is  little  consolidation  among  farmers.  Hatløy,  et  al.  (2012)  report  that  about  

15  percent  of  Ivorian  producers  are  in  formal  organizations  such  as  co-­‐ops.  Fortson,  Murray  and  

Velyvis  (2011)  found  that  co-­‐op  membership  was  17  percent  in  Côte  d’Ivoire,  14  percent  in  Ghana,  

21  percent  in  Nigeria  and  33  percent  in  Cameroon.  At  the  country  level,  the  top  three  producers,  

Côte  d’Ivoire,  Ghana  and  Indonesia,  represented  69  percent  of  global  production  in  2012-­‐13  (ICCO  

0  

500  

1000  

1500  

2000  

2500  

3000  

3500  

Average  Monthy  ICCO  Cacao  Price  

 

  42  

2014b).  West  Africa  dominates  as  a  region,  with  Côte  d’Ivoire,  Ghana,  Nigeria  and  Cameroon  

providing  70  percent  of  supply  in  2012-­‐13.  Côte  d’Ivoire  accounted  for  36  percent  of  global  output  

and  Ghana  provided  21  percent.  Both  countries  have  export  monopolies,  making  them  oligopolists.  

At  the  level  of  traders,  three  multinationals—Cargill,  ADM  and  Olam—and  one  local  trader,  

Ghana’s  state-­‐owned  Produce  Buying  Company,  held  45  percent  of  the  West  African  market  in  the  

2011-­‐12  season  (George  2012).  Consolidation  is  greater  in  Côte  d’Ivoire,  with  the  top  three  traders,  

Cargill,  ADM  and  Barry  Callebaut,  controlling  50%  of  the  market.  The  largest  Ivoirian  exporter  is  

Saf-­‐Cacao  with  a  7  percent  share.  Ecom  acquired  Armajaro’s  commodity  trading  business  in  2013,  

making  Ecom  the  third  largest  trader  in  West  Africa  and  the  fourth  largest  in  Côte  d’Ivoire,  per  

2011-­‐12  figures  (ICCO  2012,  Almeida  2013).    

Processing  is  similarly  consolidated,  with  Barry  Callebaut,  Cargill  and  ADM  controlling  

approximately  46  percent  of  grindings;  and  Barry  Callebaut,  Cargill  and  Blommer  representing  

about  68  percent  of  industrial  chocolate  (UNCTAD  2008,  Barry  Callebaut  2012).  In  September  

2014,  Cargill  announced  its  acquisition  of  ADM’s  chocolate  business,  consolidating  the  market  

further  (Bunge  &  Josephs  2014).  Concentration  among  brand  owners  is  less  intense.  As  of  2012,  the  

top  five  brand  owners,  Kraft,  Mars,  Nestlé,  Ferrero  and  the  Hershey  Company,  controlled  35%  of  

the  market,  with  the  top  three  holding  27%  (George  2012).  Thus,  producers  face  oligopsonies  in  

trading  and  processing,  which  have  intensified  over  time  due  to  acquisitions  among  major  firms.    

4.6  Supply  and  Demand  

The  International  Cocoa  Organization  (ICCO  2014b)  estimates  2013-­‐14  crop  production  at  4.35  

million  MT,  and  grindings  at  4.26  million  MT.  Figure  4.3  illustrates  production  and  grindings  from  

2005  through  2014  (ICCO  2014b).  Over  the  past  decade,  production  and  grindings  have  increased  

overall,  with  production  showing  more  volatility  than  grindings.  Grindings  have  fallen  below  crop  

output  during  five  of  the  last  ten  years,  requiring  the  industry  to  draw  on  stocks.  

 

 

  43  

Figure  4.3:  Global  Cacao  Production  and  Grindings,  2005  to  2014  

 

Data  source:  ICCO  (2014b)  

 

Demand  for  certified  cacao  has  grown  with  overall  demand.  Fairtrade  cacao  sales  volumes  

increased  47  percent  from  2011-­‐12  while  UTZ  purchasing  rose  149  percent  in  2013  (FLO  2014b,  

UTZ  2014c).  Mainstream  brand  owners,  including  The  Hershey  Company,  Mars  and  Ferrero  Rocher,  

have  committed  to  converting  100%  of  their  cacao  to  certified  sources  by  2020,  indicating  that  

demand  growth  will  continue  (TCC  2012).  Child  labor  has  been  a  key  demand  shifter  (Sendjou  

2014).  In  2001,  media  reports  of  child  slavery  on  cacao  farms  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  spurred  campaigns  

demanding  that  companies  use  certified  cacao  (Payson  Center  2010).  In  order  to  stave  off  national  

legislation  that  would  have  mandated  slavery  free  labels  on  chocolate,  industry  negotiated  the  

Harkin-­‐Engel  Protocol.  The  Protocol  requires  industry  to  take  steps  to  eliminate  the  ILO’s  Worst  

Forms  of  Child  Labor  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  and  Ghana,  and  implement  an  independent  certification  

system  to  verify  this.  Subsequent  research  (Payson  Center  2010,  Fair  Labor  Association  2012)  

found  that  a  significant  number  of  children  in  West  Africa  engage  in  dangerous  work  on  their  

families’  farms,  such  as  using  machetes  and  pesticides.  This  has  led  to  growing  demand  for  certified  

chocolate.    

2,000  

2,500  

3,000  

3,500  

4,000  

4,500  

2005   2006   2007   2008   2009   2010   2011   2012   2013   2014  

Production  (1,000  MT)  

Grindings  (1,000  MT)  

 

  44  

At  the  same  time,  consumers  have  shown  increasing  concerns  about  the  environmental  

impacts  of  products  they  purchase,  and  the  incomes  of  farmers  and  workers  in  supply  chains,  

boosting  demand  for  goods  with  the  target  certifications  (Nielsen  2014).  The  sector  has  come  to  see  

certification  as  a  way  to  improve  farmer  livelihoods  and  address  the  projected  supply  deficit,  by  

training  farmers  on  yield-­‐enhancing  practices,  providing  higher  prices  that  incent  farmers  to  

implement  these,  and  monitoring  farm  management  and  outcomes  (TCC  2012,  Major  2014).  More  

stringent  food  safety  regulations  have  increased  the  appeal  of  the  traceability,  which  certification  

provides.  Thus,  certification  has  moved  from  a  niche  concept  to  a  mainstream  business  strategy.  

4.7  Production  Constraints    

Producers  face  diverse  challenges,  many  of  which  go  beyond  issues  that  certification  addresses.  It  is  

important  to  consider  these,  as  they  stand  to  limit  the  potential  of  certification  to  affect  producer  

profits.  Hatløy  et  al.  (2012)  consulted  a  broad  range  of  stakeholders  to  identify  key  production  and  

marketing  constraints  in  the  Ivorian  cacao  sector.  These  include  subsistence  incomes,  lack  of  access  

to  affordable  credit,  low  physical  quality  and  poor  yields.  Average  yields  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  range  from  

200  to  500  kg  per  hectare  (ha),  far  below  the  yields  of  one  to  two  MT  per  ha  seen  in  Indonesia.  

Hatløy  et  al.  (2012)  attributed  low  yields  to  aging  tree  stock,  poor  soil  fertility  and  insufficient  pest  

control,  which  result  from  high  input  costs,  insufficient  credit,  and  lack  of  training  (World  Cocoa  

Foundation  2013).  Per  Fortson  et  al.  (2011),  input  use  is  particularly  low  in  Côte  d’Ivoire.  They  

found  that  11  percent  of  Ivorian  farmers  used  fertilizer  and  54  percent  used  pesticide  (insecticide  

and  fungicide).  In  contrast,  44  percent  of  farmers  in  Ghana  used  fertilizer,  while  77  to  89  percent  of  

producers  in  Cameroon,  Ghana  and  Nigeria  used  pesticide.    

Hatløy  et  al.  (2012)  also  note  that  the  low  prevalence  of  cooperatives  makes  service  

provision  costly,  and  leaves  producers  with  little  bargaining  power.  Where  co-­‐ops  exist,  they  may  

have  poor  management  and  governance,  which  effectively  reduce  member  returns.  They  also  may  

pay  members  on  a  delayed  schedule,  leaving  farmers  to  sell  their  cacao  to  intermediaries  at  a  lower  

 

  45  

price  if  they  need  immediate  payment.  All  of  the  target  certifications  fill  gaps  in  training  on  IPM  and  

fertility  improvement.  UTZ  also  addresses  productivity  and  physical  quality  improvement,  while  

Fairtrade  requires  buyers  to  provide  pre-­‐financing  that  helps  co-­‐ops  purchase  members’  output.    

However,  none  of  the  certifications  addresses  input  costs  or  farm-­‐level  credit  access.  

Hatløy  et  al.  (2012)  also  identified  social  issues  that  can  constrain  farm  outcomes,  including  

lack  of  access  to  water,  education  and  sanitation;  poor  roads,  malaria,  and  HIV/AIDS.  Ill  health  can  

reduce  labor  capacity,  while  poor  roads  add  transport  costs.  Low  levels  of  education  leave  farmers  

without  the  skills  to  manage  farm  finances,  use  market  information  and  ensure  that  buyers  are  not  

cheating  them  (e.g.,  with  faulty  scales,  or  calculations).  Certification  involves  financial  auditing  that  

addresses  some  forms  of  cheating.  It  does  not  address  water,  sanitation,  public  education,  

infrastructure,  health  or  input  costs,  leaving  constraints  that  may  dampen  certification  impacts.    

4.8  Cacao  Development  Projects  

In  order  to  address  the  constraints  that  affect  cacao  farmers  and  the  sector,  governments,  NGOs,  

and  industry  have  implemented  diverse  development  initiatives.  Where  certification  and  

development  efforts  co-­‐occur,  both  shape  producer  outcomes.  Thus,  these  efforts  must  be  

considered  when  evaluating  the  effects  of  certification.    Table  4.2  outlines  programs  implemented  

in  Côte  d’Ivoire  from  2004,  when  certification  began,  through  2013,  when  fieldwork  occurred.  It  

identifies  activities  that  overlap  with  certification,  or  that  affect  price,  yield  or  expenditure.  

There  are  several  similarities  across  the  initiatives.  Apart  from  Côte  d’Ivoire’s  extension  

(Hatløy  2012),  all  are  led  by  industry,  or  by  NGOs  with  industry  support.  All  are  diversified  in  scope,  

except  for  the  IDH  Fertilizer  Initiative  (IDH,  Undated).  Most  programs  reach  only  a  small  proportion  

of  Côte  d’Ivoire’s  farmers,  though  the  World  Cocoa  Foundation  (WCF  2014b)  and  Mars  (Undated)  

seek  to  engage  over  10  percent,  while  IDH  aims  to  reach  more  than  20  percent.    Cargill  (2014)  and  

Nestlé  (Undated)  provide  free  improved  planting  material,  and  Cargill  also  provides  inputs,  which  

could  reduce  expenditures  and  boost  yields.  

 

  46  

Table  4.2:  Cacao  development  efforts  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  (CI),  2004  to  present  

Initiative  Name     Lead  Organization  and  

Partners  

Lead  Organization  

Type  

Aspects  That  Overlap  With  Certification  or  Affect  Outcomes  

Years  and  Farmers  Reached  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  

National  Extension:  ANADER  

Côte  d’Ivoire  government  

Government   Farmer  training  and  advising  

Ongoing    

Reach:  Not  Reported  

Sustainable  Tree  Crops  Program  (STCP)  

International  Inst.  of  Tropical  Agriculture  (IITA)  with  chocolate  and  cacao  industry  

Research  Inst.   Farmer  training  (including  RA  criteria).  Group  formation,  and  management  training  

2003-­‐2011    Trained  12,297  farmers  in  person,  142  with  videos;  20  co-­‐ops    

Fertilizer  Initiative  

IDH  Sustainable  Trade  Initiative  (IDH)  with  industry,  ICCO,  fertilizer  suppliers  and  governments  

NGO  (Dutch)   Fertilizer  usage  training  and  promotion  

2012-­‐present    Goal:  200,000  farmers  in  CI  and  Nigeria  

Cocoa  Livelihoods  Program  

World  Cocoa  Foundation  with  BMZ,  IDH,  and  Bill  and  Melinda  Gates  Foundation  

Industry  association  

Famer  and  group  management  training,  increase  access  to  credit,  certification  training  

2009-­‐13    106,000  farmers  and  36  groups  (12,500  members)  in  CI  and  four  countries    

Encouraging  Socially  and  Environmentally  Responsible  Ag.  Practices  (SERAP)  

ADM  with  GIZ  and  IITA  

Trader   Farmer  and    co-­‐op  training,  interest-­‐free  credit,  quality  premiums,  certification  

2005-­‐present    60,000  farmers  in  CI,    Nigeria  and  Indonesia  

Quality  Partner  Program    

Barry  Callebaut   Trader   Farmer  training,  audits,  interest-­‐free  loans  to  co-­‐ops;  incentives  for  co-­‐ops  for  quality,  output  and  management  

2005-­‐present    40,000  farmers  in  82  co-­‐ops  as  of  2013  

Cocoa  Horizons   Barry  Callebaut   Trader   Farmer  training,  controlled  fermentation  with  premium  

2012-­‐21    Goal:  50,000  farmers  in  CI  and  four  other  countries    

 

  47  

Cocoa  Promise,  Co-­‐op  Academy  

Cargill  with  CCC,  IDH,  CARE  

Trader   Farmer  and  extension  training,  input  and  seedling  provision,  co-­‐op  capacity  building,  certification  

2012-­‐present      50,395  farmers  trained  and  certified;  supporting  240  farmer  groups    

iMPACT  (Mars  Partnership  for  African  Cocoa  Communities  of  Tomorrow)  

Mars  with  Africare,  GIZ,  IFESH,  IITA,  RA,  Int.  Cocoa  Initiative  

Brand  owner   Farmer  training,  group  capacity  building  

2007-­‐11    Reached  40,000  people  in  CI  &  Ghana  

Vision  for  Change  

Mars  with  ICRAF   Brand  owner   Farmer  training,  farm  rehabilitation,  certification  

2010-­‐20    Goal:  150,000  farmers  

Market-­‐Oriented  Promotion  of  Sustainable  Certified  Cocoa  Production  

 

Mondelez  with  RA,  GIZ,  USAID,  IITA,  Armajaro,  ANADER  

Brand  owner   Co-­‐op  capacity  building;  RA  certification  training  

2005-­‐09    2,039  farmers  in  32  co-­‐ops  

Cocoa  Plan   Nestlé   Brand  owner   Farmer  training,  seedling  provision,  Fairtrade  &  UTZ  certification,  computers  and  bikes  for  co-­‐ops  

28,000  from  60  co-­‐ops  

Sources:  See  text,  and  GIZ  2011  

Most  programs  include  a  strong  focus  on  training  farmers  to  use  good  agricultural  practices  

that  improve  yield  and  physical  quality,  filling  the  gap  in  extension  and  farmer  training.  Producer  

group  formation  and  capacity  building,  such  as  record  keeping  and  management  training,  are  

included  in  efforts  implemented  by  the  IITA  (2009),  Barry  Callebaut  (2014),  Cargill  (2014),  

Mondelez  (GTZ  2008)  and  Nestlé  (Undated).  ADM  (2011)  and  Barry  Callebaut  also  provide  

premiums  for  physical  quality  and  volume.  All  of  these  activities  overlap  with  certification.  

Certification  is  also  a  component  of  initiatives  run  by  the  World  Cocoa  Foundation  (WCF  2014b),  

IITA,  ADM,  Cargill,  Mars,  Mondelez  and  Nestlé.  Most  programs  also  include  social  development  

activities  that  are  not  stated  in  Table  4.2,  as  they  do  not  overlap  with  certification  or  affect  

 

  48  

economic  outcomes  directly.  However,  by  addressing  constraints  in  the  enabling  environment,  such  

efforts  indirectly  affect  producers’  outcomes,  and  thus  modulate  the  potential  impacts  of  

certification.    

4.9  Conclusion  

A  review  of  the  cacao  sector,  and  Côte  d’Ivoire’s  industry  in  particular,  indicates  that  producers  and  

certifiers  operate  in  a  complex  environment  that  is  marked  by  heterogeneity  across  producers  and  

time.  Farmers  face  diverse  economic,  agronomic  and  social  challenges  that  can  limit  the  potential  

effects  of  certification.  They  may  market  independently  and/or  through  co-­‐ops,  and  co-­‐ops  sell  to  

different  sets  of  buyers,  resulting  in  price  variation.  Over  time,  market  prices  have  shown  volatility,  

and  market  power  and  supply/demand  balance  have  shifted.  The  Ivorian  government  regulates  

internal  markets,  limiting  our  ability  to  generalize  research  findings  on  certification  outcomes  in  

other  countries  that  do  not  set  prices.    

Certified  demand  has  grown  over  time  but  so,  too,  has  supply,  making  it  uncertain  what  

percentage  of  output  a  given  group  would  sell  under  certified  terms.  Farmers  may  be  involved  in  

various  cacao  development  initiatives  that  seek  to  rectify  the  same  constraints  that  certification  

targets,  making  it  difficult  to  determine  the  relative  effects  of  certification.  Such  efforts  also  aim  to  

improve  social  problems  that  constrain  outcomes,  modulating  the  enabling  environment.  

In  order  to  evaluate  the  effects  of  certification  in  a  given  context,  it  is  essential  to  undertake  

field  research  using  non-­‐certified  controls  that  are  otherwise  comparable  to  certified  producers,  

and  analyze  the  data  using  techniques  that  address  selection  bias  and  account  for  the  effects  of  

other  relevant  variables.  The  next  chapter  will  present  the  results  of  producer  surveys  conducted  in  

Côte  d’Ivoire,  designed  to  fill  this  need.  

 

 

  49  

Chapter  5. Field  Research  

Given  that  the  theoretical  evaluation  and  the  literature  review  both  indicate  that  the  effects  of  

certification  on  smallholders’  net  incomes  vary,  I  undertook  fieldwork  on  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  to  explore  

this  question  with  respect  to  mass-­‐market  cacao.  Sections  5.1  through  5.3  outline  the  design,  

fieldwork,  and  data  analyses  respectively.  Section  5.4  presents  the  results  and  Section  5.5  discusses  

overall  conclusions.  

   

5.1  Design  and  Sample  

The  study  used  a  cross-­‐section  design  with  301  cacao  farmers  in  35  co-­‐ops  in  Côte  d’Ivoire.  Table  

5.1  shows  the  sample  distribution.  Farmers  include  76  controls  and  225  certified  producers  (125  

single-­‐certified,  75  dual-­‐certified,  and  25  triple-­‐certified).  Among  co-­‐ops,  12  are  controls  and  23  are  

certified  (15  single-­‐certified,  seven  dual-­‐certified  and  one  triple-­‐certified).  Using  only  single-­‐

certified  farmers  would  have  been  ideal.  However,  due  to  the  prevalence  of  multi-­‐certified  co-­‐ops,  

and  the  small  number  of  Fairtrade  (FLO)  co-­‐ops  in  the  target  regions,  it  was  not  possible  to  recruit  

any  producers  with  only  FLO,  or  only  Rainforest  Alliance  (RA)  in  one  region.  

The  World  Agroforestry  Center  partnered  on  fieldwork  and  advised  on  sampling  locations.  

We  excluded  border  areas  for  security,  and  the  southeast,  where  Stemler  (2012)  found  the  soils  to  

be  highly  acidic  (pH  <  5.5)  in  contrast  to  other  cacao  regions.  High  acidity  limits  phosphorous  

uptake,  reducing  yield.  We  chose  three  departments  (regions):  Soubré  in  the  west,  Divo  in  the  

center,  and  Adzopé  in  the  east.  In  each  department,  fieldwork  took  place  in  four  geographically  

dispersed  sous-­‐preféts,  selected  based  on  the  presence  of  certified  co-­‐ops.  Figure  5.1  shows  the  

location  of  each  region  and  select  sous-­‐preféts.  

 

       

 

  50  

Table  5.1:  Sample  Distribution    

 

Overall  Distribution  Control   RA   RA-­‐UTZ   UTZ   FLO-­‐RA   FLO-­‐UTZ   FLO-­‐RA-­‐

UTZ  F   C   F   C   F   C   F   C   F   C   F   C   F   C  

Overall  Total   76   12   50   6   25   4   75   9   25   1   25   2   25   1    

 

Distribution  By  Department  and  Sous-­‐Prefét  Control   RA   RA-­‐UTZ   UTZ   FLO-­‐RA   FLO-­‐UTZ   FLO-­‐RA-­‐

UTZ     F   C   F   C   F   C   F   C   F   C   F   C   F   C  Soubré  Dept.                              Boyu   5   1           15   3       10   1      Lilyo   10   1           10   1              Meagui   5   1   15   1                      Oupoyo   5   1   10   1               15   1      

Soubré  Total   25   4   25   2       25   4       25   2        

Divo  Dept.                              

Didoko   5   1   10   1       15   1              Divo   5   1   5   1                      Guitry   10   1   10   2       10   1              

Ogoudou  5   1               25   1          

Divo  Total   25   4   25   4       25   2   25   1            

Adzopé  Dept.                              

Adzopé   5   1       5   1   10   1           25   1  Affrey   10   1           15   2              Akoupé   6   1       10   1                  Yakassé   5   1       10   2                  

Adzopé  Total   26   4       25   4   25   3           25   1    

Regional  Total   76   12   50   6   25   4   75   9   25   1   25   2   25   1  F=  Farmers,  C  =  Co-­‐ops    

 

  51  

 Figure  5.1  Research  Sites    

Source:  Created  in  Google  Earth  with  data  from  GPS  watch.  

 

Lists  from  certifiers,  and  ANADER  and  the  CCC,  served  to  identify  certified  and  control    

co-­‐ops  respectively.  I  randomly  selected  co-­‐ops  for  recruitment  using  Microsoft  Excel  to  randomize  

co-­‐ops  in  each  sous-­‐prefét.  Each  sous-­‐prefét  had  at  least  one  certified  and  one  control  co-­‐op.  Due  to  

the  geographic  distribution  of  certified  co-­‐ops  it  was  not  possible  to  recruit  a  co-­‐op  with  each  

certification  in  each  sous-­‐prefét.  Additionally,  each  multi-­‐certified  type  (FLO-­‐RA,  FLO-­‐UTZ,    

FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ,  and  RA-­‐UTZ)  is  in  only  one  department,  and  there  are  only  one  or  two  FLO  co-­‐ops  per  

type.  As  such,  multi-­‐certification  is  confounded  with  location  for  all  multi-­‐certifications,  and  co-­‐op  

for  FLO  types.    

 

  52  

5.2  Data  Collection  and  Survey  Instruments    

Fieldwork  took  place  in  August  and  September  2013.  It  consisted  of  structured  farmer  surveys  and  

semi-­‐structured  co-­‐op  management  interviews  covering  the  2012-­‐13  cacao  season  (October  to  

September).  Six  enumerators,  and  the  field  coordinator  in  a  few  cases,  conducted  the  surveys  and  

interviews.  They  randomly  selected  farmers  to  survey  at  each  village  or  co-­‐op  facility.  Training  and  

pilots  preceded  data  collection.  I  also  interviewed  representatives  from  certifiers,  traders  and  

brand  owners  to  obtain  background  information.  

Survey  and  interview  instruments  are  in  Appendix  A.  Producer  surveys  covered  socioeconomic  

and  farm  characteristics,  cacao  farming  experience,  farm  management  practices,  training,  

extension,  markets,  certified  crop  volume  sold,  certified  crop  revenue,  price  premiums  received,  

family  labor,  farm  expenditures,  co-­‐op  membership  payments,  perceptions  on  livelihoods  factors,  

and  what  farmers  expected  and  received  from  certification.  Questions  on  farm  management,  sales  

volume  and  revenue,  expenditures,  and  livelihoods  perceptions  also  asked  about  change  over  the  

past  four  years,  and  since  certification.  Co-­‐op  interviews  covered  membership  size,  founding,  prices  

and  premiums  received  and  paid  to  members,  volumes  sold  at  a  premium,  projects  funded  with  

buyer  funds  and  premiums,  and  member  fees.  Certified  co-­‐ops  were  also  asked  to  state  when  and  

why  they  became  certified,  certification  costs  and  certified  sales.    

Certifier  interviews  addressed  the  certification  process  and  costs,  training  and  support  that  

certifiers  provide  to  farmers,  premium  amounts  and  usage,  certified  sales  volumes,  and  what  

outcomes  certifiers  measure  and  observe.  Trader  and  brand  owner  interviews  covered  reasons  for  

purchasing  certified  cacao,  expected  and  observed  outcomes,  if  and  how  they  select  producers  and  

groups  for  certification,  challenges  in  certifying  farmers,  support  they  give  farmers  and  groups,  key  

needs  certification  doesn’t  address,  and  premium  payments  and  allocation.  

 

 

  53  

5.3  Data  Analyses  

Data  were  entered  into  Excel,  double-­‐checked  for  accuracy,  screened  for  outliers,  and  analyzed  in  

Stata.  Two  outliers  were  removed,  one  each  for  extremely  high  or  low  average  prices.  Another  

subject  did  not  report  cacao  growing  area,  limiting  their  useable  data.  This  left  298  subjects  in  all  

analyses,  and  299  for  most  group  means  tests.  Analyses  focused  on  evaluating  differences  between  

certified  producers  and  controls,  and  characterizing  the  effects  of  certification  on  farm  gate  price,  

yield,  and  variable  cash  expenditure  per  hectare  (ha).    

Farm  gate  price  is  defined  as  average  price  across  volume  sold,  calculated  as  total  revenue  

divided  by  total  volume  sold.  Yield  is  calculated  as  total  output  divided  by  bearing  cacao  area,  which  

contains  trees  aged  four  or  more  years.14  Variable  expenditure  includes  hired  labor,  agrochemicals,  

planting  material,  pesticide  sprayer  rental,  and  fuel  for  machinery  and  cacao  transport.  It  excludes  

family  labor  opportunity  cost.  It  is  calculated  as  total  variable  expenditure  divided  by  total  cacao  ha.  

5.3.1  Differences  in  Means,  and  Certification  Effects  on  Price  

T-­‐tests  served  to  evaluate  differences  between  certified  and  control  group  means  for  

socioeconomic,  agronomic  and  economic  measures.  Analyses  compared  differences  between  

controls  and  certified  producers  as  a  group,  and  by  certification  type,  for  the  overall  sample  and  

within  each  region.  T-­‐tests  for  equal  or  unequal  variance  were  used  as  appropriate,  per  variance  

ratio  tests.  T-­‐tests  were  sufficient  to  assess  the  effects  of  certification  on  farm  gate  price,  as  this  

requires  a  simple  comparison  of  prices  across  producers  who  sell  any  portion  of  their  crop  via  

certified  channels  and  those  who  do  not.    

 

                                                                                                                         14  Bearing  cacao  area  was  determined  per  survey  data  on  cacao  areas  of  different  ages.  I  chose  a  four-­‐year  age  cutoff  per  data  on  the  use  of  improved  varietals  (which  can  bear  at  age  three)  versus  traditional  varietals  (which  can  bear  at  age  four).  Only  two  producers  with  trees  aged  three  years  used  improved  varietals,  but  it  is  uncertain  whether  they  used  them  exclusively.  To  be  conservative,  I  treated  them  as  nonbearing.  Bearing  area  differed  from  total  cacao  area  for  26  producers.  

 

  54  

5.3.2  Yield  and  Variable  Cash  Expenditure  Regressions  

Regressions  provided  estimates  of  the  effects  of  certification  on  yield  and  expenditure.  The  yield  

models  include  three  certification  dummies  (for  each  certification:  FLO,  RA  and  UTZ),  and  economic  

and  agronomic  inputs  that  prior  research  has  found  to  have  significant  effects:  secure  land  tenure  

(Smith  2004,  Place  2009),  cacao  area  and  farm  area  (Carter  1984,  Aneani  and  Ofori-­‐Frimpong  

2013),  fertilizer  and  pesticide  expenditures,  frequency  of  weeding  and  pruning  (Aneani  and  Ofori-­‐

Frimpong  2013),  cacao  trees  per  ha  (Spaggiari  Souza  et  al.  2009),  hired  labor  expenditure  (Onoja,  

Deedam,  and  Achike  2012),  and  tree  age  (farmer’s  age  served  as  a  proxy).  The  studies  cited  indicate  

that  all  of  these  variables  positively  affect  yields,  except  for  cacao  area  and  farm  area,  which  have  a  

negative  effect,  and  tree  age,  which  has  a  positive  effect  up  to  a  point,  then  plateaus  and  declines.    

The  yield  models  are  stated  below.  Model  1  and  Model  2  are  for  the  overall  sample.  Model  2  

differs  from  Model  1  in  that  it  includes  farmer’s  age,  farm  ownership,  and  dummies  for  each  region  

and  certification-­‐region  interaction.  Model  3  was  estimated  separately  for  each  department,  with  

only  significant  variables  retained.  All  models  assume  error  terms  (ei)  are  independent  and  

normally  distributed,  and  use  pooled  standard  errors  (assuming  equal  variance  within  groups).  

 1.  Yieldi  =  ß1FLO  +  ß2RA  +  ß3UTZ  +  ß4BearingCacaoAreai    +  ß5Cacao  Trees/hai    

+  ß6FertilizerExpenditure/hai  +  ß7PesticideExpenditure/hai  +  ß8LaborExpenditure/hai    +  ei      2.  Yieldi  =  ß1FLO  +  ß2RA  +  ß3UTZ  +  ß4Farmer’s  Agei    +  ß5Owns  Farmi    +  ß6BearingCacaoAreai      

+  ß7Cacao  Trees/hai  +  F  ß8FertilizerExpenditure/hai  +  ß9PesticideExpenditure/hai    

+  ß10LaborExpenditure/hai    +  ß11Soubré  +  ß12Adzopé  +  ß13Soubré*FLO  +  ß14Soubré*RA    

+  ß15Soubré*UTZ  +  ß16Adzopé*FLO  +  ß17Adzopé*RA    +  ß18Adzopé*UTZ    +  ei    3.  Yieldi,  by  region  =  ß1FLO  +  ß2RA  +  ß3UTZ  +  ß4Owns  Farmi    +  ß5BearingCacaoAreai      

+  ß6Weeding  Frequencyi  +  ß7Cacao  pruning  Frequencyi  +  ß8FertilizerExpenditure/hai    

+  ß9InsecticideExpenditurei  +  ß10HiredLaborExpenditure/hai    +  ß11Family  Labor/wk/hai    

+  ei  

 

 

  55  

Two  measures  quantified  the  effect  of  certification  on  yield:  

 1.  Total  intercept  shift.  This  represents  the  effect  of  certification  without  considering  other  

variables  that  affect  yield,  and  that  might  also  be  impacted  by  certification.  It  reflects  the  

assumption  that  we  would  not  attribute  group  differences  on  other  explanatory  variables  to  

certification.  It  is  the  sum  of  dummies  for  each  certification  type.  For  example,  for  FLO-­‐UTZ,  the  

total  intercept  shift  is:  ß1+  ß3.  

 2.  Total  effect  of  certification:  This  estimates  how  certification  may  affect  yields  through  both  the  

intercept  shift  and  the  other  explanatory  variables.  It  assumes  that  certification  explains  the  entire  

difference  between  certified  producers  and  controls,  for  every  explanatory  variable.  Formally,  this  

is  known  as  the  Oaxaca  decomposition  (O’Donnell  et  al  2007).  It  is  the  sum  of  certification  dummies  

for  each  certification  type,  and  the  coefficient  for  each  additional  explanatory  variable  multiplied  by  

the  difference  in  certified  and  control  means  for  that  variable.  For  example,  for  FLO-­‐UTZ,  the  total  

effect  of  certification  is:  ß1+  ß3  +  ∑j=1..N  [ßj  *  (certified  meanFLO-­‐UTZ  –  control  mean)]  

 

The  variable  expenditure  regression  models  include  three  certification  dummies  (FLO,  RA  

and  UTZ);  and  economic  and  agronomic  variables  that  prior  research  has  found  to  affect  

expenditure:  household  assets,  family  labor  supply,  farming  knowledge  and  farm  size  (Marenya  and  

Barrett  2007,  Adimassu,  Kessler  and  Hengsdijk  2012,  Danso-­‐Abbeam,  Setsoafia  and  Ansah  2014).15  

They  also  include  cacao  trees  per  ha  and  frequency  of  input  applications,  which  would  logically  

increase  labor  and  input  demands;  and  family  labor,  as  this  was  not  included  in  the  expenditure  

variable  and  must  be  accounted  for.  As  with  yield,  analyses  included  models  with  regional  

dummies,  and  calculations  of  the  total  intercept  shift,  and  total  effect  of  certification.    

                                                                                                                         15  The  studies  cited  used  household  size  or  adults  in  the  household  to  represent  labor  supply.  Secure  land  tenure  has  also  been  found  to  have  a  significant  effect  (Smith  2004,  Fenske  2011),  though  it  was  not  significant  in  my  models.    

 

  56  

The  expenditure  models  are  below.  Models  1A  and  1B  use  Total  Farm  Size,  where  Models  

2A  and  2B  use  household  size.  The  “A”  models  do  not  include  family  labor,  while  the  “B”  models  do.  

All  models  assume  errors  (ei)  are  independent  and  normally  distributed,  and  use  pooled  standard  

errors  (assuming  equal  variance  within  groups).  

1A.  Variable  Cash  Expenditure/cacao  hai  =  ß1FLO  +  ß2RA  +  ß3UTZ  +  ß4TotalFarmSizei      

+  ß5Cacao  Trees/hai  +  ß6Training  Sessions/yri  +  ß7FertilizerApplications/yri    

+  ß8FungicideApplications/yri  +  ei    

 

1B.  Variable  Cash  Expenditure/cacao  hai  =  ß1FLO  +  ß2RA  +  ß3UTZ  +  ß4TotalFarmSizei      

+  ß5Cacao  Trees/hai  +  ß6Training  Sessions/yri  +  ß7FertilizerApplications/yri    

+  ß8FungicideApplications/yri  +  ß9Family  Labor/wk/hai    +  ei    

 

2A.  Variable  Cash  Expenditure/cacao  hai  =  ß1FLO  +  ß2RA  +  ß3UTZ  +  ß4HouseholdSizei      

+  ß5Cacao  Trees/hai  +  ß6Training  Sessions/yri  +  ß7FertilizerApplications/yri    

+  ß8FungicideApplications/yri  +  ei    

 

2B.  Variable  Cash  Expenditure/cacao  ha  =  ß1FLO  +  ß2RA  +  ß3UTZ  +  ß4HouseholdSizei    +  ß5Cacao  

Trees/ha  i  +  ß6Training  Sessions/yri  +  ß7FertilizerApplications/yri  +  

ß8FungicideApplications/yri  +  ß9Family  Labor/wk/hai    +  ei    

 

5.4  Results  

Table  5.2  presents  overall  descriptive  statistics.  Most  variables  have  wide  variation.  Some  have  

particularly  large  ranges  that  might  be  taken  as  signs  of  outliers  or  errors,  such  as  pruning  and  

input  expenditures.  However,  the  upper  bounds  for  fertilizer  and  pesticide  are  not  aberrations  and  

represent  the  recommended  quantities:  nine  bags  of  fertilizer  and  two  liters  of  insecticide  per  ha  

(ICRAF  2013,  survey  data).  For  pruning,  the  upper  bound  applies  to  over  ten  percent  of  the  sample,  

and  represents  less  efficient  pruning  (e.g.,  pruning  is  done  each  time  the  producer  visits  the  farm).    

The  means  align  with  sector  data  (Fortson  et  al.  2011,  Hatløy  et  al.  2012),  indicating  that  the  

sample  is  typical  of  Ivorian  producers.  Farmers  are  almost  all  male  with  a  mean  age  of  46.  On    

 

  57  

Table  5.2:  Producer  Summary  Statistics,  Full  Sample,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season  

a.  Fungicide  expenditure  is  per  bearing  cacao  area,  as  fungicide  is  used  on  pods.    b.  Pesticide  expenditure  is  the  sum  of  insecticide  and  fungicide  expenditures.  c.  Yield  is  per  bearing  cacao  ha.  Gross  revenue,  variable  expenditure  and  profit  are  per  total  cacao  ha.    

Variable   N   Mean   Std.  Dev.   Min   Max    Farmer  Socioeconomic  Characteristics  Age   297   45.69   10.9       20   83  Male  (dummy,  Male  =  1)   299   0.98   0.14   0   1  Household  (HH)  size   296   10.78   6.60   1   40  HH  income,  CFA   299   1,894,894   1,696,484   70,325   11,100,000  HH  inc./HH  member,  CFA   296   205,316.7   178,669   5,409.62   1,120,760  Years  of  education   289   6.2   4.74   0   15  Farmer  Experience,  Farm  Characteristics,  Farm  Practices  and  Itemized  Expenditures  Per  Year  Own/family  farm  (dum.  Y=1)   299   0.60   0.49   0   1  Cacao  experience,  years   294   19.20   10.49   1   49  Extension  visits/year   287   8.79   11.61   0   50  Training  sessions/year   298   12.31   13.93   0   48  Total  cacao  hectares  (ha)   298   5.80   4.48   1   28  Bearing  cacao  ha     298   5.67   4.46   1   28  Total  farm  ha   291   7.71   5.87   1   38  Average  cacao  trees/ha   255   1,303.87   212.77   513.16   2,000  Average  shade  trees/ha   294   7.14   8.00   0   75  No.  of  Good  ag  practices  (of  7)   297   4.88   1.17   2   7  Weeding  frequency/year   298   2.77   1.41   0   24  Pruning  frequency/year   262   12.01   28.84   0   200  Fertilizer  applications/year   298   0.22   0.49   0   2  Insecticide  applications/year   299   1.71   1.24   0   12  Fungicide  applications/year   298   1.30   1.20   0   5  Fertilizer  expenditure/ha,  CFA   296   5,048.64   17,233.07   0   180,000  Insecticide  exp./ha,  CFA   295   4,551.21   7,166.83   0   42,000  Fungicide  exp./ha,  CFA  a   295   1,202.85   3,661.76   0   36,000  Pesticide  exp./ha,  CFA  b   220   5,756.62   9,648.76   0   72,000  Labor  expenditure/ha,  CFA   220   36,032.75   50,694.74   0   312,745.10  Family  labor  hours/wk/ha   297   24.41   34.28   0   520  Marketing  and  Economic  Outcomes  c  Buyers  used     299   1.13   0.39   1   4  Buyers  in  market   287   1.84   1.62   1   10  %  volume  sold  to  co-­‐op   296   96.44   13.64   0   100  Transports  cacao  to  sell  (Y=1)   296   0.26   0.44   0   1  Minutes  to  transport  cacao   291   22.02   48.32   0   240  Yield,  kg/ha   298   458.19   303.94   44.44   2,266  Average  price,  CFA/kg   298   752.98   29.45   533.33   925  Gross  revenue,  CFA/ha   298   336,958.4   224,378.7   18,750   1,716,667  Variable  cash  exp.  CFA/ha   298   51,931.52   61,135.89   0   442,333.3  Expenditure  efficiency,  CFA/kg   299   152.86   151.45   0   1,195  Cash  profit  CFA/ha   298   285,026.9   207,386.5   -­‐5,862.5   1,274,333  

 

  58  

average,  they  have  grown  cacao  for  19  years  and  have  5.8  ha  of  cacao.  Input  use  is  low,  with  mean  

expenditures  representing  one-­‐quarter  of  a  bag  of  fertilizer  and  one-­‐half  liter  of  insecticide  per  ha.  

Mean  yield  is  456  kg/ha  and  mean  price  is  753  CFA/kg.    

Farmers  receive  extension  visits  less  than  monthly,  attend  trainings  12  times  annually  and  

use  almost  five  of  seven  good  agricultural  practices.16  On  average,  farms  make  positive  variable  

profits,  though  some  realize  a  loss.  Farmers  sell  over  96  percent  of  their  crop  to  their  co-­‐ops,  

showing  high  loyalty.  On  average,  they  have  less  than  two  accessible  buyers,  suggesting  that  buyers  

have  market  power.  Certified  farmers  sell  an  average  of  88  percent  of  their  output  at  certified  

terms,  with  certified  sales  ranging  from  11  to  100  percent  across  producers.  If  this  figure  is  

adjusted  to  account  for  multi-­‐certification,  by  dividing  the  percentage  of  output  each  farmer  sells  as  

certified  by  the  number  of  certifications  covering  their  farm,  the  mean  is  68  percent.  The  difference  

between  the  two  could  be  thought  of  as  representing  the  unrecovered  costs  of  multi-­‐certification.  

Both  figures  are  well  above  sector  averages  of  48  percent  or  less,  as  reported  in  Chapter  4.  

5.4.1  Differences  in  Means,  and  Certification  Effects  on  Price  

Table  5.3  presents  differences  in  means  between  certified  farmers  and  controls,  for  regression  

variables  and  economic  outcomes,  overall  and  by  region.  Appendix  B  has  tables  with  overall  group  

means  for  all  variables  (Table  B1)  regional  group  means  for  agronomic  and  economic  variables  

(Table  B2),  and  significant  differences  by  region  for  all  variables  (Table  B3).  Overall,  compared  to  

controls,  certified  farmers  have  significantly  higher  prices,  lower  variable  expenditures  per  ha  and  

per  kg  of  cacao  sold,  higher  profits  per  ha,  more  extension  visits  and  training  sessions,  higher  

weeding  and  pruning  frequencies,  fewer  insecticide  applications,  and  lower  insecticide  and  

pesticide  expenditures  per  ha.  These  overall  significant  differences  hold  in  all  regions  for  price,  

extension  and  training  only.  Some  group  means  differ  significantly  only  in  one  region.  Certified    

                                                                                                                           16  Good  agricultural  practices  are  weeding,  structural  pruning,  sanitary  pruning,  fertilizing,  applying  insecticide  and  fungicide,  and  pruning  shade  trees.  

 

  59  

Table  5.3:  Differences  in  Means  Between  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls,  Regression  Variables  and  Economic  Outcomes,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season  a  

 Soubré   Divo   Adzopé   Overall  

Variable   N   Difference    and  p-­‐value   N   Difference    

and  p-­‐value   N   Difference    and  p-­‐value   N   Difference  

and  p-­‐value  

Farmer’s  Age   24  73                -­‐0.33  

25  74      0.11  

26  75                  3.29  

75  222            1.07  

Owns  Farm  (dum.  Y=1)  

25  74   0.06  

25  74    -­‐0.01  

26  75                  0.03  

76  223            0.03  

Cacao  ha,  bearing  

25  74   -­‐0.01  

25  74                      0.62  

26  74                  0.28  

76  222            0.32  

Total  farm  ha   2474                -­‐1.16  

2172                      0.69  

25  72                  0.40  

70  218          -­‐0.22  

Cacao  trees/ha   25  72              -­‐36.49  

2371                -­‐38.45  

17  47              71.57  

65  154      -­‐11.00  

Training  sessions  

25  74   10.12  ***  

24  74   5.54  ***  

26  74   14.17  ***  

76  222   9.96  ***  

Weeding  frequency/yr  

24  74    0.21  

25  74        0.24  

26  75                  0.44  

75  223   0.30      **  

Pruning  Frequency/yr  

21  63   1.51  

25  74   15.55  ***  

23  56   13.24  ***  

69  193   9.16  ***  

Fertilizer  applications  

25  73   0.05  

25  74   0.16  ***  

26  75                  0.18  

76  222            0.01  

Fungicide  applications  

25  74   0.24  

25  74   0.42        *  

25  75                  0.27  

75  223            0.03  

Fertilizer    exp./ha,  CFA  

25  73   -­‐  12,14.53  

24  74   758.62  **  

26  74   -­‐  656.83  

75  220   430.70    

Insecticide  exp./ha,  CFA  

25  73   -­‐  240.82  

24  74    -­‐2,699    *  

26  73   -­‐5,052    ***  

75  220   -­‐2,728    **  

Pesticide  exp./ha,  CFA  

25  73   598.19  

25  74   -­‐3,522.5    **  

25  73   -­‐8,125.8  **  

74  220   -­‐3,735    **  

Labor  exp/ha,  CFA  

23  72   -­‐  15,979.6  

25  74   -­‐  5,340.29  

26  74   -­‐10,618.6  

74  220   -­‐10,572  

Family  labor  hr/wk/ha  

25  74   -­‐1.24  

25  73                    -­‐3.76  

26  74            7.59  

76  221          0.94  

Yield,  kg/bearing  ha  

25  74   -­‐  139.78  

25  74    127.41    **  

26  74        66.40  

76  222      18.88  

Average  price,  CFA/kg  

25  74   30.58  ***  

25  74   45.26  ***  

26  74   17.37  ***  

76  222   30.98  ***  

Gross  rev.,  CFA/ha  

25  74   -­‐  88,355.1  

25  74   106,288  ***  

26  74   62,972.15  

76  222   27,793.4  

Variable  cash  exp.  CFA/ha  

25  74   -­‐  14,699.1  

25  74        -­‐9,457.37  

26  74  

-­‐  32,181                                  **  

76  222  

-­‐18,812                              **  

Expenditure  effic.,  CFA/kg  

25  74          -­‐49.49  

25  74   -­‐67.37    **  

26  75   -­‐114.74  ***  

76  223   -­‐77.5    ***  

Cash  profit  CFA/ha  

25  74    -­‐  73,656  

25  74  

   276,216                                      ***  

26  74  

   95,154                                ***  

76  222  

46,606.8                                        *  

a  In  the  N  column,  controls  are  listed  above  certified  farmers.  The  difference  is  the  certified  mean  minus  the  control  mean.    *  p  ≤  0.1,          **  p  ≤  0.05,          ***  p  ≤    0.01            

 

  60  

farmers  have  significantly  higher  fertilization  frequencies,  fertilizer  expenditures,  yields  and  

revenues  per  ha  in  Divo  only;  and  lower  fungicide  expenditures  in  Adzopé  only.  

Table  5.4  states  differences  in  means  for  economic  outcomes  between  each  certification  type  and  

controls  in  the  same  regions.  Regional  differences  are  stated  where  they  are  significant,  but  overall  

differences  are  not.  Corresponding  tables  with  means  for  agronomic  and  economic    

 

Table  5.4:  Differences  in  Means  Between  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls  By  Certification  Type,  Economic  Outcomes,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season  a  

 

FLO-­‐UTZ  (Soubré,  2  co-­‐ops)  

FLO-­‐RA  (Divo,  1  co-­‐op)  

FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ  (Adzopé,  1  co-­‐op)  

  N   25  certified  25  controls   N   25  certified  

25  controls   N   24  certified  26  controls  

Variable  Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Yield,  kg/bearing  ha   -­‐  208.81    **    110.11        *                                    41.61  Average  price,  CFA/kg   25.28  ***   47.55  ***                                          0.77  Gross  revenue,  CFA/ha   -­‐  142,936    **   89,329.01      *                        48,420.46  Variable  exp.  CFA/ha   -­‐  32,585.44      *                              -­‐8,639.05   -­‐65,440.98  ***  Profit  CFA/ha   -­‐  110,350.60      *   97,968.06    **   113,861.40    **  

 

 RA  

(Soubré  and  Divo)  RA-­‐UTZ  

(Adzopé,  4  co-­‐ops)  UTZ  

(All  Departments)  

  N   48  certified  50  controls   N   25  certified  

26  controls   N   75  certified  76  controls  

Variable  Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Yield,  kg/bearing  ha  

Overall    22.59    Divo    102.71      *                                        62.00    

Overall    38.64      Divo  168.41  *  

Average  price,  CFA/kg   38.97  ***   24.90  ***   34.11  ***  Gross  revenue,  CFA/ha  

Overall    33,278  Divo    90,404.62      *                        63493.58  

Overall    40,564.31  Divo  138,494.9  **  

Variable  exp.  CFA/ha   -­‐  2,913                        -­‐1,950.44   -­‐  18,422.67    **  

Profit  CFA/ha   Overall    36,191.01  Divo      95,827.46    **                        65,444.02  

Overall  58,986.98  Divo  152,643.7    **  Adzopé  106,903    **  

a  The  difference  is  the  certified  mean  minus  the  control  mean  *  p  ≤  0.1,          **  p  ≤  0.05,          ***  p  ≤    0.01            

 

  61  

variables  (Table  B4),  and  significant  differences  for  all  variables  (Table  B5)are  in  Appendix  B.  All  

certification  types  except  FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ  earn  significantly  higher  prices  than  controls.  

For  other  economic  outcomes,  UTZ-­‐only  producers  have  significantly  lower  expenditures  

than  controls  overall,  higher  yields  and  revenues  in  Divo,  and  higher  profits  in  Divo  and  Adzopé.  

Those  with  FLO  show  the  same  outcomes,  except  they  have  significantly  lower  expenditures  than  

controls  in  only  two  regions.  RA-­‐only  farmers  have  significantly  higher  yields,  revenues  and  profits  

than  controls  in  Divo  only.  RA-­‐UTZ  farmers  do  not  differ  significantly  from  controls  for  measures  

other  than  price.  

Table  5.5  presents  means  for  certified  and  control  co-­‐ops,  for  variables  that  can  affect  

farmers’  prices  and  costs.  The  stated  prices  are  low  and  high  unit  prices,  for  the  main  and  light    

 

Table  5.5:  Summary  Statistics  for  Certified  and  Control  Co-­‐ops,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season      

Variable  Control     Certified  

N   Mean   N   Mean  Years  since  founding   12   7.67   22   8.48  Members   12   267.83   22   657.36  Member  fees  (one  time),  CFA   12   20,667   22   21,598  Buyers  used   11   1.45   22   1.32  Low  price  from  buyers,  non-­‐certified  cacao,  CFA/kg   12   755.63   18   770.83  High  price  from  buyers,  non-­‐certified  cacao,  CFA/kg   12   762.29   18   773.61  Low  price  for  members,  non-­‐certified  cacao,  CFA/kg   12   718.75   23   716.74  High  price  for  members,  non-­‐certified  cacao,  CFA/kg   12   727.50   23   725.87  

 

Certified  Co-­‐ops  Only     N   Mean  Years  since  first  certification   20   3.05  %  volume  sold  as  certified   23   78.72  Low  price  from  buyers,  certified  cacao,  CFA/kg   9   873.89  High  price  from  buyers,  certified  cacao,  CFA/kg   9   876.67  Premium  from  buyers,  certified  cacao,  CFA/kg   9   91.11  Premium  paid  to  members  for  certified  cacao,  CFA/kg     23   47.61  Initial  certification/audit  fee  per  member,  CFA  a   16    27,145.50  Annual  certification/audit  fee  per  member,  CFA   16   15,878.64  a  Seven  co-­‐ops  did  not  know  the  amount  of  one  or  both  fees  because  the  buyer  paid  them.    

 

 

  62  

crops  respectively,  and  include  applicable  premiums.  All  co-­‐ops  indicated  that  they  received  the  

government’s  set  prices.  Non-­‐certified  prices  include  premiums  of  five  to  30  CFA/kg,  for  quantity,  

physical  quality  and  controlled  fermentation.  

Overall,  co-­‐ops  are  similar,  except  certified  co-­‐ops  are  larger  and  receive  slightly  higher  

prices  from  buyers,  while  control  co-­‐ops  use  more  buyers.  On  average,  certified  co-­‐ops  sell  78.72  

percent  of  their  output  at  certified  terms,  well  above  sector  averages.  They  receive  an  average  

premium  of  93.3  CFA/kg  for  certified  cacao,  and  pay  members  about  half  of  this,  47.6  CFA/kg.17  

Certification  and  audit  fees  per  member  are  illustrative  only,  as  co-­‐ops  did  not  report  charging  

these  directly  to  members.  Certifier  and  co-­‐op  interviews  indicate  that  certified  co-­‐ops  allocate  

premiums  to  certification  costs,  so  farmers  bear  them  via  lower  potential  price  premiums.  

The  analyses  of  certified  and  control  means  align  with  the  theoretical  analysis  in  indicating  

that  a)  certification  is  most  strongly  associated  with  higher  prices,  and  less  strongly  associated  with  

higher  yields,  revenues  or  profits,  or  lower  expenditures;  and  b)  certified  producers’  practices  and  

outcomes  vary  across  regions  and  certifications.    

Price  is  the  only  economic  outcome  for  which  certified  producers  fare  significantly  better  

than  controls  overall,  in  every  region,  and  for  each  certification  except  FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ.  FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ  

farmers  are  in  one  co-­‐op,  and  16  of  the  25  surveyed  had  not  yet  received  premiums  for  certified  

sales,  explaining  the  non-­‐significant  difference.  Co-­‐op  data  confirm  that  certification  drives  certified  

farmers’  higher  prices,  as  other  premiums  are  much  smaller.  Thus,  we  can  conclude  that  

certification  has  a  positive  effect  on  farm  gate  price.  The  effect  is  small,  equating  to  a  4.25  percent  

price  differential  (see  means  in  Table  B1).  

  Certified  farmers  have  significantly  lower  average  expenditures  and  higher  average  variable  

profits  than  controls  overall,  though  not  for  every  region  and  certification  type.  Certified  farmers’  

expenditures  per  ha  are  28.5  percent  lower  than  controls,  while  their  variable  profits  per  ha  are  

                                                                                                                         17  Every  certified  co-­‐op  reported  that  the  total  premium  for  certified  cacao  was  100  CFA/kg.  Two  co-­‐ops  said  a  buyer  retains  30  CFA/kg  of  this  to  recover  certification  fees  the  buyer  paid.      

 

  63  

18.62  percent  higher.  Certified  producers  do  not  have  significantly  higher  mean  yields  or  revenues  

than  controls  overall,  only  in  Divo.  These  figures  indicate  that  certification  is  associated  with  a  non-­‐

trivial  increase  in  profits,  which  appears  to  be  linked  to  lower  expenditures  more  than  higher  prices  

or  yields.  

Certified  producers’  lower  expenditures  may  be  due  to  lower  spending  on  pesticides,  rather  

than  substituting  family  labor  for  hired  labor  and/or  pesticide  use.  Insecticide  and  total  pesticide  

expenditures  are  significantly  lower  among  certified  producers  than  controls,  but  the  groups  do  not  

differ  significantly  for  either  labor  measure.  This  could  indicate  that  certification  improves  input  

efficiency,  as  identified  in  the  theoretical  analysis,  but  could  also  reflect  financial  constraints,  raising  

a  question  for  further  investigation.  

Outcomes  clearly  differ  regionally.  Divo  is  the  only  department  where  certified  farmers  

have  significantly  higher  yields,  revenues  and  profits  than  controls.  This  may  be  due  to  the  fact  that  

no  controls  in  Divo  use  fertilizer  while  certified  farmers  do,  and  that  the  certified  price  differential  

is  largest  in  the  region,  amounting  to  a  6.2  percent  difference  over  controls.  In  Adzopé,  certified  

farmers  differ  significantly  from  controls  only  in  having  lower  expenditures  and  higher  profits.  

Certified  producers  in  Soubré  do  not  differ  significantly  from  controls  for  yields,  revenues,  

expenditures  and  profits,  but  all  are  lower.  Though  certification  seems  to  be  associated  with  

negative  outcomes  in  Soubré,  certified  farmers’  yields,  revenues  and  profits  are  not  significantly  

lower  in  Soubré  than  other  regions.  Rather,  controls  have  higher  yields  there  than  other  regions  

(see  Table  B4)  while  certified  producers  do  not.  This  may  be  due  to  the  fact  that  controls  spend  

much  more  on  fertilizer  per  ha  than  certified  farmers  in  Soubré.  It  would  be  beneficial  to  validate  

whether  this  result  holds  for  a  larger  sample,  and  why,  if  so,  to  improve  certification  outcomes.    

We  cannot  make  generalized  conclusions  about  outcomes  across  certification  types,  or  

regarding  multi-­‐certification,  due  to  differences  in  sample  sizes,  and  regional  specificity.  While  it  

seems  that  UTZ-­‐only  and  FLO  producers  fare  best,  RA  and  RA-­‐UTZ  have  smaller  sample  sizes  than  

 

  64  

UTZ,  which  could  explain  the  lower  prevalence  of  significant  t-­‐test  results.  Each  FLO  type,  and    

RA-­‐UTZ,  is  in  only  one  region,  so  region  overlaps  with  multi-­‐certification  type.  

5.4.2  Yield  Regressions    

Table  5.6  presents  the  yield  regressions.  Overall,  the  results  of  the  yield  models  align  with  the  

theoretical  evaluation,  in  that  the  effects  of  certification  on  yield  are  weak,  and  vary  across  regions  

and  certification  types.  Certification  coefficients  are  significant  only  in  models  that  account  for  

region-­‐specific  differences:  Model  2  and  regional  models.  UTZ  is  significant  in  all  of  these  models.  

RA  is  significant  in  Model  2  and  Divo  only.  FLO  is  not  significant  in  any  model,  unless  weeding  is  

added  to  the  Adzopé  model.  In  that  case,  FLO  becomes  significant,  though  weeding  is  not  significant.  

Thus,  the  Adzopé  model  can  be  considered  to  be  fragile  with  respect  to  the  significance  of  FLO.  

 Table  5.7  indicates  total  intercept  shift  by  certification  type  for  each  model.  Model  2  

intercept  shifts  include  region-­‐certification  interactions.  All  intercept  shifts  are  positive  in  Model  1,  

and  the  Divo  and  Adzopé  models,  and  negative  in  the  Soubré  model.  In  Model  2,  intercept  shifts  are  

negative  for  RA-­‐UTZ,  and  all  certifications  in  Soubré,  but  positive  otherwise.  These  results  signify  

the  presence  of  regional  differences,  as  with  group  means.    

UTZ  seems  to  have  the  largest  positive  intercept  shift,  alone  and  with  other  certifications.  

This  concurs  with  the  theoretical  evaluation,  which  found  that  UTZ  has  most  yield-­‐enhancing  

criteria.  When  regional  dummies  are  used  (Model  2),  UTZ-­‐only  and  FLO  multi-­‐certification  both  

have  positive,  significant  total  intercept  shifts  in  Divo  and  Adzopé  while  this  holds  for  RA  in  Divo  

only.  In  single-­‐region  models,  total  intercept  shift  for  UTZ  is  significant  and  positive  in  two  regions,  

and  significant  and  negative  in  one  (Soubré),  while  FLO  and  RA  certification  types  are  significant  

and  positive  in  only  one  region.    

 

   

 

  65  

 

Table  5.6:  Yield  Regression  Models  

   

1   2   3a:  Soubre   3b:  Divo   3c:  Adzopé  Coeff.  

(Std.  Err.)  Coeff.  

(Std.  Err.)  Coeff.  

(Std.  Err.)  Coeff.  

(Std.  Err.)  Coeff.  

(Std.  Err.)  

 FLO  dummy  

15.65  (42.93)  

-­‐19.04  (77.08)  

32.96  (87.82)  

-­‐76.17  (73.46)  

125.61  (82.48)  

RA  dummy  5.51  

(39.35)  150.74  (78.47)  *  

-­‐24.75  (81.50)  

156.66  (71.70)  **  

-­‐92.64  (77.79)  

UTZ  dummy  34.36  (37.66)  

235.99  (78.74)***  

-­‐158.39  (86.18)  *  

192.04  (70.73)  ***  

183.13  (78.66)  **  

Farmer’s  age    -­‐3.20  (1.68)  *      

 

Own  farm  or  family’s  farm    

113.48  (42.17)  ***    

179.85  (55.61)  **  

 

Bearing  cacao  ha  -­‐17.43  

(3.99)  ***  -­‐16.69  

(3.96)  ***  -­‐17.15  

(5.90)  ***  -­‐11.79  (5.52)  **  

 

Average  cacao  trees/ha  0.19  

(0.08)  **  0.17  

(0.08)  **        

Weeding  frequency/yr      120.21  

(47.59)  ***      

Pruning  frequency/yr      15.88  

(6.19)  ***      

Fertilizer  expenditure,  1,000’s  of  CFA  

0.03  (0.01)  ***  

0.03  (0.01)  ***  

0.03  (0.01)  ***    

 

Insecticide  exp.,  1,000’s  of  CFA          

0.15  (0.05)***  

Pesticide  expenditure,  1,000’s  of  CFA  

0.04    (0.02)  *  

0.06  (0.02)  ***  

   

 

Hired  labor  expenditure,  1,000’s  of  CFA  

1.44    (0.38)  ***  

1.52  (0.38)  ***  

2.47  (0.83)***  

1.23  (0.48)***  

1.95  (0.56)***  

Family  Labor/week/ha      2.39  

(1.37)  *      

Soubré  regional  dummy     154.35  

(81.46)  *    

   

Adzopé  regional  dummy     -­‐56.82  

(88.42)    

   

FLO*Soubré  dummy     16.37  

(108.44)    

   

RA*Soubré  dummy     -­‐231.04  

(112.60)  **    

   

UTZ*Soubré  dummy     -­‐351.78  

(110.17)  ***    

   

FLO*Adzopé  dummy     301.37  

 (123.29)  **    

   

RA*Adzopé  dummy     -­‐396.77  

(123.19)  ***    

   

UTZ*Adzopé  dummy  

  -­‐15.41  (123.16)  

 

 

 

 

  66  

Constant  

202.16  (114.28)  *  

226.39  (142.25)  

116.89  (153.82)  

296.21  (65.95)  ***  

197.77  (64.63)    ***  

 

N   247   246   81   99   99  R2   0.240   0.330   0.524   0.228   0.230  *  p  ≤  0.1,          **  p  ≤  0.05,          ***  p  ≤    0.01              

Table  5.7:  Total  Intercept  Shift  for  Certification  Dummies,  Yield  Regressions  

Certification  Type   Region   Model  1   Model  2   Regional  Modelsa  FLO-­‐UTZ     Soubré   50.01      -­‐118.45                                -­‐125.43  FLO-­‐RA   Divo   21.16   131.71          *                                      80.49  FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ   Adzopé   55.52   256.89    ***     216.10    **  RA   Soubré  and  Divo   5.51          RA     Soubré       -­‐80.29                                  -­‐24.75  RA   Divo       150.74      *   156.66    **  RA-­‐UTZ   Adzopé   39.87   -­‐25.45                                    90.49  UTZ   All  regions   34.36          UTZ   Soubré          -­‐115.70   -­‐158.39          *  UTZ   Divo       235.99  ***   192.04  ***  UTZ   Adzopé          220.58      **   183.13      **  a  Number  is  the  sum  of  relevant  certification  dummies  in  model  corresponding  to  “Region”  column”  *  p  ≤  0.1,          **  p  ≤  0.05,          ***  p  ≤    0.01                

The  non-­‐certification  variables  that  are  significant  differ  across  models.18    Across  Models  1  

and  2,  farmer’s  age  and  farm  ownership  and  are  significant  only  in  Model  2.  In  Model  2,  one  

department  dummy  and  four  department-­‐certification  dummies  are  significant.  In  both  models,  all  

non-­‐dummy  variables  have  a  positive  effect  on  yield,  except  bearing  cacao  area,  which  has  a  

negative  effect.  Across  single-­‐regional  models,  the  number  and  nature  of  significant  variables  differ.  

The  Soubré  model  has  six  significant  non-­‐certification  variables  (cacao  area,  weeding,  pruning,  

fertilizer  expenditure,  hired  labor  expenditure,  and  family  labor),  Divo  has  only  three  (farm  

ownership,  cacao  area  and  hired  labor  expenditure),  and  Adzopé  has  only  two  (insecticide  and  

hired  labor  expenditures).  In  all  models,  hired  labor  has  the  highest  coefficient  among  expenditures.  

                                                                                                                         18  Insecticide  expenditure  is  significant  if  used  to  replace  pesticide  expenditure  in  Models  1  and  2.  Models  with  pesticide  expenditure  have  a  slightly  higher  R2.  Age  squared  is  significant  in  Model  2  if  used  to  replace  age.  If  both  are  used,  neither  is  significant.  The  advanced  age  of  trees  explains  this.  

 

  67  

Overall,  the  yield  regression  results  align  with  prior  research,  and  what  one  would  expect  

from  an  agronomic  perspective  and  economic  theory.  Cacao  area;  and  expenditures  on  hired  labor,  

fertilizer  and  pesticides;  have  a  particularly  robust  effect,  as  they  are  significant  in  overall  and  

regional  models.  Other  variables,  such  as  land  ownership  and  cacao  trees/ha,  are  significant  only  in  

models  that  account  for  region-­‐specific  differences.  The  regional  models  concur  with  the  theoretical  

evaluation  in  confirming  geographic  variation  in  the  factors  that  influence  yield,  and  the  effect  of  

certification.  It  is  not  fully  clear  from  the  data  why  certain  variables  affect  yield  in  one  region  but  

not  another.  The  significance  of  expenditures  on  fertilizer  in  Soubré,  and  insecticide  in  Adzopé,  may  

be  explained  by  large  differences  in  regional  group  means  for  these  variables.  It  seems  beneficial  to  

conduct  further  research  to  confirm  which  factors  most  affect  yield  in  a  given  context,  and  thus  

identify  areas  that  certifiers,  industry  and  others  should  target  to  optimize  certification  outcomes.  

Table  5.8  presents  the  estimated  total  effects  of  certification  for  Model  1,  with  total  

intercept  shifts  and  differences  between  group  means  for  comparison.  The  estimated  total  effects  

are  negative  for  all  certifications  except  RA-­‐UTZ,  contrasting  the  positive  polarity  of  intercept  shifts  

in  Model  1,  and  none  are  significant.19  Total  effect  of  certification  matches  the  polarity  of  the  total  

intercept  shift  for  RA-­‐UTZ  only,  and  the  difference  between  group  means  for  FLO-­‐UTZ  and  FLO-­‐RA-­‐

UTZ  only.  The  magnitudes  of  the  three  measures  diverge  in  almost  all  cases,  except  for  total    

 

Table  5.8:  Estimated  Total  Effect  of  Certification  on  Yield,  Total  Intercept  Shift,  and  Difference  in  Means  

  Total  Effect  of  Certification,  Model  1  

P-­‐value   Total  Intercept  Shift,  Model  1  

Difference  in  Means:  Certified  Minus  All  

Controls  FLO-­‐RA   -­‐21.98  (48.49)   0.65   50.01     13.08  FLO-­‐UTZ   -­‐11.57  (50.89)   0.82   21.16   -­‐43.55  FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ   -­‐21.7  (62.27)   0.72   55.52   -­‐23.99  RA   -­‐19.36  (39.89)   0.63   5.51   56.71  RA-­‐UTZ   43.65  (61.14)   0.48   39.87   -­‐3.60  UTZ   -­‐7.53  (37.63)   0.84   34.36   38.65                                                                                                                            19  Significance  is  from  Stata’s  lincom  command,  used  to  calculate  total  certification  effect.  

 

  68  

certification  effect  and  total  intercept  shift  for  RA-­‐UTZ,  and  total  intercept  and  difference  between  

group  means  for  UTZ.  

It  is  not  surprising  that  total  effect  of  certification  does  not  match  the  difference  between  

group  means,  since  the  latter  is  a  simple  descriptive  measure  of  an  outcome,  while  the  former  

estimates  the  effects  of  certification  on  that  outcome.  This  is  the  reason  that  higher-­‐level  

econometrics  are  essential  in  evaluating  the  effects  of  certification.  We  would  also  expect  total  

effect  of  certification  and  total  intercept  shift  to  differ,  given  that  multiple  variables  affect  yield,  and  

that  there  is  variation  within  and  between  groups  for  these  variables.  Total  intercept  shift  

disregards  explanatory  variables  besides  the  certification  dummies,  while  total  effect  of  

certification  represents  an  adjustment  to  the  total  intercept  shift  per  group  differences  for  all  other  

variables  that  affect  yield.  The  measures  would  be  equal  only  if  groups  were  identical  for  all  non-­‐

certification  variables.  

Total  intercept  shift  and  total  effect  of  certification  can  be  thought  of  as  the  boundaries  of  

the  potential  effect  of  certification  on  yield,  for  this  sample.  On  the  end  of  the  range  estimated  by  

total  intercept  shift,  certification  can  be  expected  to  have  a  positive  effect.  However,  on  the  other  

end  of  the  range,  represented  by  total  effect  of  certification,  certification  would  be  expected  to  be  

associated  with  a  negative  effect.  In  the  absence  of  baseline  data  indicating  how  groups  differed  on  

each  explanatory  variable  prior  to  certification,  we  cannot  be  certain  if  and  how  certification  caused  

observed  group  differences  in  each  the  variables  that  affected  yield.  Without  an  exhaustive  list  of  

specific  selection  criteria,  we  also  cannot  specify  regression  models  that  would  fully  address  

selection  bias,  such  as  a  Heckman  two-­‐stage  model.  Due  to  these  issues,  we  cannot  determine  a  

point  estimate  for  the  effect  of  certification.  We  can  conclude  only  that  it  lies  between  the  total  

intercept  shift  and  total  effect  of  certification.  

 

 

  69  

5.4.3  Variable  Cash  Expenditure  Regressions  

Table  5.9  presents  the  variable  expenditure  regressions.  Among  certification  dummies,  FLO  and  

UTZ  are  significant  and  negative  in  all  models,  while  RA  is  non-­‐significant  and  positive  in  each.  

Table  5.10  indicates  total  intercept  shifts  by  model.  All  FLO  types,  UTZ  and  RA-­‐UTZ  are  negative  in  

all  models,  while  RA  is  positive.  FLO-­‐UTZ,  FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ  and  UTZ  are  significant  in  all  models.  

 Table  5.9:  Variable  Cash  Expenditure  Regression  Models  

 

Model  1A   Model  1B   Model  2A   Model  2B  Coef.  

Std.  Err.  Coef.  

Std.  Err.  Coef.  

Std.  Err.  Coef.  

Std.  Err.  

FLO  

-­‐17,613.56  (8,816.44)  

**  

-­‐17,958.10  (8,847.57)  

**  

-­‐16,532.70  (8,874.01)  

*  

-­‐16,782.69  (8,919.66)  

*  

RA  2,095.32  (8,262.46)  

3,137.34  (8,339.72)  

2,853.30  (8,130.22)  

32,40.47  (8,208.1)  

UTZ  

-­‐17,721.84  (8,233.94)  

**  

-­‐17,396.60  (8,268.50)  

**  

-­‐15,502.85  (8,092.82)  

*  

-­‐15,554.86  (8,129.42)  

*  Total  farm  size,  ha  (cacao  and  other  crops)  

1,155.95  (645.31)  

*  

1,324.51  (675.86)  

**      

Household  Size      

1,096.38  (534.83)  

**  

1,086.68  (538.01)  

**  

Cacao  trees/ha  

44.33  (17.45)  ***  

47.99  (17.84)  ***  

43.09  (16.57)  ***  

44.33  (16.92)  ***  

Training  Sessions/yr  

-­‐501.99  (271.76)  

*  

-­‐541.22  (275.24)  

**  

-­‐541.18  (268.43)  

**  

-­‐550.185  (273.17)  

**  

Fertilizer  applications/yr  

27,044.72  (7,097.84)  

***  

27,064.93  (7,116.47)  

***  

28,825.57  (7,064.71)  

***  

28,739.46  (7097.72)  

***  

Fungicide  applications/yr  

7,198.21  (3,242.95)  

**  

6,763.73  (3,289.13)  

**  

7,828.65  (3,207.74)  

**  

7,819.827  (3235.43)  

**  Family  Labor/wk/ha    

174.33  (201.21)  

 

17.24  (192.43)  

Constant  -­‐12,192.45  (24,441.65)  

-­‐21,517.12  (26,242.14)  

-­‐16,300.58  (23,900.91)  

-­‐18,012.86  (24,941.64)  

N   246   245   250   249  R2   0.195   0.199   0.196   0.197    

 

  70  

Table  5.10:  Total  Intercept  Shift  for  Certification  Dummies,  Expenditure  

Cert.  Type   Region/s   Model  1A   Model  1B   Model  2A   Model  2B  

FLO-­‐UTZ     Soubré  -­‐35,335.40  

 ***  -­‐35,354.7    

***  -­‐32,035.55  

***  -­‐32,337.55    

***  FLO-­‐RA   Divo   -­‐15,518.24   -­‐14,820.76   -­‐13,679.4   -­‐13,542.22  

FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ   Adzopé  -­‐33,240.08        

**  -­‐32,217.36    

 **  -­‐29,182.25      

**  -­‐29,097.08      

**  

RA  Soubré  and  Divo            2,095.30   3,137.34   2,853.30   3,240.472  

RA-­‐UTZ   Adzopé    -­‐15,626.51   -­‐14,259.26   -­‐12,649.56   -­‐12,314.39  

UTZ   All    -­‐17,721.84      

**  -­‐17,396.6    

**  -­‐15,502.85    

*  -­‐15,554.86    

*    

All  non-­‐certification  variables  except  training  have  a  positive  effect  on  expenditure,  and  all  

except  family  labor  are  significant.  Fertilizer  application  frequency  has  a  much  larger  effect  than  

fungicide  application  frequency.  The  coefficients  on  each  variable  are  similar  across  models,  except  

that  family  labor  is  much  smaller  in  model  2B  and  1B.    

Table  5.11  shows  the  estimated  total  effect  of  certification  on  expenditure  for  all  models.  In  

Models  1A  and  1B,  all  total  effects  of  certification  are  negative,  and  all  but  RA  are  significant.  In  

Models  2A  and  2B,  all  total  effects  except  RA  are  negative,  while  only  FLO-­‐UTZ,  FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ  and  

UTZ  are  significant.  Total  effect  of  certification  matches  the  total  intercept  in  polarity  (positive  or  

negative)  in  all  cases,  except  RA  in  Models  1A  and  1B.  

 

Table  5.11:  Estimated  Total  Effect  of  Certification  on  Expenditure,  All  Models    

  Model  1A   Model  1B   Model  2A   Model  2B  FLO-­‐UTZ   -­‐34,031.59  

***  -­‐34,214.30  

***  -­‐29,681.57  

***  -­‐30,065.31  

***  FLO-­‐RA   -­‐17,169.51  

*  -­‐17,794.25  

*  -­‐15,896.47  (p=0.118)  

-­‐15,900.67  (p=0.121)  

FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ   -­‐53,729.0  ***  

-­‐53,415.20    ***  

-­‐53,346.01  ***  

-­‐53,280.66  ***  

RA   -­‐1,091.77  (p=0.894)  

-­‐359.61  (p=0.965)  

48.19  (p=0.995)  

281.69  (p=0.972)  

RA-­‐UTZ   -­‐22,798.91  *  

-­‐22,646.02  *  

-­‐20,287.07  (p=0.106)  

-­‐20,075.97  (0.112)  

UTZ   -­‐22,589.75  ***  

-­‐21,746.31  ***  

-­‐20,438.03  ***  

-­‐20,506.29  ***  

 

  71  

Overall,  the  expenditure  regressions  indicate  that  certification  has  a  robust  negative  effect  

on  expenditure,  except  in  the  case  of  RA-­‐only  farmers.  As  with  yield,  the  total  intercept  shift  and  the  

total  effect  of  certification  represent  the  boundaries  of  this  effect.  Total  intercept  shift  and  total  

effect  of  certification  are  significant  and  negative  for  producers  with  UTZ  only,  and  with  both  FLO  

and  UTZ,  in  all  models.  Both  measures  are  negative  for  producers  with  FLO-­‐RA  and  RA-­‐UTZ,  though  

significant  in  only  some  models.  RA-­‐only  producers  have  positive,  non-­‐significant  values  for  both  

measures,  except  for  negative,  non-­‐significant  total  effects  in  Model  1A  and  1B.  The  theoretical  

evaluation  of  certification  does  not  indicate  why  RA  would  increase  expenditures,  while  FLO  and  

UTZ  would  reduce  expenditures.  RA  and  UTZ  have  the  most  criteria  that  could  potentially  increase  

or  decrease  different  expenditures,  and  these  criteria  are  similar  in  number  and  nature.  However,  

UTZ  seems  to  have  a  few  more  criteria  that  could  reduce  expenditures  than  RA.  

These  results  may  indicate  that  producers  with  UTZ  and  FLO  may  be  realizing  economic  

efficiencies  as  a  result  of  certification  requirements,  such  as  training  on  efficient,  appropriate  

pesticide  use.20  Alternately,  it  may  be  that  farmers  who  were  more  cost  efficient  prior  to  

certification  were  more  likely  to  seek  certification,  or  be  selected  for  certification  by  others.  

Without  pre-­‐certification  baseline  data  or  known  selection  criteria,  we  cannot  conclude  which  

scenario  holds.  Thus,  as  with  yield,  we  can  conclude  only  that  the  effect  of  certification  on  total  

expenditure  lies  between  the  total  intercept  shift  and  the  total  effect  of  certification.  We  cannot  

pinpoint  the  magnitude  of  the  effect.    

The  non-­‐certification  variables  that  are  significant  make  sense.  Total  farm  size  and  

household  size  appear  to  be  interchangeable,  suggesting  that  both  may  represent  assets.  Land  can  

serve  as  collateral  (if  titled),  non-­‐cacao  farm  area  can  be  used  to  produce  other  market  or  food  

crops,  and  household  members  represent  labor  that  can  generate  off-­‐farm  income.  A  higher  number  

                                                                                                                         20  Certified  and  control  farmers  indicated  that  they  received  free  insecticide  and/or  fungicide  from  their  co-­‐ops,  but  they  were  not  asked  to  report  quantities.  Therefore,  expenditures  do  not  represent  total  quantities  used.  The  proportion  of  producers  reporting  free  inputs  did  not  differ  significantly  across  groups,  so  it  is  assumed  free  inputs  would  not  explain  certified  producers’  lower  expenditures.    

 

  72  

of  cacao  trees  per  ha  increases  the  total  costs  associated  with  pruning,  pesticide  application  and  

harvesting.  Increased  training  can  help  farmers  realize  efficiencies,  particularly  in  pesticide  use  (see  

Ingram  et  al.  2014).  Higher  frequencies  of  fertilizer  and  fungicide  use  would  logically  increase  

expenditure.  The  data  indicate  that  producers  do  not  all  use  the  same  amount  per  application,  so  

this  effect  would  not  be  expected  to  be  identical  across  producers.  

5.5  Conclusion  

Piecing  together  the  comparison  of  average  prices  across  certified  and  control  producers,  and  the  

regressions  on  yield  and  expenditure,  we  can  conclude  that  certification  is  associated  with  

significantly  higher  prices,  though  the  relative  difference  is  rather  small,  has  a  significant  negative  

effect  on  expenditure,  and  has  varied  effects  on  yield  that  range  from  negative  to  positive.  Thus,  we  

would  conclude  that  its  effect  on  farm-­‐level  profit  is  variable  in  direction  and  magnitude.  So  long  as  

certification  does  not  lead  to  decreased  yields  relative  to  non-­‐certified  farmers,  certified  producers  

would  earn  higher  profits  than  those  who  are  not  certified.  However,  if  certification  affects  yields  

negatively,  or  fails  to  improve  pre-­‐certification  yield  that  were  poor,  the  differences  in  profits  

across  certified  and  non-­‐certified  farmers  will  depend  on  the  magnitude  of  the  price  increases  and  

expenditure  reductions  associated  with  certification,  and  the  difference  in  yields  between  groups.  

It  is  noteworthy  that  certification  is  associated  with  lower  spending  on  pesticides  

(insecticide  and  fungicide),  while  expenditures  on  these  items  have  a  positive  effect  on  yield.  Thus,  

certified  producers’  lower  spending  may  be  one  factor  that  explains  why  the  total  effect  of  

certification  on  yield  is  negative.  However,  reduced  pesticide  expenditures  could  reflect  the  use  of  

better  cultural  practices  that  reduce  the  need  for  these  chemicals,  or  more  efficient,  appropriate  

application  practices.  Further  research  is  needed  to  determine  why  certified  producers  spend  less  

on  pesticides,  and  if  they  are  applying  sufficient  amounts.  If  they  are  not  applying  sufficient  

amounts,  then  it  is  important  to  determine  whether  this  is  due  to  certification  requirements,  or  

financial  constraints,  and  gauge  the  net  benefit  of  addressing  the  identified  causes.  

 

  73  

The  fieldwork  findings  cannot  be  generalized  beyond  cacao  farmers  who  are  in  producer-­‐

run  groups  such  as  co-­‐ops,  which  represent  about  15  percent  of  farmers,  as  noted  in  the  cacao  

sector  overview.  Additionally,  they  cannot  be  generalized  without  qualifications  beyond  those  who  

sell  bulk  cacao  (as  opposed  to  fine  flavor)  through  government-­‐controlled  markets,  as  both  factors  

have  effects  on  price  apart  from  certification.  Given  that  producer  organization  formation  is  part  of  

many  development  initiatives,  per  the  cacao  sector  overview,  the  present  study  can  be  expected  to  

be  relevant  to  more  producers  over  time.  

The  comparison  of  group  means  tests  and  regression  results  indicates  the  importance  of  

using  higher-­‐level  econometric  methods  to  evaluate  certification  effects.  If  we  looked  only  at  t-­‐test  

results  for  yield,  expenditure  and  profits,  we  would  conclude  that  certification  is  associated  with  

higher  yields,  though  not  significantly  so;  significantly  lower  expenditures,  and  significantly  higher  

profits.  The  regressions  do  not  allow  us  to  make  these  same  conclusions  for  yield  and  profit  for  any  

certification  type,  or  for  expenditures  in  the  case  of  RA-­‐only  producers.    

The  regression  models  also  indicate  the  importance  of  estimating  the  effects  of  certification  

in  isolation,  and  along  with  other  variables  that  affect  producers’  outcomes.  In  the  case  of  yield,  if  

we  use  only  the  total  intercept  shift  to  evaluate  certification  effects  in  isolation,  we  would  conclude  

that  it  generally  results  in  yields  that  are  higher  than  controls  (or  that  higher  yield  increases  the  

likelihood  of  certification),  excepting  one  region  where  controls  fare  significantly  better.  If  we  look  

only  at  the  total  effect  of  certification,  we  would  conclude  that  certification  is  more  likely  to  reduce  

yield  (or  that  producers  with  poor  yields  are  more  likely  to  seek  certification).  By  considering  both  

measures,  we  can  estimate  the  range  of  the  effect  that  certification  may  have,  and  make  more  

accurate  conclusions  about  expected  outcomes.  This  is  particularly  important  when  we  do  not  have  

baseline  data  or  known  selection  criteria,  and  must  estimate  effects  as  a  range  rather  than  a  point  to  

account  for  both  pre-­‐  and  post-­‐certification  differences  in  explanatory  variables.  

   

 

  74  

Chapter  6. Conclusions  

This  thesis  has  evaluated  the  direct  effects  of  the  FLO,  RA  and  UTZ  certifications  on  smallholders’  

net  incomes,  through  generalized  and  specific  lenses,  using  primary  and  secondary  data.  It  began  

with  a  theoretical  evaluation  of  the  potential  effects  of  certification,  irrespective  of  crop  or  location,  

proceeded  to  a  literature  review,  and  ended  with  an  analysis  of  primary  data  from  cacao  farmers  in  

co-­‐ops  in  Côte  d’Ivoire.  These  three  modes  of  inquiry  lead  to  similar  conclusions  about  the  effects  of  

certification  on  net  income  and  its  components,  and  identify  several  ways  in  which  certifiers  and  

partners  can  improve  certified  farmers’  profits.  Sections  6.1  and  6.2  cover  these  topics  respectively.  

6.1  Effects  and  Limits  of  Certification    

Overall,  the  direct  effect  of  certification  on  farm-­‐level  net  income  varies  within  and  across  crops  and  

locations,  and  appears  to  be  more  positive  or  null  than  negative.  Regarding  the  components  of  net  

income,  certification  seems  to  have  the  most  robust  and  positive  impact  on  farm  gate  price.  The  

literature  review  and  primary  data  support  the  theoretical  supposition  that  certification  raises  

prices  by  differentiating  commodities  in  ways  that  are  associated  with  a  higher  willingness  to  pay.  

Certified  producers  are  likely  to  sell  only  a  portion  of  their  crop  through  certified  channels,  while  

marketing  the  rest  conventionally.  Thus,  average  price  across  total  output  will  lie  between  

conventional  and  certified  prices  in  the  local  market.  The  literature  review  and  cacao  sector  

overview  indicate  that  the  price  differential  can  be  expected  to  vary  across  time,  commodities  and  

locations.  It  proved  to  be  rather  small  for  the  Côte  d’Ivoire  producers  surveyed,  about  4.25  percent.    

Effects  on  yield  and  total  output  are  much  less  certain.  The  theoretical  evaluation  identified  

numerous  ways  in  which  the  target  certifications  could  increase  or  decrease  yield,  or  reduce  

planted  area  and  thus  total  output.  The  literature  review  found  that  certification  has  been  

associated  with  higher,  lower  and  equal  yields  relative  to  non-­‐certified  controls,  in  different  cases.  

However,  most  studies  evaluated  only  group  means,  which  describe  outcomes  but  do  not  quantify  

how  certification  has  shaped  them.  Among  the  few  studies  that  used  regressions,  the  estimated  

 

  75  

effect  of  certification  ranged  from  negative  to  positive.  The  yield  regressions  using  primary  data  

from  Côte  d’Ivoire  similarly  show  mixed  results  when  certification  effects  are  characterized  as  a  

range  bounded  by  total  intercept  shift  and  total  effect  of  certification.  Total  intercept  shift,  which  

represent  the  isolated  effects  of  certification,  is  largely  positive  across  certification  types.  Total  

effect  of  certification,  which  accounts  for  all  variables  that  affect  yield,  is  generally  negative.  

For  variable  cash  expenditure,  both  the  theoretical  evaluation  and  the  literature  review  

indicate  that  certification  may  be  associated  with  an  increase,  decrease,  or  no  change  relative  to  

non-­‐certified  producers.  The  actual  difference  depends,  to  a  large  degree,  on  farmers’  pre-­‐

certification  farming  practices  and  knowledge,  such  as  whether  they  have  been  trained  on  efficient  

pesticide  application,  the  input  quantities  they  use,  and  how  much  they  weed  and  prune.  It  also  

rests  on  factors  outside  the  farm  household  and  the  scope  of  certification,  such  as  access  to  credit,  

which  was  identified  as  a  pervasive  constraint  in  the  cacao  sector  overview.    

Among  the  Ivorian  farmers  surveyed,  certification  appears  to  have  a  significant  and  large  

negative  effect  on  expenditure  for  FLO  and  UTZ,  but  a  small  positive  effect  for  RA.  It  is  possible  that  

groups  differed  in  expenditures  before  certification,  in  which  case  we  would  interpret  the  results  as  

meaning  that  producers  with  lower  expenditures  seek  FLO  and  UTZ,  while  those  who  spend  more  

obtain  RA.  In  any  case,  regression  results  align  with  theory  and  secondary  data  in  showing  mixed  

outcomes.  It  is  not  clear  why  RA  is  linked  to  increased  expenditures,  while  the  other  certifications  

are  associated  with  reduced  expenditures.    

Looking  across  the  components  of  net  income,  we  can  conclude  that  certification  has  a  

robust  effect  on  raising  average  farm  gate  price  across  crops  and  locations,  while  the  ways  in  which  

it  modulates  expenditure  and  yield  vary  across  contexts.  Thus,  one  cannot  make  general  predictions  

about  how  any  of  the  target  certifications  would  shift  net  income.  Among  the  Ivorian  cacao  farmers  

in  the  fieldwork,  we  can  conclude  that  certification  seems  likely  to  increase  profits  more  often  than  

not,  via  higher  prices  and  lower  expenditures,  rather  than  increased  yields.  As  noted,  the  fieldwork  

 

  76  

findings  cannot  be  generalized  beyond  cacao  producers  who  are  in  co-­‐ops,  and  possibly  not  past  

those  who  sell  bulk  cacao  through  government-­‐controlled  markets.  The  theoretical  evaluation  and  

literature  review  afford  conclusions  that  can  be  applied  more  broadly.  

Per  the  total  evidence  base  we  can  conclude  that,  overall,  certification  has  had  a  limited  

effect  on  raising  farmers’  net  incomes.  It  does  not  seem  that  we  can  fault  certification  for  this  

entirely,  given  the  complex  challenges  that  exist  in  development  contexts,  and  the  complementary  

roles  that  certifiers  and  other  entities  play  in  addressing  these.  When  we  consider  the  broader  

context,  it  is  apparent  that  we  should  not  expect  certification  alone  to  guarantee  significantly  higher  

profits  for  farmers  in  every  situation,  nor  should  we  believe  marketing  statements  that  promise  or  

claim  otherwise.  Certification  also  involves  benefits  that  lie  outside  the  scope  of  this  thesis,  

including  those  realized  at  the  level  of  producer  organizations,  communities,  and  the  environment.  

Thus,  conclusions  about  its  effects  on  farm-­‐level  profits  cannot  be  extrapolated  to  total  welfare.  

Per  their  missions,  the  target  certifications  seem  to  exist  primarily  to  recognize  producers  

who  uphold  better  social  and  environmental  practices,  and  incent  such  practices  with  above-­‐

market  prices  (though  UTZ  also  seeks  to  improve  farm  management,  and  FLO  works  to  strengthen  

producer  organizations).  The  evidence  base  shows  that  they  have  achieved  this  end,  as  producers  

receive  above-­‐market  prices  for  certified  sales.  However,  the  overall  effect  of  such  price  

differentials  is  small  because  demand  for  certified  commodities  lies  below  supply,  and  thus  certified  

producers  sell  the  majority  of  their  output  through  conventional  channels.  Certifiers  can  and  do  

undertake  marketing  to  boost  demand,  but  they  cannot  unilaterally  shift  the  market  toward  higher  

certified  purchasing.  Certifiers  also  cannot  affect  input  costs,  limiting  their  potential  impacts  on  

expenditure  to  improving  cost  efficiency  at  the  group  and  farm  levels  via  certification  requirements,  

and  finding  ways  to  reduce  certification  costs.  

Additionally,  certifiers  are  not  agricultural  development  organizations  that  are  focused  

primarily  on  improving  technical  agronomic  practices  and  yields,  though  each  certification  has  

 

  77  

criteria  in  these  areas,  particularly  UTZ.  Certifiers  and  development  programs  also  operate  within  a  

dynamic  context  marked  by  diverse  constraints.  The  overview  of  the  cacao  sector  and  Côte  d’Ivoire  

identified  factors  such  as  limited  national  extension  and  R&D  capacities,  aged  trees,    low-­‐yielding  

genetic  stock,  gaps  in  input  supply,  lack  of  access  to  affordable  credit,  and  poor  infrastructure.  

Jessop  et  al.  (2012)  indicate  that  these  issues  exist  across  crops  and  geographies.  No  single  entity  

can  be  expected  to  solve  all  these  problems.  Realizing  this,  certifiers  have  collaborated  with  other  

entities  to  address  issues  beyond  their  scope,  as  the  cacao  sector  overview  found.  

6.2  Recommendations  for  Improving  Certification  Outcomes  

It  is  clear  that  farm-­‐level  economic  outcomes  could  be  better  for  certified  producers.  Certifiers,  

partners  such  as  traders  and  brand  owners,  ad  others  can  take  numerous  steps  to  address  factors  

that  affect  producers’  prices,  yields  and  expenditures.  In  some  cases,  this  will  require  broadening  

the  scope  of  certification  training,  standards,  producer  services,  or  implementation  partners  to  

address  constraints  that  lie  beyond  certifiers’  current  requirements,  activities  and  capabilities.    

Certifiers,  brand  owners  and  advocacy  groups  can  help  raise  producer  prices  through  

marketing  that  builds  demand  for  certified  goods.  Certifiers  and  buyers  can  also  train  producer  

group  management  on  efficient  administration  of  processes  such  as  product  traceability,  financial  

accounting  and  record  keeping,  helping  groups  increase  profits  and  pay  higher  prices  to  members.  

Additionally,  certifiers  can  work  to  reduce  duplicate  costs  incurred  by  multi-­‐certified  groups,  which  

would  raise  farm  gate  prices  indirectly.  Numerous  groups  hold  multiple  certifications  that  cover  the  

same  farms.  Such  groups  pay  multiple  certification  costs  for  output  that  will  bring  them  a  premium  

for  only  one  label.  Certifiers  can  reduce  duplicate  costs,  such  as  audit  fees,  by  training  auditors  on  

each  standard  and  accepting  a  common  audit.  One  such  example  is  the  Certification  Capacity  

Enhancement  Project  implemented  in  West  Africa  from  2010-­‐13,  which  included  joint  auditor  

training  (IDH,  Undated).  Finally,  RA  and  UTZ,  which  allow  groups  to  certify  only  a  subset  of  farms,  

can  confer  with  buyers  to  estimate  demand  for  each  certification,  and  help  groups  determine  how  

 

  78  

many  farms  to  certify  to  fulfill  that  amount.  This  will  optimize  the  cost  efficiency  of  certification,  

and  increase  the  resulting  farm  gate  price.      

Regarding  yield,  the  literature  review  and  fieldwork  suggest  that  certifiers  and  partners  

have  great  potential  to  enhance  producers’  economic  outcomes  by  supporting  productivity  

improvement.  The  cacao  sector  overview  revealed  that  industry,  governments,  NGOs  and  others  are  

already  incorporating  relevant  activities  into  development  initiatives,  having  recognized  this.  In  the  

Ivorian  sample,  when  certified  producers  have  higher  yields  than  controls,  their  productivity  is  still  

well  below  the  yield  potentials  stated  in  the  cacao  sector  overview.  Many  farmers  have  aged  trees  

with  declining  yields,  unimproved  low-­‐yield  varietals  and  very  low  fertilizer  use.  There  is  also  wide  

variation  in  the  use  of  good  agricultural  practices,  and  pesticides  use.  UTZ  is  the  only  standard  with  

requirements  related  to  crop  regeneration,  and  selecting  planting  material  with  consideration  for  

yield  potential.  It  would  be  beneficial  for  other  certifiers,  and  other  entities  in  the  sector,  to  

disseminate  information  on  improved  planting  material  and  yield-­‐enhancing  practices.    

Certifiers  and  partners  would  need  to  complement  education  with  efforts  to  increase  the  

availability  of  high-­‐quality  genetic  stock.  This  is  not  a  simple  or  quick  task,  as  it  requires  R&D  

capacities  and  time  to  develop  varietals,  government  approval  for  their  use,  and  capacity  building  

for  production  and  distribution.  Relevant  efforts  are  under  way  in  Côte  d’Ivoire,  such  as  Mars’  

(Undated)  Vision  for  Change  and  the  Nestlé  (Undated)  Cocoa  Plan,  which  include  R&D  and  

distribution  of  planting  material,  in  coordination  with  CNRA,  the  Ivorian  cacao  research  agency.  

The  use  of  yield-­‐enhancing  good  agricultural  practices  and  inputs  has  been  tied  to  

knowledge,  skills,  and  access  to  sufficient  inputs,  labor  and  finance  (Hatløy  et  al.  2012,  World  Cocoa  

Foundation  2012).  Economic  theory  indicates  that  farmers  must  also  believe  that  implementation  

will  be  profitable.  All  certifications  require  training  on  integrated  pest  management  and  fertility  

management.  RA  and  UTZ  mandate  training  on  additional  good  agricultural  practices,  with  UTZ  

having  the  most  comprehensive  coverage.  Numerous  buyers  also  provide  such  training.    

 

  79  

Certifiers  and  partners  who  wish  to  support  yield  enhancement  should  determine  if  

producers  are  receiving  training  on  good  agricultural  practices  that  are  not  covered  under  

certification  standards,  and  train  farmers  on  additional  practices  as  needed.  Per  industry  interviews  

(Major  2014,  Sendjou  2014),  certification  requirements  and  good  agricultural  practices  are  already  

being  combined  into  a  single  training  program,  in  some  cases.  It  seems  beneficial  for  such  training  

to  include  cost-­‐benefit  information  that  would  help  farmers  determine  how  changing  their  

practices  will  affect  their  profits.  Demonstration  plots  also  help  farmers  see  the  results  of  various  

management  regimes,  and  evaluate  their  potential  benefits.  Development  initiatives  such  as  Mars’  

(Undated)  Vision  for  Change  incorporate  these.      

Low  fertilizer  use  has  largely  been  tied  to  financial  constraints  (Hatløy  et  al.  2012),  as  well  

as  lack  of  local  suppliers  (World  Cocoa  Foundation  2013,  IDH  Undated).  FLO  provides  credit  

through  its  Fairtrade  Access  Fund,  but  it  has  largely  limited  this  to  financing  group  purchases  of  

member  crops,  leaving  farmers’  pre-­‐season  finance  needs  unaddressed  (FLO  2014b).  RA  connects  

groups  with  credit  providers,  but  does  not  offer  credit  (RA  2014b).  Per  the  cacao  sector  overview,  

several  buyers  extend  pre-­‐season  and  pre-­‐purchase  credit  to  co-­‐ops.  Access  to  affordable  farm-­‐level  

credit  remains  a  widespread  challenge  in  agricultural  development,  and  addressing  it  requires  

cross-­‐sector  collaboration.  Easing  credit  constraints  will  not  only  enable  farmers  to  purchase  more  

inputs,  drawing  more  suppliers,  but  would  help  finance  suppliers’  operations.    

Through  principled  producer  engagement  that  is  tailored  to  each  group’s  needs,  and  

concerted  collaboration  that  addresses  challenges  beyond  the  scope  of  certification,  certifiers,  and  

others  who  look  to  certification  as  a  way  to  increase  producers’  profits,  can  increase  the  likelihood  

that  such  improvements  will  occur.  This  would  help  certification  live  up  to  its  potential,  and  

promises,  and  advance  the  livelihoods  of  smallholders.    

 

 

  80  

References  

 Adimassu,  Z.,  A.  Kessler  and  H.  Hengsdijk.  2012.  Exploring  Determinants  of  Farmers’  Investments  in  

Land  Management  in  the  Central  Rift  Valley  of  Ethiopia.  Applied  Geography  35:  191-­‐198.    ADM.  2011.  “Our  Commitment  to  Sustainable  Cocoa.”  Retrieved  on  10/13/14  from  adm.com.    Afari-­‐Sefa,  V.,  J.  Gockowski,  N.  Agyeman  and  A.  Dziwornu.  “Economic  Cost-­‐Benefit  Analysis  Of  Certified  

Sustainable  Cocoa  Production  in  Ghana.”  Paper  to  African  Association  of  Agricultural  Economists  and  Agricultural  Economists  Association  of  South  Africa  Conference,  September  2010.  

 Agritrade.  2012.  “Special  Report—December  2012.  Côte  d’Ivoire’s  Cocoa  Sector  Reforms  2011–2012.”  

Retrieved  on  3/9/13  from  agritrade.ca.int.      Almeida,  I.  2013.  “Armajaro  Trading  Sold  to  Ecom  After  Loss  of  $7.6  Million.”  Bloomberg  News,  

11/11/13.  Accessed  at  bloomberg.com.    Alvarez,  G.  and  O.  von  Hagen.  2011.  “The  Impacts  of  Private  Standards  on  Producers  in  Developing  

Countries:  Literature  Review  Series  on  the  Impacts  of  Private  Standards  -­‐  Part  II.”  International  Trade  Centre  Technical  Paper.  Available  at  http://ssrn.com/abstract=2184273.  

 Aneani,  F.  and  K.Ofori-­‐Frimpong  2013.  “An  Analysis  of  Yield  Gap  and  Some  Factors  of  Cocoa  (Theobroma  

cacao)  Yields  in  Ghana.”  Sustainable  Agriculture  Research  4:  117-­‐127.    Arnould,  E.,  A.  Plastina  and  D.  Ball.  2009.  “Does  Fair  Trade  Deliver  on  Its  Core  Value  Proposition?  Effects  

on  Income,  Educational  Attainment,  and  Health  in  Three  Countries.”  Journal  of  Public  Policy  &  Marketing  28  (2):  186-­‐201.      

 Barham,  B.  and  J.  Weber.  2011.  “The  Economic  Sustainability  of  Certified  Coffee:  Recent  Evidence  from  

Mexico  and  Peru.”  World  Development  40  (6):  1269-­‐1279.    Barry  Callebaut.  2014.  “Cocoa  Sustainability  Report  2013/14.”  Retrieved  on  10/21/14  from  barry-­‐

callebaut.com.    Barry  Callebaut.  2012.  “Acquisition  of  Petra  Foods'  Cocoa  Ingredients  Division.  Presentation  to  

Investors,  Analysts  and  Media  Conference  Call.  12/12/12.”  Accessed  on  6/3/13  at  barry-­‐callebaut.com.  

 Bassett,  T.  2010.  “Slim  pickings:  Fairtrade  Cotton  in  West  Africa.”  Geoforum  41  (1):  44-­‐55.      Becchetti,  L.  and  M.  Costantino.  2008.  “The  Effects  of  Fair  Trade  on  Affiliated  Producers:  An  Impact  

Analysis  on  Kenyan  Farmers.”  World  Development  36  (5):  823-­‐842.    Bennett,  M.,  D.  Giovannucci,  C.  Rue,  H.  Ayerakwa  and  A.  Agyei-­‐  Holmes.  2013.  “Cocoa  Farms  in  Ghana:  An  

Evaluation  of  the  Impact  of  UTZ  Certification  on  the  Sustainability  of  Smallholders  Supported  by  the  Solidaridad  Cocoa  Programme  (2010-­‐2012).”  Committee  on  Sustainability  Assessment.  Retrieved  on  9/26/14  from  utzcertified.com.  

 Beuchelt,  T.D.  and  Zeller,  M.  2011.  “Profits  and  Poverty:  Certification’s  Troubled  Link  for  Nicaragua’s  

Organic  and  Fairtrade  Coffee  Producers.”  Ecological  Economics  70:  1316–1324.      

 

  81  

Bisseleua,  H.,  D.  Fotio,  Yede,  A.  Missoup  and  S.  Vidal.  “Shade  Tree  Diversity,  Cocoa  Pest  Damage,  Yield  Compensating  Inputs  and  Farmers’  Net  Returns  in  West  Africa.”  PLoS  One  8  (3):  e56115.  

 Blackman,  A.  and  J.  Rivera.  2011.  “Producer-­‐level  Benefits  of  Sustainability  Certification.”  Conservation  

Biology  25  (6):  1176-­‐1185.      Blackman,  A.  and  J.  Rivera.  2010.  “The  Evidence  Base  for  Environmental  and  Socioeconomic  Impacts  of  

“Sustainable”  Certification.”  Resources  for  the  Future  Discussion  Paper  EfD  10-­‐10.    Blowfield,  M.  and  C.  Dolan.  2011.  “Fairtrade  Facts  and  Fancies:  What  Kenyan  Fairtrade  Tea  Tells  Us  

about  Business’  Role  as  a  Development  Agent.”  Journal  of  Business  Ethics  93:  143-­‐162.    Bunge,  J.  and  L.  Josephs.  2014.  “Cargill  to  Buy  ADM's  Chocolate  Business  for  $440  Million.”  Wall  Street  

Journal,  9/2/14.  Accessed  on  10/20/14  at  wsj.com.    Buyo,  M.  2013.  Manager,  CEFCA.  Personal  interview  with  author.  22  August  2013.    Cargill.  2014.  “A  thriving  cocoa  sector  for  generations  to  come:  The  2014  Global  Cargill  Cocoa  Promise  

report.”  Retrieved  on  10/21/14  from  cargillcocoachocolate.com.    Carter,  M.  R.  1984.  "Identification  of  the  Inverse  Relationship  Between  Farm  Size  and  Productivity:  An  

Empirical  Analysis  of  Peasant  Agricultural  Production.”  Oxford  Economic  Papers  36:  131-­‐145.    CEval.  2012.  “Assessing  the  Impact  of  Fairtrade  on  Poverty  Reduction  through  Rural  Development.”  

Retrieved  on  1/3/13  from  www.ceval.de.    Chan,  M.  and  B.  Pound.  2009.  “Final  Report:  Literature  Review  of  Sustainability  Standards  and  Their  

Poverty  Impact.”  Department  for  International  Development  and  Natural  Resources  Institute.  Retrieved  on  3/25/13  from  nri.org.  

 Chavez,  A.  2014.  Cocoa  Sustainability  Manager,  Certification,  Mars,  Inc.  Personal  Interview  with  the  

author.  29  September  2014.    Chiputwa,  B.,  D.  Spielman  and  M.  Qaim.  2014.  “Food  Standards,  Certification,  and  Poverty  among  Coffee  

Farmers  in  Uganda”  World  Development  66:  400-­‐412.    Cone  Communications/ECHO.  2013.  “Global  CSR  Study.”  Cone  Communications.  Retrieved  on  10/17/14  

from  conecomm.com.    The  Committee  on  Sustainability  Assessment  (COSA).  2014.  “The  COSA  Measuring  Sustainability  Report:  

Coffee  and  Cocoa  in  12  Countries.”  Philadelphia,  PA:  The  Committee  on  Sustainability  Assessment.  Retrieved  1/30/14  from  thecosa.org.  

 Coulibaly,  L.  2011.  “Ivory  Coast  lifts  ban  on  cocoa  exports,  taxes.”  Reuters,  4/14/11.  Accessed  at  

reuters.com.    Danso-­‐Abbeam,  G.,  E.  Setsoafia  and  I.  Ansah.  2014.  “Modelling  Farmers’  Investment  in  Agrochemicals:  

The  Experience  of  Smallholder  Cocoa  Farmers  in  Ghana.”  Research  in  Applied  Economics  6  (4):  12-­‐27.    de  Janvry,  A.,  C.  McIntosh  and  E.  Sadoulet.  2014.  “Fair  Trade  and  Free  Entry:  Can  a  Disequilibrium  

Market  Serve  as  a  Development  Tool?”  Forthcoming  in  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics.  Retrieved  from  http://are.berkeley.edu/~esadoulet.  

 

  82  

Deppeler,  A.,  I.  Fromm  and  R.  Aidoo.  2014.  “The  Unmaking  of  the  Cocoa  Farmer:  Analysis  of  Benefits  and  Challenges  of  Third-­‐party  audited  Certification  Schemes  for  Cocoa  Producers  and  Laborers  in  Ghana.”  Paper  presented  at  the  IFAMA  and  CCA  Agribusiness  &  Food  World  Forum,  June  2014.  

 Deutsche  Gesellschaft  für  Technische  Zusammenarbeit  (GTZ).  2008.  “Realise  the  Difference:  Impacts  of  

the  Public  Private  Partnership  Project  PPDC.”  Retrieved  on  10/13/14  from  www2.gtz.de.    Fair  Labor  Association.  2012.  “Sustainable  Management  of  Nestlé’s  Cocoa  Supply  Chain  in  the  Ivory  

Coast—Focus  on  Labor  Standards.”  Retrieved  on  1/20/13  from  fairlabor.org.    Fair  Trade  USA.  2010.  “Fair  Trade  CertifiedTM  Cocoa  Review.”  Retrieved  on  9/11/14  from  

fairtradeusa.org.    [FLO  Undated]  Fairtrade  International.  Undated.  “The  Cocoa  Market  1994-­‐2013:  Comparison  of  

Fairtrade  &  New  York  Prices.”  Retrieved  on  10/21/14  from  fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2014a]  Fairtrade  International.  2014a.  “Fairtrade  Cocoa  in  West  Africa.”  Retrieved  on  6/14/14  

from  fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2014b]  Fairtrade  International.  2014b.  “Strong  Producers,  Strong  Future:  2013-­‐14  Annual  Report.”  

Retrieved  on  9/2/14  from  fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2013a]  Fairtrade  International.  2013a.  “Monitoring  the  Scope  and  Benefits  of  Fairtrade,  5th  

Edition.”  Retrieved  on  1/14/14  from  fairtrade.net.        [FLO  2013b]  Fairtrade  International.  2013b.  “Fairtrade  Standard  for  Cocoa  for  Small  Producer  

Organizations  (Current  Version  01.05.2011  v1.2).”  Retrieved  on  6/14/14  from  fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2013c]  Fairtrade  International.  2013c.  “Fairtrade  Theory  of  Change.”  Retrieved  on  5/24/14  from  

fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2012]  Fairtrade  International.  2012.  “Fairtrade  Standard  for  Small  Producer  Organizations  

(Current  Version  01.05.2011  v1.1).”  Retrieved  on  5/28/14  from  fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2011a]  Fairtrade  International.  2011a.  “Products”  website  section.  Accessed  on  9/3/14  at  

fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2011b]  Fairtrade  International.  2011b.  “About  Us”  website  section.  Accessed  on  9/3/14  at  

fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2011c]  Fairtrade  International.  2011c.  “Standards”  website  section.  Accessed  on  9/14/14  at  

fairtrade.net.    [FLO  2011d]  Fairtrade  International.  2011d.  “Generic  Fairtrade  Trade  Standard  (Current  Version  

01.05.2011).”  Retrieved  on  10/21/11  from  fairtrade.net.      Fenske,  J.  2011.  Land  Tenure  and  Investment  Incentives:  Evidence  from  West  Africa.  Journal  of  

Development  Economics  95:  137-­‐156.    FLOCERT.  2014.  “Fee  System  Small  Producer  Organizations.“  Retrieved  on  from  fairtrade.net.    

 

  83  

Fort,  R.,  and  R.  Ruben.  2008a.  “The  impact  of  Fair  Trade  on  Banana  Producers  in  Northern  Peru.”  In  R.  Ruben,  editor.  The  Impact  of  Fair  Trade.  Wageningen  Academic  Publishers,  Wageningen,  the  Netherlands:  49-­‐73.  

 Fort,  R.,  and  R.  Ruben.  2008b.  “Assessment  of  the  Effect  of  Fair  Trade  on  Smallholder  Producers  in  Costa  

Rica:  A  Comparative  Study  in  the  Coffee  Sector.”  In  R.  Ruben,  editor.  The  Impact  of  Fair  Trade.  Wageningen  Academic  Publishers,  Wageningen,  the  Netherlands:  75-­‐98.  

 Fortson,  J.,  N.  Murray  and  K.  Velyvis.  2011.  “Cocoa  Livelihoods  Program  (CLP)  Baseline  Memo.”  

Mathematica  Policy  Research,  Inc.    Fromm,  I.  and  J.  Dubón.  2006.  “Upgrading  and  the  Value  Chain  Analysis:  The  Case  of  Small-­‐scale  Coffee  

Farmers  in  Honduras.”  Presented  at  Tropentag  2006,  a  Conference  on  International  Agricultural  Research  for  Development,  Bonn,  Germany,  October  2006.    

 GIZ.  2011  “Mars  Partnership  for  African  Cocoa-­‐Communities  of  Tomorrow  (iMPACT).”  Retrieved  on  

10/13/14  from  giz.de.    George,  E.  2012.  “Structure  &  Competition  in  West  Africa’s  Cocoa  Trade,”  11/21/12.  Ecobank.  Retrieved  

on  6/25/14  from  ecobank.com.    Giovannucci,  D.  and  J.  Potts.  2010.  “Seeking  Sustainability:  COSA  Preliminary  Analysis  of  Sustainability  

Initiatives  in  the  Coffee  Sector.”  Committee  on  Sustainability  Assessment.  Retrieved  on  3/21/12  from  from  thecosa.org.  

 Hatløy,  A.,  T.  Kebede,  P.  Adeba  and  C.  Elvis.  2012.  “Towards  Côte  d’Ivoire  Sustainable  Cocoa  Initiative.”  

Fafo.  Retrieved  on  9/27/14  from  nhomatogdrikke.no.    ICRAF/World  Agroforestry  Center  2013.  “Grafting  and  Replanting  Plan.”  (From  K.  Smoot.)    IDH  Sustainable  Trade  Initiative.  Undated.  “Cocoa  Program”  website  section.  Accessed  on  9/30/14  at  

idhsustainabletrade.com.    Ingram,  V.,  Y.  Waarts,  L.  Ge,  S.  van  Vugt,  L.  Wegner,  L.  Puister-­‐Jansen,  F.  Ruf  and  R.  Tanoh.  2014.  “Impact  

of  UTZ  Certification  of  Cocoa  in  Ivory  Coast:  Assessment  Framework  and  Baseline.”  LEI  Wageningen  UR.  Retrieved  on  10/24/14  from  utzcertified.org.  

 [ICCO  2014a]  International  Cocoa  Organization.  2014a.  “Monthly  Average  of  World  Cocoa  Prices.”  

Accessed  October  2014  from  icco.org.    [ICCO  2014b]  International  Cocoa  Organization.  2014b.  Quarterly  Bulletin  of  Cocoa  Statistics:  Cocoa  year  

2013/2014,  XL  (3),  9/5/14.  ICCO.  Accessed  on  9/9/14  at  icco.org.    [ICCO  2014c]  International  Cocoa  Organization.  2014c.  “The  World  Cocoa  Economy:  Current  Status,  

Challenges  and  Prospects.”  Retrieved  on  9/13/14  from  unctad.org.    [ICCO  2014d]  International  Cocoa  Organization.  2102.  “The  World  Cocoa  Economy:  Past  and  Present.”  

Retrieved  on  9/13/14  from  icco.org.    [ICCO  Undated]  International  Cocoa  Organization.  Undated.  “About  Cocoa”  website  section.  Accessed  on  

9/7/14  at  www.icco.org.    

 

  84  

Jaffee,  D.  2008.  “Better,  But  Not  Great’:  The  Social  and  Environmental  Benefits  and  Limitations  of  Fair  Trade  for  Indigenous  Coffee  Producers  in  Oaxaca,  Mexico.”  In  R.  Ruben,  editor.  The  Impact  of  Fair  Trade.  Wageningen  Academic  Publishers,  Wageningen,  the  Netherlands.  

 Jena,  P.  R.,  B.  Chichaibelub,  T.  Stellmachera  and  U.  Grote.  2012.  “The  Impact  of  Coffee  Certification  on  

Small-­‐scale  Producers’  Livelihoods:  A  Case  Study  From  the  Jimma  Zone,  Ethiopia.”  Agricultural  Economics  43:  429–440  

 Jessop,  R.,  B.  Diallo,  M.  Duursma,  A.  Mallek,  J,  Harms  and  B.  van  Manen.  2012.  “Creating  Access  to  

Agricultural  Finance:  Based  on  a  horizontal  study  of  Cambodia,  Mali,  Senegal,  Tanzania,  Thailand  and  Tunisia.  Agencie  Francias  Developpement.”  Retrieved  on  7/20/14  from  afd.fr.  

 Kamau,  M.,  L.  Mose,  R.  Fort,  and  R.  Ruben.  2012.  “The  Impact  of  Certification  on  Smallholder  Coffee  

Farmers  in  Kenya:  The  case  of  ‘UTZ’  Certification  Program.”  Paper  presented  at  the  Joint  3rd  African  Association  of  Agricultural  Economists  and  48th  Agricultural  Economists  Association  of  South  Africa  Conference,  Cape  Town,  South  Africa,  September  2010.  

 KPMG.  2012.  “Cocoa  Certification:  Study  of  the  Costs,  Advantages  and  Disadvantage  of  Cocoa  

Certification,  Commissioned  by  the  International  Cocoa  Organization.”  Retrieved  on  11/22/12  from  icco.org.  

 Laan,  T.  and  H.  Guilhuis.  2014.  M&E  Officer,  UTZ  Certified.  Personal  communication  with  the  author,  

September  2014.    Lazaro,  A.,  J.  Makindara,  and  T.  Kilma.  2008.  “Sustainability  Standards  and  Coffee  Exports  from  

Tanzania.”  Working  paper  No  2008/1.  Danish  Institute  for  International  Studies,  Copenhagen.    Major,  R.  2014.  Senior  Manager,  Sustainability  Initiatives,  The  Hershey  Company.  Personal  

communication  with  the  author.  29  October  2014.    Marenya,  P.  and  C.  Barrett.  2007.  “Household-­‐level  Determinants  of  Adoption  of  Improved  Natural  

Resources  Management  Practices  Among  Smallholder  Farmers  in  Western  Kenya.”  Food  Policy  32:  515-­‐536.  

 Mars,  Inc.  Undated.  “Vision  for  Change.”  Retrieved  on  3/11/13  at  mars.com.    Melo,  C.  and  G.  Hollander.  2013.  “Unsustainable  Development:  Alternative  Food  Networks  and  the  

Ecuadorian  Federation  of  Cocoa  Producers,  1995-­‐2010.”  Journal  of  Rural  Studies  32:  251-­‐263.    Méndez,  V.E.,  C.  M.  Bacon,  M.  Olson,  S.  Petchers,  D.  Herrador,  C.  Carranza,  L.  Trujillo,  C.  Guadarrama-­‐

Zugasti,  A.  Cordón  and  A.  Mendoza.  2010.  “Effects  of  Fair  Trade  and  Organic  Certifications  on  Small-­‐scale  Coffee  Farmer  Households  in  Central  America  and  Mexico.”  Renewable  Agriculture  and  Food  Systems  25  (3):  236–251  

 Nelson,  V  &  B.  Pound.  2009.  “A  Review  of  the  Impact  of  Fairtrade  over  the  Last  Ten  Years.”  Fairtrade  

Foundation.  Retrieved  on  3/27/13  from  fairtrade.net.    Nestlé.  Undated.  “Nestlé  and  Sustainable  Cocoa:  ‘The  Cocoa  Plan’.”  Retrieved  on  10/13/14  at  nestle.com.    Nieberg,  O.  2014.  “Over  half  of  certified  cocoa  may  be  sold  as  conventional  cocoa.”  Confectionery  

News.com,  8/27/14.  Accessed  at  confectionerynews.com.    

 

  85  

Nielsen  Company,  The.  2014.  “Doing  Well  By  Doing  Good.”  Retrieved  on  10/17/14  at  nielsen.com.    Onoja,  A.,  N.  Deedam,  and  A.  Achike.  2012.  “Profitability  and  Yield  Determinants  in  Nigerian  Cocoa  

Farms:  Evidence  from  Ondo  State.”  Journal  of  Sustainable  Development  in  Africa  14  (4):  172-­‐182.    Opoku-­‐Ameyaw,  K.,  F.  Baah,  E.  Gyedu-­‐Akoto,  V.  Anchirinah,  H.  K.  Dzahini-­‐Obiatey,  A.  R.  Cudjoe,  S.  Aquaye  

and  S.  Y.  Opoku.  2010.  Cocoa  Manual.  Cocoa  Research  Institute  of  Ghana.    Payson  Center  for  International  Development  and  Technology  Transfer,  Tulane  University.  2010.  

“Fourth  Annual  Report:  Oversight  of  Public  and  Private  Initiatives  to  Eliminate  the  Worst  Forms  of  Child  Labor  in  the  Cocoa  Sector  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  and  Ghana.”  Retrieved  on  9/30/10  from  cocoainitiative.org  

 Pinto,  L.,  T.  Gardner,  C.McDermott  and  K.  Ayub.  2014.  “Group  Certification  Supports  an  Increase  in  the  

Diversity  of  Sustainable  Agriculture  Network–Rainforest  Alliance  Certified  Coffee  Producers  in  Brazil.”  Ecological  Economics  107:  59–64  

 Place,  F.  2009.  “Land  Tenure  and  Agricultural  Productivity  in  Africa:  A  Comparative  Analysis  of  the  

Economics  Literature  and  Recent  Policy  Strategies  and  Reforms.”  World  Development  37  (8):  1326–1336.  

 Potts,  J.,  M.  Lynch,  A.  Wilkings,  G.  Huppé,  M.  Cunningham  and  V.  Voora.  2014.  “State  of  Sustainability  

Initiatives.”  International  Institute  for  Sustainable  Development  and  the  International  Institute  for  Environment  and  Development.  Retrieved  on  4/4/14  from  iisd.org.  

 RA-­‐Cert.  2012.  “Rainforest  Alliance  Certification  Manual,  Sustainable  Agriculture.”  Retrieved  on  9/15/14  

from  rainforest-­‐alliance.org.      [RA  2014a]  Rainforest  Alliance.  2014a.  “Our  Work.”  Accessed  on  9/4/14  at  rainforest-­‐alliance.org.    [RA  2014b]  Rainforest  Alliance.  2014b.  “Engage  Your  Business”  website  section.  Accessed  on  9/15/14  at  

rainforest-­‐alliance.org.    [RA  2014c]  Rainforest  Alliance.  2014c.  “About  Us”  website  section.  Accessed  on  9/4/14  at  rainforest-­‐

alliance.org.    [RA  2013a]  Rainforest  Alliance.  2013a.  “Connections:  Rainforest  Alliance  Annual  Report  2013.”  

Retrieved  on  9/4/14  from  rainforest-­‐alliance.org.    [RA  2013b]  Rainforest  Alliance.  2013b.  “2013  Highlights:  The  Rainforest  Alliance’s  Global  Sustainability  

Efforts.”  Retrieved  on  8/13/14  from  rainforest-­‐alliance.org.      Riisgaard,  L.,  G.  Michuki,  P.  Gibbon,  S.  Bolwig,  N.  Warring  and  L.  Rantz.  2009.  “The  Performance  of  

Voluntary  Standard  Schemes  from  the  Perspective  of  Small  Producers  in  East  Africa.”  Copenhagen:  Danish  Institute  for  International  Studies,  Copenhagen.  

 Ruben,  R.  and  R.  Fort  2011.  “The  Impact  of  Fair  Trade  Certification  for  Coffee  Farmers  in  Peru.”  World  

Development  40  (3):  570-­‐582.      Ruben,  Fort  and  Zúñiga-­‐Arias.  2009.  “Measuring  the  Impact  of  Fair  Trade  on  Development.”  Development  

in  Practice,  19  (6):  777-­‐788.    

 

  86  

Ruben,  R.,  L.  Clercx,  D.  Cepeda,  and  T.  de  Hopp.  2008.  “Fair  Trade  Impact  of  Banana  Production  in  El  Guabo  Association,  Ecuador:  a  Production  Function  Analysis.”  In  R.  Ruben,  editor.  The  Impact  of  Fair  Trade.  Wageningen  Academic  Publishers,  Wageningen,  the  Netherlands:  155-­‐167.  

 Ruben,  R.  and  G.  Zuniga.  (2011).  “How  Standards  Compete:  Comparative  Impact  of  Coffee  Certification  

Schemes  in  Northern  Nicaragua.”  Supply  Chain  Management:  An  International  Journal  16  (2):  98-­‐109.      

Rueda,  X.  and  E.  Lambin.  2013.  “Responding  to  Globalization:  Impacts  of  Certification  on  Colombian  Small-­‐Scale  Coffee  Growers.”  Ecology  and  Society  18  (3):  21  

 Saitone,  T.  and  R.  Sexton.  2010.  “Product  Differentiation  and  Quality  in  Food  Markets:  Industrial  Organization  Implications.”  Annual  Review  of  Resource  Economics  2:  341–68.    Saltini,  R.,  R.  Akkerman  and  S.  Frosch.  2013.  “Optimizing  Chocolate  Production  Through  Traceability:  A  

Review  of  the  Influence  of  Farming  Practices  on  Cocoa  Bean  Quality.”  Food  Control  29:  167-­‐187.    Sendjou,  G.  2014.  Sustainability  Manager,  Archer  Daniels  Midland.  Personal  Interview  with  the  author.  4  

November  2014.    Smith,  R.    2004.  Land  Tenure,  Fixed  Investment,  and  Farm  Productivity:  Evidence  from  Zambia’s  

Southern  Province.  World  Development  32  (10):  1641–1661.    Smith,  S.  2010.  “Fairtrade  Bananas:  A  Global  Assessment  of  Impact.”  Institute  of  Development  Studies,  

University  of  Sussex.  Retrieved  on  8/4/14  from  fairtrade.net.    Spaggiari  Souza,  C.,  L.  dos  Santos  Dias,  M.  Galeas  Aguilar,  S  Sonegheti,  J.  Oliveira  and  J.  Andrade  Costa.  

2009.  “Cacao  Yield  in  Different  Planting  Densities.”  Brazilian  Archives  of  Biology  and  Technology  52:  1313-­‐1320.  

 Stemler,  C.  2012.  “Analysis  of  On-­‐farm  Fertilizer  Trials  in  Côte  d’Ivoire  and  Implications  for  Fertilizer  

Distribution  Strategies.”  IDH  Sustainable  Trade  Initiative.  Retrieved  on  8/3/14  from  idhsustainabletrade.com.  

 [SAN  2014]  Sustainable  Agriculture  Network.  2014.  “General  Interpretation  Guide  -­‐  Sustainable  

Agriculture  Standard.”  Retrieved  on  from  san.ag.      [SAN  2011a]  Sustainable  Agriculture  Network.  2011a.  “Group  Certification  Standard,  March  2011  (v.  2).”  

Retrieved  on  3/7/12  from  san.ag.    [SAN  2011b]  Sustainable  Agriculture  Network.  2011b.  “Group  Certification  Policy,  March  2011  (v.  2).”  

Retrieved  on  3/7/12  from  san.ag.    [SAN  2010]  Sustainable  Agriculture  Network.  2010.  “Sustainable  Agriculture  Standard,  July  2010  (v.  2).”  

Retrieved  3/7/12  on  from  san.ag.    Sustainable  Tree  Crops  Program.  2009.  “Sustainable  Tree  Crops  Program—Côte  d’Ivoire.”  Retrieved  on  

10/13/14  at  iita.org.    [TCC  2012]  Tropical  Commodity  Coalition.  2012.  “2012  Cocoa  Barometer.“  Retrieved  on  12/3/12  from  

cocoabarometer.org.    

 

  87  

[UNDP  2013]  United  Nations  Development  Program.  2013.  “Human  Development  Report  2013:  The  Rise  of  the  South:  Human  Progress  in  a  Diverse  World.”  Available  at  hdr.undp.org.  

 [UNCTAD  2008]  United  Nations  Conference  on  Trade  and  Development.  2008.  “Cocoa  Study:  Industry  

Structures  and  Competition.”  Retrieved  on  10/20/11  from  unctad.org.    Utting-­‐Chamorro,  K.  2005.  “Does  Fair  Trade  Make  a  Difference?  The  Case  of  Small  Coffee  Producers  in  Nicaragua.”  Development  in  Practice  153:  584-­‐99.      [UTZ  2014a]  UTZ  Certified.  2014a.  “About  UTZ  Certified”  website  section.  Accessed  on  9/4/14  at  

www.utzcertified.org.    [UTZ  2014b]  UTZ  Certified.  2014b.  “Annual  Report  2013.“  Retrieved  on  9/5/14  from  utzcertified.org.    [UTZ  2014c]  UTZ  Certified.  2014c.  “UTZ  Certified  Impact  Report  2014.”  Retrieved  on  1/21/14  from  

utzcertified.org.    [UTZ  2014d]  UTZ  Certified.  2014d.  “Core  Code  of  Conduct,  Version  1.0:  For  individual  and  multi-­‐site  

certification.”  Retrieved  on  9/3/14  from  utzcertified.org.    [UTZ  2014e]  UTZ  Certified.  2014e.  “Code  of  Conduct,  Cocoa  Module,  Version  1.0.”  Retrieved  on  9/2/14  

from  utzcertified.org.    [UTZ  2009]  UTZ  Certified.  2009.  “Good  Inside  Code  of  Conduct  for  Cocoa.”  Retrieved  on  6/13/10  from  

utzcertified.org.    Vagneron,  I.  and  S.  Roquigny.  2010.  “What  Do  We  Really  Know  About  the  Impact  of  Fair  Trade?”  CIRAD.  

Retrieved  on  8/10/14  from  commercequitable.org.    Valkila,  J.  2009.  “Fair  Trade  Organic  Coffee  Production  in  Nicaragua  —  Sustainable  Development  or  a  

Poverty  Trap?”  Ecological  Economics  68  (12):  3018-­‐3025.      Valkila,  J.  and  A.  Nygren.  2008.  “Impacts  of  Fair  Trade-­‐certification  on  Coffee  Farmers,  Cooperatives,  and  

Laborers  in  Nicaragua.”  Paper  presented  at  the  3rd  Fair  Trade  International  Symposium,  May  2008.    Waarts,  Y.,  L.  Ge,  G.  Ton  and  D.  Jansen.  2012.  “Sustainable  Tea  Production  in  Kenya:  Impact  Assessment  

of  Rainforest  Alliance  and  Farmer  Field  School  Training.”  LEI  Wageningen  UR.  Retrieved  on  10/11/14  from  rainforest-­‐alliance.org.  

 World  Cocoa  Foundation.  2014a.  “Cocoa  Market  Update,  April,  2014.”  Retrieved  on  9/11/14  from  

worldcocoa.org.    [WCF  2014b]  World  Cocoa  Foundation.  2014b.  “Programs”  website  section.  Accessed  on  10/12/14  at  

worldcocoa.org.    World  Cocoa  Foundation.  2013.  “Committed  to  Cocoa-­‐Growing  Communities.”  Retrieved  on  9/11/14  

from  worldcocoa.org.    Zúniga-­‐Arias,  G.,  and  F.  Sáenz  Segura.  2008.  The  Impact  of  Fair  Trade  in  Banana  Production  of  Costa  Rica.  

In  R.  Ruben,  editor.  The  Impact  of  Fair  Trade.  Wageningen  Academic  Publishers,  Wageningen,  the  Netherlands:  99-­‐116.  

 

  88  

Appendix  A:  Survey  Instruments  

A1:  Producer  Survey    

Harvest  Year  For  Survey:  October  2012-­‐September  2013  *  Emphasize  to  farmer  that  questions  refer  to  this  period  –  where  it  says  the  "last  cocoa  year"  unless  specified  *  

 i.  Survey  Number:  ____________________________  Date:________________  ii.  Surveyor's  name:  _______________________________    iii.  Initial  for  YES:  Farmer  provided  consent_______      Met  Screening  Questions  ______  iv.  Farmer's  Name:  _________________________________________________  v.  Farm  Location:  Sub-­‐Prefecture  ___________________    Village  ________________  vi.  Farmer's  Cooperative:  ______________________________Year  Joined  ________  vii.  Certification/s  (if  applicable):  Fairtrade    Rainforest  Alliance    Utz    Year  Obtained  _____  vii.  How  did  producer  get  into  certification  (circle):    a)  Co-­‐op  chose  to  get  certified          

b)  Third  party  (specify)  asked  Co-­‐op  asked  to  get  certified:_____________________  c)  Producer  chose  to  join  co-­‐op  that  was  already  certified    

Socioeconomic  Characteristics    1. What  is  your  age?  ____________  OR  what  year  were  you  born  __________  2. What  is  the  primary  farmer's  gender?                              M            F  3. What  is  your  ethnicity?  _________________    Nationality?  _______________  4. What  level  of  schooling  have  you  completed:  __________  5. How  many  family  members  live  in  your  home?  Under  18  _____      Over  18  _____  6. What  was  your  household's  total  income  last  year?  ____________________    Farm  Characteristics    7. How  many  years  have  you  been  working  as  a  cacao  farmer?  _______________  

 8. What  is  the  arrangement  for  the  land  you  farm  on  (circle)?    Own  Family  Land,  Sharecropper          

Rent          Work  on  land  for  another  person          Other  If  other,  what  is  the  arrangement?  __________________________________    9.  How  many  hectares  are  planted  in  cacao,  what  age  are  the  trees  and  how  many  trees  do  you  have  per  hectare?  (Fill  in  total  if  farmer  knows.  Use  chart  only  if  they  can  report  only  separate  plots.)    TOTAL  i)  Hectares  _____________                              ii)  Age  of  trees  ____________                                  iii)  Cacao  trees/ha  _____________        

 

  89  

Cacao   Hectares   Age  of  trees   Cacao  Trees/ha  1        2        3        4          10.  a.  How  many  shade  trees  do  you  have  in  your  cacao  plots,  in  all?  ___________    b.  How  has  the  number  of  shade  trees  changed  in  the  last  four  years  (circle)?  Added          Removed      Same  

 c.  IF  Certified:  How  has  the  number  of  shade  trees  changed  since  before  you  were  certified  (circle)?          Added          Removed      Same    11.  How  many  other  hectares  do  you  farm?    _______________      Farm  practices    12.  a.  How  many  cacao  trees  did  you  graft  and  plant  in  the  last  cocoa  season?  Grafted:  ________      Seedlings  planted:  ________          Seeds  planted:  _________  b.  How  has  the  number  and  type  trees  you  have  planted  and  grafted  changed  in  the  last  four  years?      Number:  Increased                Decreased              Same          Varietals:  Improved  Varietals      Same  Varietals  (No  change)  

 c.  IF  Certified  How  has  the  number  and  type  trees  you  have  planted  and  grafted  changed  since  before  becoming  certified?        Number:  Increased              Decreased              Same          Varietals:  Improved  Varietals        Same  Varietals  (No  change)    13.  a.  At  what  frequency  do  you  harvest  your  cacao?  (e.g.,  weekly,  every  two  weeks):  ___________________________________________________________  b.  How  has  this  changed  in  the  last  four  years?    More  frequent      Less  frequent    Same  

 c.  IF  Certified:  How  has  this  changed  since  before  becoming  certified?    More  frequent      Less  frequent      Same        

 

  90  

14.  Over  the  past  cocoa  season,  how  often  have  you  done  the  following  tasks?  Have  you  changed  any  tasks  in  the  last  four  years,  or  since  becoming  certified,  by  starting  or  stopping  it,  or  increasing  or  decreasing  the  frequency  of  the  task?    

Farm  Task  

Freq.    last  cocoa  yr  

Changed  in  last  four  years?  

If  certified:  Changed  since  before  certified?  

Weeding     Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                  

SAME  

Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                   SAME  

Pruning  cacao  

  Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                  

SAME  

Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                   SAME  

Remove  diseased  pods,  branches  

  Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                  

SAME  

Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                   SAME  

Apply  fertilizer  

  Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                  

SAME  

Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                   SAME  

Apply  insecticide    

  Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                  

SAME  

Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                   SAME  

Apply  fungicide    

  Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                  

SAME  

Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                   SAME  

Prune  shade  trees  

  Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                  

SAME  

Started              Stopped        Increased      Decreased                   SAME  

 Training  and  Extension  15. How  many  times  in  the  last  season  did  you  visit  or  were  visited  by  an  extension  agent  for  advice  

(not  training)  (e.g.,  ANADER,  etc.)?  _____________________    16. a.  Did  you  receive  any  trainings  in  the  last  season?                Y                      N                    IF  YES:  

b. What  did  these  trainings  cover?  ___________________________________  c. How  many  days  per  month  did  these  trainings  take,  on  average?  __________  d. How  many  trainings  did  you  attend?  ______________________  

 

 

  91  

17. If  certified:  a.  Were  you  required  to  participate  in  trainings  to  get  certified?        Y              N          IF  YES:  b. What  did  these  trainings  cover?  ___________________________________  c. How  many  days  per  month  did  these  trainings  take,  on  average?  __________  d. How  many  trainings  did  you  attend?  ______________________  

 Revenue  and  Marketing      18.  a.  How  many  buyers  did  you  sell  to  in  the  last  season?        ___________  

b.  How  many  buyers  could  you  have  sold  to  in  the  last  season?  __________  

c.  Did  any  buyers  limit  how  much  they  would  buy?      Y        N  

d.  What  percentage  of  your  cacao,  or  total  kg,  did  you  sell  to  you  co-­‐op  un  the  last  season    ____________    

circle:    percentage          total  kg  

 20.  Do  you  transport  your  cacao  before  selling  it?          Y        N  a.  If  yes,  how  many  km  do  you  travel  and  how  many  minutes  does  it  take?    Distance  ___________________  km      Time  __________________  Minutes    **  For  20-­‐23,  ask  farmer  to  show  you  sales  tickets,  records  or  other  verification.  Note  here  what  verification  was  shown,  if  any:  __________________________  **    20.  How  much  cacao  did  you  sell  in  the  last  cacao  season  and  how  much  money  did  you  receive  for  this,  including  premiums/bonuses  received  when  you  sold  the  cacao?  

  Amount      (circle  unit)  

Changed  in  last  four  years?  If  yes,  more  or  

less?  

If  certified:  Changed  since  becoming  

certified?  If  yes,  more  or  less?  

Amount  Sold   ______  Kg      Bags    ______  Kg  per  bag  

Y      N            More      Less   Y      N            More      Less  

Income    ________  CFA        

Y      N            More      Less   Y      N            More      Less  

 *  If  farmer  does  not  know  total  income,  ask  i)  average  price  per  bag  or  kg  after  deductions  were  made  and  including  any  premium/bonus  received  at  the  time  of  sale,  ii)  average  kg  per  bag  if  bags  used,  Average  price:  _____      Unit  (circle)    kg      bag                                                Kg/bag  ______    21  a.  Did  you  receive  any  premiums/bonuses  after  selling  your  cacao  to  the  buyer,  such  as  at  the  end  of  the  season,  that  you  didn't  include  in  your  previous  answer?    Y        N  b.  IF  YES:  Total  premium:  _________    OR        Bags  receiving  premiums  _________  Average  premium  per  bag  __________  

 

  92  

 22.  IF  farmer  reported  premiums  above:  Do  you  know  how  much  of  a  premium  you  received  for  quality,  certification  and  other  premiums.  

Type  of  Premium   Premium  Received  

Amount  of  Premium  

Unit  Premium  Applied  To  

Quality   Y          N     Kg    Bag  Other  (state)  Certified  cacao  (if  certified)  

Y          N     Kg    Bag  Other  (state)  

Other  (state)   Y          N     Kg    Bag  Other  (state)    23.  If  certified:  How  many  kg  of  cacao  did  you  sell  under  certified  terms  (designated  as  certified  at  the  "certified"  price/premium)  in  the  last  cacao  year?  ___________    Expenditures    24.  How  much  time  did  family  members  work  on  the  cacao  farm  year  last  season?      Age  range   Hours  

worked  per  day  

Days  worked  per  week  

Changed  in  last  four  

years?  If  yes,  more  or  less?  

If  certified:  Changed  since  becoming  certified?  If  yes,  more  or  less?  

Adults  age  18+       Y      N            More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Youth  <  age  18       Y      N            More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

       

 

  93  

25.  Please  state  expenditures  for  the  following  in  the  last  cacao  year,  for  the  cacao  crop  only  Input  or  Service     Annual  

Cost  (CFA)  

OR  Quantity  X  Cost/unit  (state  units)    

Cost  changed  in  last  four  years?  If  yes,  more  or  less?  

If  certified:  Cost  changed  since  becoming  

certified?  If  yes,  more  or  less?  

Hired  Labor     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Fertilizer     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Pesticide     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Fungicide    

  X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Herbicide     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Cacao  Seeds     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Planting  Sacs     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Cacao  Seedlings     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Scion  for  Grafting     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Motorized  sprayer  (circle):  rent  OR  hire  person/team  to  do  spraying  

  X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Petro  for  spraying     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Water  for  spraying     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Equipment  Rental  (name  equipment)  

  X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Vehicle  transport  to  sell  cacao/buy  inputs  

  X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Cooperative  Fees     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Certification  Fees     X   Y      N            More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Training     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Loan  Payment  –  state  interest  rate  

  X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Other:     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

Other     X   Y      N              More      Less  

Y      N            More      Less  

 

  94  

 26.  Please  state  any  inputs  or  services  you  received  for  free  or  at  a  reduced  cost  in  the  last  cocoa  season:_________________________________________________________________________________________________________    __________________________________________________________________________________________________________________    Perception  on  Livelihoods  Changes      27.  How  has  your  ability  to  meet  expenditures,  such  as  paying  school  fees,  medical  bills,  and  feeding  your  family,  and  save  money  changed  (circle  answers):  a.  In  the  past  year?                  Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same  b.  In  the  past  four  years?  Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same  c.  Since  becoming  certified:  Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same    28. How  has  your  ability  to  access  low  interest  credit  changed:  a.  In  the  past  year?                    Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same  b.  In  the  past  four  years?  Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same  c.  Since  becoming  certified?  Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same    29. How  have  your  influence  and  position  in  your  community  and  cooperative  changed,  such  as  the  

respect  you  feel  and  your  level  of  participation  in  decision  making:  a.  In  the  past  year?                                Higher          Lower          Same  b.  In  the  past  four  years?              Higher          Lower          Same  c.  Since  becoming  certified?    Higher          Lower          Same    30. How  has  your  amount  of  household  and  farm  assets,  such  as  mobile  phones,  cacao  farming  and  

processing  tools  and  equipment,  changed:  a.  In  the  past  year?                              Increased          Decreased          Same  b.  In  the  past  four  years?              Increased          Decreased          Same    c.  Since  becoming  certified?    Increased          Decreased          Same    31. How  have  your  cacao  farming,  harvest  and  post-­‐harvest  processing  knowledge  and  skills  

changed:  a.  In  the  past  year?                            Increased  a  lot        Increased  a  little            Same  b.  In  the  past  four  years?          Increased  a  lot        Increased  a  little            Same    c.  Since  becoming  certified:  Increased  a  lot        Increased  a  little            Same    32. How  have  your  relationships  with  buyers,  and  your  marketing  skills  and  knowledge  changed:  a.  In  the  past  year?            Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same  b.  In  the  past  four  years?  Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same  c.  Since  becoming  certified:  Much  better      A  bit  better      Much  worse      A  bit  worse      Same  

 

  95  

33. If  Certified:  What  were  you  promised,  that  you  would  get  from  certification,  and  what  did  you  expect  to  get  from  it?  Which  of  these  have  you  received?  

  Promised   Expected   Received  Better  prices    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Better  income    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  More  timely  payments    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Better  access  to  markets  and  buyers  

 Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  

Better  relationship  with  buyers    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Better  farming  and  processing  skills  

 Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  

Higher  yields    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Better  quality  cacao    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  More  training    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Better  inputs  –  planting  material,  chemicals  

 Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  

Cheaper  inputs    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Cheaper  services    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Pre-­‐financing  from  your  buyer/s    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Better  access  to  credit,  besides  buyer  pre-­‐financing  

 Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  

Cheaper  loan  rates    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N  Other  (specify):    Y              N   Y              N   Y              N          

 

  96  

A2.  Co-­‐op  Management  Interview:  Certified  Co-­‐ops    Surveyor  ______________________________________Date  ___________________________  

Co-­‐op  name____________________________________________________________________  

Year  founded  ___________________________  Number  of  members  _____________________  

Sub-­‐Prefect________________________________  Village______________________________  

Nam  and  title  of  person  interviewed  _________________________________________________  

 

 1. What  certification/s  does  your  co-­‐op  have,  and  what  year  were  these  obtained?    Certification  ______________________________      Year  Obtained  ________________    Certification  ______________________________      Year  Obtained  ________________    Certification  ______________________________      Year  Obtained  ________________      IF  co-­‐op  has  multiple  certifications,  complete  a  separate  survey  for  each  and  state  certification  the  below  questions  relate  to:  _________________________________________  

 2. Why  did  the  co-­‐op  decide  to  get  certified?    Also,  did  you  approach  the  certifier  or  were  you  

approached?    3. How  much  did  the  co-­‐op  spend  to  obtain  this  certification,  including  direct  costs  such  as  farm  

inspections  and  indirect  costs  like  hiring  extra  staff  to  track  sales?  ______________________    4. How  much  does  the  co-­‐op  spend  yearly  to  maintain  this  certification,  including  direct  costs  like  

farm  inspections  and  indirect  costs  like  hiring  extra  staff  to  track  sales?  ______________    

5. What  was  the  price/kg  the  co-­‐op  received  for  cacao  under  this  certification  in  the  2012013  season?  _______________  

 6. What  was  the  premium/bonus  farmers  received  from  the  buyer  under  this  certification  in  the  

2012-­‐13  season?  _____________  CIRCLE  unit  premium  applies  to:       kg     bag     annual  flat  rate  

 7. What  percentage  of  the  co-­‐op's  cacao  is  sold  under  this  certification?  __________________  

 8. What  was  the  average  price/kg  the  co-­‐op  received  for  non-­‐certified  cacao  in  the  2012013  

season?  _______________        

 

  97  

9. In  the  last  cacao  season,  what  were  the  amounts  of  any  premiums/bonuses  given  to  the  co-­‐op,  and/or  invested  directly  by  your  buyer/s,  for  co-­‐op  and  community  development  projects?    a.  Premium  given  to  co-­‐op  by  certified  buyer/s,  for  projects  selected  by  co-­‐op  ___________________    b.  Direct  investment  by  certified  buyer/s,  for  projects  identified  by  buyer  ________________________  

 c.  Funds  given  to  co-­‐op  by  non-­‐certified  buyer/s,  for  projects  selected  by  co-­‐op  ___________________    d.  Direct  investment  by  non-­‐certified  buyer/s,  for  projects  identified  by  buyer  ____________________  

   10. What  projects  were  funded  in  the  last  three  years  from  the  following  funds?    

a.  Premium  given  to  co-­‐op  by  certified  buyer/s,  for  projects  selected  by  co-­‐op  (with  or  without  buyer  input)  

 b.    Direct  investment  by  certified  buyer/s  for  projects  identified  by  buyer  (with  or  without  co-­‐op  input)    c.  Funds  given  to  co-­‐op  by  non-­‐certified  buyer/s,  for  projects  selected  by  co-­‐op    

 d.  Direct  investment  by  non-­‐certified  buyer/s,  for  projects  identified  by  buyer    

   11. Overall,  how  do  you  feel  certification  has  impacted  the  co-­‐op  and  its  members  financially?  

   12. What  price  per  kg  did  the  co-­‐op  pay  its  members  in  the  2012-­‐13  season?  ________________      13. What  fees  do  co-­‐op  members  pay  the  co-­‐op  at  present:  

 a. Annual  dues    _______________________  

 b. Mandatory  services,  and  fees  including  cost  share  for  certification  fees,  not  covered  under  

annual  dues  (specify  service  with  fee  and  term—annual,  per  use,  etc.    

c. Voluntary  services  and  fees  (specify  service  with  fee  and  term)            

 

  98  

A3.  Co-­‐op  Management  Interview:  Non-­‐Certified  Co-­‐ops    Surveyor  ______________________________________Date  ___________________________  

Co-­‐op  name____________________________________________________________________  

Year  founded  ___________________________  Number  of  members  _____________________  

Sub-­‐Prefect________________________________  Village______________________________  

Nam  and  title  of  person  interviewed  _________________________________________________  

 

   

1. What  is  the  average  price/kg  the  co-­‐op  receives  for  its  cacao?  _______________    2. What  is  the  average  premium  farmers  receive  from  the  co-­‐op's  buyers  if  any?  _____________          

CIRCLE  unit  premium  applies  to:          kg   bag   annual  flat  rate    

 3. What  percentage  of  the  co-­‐op's  cacao  receives  any  price  premium?  ___________________  

   4. In  the  last  cacao  season,  what  were  the  amounts  of  any  payments  or  bonus  given  to  the  co-­‐op,  

and/or  investments  made  by  buyer,  for  co-­‐op,  farm  and  community  development  projects?    a.  Payments  given  to  co-­‐op,  for  projects  selected  by  co-­‐op  _______________________  

 b.  Direct  investment  by  buyer,  for  projects  identified  by  buyer  __________________  

   5. What  projects  were  funded  in  the  last  three  years  from  the  following  funds?    

a.  Payments  given  to  co-­‐op,  for  projects  selected  by  co-­‐op  (with  or  without  buyer  input)    

b.  Direct  investment  by  buyer  for  projects  identified  by  buyer  (with  or  without  co-­‐op  input)    

 6. What  price  per  kg  does  the  co-­‐op  pay  its  members?  ________________      7. What  fees  do  co-­‐op  members  pay  the  co-­‐op:  

 a. Annual  dues    _______________________  

 b. Mandatory  services,  and  fees,  not  covered  under  annual  dues  (specify  service  with  fee  

and  term—annual,  per  use,  etc.)    

c. Voluntary  services  and  fees  (specify  service  with  fee  and  term)      

 

  99  

Appendix  B:  Additional  Data  

Table  B1:  Summary  Statistics,  Certified  Producers  &  Controls,  2012-­‐13  Cacao  Season    

 Controls   Certified  Farmers   Sig.  

Diff.    Variable   N   Mean   Std.  Dev.   N   Mean   Std.  Dev.    Farmer  Socioeconomic  Traits  Age   75   44.89   10.24   222   45.96   11.13    Male   76   1   0   223   0.97   0.16    Household  (HH)  size   76   10.92   4.92   220   10.73   7.08    HH  income,  CFA   76   1,809,500   1,465,820   223   1,923,996   1,770,340    HH  income/HH  member,  CFA   76   185,654.50   153,523.7   220   212,109.1   186,502.2  

 

Years  of  education   74   5.92   4.60   215   6.32   4.79    

Farmer  and  Farm  Characteristics  Years  in  co-­‐op   75   6.91   5   220   7.42   4.8    Years  growing  cacao   75   19.80   10.55   219   19   10.49    Extension  visits/yr   72   3.79   7.27       215   10.46   12.31   ***  Training  sessions/yr   72   4.89   9.33   222   1485   14.35   ***  Total  cacao  ha   76   5.69   4.17   222   5.84   4.59    Mature  cacao  ha   76   5.44   4.08   222   5.75   4.59    Total  farm  ha   71   7.88   5.48   220   7.66   6    Avg.  cacao  trees/ha   65   1,312.07   238.88   190   1,31.07   203.68    Shade  trees/ha   74   5.88   6.55   220   7.56   8.40   *  

Farm  Practices  and  Itemized  Expenditures  Good  ag  prac.  (of  7)   76   4.87   1.11   221   4.89   1.2    

Weeding  frequency/yr   75   2.55   0.64   223   2.85   1.58   **  Pruning  frequency/yr   69   5.26   8.30   193   14.42   32.92   ***  Fertilizer  apps/yr   76   0.21   0.51   222   0.22   0.5    Insecticide  apps/yr   76   1.91   1.11   223   1.64   1.27    Fungicide  applications   75   1.32   1.22   223   1.29   1.2    Fertilizer  exp./ha,  CFA   75   5,370.20   18,919.92   221   4,939.51   6,711.15    Insecticide  exp/ha,  CFA   75   6,518.84   8,203.04   220   3,857.54   6,671.44   ***  Fungicide  exp/ha,  CFA   75   1,918.33   5,261.12   220   958.93   2,900.61    Pesticide  exp./ha,  CFA   74   8,551.68   11,799.58   220   4,816.47   8,638.22   **  Labor  exp./ha,  CFA   74   43,943.46   49,077.78   220   33,371.87   51,060.84    Family  labor  hr/wk/ha   76   23.71   20.73   221   24.67   37.88    

Marketing  Buyers  used     76   1.33   0.60   223   1.07   0.25   ***  Buyers  in  market   74   2.22   1.75   213   1.70   1.55   **  Co-­‐op  members   76   256.74   120.53   223   678.64   45.82   ***  %  cacao  sold  to  co-­‐op   75   92.47   18.98   221   97.81   10.99   **  

 

  100  

%  cacao  sold  as  certified   76   N/A   N/A   219   88.36   20.73  

 

Number  of  certs.     76   N/A   N/A   229   1.56   0.69    

Yrs.  since  1st  cert.   76   N/A   N/A   201   3.01   0.99    Transports  cacao  to  market  (dum,  Y=1)   75   0.25   0.44   221   0.26   0.44  

 

Time  to  transport  cacao  to  market,  min     75   19.88   45.93   215   22.76   49.22  

 

Economic  Outcomes  Yield,  kg/mature  ha   76   444.12   299.69   222   463.01   305.91    Avg.  price,  CFA/kg   76   729.82   22.04   222   760.81   27.4   ***  Gross  rev.,  CFA/ha   76   316,252.6   220,944.2   222   344,046.9   225,598.6    Variable  cash  expenditure  CFA/ha   76   65,946.11   60,191.11   222   47,133.73   60,850.18  

**  

Expenditure  Efficiency  CFA/kg     76       223      

***  

Cash  profit  CFA/ha   76   250,306.4   210,656.2   222   296,913.2   205,386.1   *    p-­‐values  for  certified  versus  controls  in  each  region:  *  p  ≤  0.1        **  p  ≤  0.05        ***  p  ≤    0.01              

   

 

  101  

Table  B2:  Means  For  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls  By  Region,  Agronomic  Inputs  and  Economic  Outcomes      

   Soubré    Divo   Adzopé  

  N   74  certified  25  controls   N   74  certified  

25  controls   N   74  certified  26  controls  

Variable  Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

 

Weeding  frequency  Certified   2.80   2.84   2.90  Controls   2.58   2.60   2.46  Pruning  frequency  Certified   4.15   18.27  ***   20.89  ***  Controls   5.67                                                      2.72                                              7.65  Fertilizer  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   13,100.36   758.62  **   1,069.82  Controls   14,314.89                                            0.00    1,726.65    Insecticide  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   8,164.83   1,714.88  *   1,722.24  ***  Controls   8,405.65                                              4,414.19                              6,841.08  Fungicide  expenditure/  mature  ha,  CFA  Certified   1,846.37     364.30   674.28  *  Controls   1,007.36   1,140.00                                                  3607.62  Pesticide  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   10,011.20   2,079.18  **   2,396.52  **  Controls   9,413.01                                          5,601.69                                10,522.35  Labor  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   25,744.28   45,720.23   28,444.95  Controls   41,723.89   51,060.52   39,063.61  Family  labor  hours/wk/ha  Certified   28.87   16.82   28.15  Controls   30.10   20.50   20.56  Yield,  kg/bearing  ha  Certified   469.61   474.5  **   444.93  Controls   609.38                                                347.09   378.52    Average  price,  CFA/kg  Certified   761.74***   766.97***   753.71***  Controls                              731.15                                  721.72                                          736.34  Gross  revenue,  CFA/ha  Certified   358,170.0   356,698.6  ***   317,272.1  Controls   446,525.1                    250,410.7   254,300.0  

 

  102  

Variable  expenditure,  CFA/ha  Certified   53,900.59   51,252.51   36,248.07**  Controls   68,599.68      60,709.89                                    68,429.42  Profit,  CFA/ha  Certified   304,269.4   305,446.1  ***   281,024.0  ***    Controls   377,925.4                  189,700.8                          185,870.6    p-­‐values  for  certified  versus  controls  in  each  region:  *  p  ≤  0.1        **  p  ≤  0.05        ***  p  ≤    0.01                          

 

  103  

Table  B3:  Differences  in  Means  Between  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls,  2012-­‐13  Season  a  

 Soubré   Divo   Adzopé   Overall  

Variable   N   Difference    and  p-­‐value   N   Difference    

and  p-­‐value   N   Difference    and  p-­‐value   N   Difference  

and  p-­‐value  Farm  and  Farmer  Characteristics;  Farm  Practices  and  Itemized  Expenditures  

Farmer’s  age  24  73                    -­‐0.33  

25  74                      0.11  

26  75              3.29  

75  222          1.07  

Years  of  education  

25  71                        0.94  

24  72      1.68  

25  72    -­‐1.40      *  

74  215          0.40  

Owns  Farm  (dummy  Y=1)  

25  74                        0.06  

25  74      -­‐0.01  

26  75                0.03  

76  223          0.03  

Bearing  cacao  ha  

25  74                      -­‐0.01  

25  74                      0.62  

26  74                0.28  

76  222          0.32  

Total  farm  ha   2474                      -­‐1.16  

2172                      0.69  

25  72                  0.40  

70  218        -­‐0.22  

Cacao  trees/ha   25  72                -­‐36.49  

2371              -­‐38.45  

17  47            71.57  

65  154    -­‐11.00  

Extension  visits   25  74   7.25  ***  

22  74   4.47  ***  

25  71                  9.97  

72  215   6.67  ***  

Training  sessions  

25  74   10.12  ***  

24  74   5.54  ***  

26  74   14.17  ***  

76  222   9.96  ***  

Shade  trees/ha   25  74                      0.68  

24  74                      0.78  

25  72   3.38  ***  

74  220   1.69          *  

Weeding  frequency/yr  

24  74        0.21  

25  74      0.24  

26  75                    0.44  

75  223   0.30      **  

Pruning  Frequency/yr  

21  63      1.51  

25  74   15.55  ***  

23  56   13.24  ***  

69  193   9.16  ***  

Fertilizer  applications  

25  73    0.05  

25  74   0.16  ***  

26  75                  0.18  

76  222            0.01  

Insecticide  applications  

25  74    0.02  

25  74          0.19  

26  75   -­‐0.97  ***  

76  223   -­‐0.27        *  

Fungicide  applications  

25  74    0.24  

25  74                  0.42          *  

25  75                    0.27  

75  223              0.03  

Fertilizer    exp./ha,  CFA  

25  73   -­‐  12,14.53  

24  74   758.62      **  

26  74      -­‐656.83  

75  220      430.70    

Insecticide  exp./ha,  CFA  

25  73   -­‐  240.82  

24  74    -­‐2,699    *  

26  73   -­‐5,052    ***  

75  220  

-­‐2,728      **  

Fungicide  exp./ha,  CFA  

25  73   839.00  

25  74          -­‐775.70  

25  73   -­‐2,933.3      *  

75  220   -­‐1,202.9  

Pesticide  exp./ha,  CFA  

25  73  

598.19   25  74  

-­‐3,522.51                                  **  

25  73  

-­‐8,125.8      **  

74  220  

-­‐3,735.2  **  

Labor  exp.ha,  CFA  

23  72  

-­‐  15,979.6   25  74   -­‐5,340.29  

26  74   -­‐10,618.6  

74  220   -­‐      10,572  

Family  labor  hr/wk/ha  

25  74  

                 -­‐1.24   25  73                  -­‐3.76  

26  74                    7.59  

76  221              0.94  

Marketing  and  Economic  Outcomes    

Buyers  used  25  74   -­‐0.26    **  

25  74        -­‐0.23    **  

26  75            -­‐0.29    **  

76  223   -­‐0.26  ***  

Buyers  in  market  

25  74   -­‐0.54      *  

25  67                    0.17  

24  72                -­‐0.75  

74  213   -­‐0.51    **  

 

  104  

%  output  sold  to  co-­‐op  

25  73                      2.12  

25  74    10.96    **  

25  74                    2.93  

75  221   5.34    **  

Yield,  kg/bearing  ha  

25  74          -­‐139.78  

25  74    127.41    **  

26  74            66.40  

76  222          18.88  

Average  price,  CFA/kg  

25  74   30.58  ***  

25  74   45.26  ***  

26  74   17.37    ***  

76  222   30.98  ***  

Gross  rev.,  CFA/ha  

25  74   -­‐88,355.1  

25  74   106,288  ***  

26  74   62,972.15  

76  222   27,793.4  

Variable  cash  exp.  CFA/ha  

25  74   -­‐14,699.1  

25  74        -­‐9,457.37  

26  74   -­‐  32,181  **  

76  222   -­‐18,812  **  

Expenditure  eff.,  CFa/kg  

25  74                -­‐49.49  

25  74   -­‐67.37    **  

26  75   -­‐114.74  ***  

76  223   -­‐77.5  ***  

Cash  profit  CFA/ha  

25  74        -­‐  73,656  

25  74        276,218  ***  

26  74  

   95,154                                ***  

76  222   46,606      *  

a  In  the  N  column,  controls  are  listed  above  certified  farmers.  The  difference  is  the  certified  mean  minus  the  control  mean.    *  p  ≤  0.1,          **  p  ≤  0.05,          ***  p  ≤    0.01                  

 

  105  

Table  B4:  Means  For  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls  By  Certification  Type    

 

FLO-­‐UTZ    (Soubré)  

FLO-­‐RA  (Divo)  

FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ  (Adzopé)  

  N   25  certified  25  controls   N   25  certified  

25  controls   N   24  certified  26  controls  

Variable  Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Weeding  frequency  Certified   2.84   2.6   3.64  Controls   2.58   2.6   2.46  Pruning  frequency  Certified   6.60   27.12*     27.35  **  Controls   5.67                                                          2.72                                              7.65  Fertilizer  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   6,316.47   779.05   0.00  Controls   14,314.89   0.00   1,726.65  Insecticide  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   7,966.57   216.00  ***   74.71  ***  Controls   8,405.65                      4,414.18                    6,841.08    Fungicide  expenditure/mature  ha,  CFA  Certified   1,954.00   0  *   0.00  *    Controls   1,007.36                                                1,140                                    3,607.62  Pesticide  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   9,920.58   216  ***   74.71  ***  Controls   9,413.01                                              5,601.69              10,522.35  Labor  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   13,398.08  **   48,486.50   2,630.68  ***  Controls                    41,723.89   51,060.52   39,063.61  Family  labor  hours/wk/ha  Certified   27.44   19.35   19.47  Controls   30.10   20.58   20.56  Yield,  kg/bearing  ha  Certified   400.57  **   457.20  *   420.13  Controls                                  609.38                                            347.09   378.52  Average  price,  CFA/kg  Certified   756.44  ***   769.27  ***   737.11  Controls                            731.15                            721.72   736.34  Gross  revenue,  CFA/ha  Certified   303,589.1  **   339,739.7  *   302,720.4  Controls                      446,525.1                                  250,410.7   254,300.0  Variable  expenditure,  CFA/ha  Certified   36,014.24  *     52,070.83   2,988.44  ***  Controls                                  68,599.68   60,709.89                  68,429.42  Profit  CFA/ha  Certified   267,574.9  *   287,668.9  **   299,732.0**  Controls                                  377,925.4                        189,700.8                          185,870.6  

 

  106  

 

  RA  (Soubré  and  Divo)  

RA-­‐UTZ  (Adzopé)  

UTZ  (All  Departments)  

  N   48  certified  50  controls   N   25  certified  

26  controls   N   74  certified  76  controls  

Variable  Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Weeding  frequency  Certified   2.56   2.6   2.93  ***  Controls   2.59   2.46                                    2.55  Pruning  frequency  Certified   13.23   25.42**   6.11  Controls   4.07                                                7.65   5.26  Fertilizer  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   10,236.11   2,100.00   5,023.02  Controls   7,303.52   1,726.65   5,370.20  Insecticide  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   5,437.76   2,752.82  **   4309.15  *  Controls   6,450.65                              6,841.08                                        6586.00  Fungicide  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   1,279.63   1,958.33   741.96  *  Controls   1,073.68                                    3,607.62                                    1,918.33  Pesticide  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   6,717.39   4,711.15   5,051.12  **  Controls   7,546.24              10,522.35                            8,551.68  Labor  expenditure/ha,  CFA  Certified   40,514.47   52,518.57   33,704.19  Controls   46,586.72   39,063.61   43,943.46  Family  labor  hours/wk/ha  Certified   23.21   19.55   29.74  Controls   25.34   20.56   23.71  Yield,  kg/bearing  ha  Certified   500.83   440.52   482.77  Controls   478.24   378.52   444.12  Average  price,  CFA/kg  Certified   765.40  ***   761.24  ***   763.94  ***  Controls                          726.44                              736.34                            729.82  Gross  revenue,  CFA/ha  Certified   381,745.9   317,793.6   356,816.9  Controls   348,467.9       254,300.0   316,252.6  Variable  expenditure,  CFA/ha  Certified   61,741.78   66,478.98   47,523.44  **  Controls   64,654.78   68,429.42                        65,946.11  Profit  CFA/ha  Certified   320,004.1   251,314.6   309,293.4  Controls   283,813.1   185,870.6   250,306.4        

 

  107  

Table  B5:  Significant  Differences  Between  Certified  Farmers  and  Controls  By  Certification  Type,  Economic  Outcomes  and  Agronomic  Inputs      

 

FLO-­‐UTZ  (Soubré)  

FLO-­‐RA  (Divo)  

FLO-­‐RA-­‐UTZ  (Adzopé)  

  N   25  certified  25  controls   N   25  certified    

25  controls   N   24  certified  26  controls  

Variable  Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Yield,  kg/bearing  ha   -­‐  208.81    **   110.11          *                                41.61  Average  price,  CFA/kg   25.28  ***   47.55  ***                                    0.77  Gross  revenue,  CFA/ha   -­‐  142,936    **   89,329.01      *            48,420.46  Variable  exp.  CFA/ha   -­‐  32,585.44      *                      -­‐8,639.05   -­‐65,440.98  ***  Profit  CFA/ha   -­‐  110,350.6      *   97,968.06    **   113,861.40    **  Other  significant  differences  

Higher:    Extension  (**)  Training  (**)                Lower:    Farm  buyers  (*)  

Higher:    Extension  (*)    Training  (***)  Good  ag.  prac.  (***)  Pruning  freq.  (*)  Fertilizer  app.  (*)  Fungicide  app.  (***)  %  sold  to  co-­‐op  (**)        Lower:    Education  (***)  Insecticide  exp.  (***)  Fungicide  exp.  (***)  Farm  buyers  (**),  Transport  dummy  and  minutes  (*)  

Higher:    Years  in  co-­‐op  (**)  Extension  (*)  Training  (***)  Shade  trees/ha  (*)  Pruning  freq.  (**)        Lower:    HH  Inc  (*)  Insect  exp.  (**)    Farm  and  market  buyers  (**)  

 

  RA  (Soubré  and  Divo)  

RA-­‐UTZ  (Adzopé)  

UTZ  (All  Departments)  

  N   48  certified    50  controls   N   25  certified    

26  controls   N   75  certified    76  controls  

Variable  Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Difference    and  p-­‐value  

Yield,  kg/bearing  ha  

Overall    22.59    Divo    102.71      *                                  62.00    

Overall    38.64      Divo  168.41  *  

Average  price,  CFA/kg   38.97  ***   24.90  ***   34.11  ***  Gross  revenue,  CFA/ha  

Overall    33,278  Divo    90,404.62      *                63493.58  

Overall    40,564.31  Divo  138,494.9  **  

Variable  exp.  CFA/ha   -­‐  2,913            -­‐  1,950.44   -­‐  18,422.67    **  

 

  108  

Profit  CFA/ha   Overall    36,191.01  Divo      95,827.46    **            65,444.02  

Overall  58,986.98  Divo  152,643.7    **  

Adzopé  106,903.3    **  Other  significant  differences  

Higher:    Extension  (***)  Training  (***)  %  sold  to  co-­‐op  (***)          Lower:    Farm  buyers  (***)  

Higher:    HH  income  (*)  Years  in  co-­‐op  (**)  Extension  (*)  Training  (**)  Shade  trees/ha  (*)  Pruning  (**)      Lower:    Insecticide  exp.  (**)  Farm  buyers  (**)  Market  buyers  (**)  

Higher:    Extension  (***)  Training  (***)  Weeding  (***)  %  sold  to  co-­‐op  (***)        Lower:    Insecticide  exp.  (*)  Fungicide  exp.  (*)  Pesticide  exp.  (**)  Farm  buyers  (***)  

 

p-­‐values  for  certified  versus  controls  in  each  region:  *  p  ≤  0.1        **  p  ≤  0.05        ***  p  ≤    0.01