european struggles and american resistance: inclusion of aviation … · inclusion of aviation into...

305
EUROPEAN STRUGGLES AND AMERICAN RESISTANCE: INCLUSION OF AVIATION INTO THE EU ETS by Pawel Pustelnik Thesis submitted for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy School of Geography and Planning Cardiff University 2016

Upload: others

Post on 06-Feb-2021

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • EUROPEANSTRUGGLESANDAMERICANRESISTANCE:INCLUSIONOFAVIATIONINTOTHEEUETS

    byPawelPustelnik

    ThesissubmittedfortheDegreeofDoctorofPhilosophy

    SchoolofGeographyandPlanningCardiffUniversity

    2016

  • AbstractThis research examines the process of inclusion of aviation into the European Union

    Emissions Trading System (EU ETS). The thesis investigates an environmentally-

    recalcitrantcommunity(aviationindustry)anditsattemptstosuspendtheapplication

    oftheEUETSonthesector.Itfocusesonthedecision-makingprocessesattheEuropean

    Union (EU) level and juxtaposes the European policy-making with the resistance to

    inclusion shown in the political system of theUnited States (US).More specifically, it

    seeks to understand the factors affecting the effectiveness of efforts to forge effective

    internationalenvironmentalpolicy,especially thosedrivenbytheEU in thecontextof

    climatechange.

    Theoretically, this research draws on three theories: Multi-level governance, Policy

    Network Analysis and Interpretive Policy Analysis. These theories are advanced by

    consideringthemeaning-makingactivitiespursuedbythestakeholdersanddiscursive

    aspectsoftheprocessanalysed.Empiricallythethesis is informedbyaseriesofsemi-

    structuredinterviewsconductedinWashington,DCin2013andinBrussels,Belgiumin

    2014,policydocuments,andmediacontentanalysis.

    Thethesisconcludesthattheclimateambitionsofthe(EU)mayinstigateinternational

    resistance leading todeteriorationof relationswith international partners. The thesis

    provestoothattheconflictintheEUETScaseisrelatedtotheconstructionofinterests

    bothwithintheEUandvisàvisitsinternationalpartners.Theresearchcontributesalso

    to understanding the internal proceedings of the European Commission by showing

    discrepancies in decision-making between theDirectorate Generals. It shows that the

    locusofpolicymakingcanbechangedtowardsmorenon-materialvenues.Finally, the

    results show that aviation enjoys a particularly powerful position among other

    businesses both in the EU and in the US and is able to shape policy-making at the

    nationalandinternationallevel.

  • DECLARATIONThisworkhasnotbeensubmittedinsubstanceforanyotherdegreeorawardatthisoranyotheruniversityorplaceoflearning,norisbeingsubmittedconcurrentlyincandidatureforanydegreeorotheraward.Signed Date31.10.2016STATEMENT1ThisthesisisbeingsubmittedinpartialfulfillmentoftherequirementsforthedegreeofPhD.Signed Date31.10.2016STATEMENT2This thesis is the result ofmy own independentwork/investigation, exceptwhere otherwisestated.Othersourcesareacknowledgedbyexplicitreferences.Theviewsexpressedaremyown.Signed…………………………………… Date31.10.2016STATEMENT3Iherebygiveconsentformythesis, ifaccepted,tobeavailableforphotocopyingandforinter-libraryloan,andforthetitleandsummarytobemadeavailabletooutsideorganisations.Signed………………………………… Date31.10.2016STATEMENT4:PREVIOUSLYAPPROVEDBARONACCESSIherebygiveconsentformythesis, ifaccepted,tobeavailableforphotocopyingandforinter-library loans after expiry of a bar on access previously approved by the AcademicStandards&QualityCommittee.Signed Date31.10.2016

  • Acknowledgements

    Working on this thesis was an intense experience and plenty of people greatly

    contributedtothislearningprocess.

    Firstly, I would like to thank my parents Anna and Grzegorz who have been always

    supportiveandaccepting.TheirsupportwaslaterjoinedbymylittlebrotherWojciech.

    Withouttheirconstantinspirationmylongjourneythatledmetothisthesiswouldnot

    havebeenpossible.

    I am very indebted tomy supervisors: Dr. Richard Cowell, Dr. Oleg Golubchikov and

    Prof. Peter Feindt. Their constant encouragement and extremely valuable comments

    havemadethisthesismuchbetterthanitwouldhavebeenotherwise.Iamalsograteful

    toDr.AndreaCollinswhocontributedasareviewer.Mythanksareowedalsoto

    Prof.MirandaSchreurs,Prof.FrankBiermannandProf.PhlippPattberg.

    Natalia,Mos,Morena,mydear friendsand flatmateswhowerealwaysthere forme in

    Cardiff.Theworkonthisthesishasbeengreatlyhelpedbytheenthusiasmofmythree

    very special goddesses: Ioanna, Diana and Tara. Hade and Richard have helped

    immenselywiththeirmoralandculinarysupport.Finally,Jasmin,GeorginaandHierald

    whomademy research inWashington a great experience, Kri andAgata shown their

    immense help in Brusselswhile Andrzejwas instrumental formywork in Berlin.My

    WSCFandEYCEfriendswereagreatsourceofcommunityspiritandselflesshelp.

    Manythankstomydearfriends,whokeptupwiththelong-distanceandmobileaspects

    ofthisendeavour.Agata,Katka,Kiedro,Mezz,Matuszyouhavebeengreat.

    Last but not least, very special thanks to Piotr for his unlimited care, support and

    understandinginthevariousstagesofthisthesisandofmylife.

  • Listofabbreviations

    A4A AirlinesforAmerica

    ACES AmericanCleanEnergyandSecurityAct

    ACF AdvocacyCoalitionFramework

    ACI AirportsCouncilInternational

    ACI-NA AirportsCouncilInternational–NorthAmerica

    AEA AssociationofEuropeanAirlines

    AEF AviationEnvironmentFederation

    AIA AirspaceIndustriesAssociation

    ALPA AirLinePilotsAssociation

    APA AlliedPilotsAssociation

    ATAA AirTransportAssociationofAmerica

    ATAG AirTransportActionGroup

    CAEE CommitteeonAircraftEngineEmissions

    CAEP CommitteeonAviationEnvironmentalProtection

    CAQDAS computerassistedqualitativedataanalysissoftware

    CBDR commonbutdifferentiatedresponsibilities

    CBDRRC commonbutdifferentiatedresponsibilitiesandrespective

    capabilities

    CDM CleanDevelopmentMechanism

    COP ConferenceoftheParties

    CJEU CourtofJusticeoftheEuropeanUnion

    CO carbonmonoxide

    CO2 carbondioxide

    CRS CongressionalResearchService

    DGCLIMA DirectorateGeneralClimateAction

    DGMOVE DirectorateGeneralMobilityandTransport

    EC EuropeanCommission

    ECAC EuropeanCivilAviationConference

    EDF EnvironmentalDefenseFund

    EEA EuropeanEconomicArea

    EPA EnvironmentalProtectionAgency

  • ET EmissionsTrading

    EU EuropeanUnion

    EUETS EuropeanUnionEmissionsTradingSystem

    FAA FederalAviationAdministration

    FOIA FreedomofInformationAct

    GAMA GeneralAviationManufacturersAssociation

    GHG greenhousegas

    GWP GlobalWarmingPotential

    IATA InternationalAirTransportAssociation

    ICAO InternationalCivilAviationOrganisation

    ICSA InternationalCoalitionforSustainableAviation

    IMO InternationalMaritimeOrganization

    IPA interpretivepolicyanalysis

    IPCC IntergovernmentalPanelonClimateChange

    JI JointImplementation

    MEP MemberoftheEuropeanParliament

    MLG multi-levelgovernance

    NAP NationalAllocationPlan

    NBAA NationalBusinessAviationAssociation

    NOx nitrogenoxides

    NRDC NationalResourcesDefenseCouncil

    PNA policynetworkanalysis

    RECLAIM RegionalCleanAirIncentivesMarket

    RFI RadiativeForcingIndex

    SOx sulphuroxides

    T&A TransportandEnvironment

    TTIP TransatlanticTradeandInvestmentPartnership

    UNFCCC UnitedNationsFrameworkConventiononClimateChange

    WWF WorldWideFundforNature

  • ListofTables

    Table1:Outlineoftheresearchmethodsused……………………………….………………. 84

    Table2:InterviewsconductedinBrussels…………………………………………………….… 95

    Table3:InterviewsconductedinWashington,DC……………………………………….…... 98

    Table4:Typesofcodesemployed…………………………………………………………….…..… 104

    Table5:EUETSProhibitionActTimeline……………………………………...…………….……137

    Table6:BRICspositiontowardstheEUETSinclusionofaviation…………………......189

  • 8

    TableofContents 1 Introduction............................................................................................................................111.1 Researchrationale......................................................................................................................111.2 Researchquestions.....................................................................................................................171.3 Structureofthethesis................................................................................................................21

    2 LiteratureReviewandContextualization.....................................................................242.1 Introduction...................................................................................................................................242.2 Emissionstrading........................................................................................................................242.2.1 Benefitsofflexiblemechanisms.......................................................................................................262.2.2 Challengesfacedbytheemissionstradingconcept................................................................28

    2.3 TheEuropeanUnionEmissionsTradingSystem..............................................................322.4 Aviation,climatechangeandtheEUETS.............................................................................382.4.1 Impactsofaviationonclimatechange..........................................................................................382.4.2 Internationalregulationofaviationemissions.........................................................................402.4.3 AviationintheEUETS..........................................................................................................................452.4.4 Exceptionalisminaviationpolicyandregulation:origins,pathdependencyandretrenchment...........................................................................................................................................................47

    2.5 Conclusions....................................................................................................................................493 Theoreticaldiscussion.........................................................................................................513.1 Introduction...................................................................................................................................513.2 Thefirstpillaroftheinvestigation:policynetworkanalysis.......................................523.3 Therefinementprovidedbyinterpretativepolicyanalysis.........................................573.4 GovernanceandMulti-levelgovernance.............................................................................613.4.1 Multi-levelgovernance.........................................................................................................................643.4.2 Spaceforpower.......................................................................................................................................683.4.3 Geographicalapproachesvs.MLGtheory....................................................................................71

    3.5 Combiningthethreeapproachestothepolicyprocess..................................................723.6 Conclusions....................................................................................................................................76

    4 Methodology............................................................................................................................784.1 Introduction...................................................................................................................................784.2 Logicoftheinquiry......................................................................................................................794.3 Casestudydesign.........................................................................................................................804.4 Desktopanalysis..........................................................................................................................844.5 Interviews–whyinterview?....................................................................................................864.5.1 Semi-structuredinterviews...............................................................................................................894.5.2 Whoaretheexperts?............................................................................................................................904.5.3 Preparationfortheinterviews.........................................................................................................92

    4.6 FieldworkinBrussels.................................................................................................................944.6.1 IdentificationoftheintervieweesattheEuropeanCommissionandaccesstothehighprofileinterviewees....................................................................................................................................964.6.2 AccessingtheEuropeanParliament...............................................................................................964.6.3 AccessingtheenvironmentalNGOs................................................................................................974.6.4 Accessingtheaviationindustry.......................................................................................................974.6.5 Intervieweesrepresentingothersectors.....................................................................................97

    4.7 FieldworkinWashington,DC..................................................................................................984.7.1 IdentificationofthepotentialintervieweesattheCongressionallevel.........................994.7.2 AccessingtheeNGOs..........................................................................................................................1004.7.3 Accessingthesectoralorganisations..........................................................................................101

  • 9

    4.7.4 Accessingtheadministration.........................................................................................................1014.7.5 Othertypesofinterviewees............................................................................................................102

    4.8 Dataanalysis...............................................................................................................................1034.8.1 Remarksontranscription................................................................................................................1034.8.2 Dataanalysis..........................................................................................................................................103

    4.9 ResearchEthics..........................................................................................................................1054.9.1 Informedconsent................................................................................................................................1054.9.2 Confidentialityandanonymity......................................................................................................106

    4.10 Conclusion.................................................................................................................................1065 TheEUgoesintotrenchestostimulateICAO:EU’sleadershipintheclimatepolicy..............................................................................................................................................1075.1 Introduction................................................................................................................................1075.2 TheemergingroleofICAOinCO2emissionsregulation..............................................1085.3 TheICAOandEUintersectionontacklingCO2emissions...........................................1165.3.1 TheroleoftheEUMemberStates................................................................................................1185.3.2 TheEUandICAO:non-environmentalvenues.......................................................................121

    5.4 “WithoutustherewouldbenodevelopmentatICAO!”CantheEUbeseenastheICAO’saccelerator?..............................................................................................................................1235.5 “Perhapsitwasn’tpainintheass…butabititwas”:issuesbetweentheECDirectorateGenerals..........................................................................................................................1285.6 Conclusions.................................................................................................................................132

    6 ThenatureoftheoppositiontotheEUETSforaviationintheUS......................1366.1 Introduction................................................................................................................................1366.2 TheaviationindustryintheUS............................................................................................1376.3 “SendingthemoneytoEuropedidnotseemlikeagoodideatoanybody”–betweenfinancialandsovereigntyissues...................................................................................1406.3.1 LegalcaseagainsttheEUETS........................................................................................................1416.3.2 USformalresistanceagainsttheEUETS..................................................................................1466.3.3 TheEUETSProhibitionBillanditssignificanceasobservedbythepolicyactors1496.3.4 Financialissues:whatmoneyistobesent?.............................................................................1596.3.5 Competitionissues:measuresequivalenttotheEUETS...................................................1626.3.6 Policychangeorcontinuity?...........................................................................................................163

    6.4 Theimportanceofasingleaviationorganisation.........................................................1676.4.1 UScarriersininternationalsectoralorganisations..............................................................1676.4.2 ConsolidationoflobbyingeffortsinWashington..................................................................171

    6.5 Conclusions.................................................................................................................................1747 Thevoicesoftheunwilling:theoppositiontotheEUETSonaglobalscale...1777.1 Introduction................................................................................................................................1777.2 Coalitionoftheunwilling.......................................................................................................1787.2.1 Coalitionmeetings:fromNewDelhitoWashingtonviaMoscow..................................180

    7.3 “Idon’tthinkthattheUSisthemostproblematicinthesenegotiations,itismainlyIndia,Russia,China”BRIC’soppositionandtheCBDRarguments.......................1887.3.1 India...........................................................................................................................................................1947.3.2 China.........................................................................................................................................................1987.3.3 Russia:“TheRussiansareachallenge”......................................................................................206

    7.4 Conclusions.................................................................................................................................2108 Discussion..............................................................................................................................2158.1 Introduction................................................................................................................................2158.2 Governanceissues:policyparadiseversuspolicystagnation?.................................2168.3 Globalraceforleadership......................................................................................................2208.4 Avenueoranon-venue?........................................................................................................225

  • 10

    8.5 Attemptstoregulateaviation:exceptionallyexceptional..........................................2298.5.1 Accesstoflying.....................................................................................................................................2308.5.2 TheEUmobilities................................................................................................................................2318.5.3 Whoreallyrulesaviation?...............................................................................................................233

    8.6 Concludingremark...................................................................................................................2349 Conclusions............................................................................................................................2369.1 Introduction................................................................................................................................2369.2 Policychange:effects,actorsandvenues.........................................................................2379.3 TheEUandthirdcountries....................................................................................................2419.4 Limitationsandfurtherstudy..............................................................................................245

    10 References...........................................................................................................................25011 Appendices..........................................................................................................................30211.1 AppendixA:MasterInterviewSchedule–EU...............................................................30211.2 AppendixB:MasterInterviewSchedule–US...............................................................304

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    11

    1 Introduction In theWestern world, flying became a part of modern lifestyles and with the

    advent of low-fare airlines it is no longer considered a luxury.While usingplanes for

    leisure,businessorevendailycommute,travellersarenotalwaysawareoftheirclimate

    impacts.LittledidtheyalsoknowthattheEuropeanUnion(EU)’sattemptstoinstigate

    internationalactiontotackleaviationemissionscouldhavegroundedEUcivilaviation

    in2012.TheEyjafjallajökulleruptionin2010gaveanideaofwhatEuropewithempty

    skiesmeans,andapotentialparalysisin2012couldhavebeenevenmorepainfulboth

    forpassengersandEUeconomies.

    This thesis focuses however on the process that led to this potential crisis. It

    advancesknowledgeof thegenesisandeffectsofambitiouspoliticalactionaspiringto

    tackle carbon dioxide emissions from civil aircraft. It unpacks the complexity of

    contemporarygovernance.Furthermore, itoffersauniqueaccountofmanyvoicesand

    evenmoreinterestsunderlyingcurrentregulationsaimingatreducinggreenhousegas

    (GHG)emissionsglobally.

    Theintervieweesthattookpartinthisstudyalwaysstartedtellingtheirversion

    of the EU’s attempts to regulate aviation emissions with worried faces. This thesis

    unpacks the reasons for these concerns, with the objective to provide a balanced

    account of the events, but also challenge someof the theoretical premises of theway

    scholarslookatgovernanceofclimatechange.

    This firstchapterof thethesisaimsatshowingtherationale forconductingthe

    studypresentedhereandproposestheparticularapproachtaken.Italsointroducesthe

    caseanalysedandliststheresearchquestionstogetherwithresearchobjectives.Finally,

    it explains the structure of the thesis by offering short summaries of the following

    chapters.

    1.1 Researchrationale The rationale for this research is based on its relevance for contemporary

    research themes around the contestation of policies and the pace of climate change.

    Thesecanbedividedintothreethemesthatarefurtherdevelopedbelow:international

    aspects of policy-making in the area of environment, EU’s policy endeavours and

    sectoralexceptionalisminregulation.

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    12

    Social science research on the European Union (EU), has flourished in recent

    yearsandthestudyoftheEUhasbecomeamainstreamendeavouramongeconomists,

    sociologists,planners,politicalscientists,geographersandothers.Theenvironment,and

    moreparticularlyclimate,joinedEUpolicy-makingagendasonlyinthe1970s,afterthe

    1972Paris Summit.Througha subsequentadoptionof the firstEnvironmentalAction

    Programme,thetopichasquicklybecomeoneofthemostdynamicareasofresearchon

    the EU. This trend has been to a large extent motivated by the environmental and

    climate policies requiring essential cooperation between the EU Member States and

    variouslevelsofgovernance.

    Another importantaspect is that theenvironmentalandclimatepoliciescanbe

    highlycontestedbythepolicyprocessparticipantsastheypertaintodifferinginterestat

    national, regional and local levels as well as differing concerns between the industry

    sectors, consumers and environmental organisations. What is more, the regulatory

    issues regarding climate change go beyond EU borders. For example, some of the

    regulations and standardsdirectly affect foreign companiesdoingbusiness inEurope.

    Lastly,thealarmingpaceofanthropogenicclimatechangemakesresearchonthe

    environmentandclimatevital,notonlywithrespecttoitscausesandimplicationsbut

    alsowithregardstothepoliticaltoolsthatcanbeimplementedinordertochallengethe

    continuedgrowthofglobalGHGemissionslevels.Finally,thisthesisisaresultofalong-

    standinginterestofitsauthorinaviationissuesandacademicfascinationinthemarket-

    basedmeasuresaddressingclimatechange.

    BylookingattheEU’sclimatepolicyinitiativesonecanexaminevariouspolitical

    phenomena that condition the functioning of the international climate arena.One can

    identifyinsightsregardingthenatureofvenueswherepolicymakingiseffectivelytaking

    place and also ask why certain decisions are being made and other initiatives

    abandoned.While the literature gives prominence to investigating the importance of

    various parts of theEU institutional architecture and theMember States, the broader

    pictureof theEUconfrontingglobal sectoralorganisationsandnon-EUstates ismuch

    lessthoroughlyanalysed,whichcreatesanimportantresearchgap.Secondly,onlyviaa

    critical assessment of the actual implementation of the ideas can one systematically

    considertheEuropeanpositionintheclimatedebateglobally.

    One of the recent and highly debated ideas of the EU has been the European

    Union Emission Trading System (EU ETS), an initiative created to address climate

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    13

    change through putting a cap on emissions of GHG from specified installations in

    selectedindustriesandallowingcarbontradingbetweentheparticipatingentities.The

    EU ETS is considered the main pillar of the EU’s fight against climate change and a

    flagship climate initiative of the EU (European Commission 2015a; European

    Commission 2015c; Skjaerseth &Wettestad 2008; Ellerman et al. 2014). This strong

    affirmationforflexiblemechanisms,suchasemissionstrading,providedbytheEUitself

    directs the researchers toanalyse the schemenotonlywith regards to its functioning

    but also pushing the enquiry towards the political intricacies of the largest carbon

    trading mechanism in the world. As will be shown in the next chapter, a variety of

    research projects have examined the EU ETS from economic and legal perspectives,

    however approaching the topic from a governance perspective has to date received

    limited attention. The case offers to address the following puzzle –what explains the

    EU’scapacitytosuccessfullyimplementitsallegedlymodelpolicy?

    Analysing the political construction of the scheme through its institutional and

    organisational architecture provides an opportunity to examine governance as a

    theoretical framework. Climatepolicieshave alsobeen identified as fertile ground for

    theory-testing, especially in themulti-level governance realm (Schreurs & Tiberghien

    2007; Zelli et al. 2010; Blok 2013). This means that for example, the capacities of

    individual actors present in the policy process can be assessed and the relations

    betweenthemexploredbyprovidinginthisthesisadequatespacefornon-stateactors,

    whichhavebeenpreviouslyignoredintheliterature.Furthermore,theexaminationcan

    consider the exercise of authority that takes place outside of the usual jurisdictions

    (Rosenau2000,p.172).TheEUETShasalsobeenafruitfularenaforlobbyistsandthe

    levelof interactionbetweenthestakeholdershasbeenextremelyhighinthis file.This

    allowsfurtherexaminationofthegovernanceframeworksthatgivesprominentspaceto

    industry–policy-makers’interactioninrelationtoclimatepolicy.

    These three research rationales are pursued through a case study of a specific

    period and sectoral context for policy implementation: the inclusion of aviation

    operations into theEUETS.Althoughregulationofaviationemissionshasbeenat the

    discretionoftheInternationalCivilAviationOrganization(ICAO),theEU-respondingto

    what itsawasICAO’s idleness-decidedtoaddthissector intotheEUETSinorderto

    curbrapidlygrowingaviationemissionsrelated to increaseddemand for flying.Given

    the hitherto special position of aviationwithin international governance regimes, this

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    14

    appears a substantial policy change1 of multilateral dimension as all civil flights

    departingfromandlandingatEuropeanairportsweretobeincludedinthescheme,no

    matter what the country of an aircraft’s registration. Indeed, the EU’s decision on

    inclusioncanbeseenasanattempttolimittheexceptionaltreatmentofthesector.The

    caseoffersacompellingexampletoanalysetheprocessofchangeinpublicpolicyatthe

    international level and the resistance to it given the sector in question and spatio-

    politicaldimensionsoftheissue.Itaddressesthenthepuzzleofextraordinarypowerof

    theaviationsectorthatdisabledtheimplementationoftheEUETSandtheremarkable

    situation in which the EU has been confronted with multi-directional international

    resistanceblockingitspolicy.

    The EU’s decision to include aviation activities into the EU ETS led to various

    political controversies, which unexpectedly for the EU, involved a large number of

    countries including theUS, Russia, China, India andBrazil aswell as other important

    politicalandbusinesspartnersoftheEU.ThecountriesopposingtheEUETSanswered

    totheinclusionwiththreatssuchasinvolvingtheWorldTradeOrganisation,grounding

    EU aircraft abroad and imposing additional levies on EU airlines. In this way, the

    oppositionmanagedtoblocktheEU’sleadership.Legalbillsenablingtheprohibitionof

    participationintheEUETSasapprovedbythedecision-makersoftheUS,ChinaorIndia

    gavelittleroomfortheEUtomanoeuvre.Thesituationhasbeenfurtheraggravatedby

    someEUMemberStates trying toprotect theirnationalaviation-relatedactivitiesand

    theEuropeanCommission’sinternalissuessurroundingleadershipoftheETSfile.Inthe

    background of the high politics, environmental non-governmental organisations

    (eNGOs)triedtosupporttheEU,butoftentheirlobbyingcapacitiesweresurpassedby

    theaviation’sbusinessflairforputtingpressureondecision-makers.

    The context outlined above allows this thesis to explain various aspects of

    international regulation. The thesis thus looks beyond the European regulations

    concerning aviation CO2 emissions and provides an insight into the reactions coming

    from the non-EU countries and negotiating over the shape of the international rules

    1The EU policy-makers started to think about abolishing kerosene exemption from taxing back in the1990s.AccordingtotheDirective92/81/EECMemberStateswereabletolimittheexemptionsforjetfuel.In 1996 the European Commission endorsed abolition of the exemption as soon as the internationalsituation is formed in a way that non-EU countries could be included in the project (EC Cons Doc11452/96, 19November1996). In 2003, according toArticle14(2) of 2003/96/ECMember States areallowed to limit the exemption “to international and intra-Community transport” or where the states“enteredintoabilateralagreementwithanotherMemberState.”

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    15

    concerningaviationemissions.Inthisway,thisthesisaddressesthegapintheliterature

    pertainingtosovereigntyofstates,states’authorityandregulatoryjurisdictionbutalso

    engageswith literaturespertaining to leader – laggarddynamics in the climate realm

    (Andresen & Agrawala 2002; Knill et al. 2012). It also contributes to bridging the

    research gap between scholarship focusing on climate leadership within the EU and

    researchonclimateleadershipglobally.

    Giventhatthemostvocalandorganisedresponsetotheinclusionofaviationinto

    theEUETShascomefromtheUnitedStates,thiscountryreceivescarefulconsideration

    inthisthesis.FromtheUS,“TheEuropeanEmissionsTradingSchemeProhibitionActof

    2011”(USHouseofRepresentatives2012b)marksadramaticdisagreementwiththeEU

    policyandcreatesan internationalprecedent.Byexamining theUS’s responses to the

    inclusion of aviation into the EU ETS, the thesis is able to look into transatlantic

    relations,theirdynamicsandtheEU’sabilitytoinfluenceacountrythathasbeenvisibly

    reluctanttoadoptbindingglobalclimateagreements(Schreursetal.2009b).

    AfurtherfacetofthedebatethatisanalysedhereconcernstheEU’sinclusionof

    aviation into the EU ETS as a unilateral step that happened without obtaining third

    countries’consent.Thislackofconsentresultedinsignificantresistancemostlyfromthe

    USwithsupportfromChina,Russia,Indiaandothers.Opponentsemphasisedproblems

    such as protection of their sovereignty, breaking of international law, the creation of

    substantial costs for third country customers, and trade distortions. All these were

    represented as severe threats for aviation operations at EU airports as well as for

    operations of EU-based airlines globally. The case allows the analysis of multiple

    understandings of climate policies by non-EU countries to be brought to bear on

    understandingoftheconstructionofEUclimatepolicy.

    Furthermore, given the EU’s failure to implement the EU ETS in its ambitious,

    broadscope, it iscrucial toanalysethe fateofattemptsto includeaviation intheETS,

    giventhattheEUisoftenregardedasa“leader”,settingthepaceforenvironmentaland

    climate policies worldwide (Vogler & Stephan 2007; Oberthür & Roche Kelly 2008;

    Mehling et al. 2013; Oberthür 2009; Rayner & Jordan 2013; Schreurs & Tiberghien

    2007).

    Another important theme that this thesis addresses pertains to circumstances

    underwhich aviation happens to operate. The aviation industry offers an interesting

    caseofasectorwhosemainfeaturesarehighlevelsofmobilityand,partlyasacorollary,

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    16

    exceptional treatment with regards to taxation. Aviation’s regulatory framework

    encompassesconflictingmandatesamongnational,internationalandglobalinstitutions

    regulating the sector (Staniland 2012). Furthermore, the sector is seen as having

    enjoyed privileges from the very start of civil aviation regulation (Havel & Sanchez,

    2012, p. 355). The exceptional treatment within systems of fiscal regulation is

    exemplifiedbythefollowing:internationalflightsareVATexempted;thereisnocharge

    duty on fuel according to Article 24 of the Chicago Convention and Air Service

    Agreementsallowingforfurtherbilateraltaxexemptionsonaviation-relatedgoodsand

    parts. Its regulation is harmonized through international treaties. The sector also

    features strong lobbying capacities and is regarded as powerful (Woll 2004). Also,

    regulation of international aviation happensmostly at the level of International Civil

    Aviation Organization, which has been formally positioned by UN institutions as an

    exclusivevenuetodealwithaviationregulation.

    A further remarkable feature of the inclusion is that in the European context,

    policy-makersdidnot expect to face thatmuch resistance.TheEuropeanCommission

    officials would often be taken aback by the reactions of the third countries to the

    scheme. Consequently, examining the internal workings of the Commission as

    showcased in the thesis contribute to a better understanding of the dynamics on the

    Europeanside.

    Tosummarise,thefocusofthisthesisisdrivenbyanumberofimportantaspects

    of internationalandclimatepolicy.Firstly, it examines theproblemof lackof sectoral

    actionforemissionsreductionsinaviationandastrongresistanceofthesectortocave

    inandcomplyunderthepressureofambitiousEUtargets.Secondly,thethesisseeksto

    extendourunderstandingoftheEU’sabilitytoshapeinternationalregulations.Thirdly,

    it considers the political dimensions of the problem such as legitimacy, authority and

    power in a fluid context of multi-stakeholder and multi-venue interactions based on

    national interests,particularbenefits for industriesononesideandthecommongood

    ontheotherside.

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    17

    1.2 Researchquestions

    The circumstances presented above pose a case for investigating complex

    governanceandcontrolissuesattheinternationallevelandprovidethejustificationfor

    thefollowingresearchquestions,asbelow:

    1. WhatweretheeffectsoftheEU’sattempttoincludeaviationintheETS?

    2. Whoarethemostprominentactorsofthedebateoninclusion?

    3. Whywereparticularvenuesofpolicyprocessesregardingaviationemissions

    preferred?

    4. Why do EU and non-EU countries differ on the shape of a global aviation

    emissionspolicy?

    5. HowarethepolicydifferencesbetweentheUSandtheEUbeingresolvedatthe

    internationallevel?

    More specifically, the first research question aims to understand the EU’s

    potentialtoinfluenceinternationalclimatedecision-making(Kilian&Elgström2010;L.

    G. van Schaik 2013), and is addressed by reconstructing the full picture of the issues

    surroundingtheinclusionofaviationintotheschemebothintheEUandinternationally.

    Thus, while focusing on opposition it invites further queries. Which key discourses,

    interests,andactorshavebroughttheEUtothisdecision?Whyweretheserationales

    met antagonistically by the EU’s key international partners? What have been the

    politicalrationalesandconsequencesof theEU’sattemptto includeaviation intheEU

    ETS?

    Thesecondquestionexaminestheclaimsregardingaviation’sprivilegedposition

    (Kopsch 2012; Havel & Sanchez 2011a; Havel & Sanchez 2012) and contributes to

    assessing the feasibility of a global agreement for aviation emissions trading systems

    (Susskind&Ali2014).Furthermore, itaddressesa frequentlyaskedquestion:what is

    thenatureofrelationshipsbetweenthestateandnon-stateorganisations?(Keohane&

    Nye1971;Keohane1984;Biermannetal. 2010; Chanetal. 2015;Newelletal. 2012;

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    18

    Arts et al. 2001; Willets 2001; Bieler et al. 2004). It also uncovers the relationships

    between the actors included in the debate, and investigates in depth the following

    issues: the role of sectoral organisations such as International Civil Aviation

    Organisation(ICAO)inthefacilitationofaircraftemissions’governance,theregulatory

    capacities of such organisations and the interplay between the sectoral organisations

    andtheEUinitiativestargetingemissions.Thethirdquestiongivesspecialattentionto

    the decision-making process per se. By unpacking it, the thesis answers why some

    decision-makingvenuesaremoreimportantthanothers,whylessformalvenuesgained

    importance and what the nature of the venues is (material versus non-material). It

    advancesthevenueshoppingtheory(Baumgartner2007;Trueetal.1999;Pralle2003)

    asitnotonlyaskswhicharetheimportantvenuesbutinquiresfurtherwhyandunder

    whatcircumstances their importance increases.At thesametime itexpands thescant

    researchonintra-EuropeanCommissionproceedings(Delreux&VandenBrande2013;

    Kassim 2013). By tracing venues and actors the thesis is able to contribute towider

    debates: the effects of unilateral action on international bodies, the ability of a non-

    specializedactortoinfluenceahighlytechnicalsector,andtheleverageofoneactorto

    regulatethetransnationalconductandbehavioursofotherstates.

    Questions 4 and 5 tackle a broader, international area of investigation. They

    pertain toassessing the feasibilityofEU leadership(s)withregards toclimatepolicies

    (Schreurs&Tiberghien2007; Zito2005; Skodvin&Andresen2006;Gupta&Vander

    Grijp2000;Christiansen&Wettestad2003)andfurthercontributetounderstandingthe

    role and construction of the interests the involved parties have had. Furthermore, by

    buildingoncomparisonsbetweenpolicynetworks(Marsh&Rhodes1992)itconfirms

    that theEUand theUShavedivergent approaches to their respective climatepolicies

    (Skjærsethetal.2013;Schreurs&Tiberghien2007;Schreursetal.2009a).WhiletheUS

    andtheEUhavedecidedtodealdifferentlywith issuessuchascommitmentstowards

    KyotoProtocoltargets,renewableenergiesoremissionstrading,thisthesisshowsthat

    the transatlanticdivisionmaybedeeper thangenerallyassessedand theEUETScase

    poignantlydocumentsthat.

    The questions pertaining to the interactions between the EU and non-EU

    countries resonate strongly with debates on the EU’s environmental and climate

    leadership (Gupta & Van der Grijp 2000; Oberthür & Rabitz 2013). Investigating

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    19

    leadership facilitates interpreting theEU’s position internationally and the level of its

    regulatoryambitions.ItalsocontributestounderstandingthebaseoftheEU’spolitical

    power, and a series of subsidiary questions. Is it based on coercion and threats to

    achieveitsresults?IstheEU’sleadershipbasedonavoluntaryfollowership(Lindenthal

    2009)? Or is the EU leadership structural and simply utilizing its power resources

    (Young1991)?The inclusionof aviation into theEUETSoffers a casewhere a policy

    envisaged as a domestic (intra-EU) tool, started to be perceived, by some non-EU

    countries, as of an external, international character infringing their sovereignty. This

    thesiscontributesthustocomprehendingtheEU’spositionforfutureinvolvementswith

    climatechangepoliciesatagloballevelbutalsotheEU’sexternalpolicyingeneral.

    Pulling these threads together, the overall aim of the thesis is to assist in

    understanding how aviation came to be includedwithin the EU ETS andwhatwere its

    consequences. It looks at the change that the EU aspired to achieve with regard to

    aviation emissions regulation. The “change” here is understood broadly following

    Convery’sthinking:

    “change is a product of many forces, including: an enabling legislative andinstitutionalcontext;aninternationalcontextandsenseofcrisisthatstimulatesandsupportsaction;anintellectualframeworkandexperiencethatprovidestheanimating idea and evidence to support action; effective political andbureaucraticleadership”(2009,p.392).

    Drawing on interviews with policy-makers, industry representatives, policy

    expertsandnon-governmentalorganisationsinWashingtonDC(US)andBrussels(EU)

    aswellasdocumentandmediacontentanalysis thethesisaspires to lookat the issue

    fromaperspectiveofdifferentnationalstances.

    Therangeofissuesthataretackledinthisthesisenableittospeaktoanumber

    ofcurrentscholarlydebates.Firstly, itaddressestheproblemofclimatepolicy-making

    both in Europe and the reactions to it in third countries whose industries may be

    affected by EU regulations. It contributes also to understanding of inter- and

    transnationalpolicy-makingwhilelookingattheroleofstateversusindustry,venuesof

    policy-makingandpolitical support formarket-basedmechanisms.Whileemployinga

    multi-level governance framework, the research also serves to uncover transnational

    policy networks, the strategies they use to influence decision-making and their

    dynamics.

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    20

    Ontheotherhand,thisthesisalsofocusesontheone-sidedleadershipoftheEU

    thatcallsforaglobalanswerfortheissueofemissions.Theleadershipbrokeredbythe

    EUisbasedonexportingitsrules,attemptingtobypassmultilateralnegotiationsandin

    thiswayincentivisenon-EUcountries’action.Thisinturnmarksanewdynamicinthe

    multi-levelgovernancecontextshowinghowmodificationofbehaviourofotherstates

    can be induced by extension of authority (Buenger 2013). The mobile nature of the

    activities intheaviationindustrypresentsacaseforexploringthespatialextensionof

    powerbeyondgovernmentalboundaries.

    This thesis supplements the existing knowledge on the EU climate policy and

    provides novel insights into the process of creating, negotiating and implementing

    policies that reach (at least according to theunderstandingof some)beyond theEU’s

    borders.Ittalksthereforetoliteraturesconcerningpolicyprocessesattheinternational

    level and dealing with a collective action problem as well as pertaining to certain

    authors’ concerns about the extension of the EU’s regulatory power (Lavenex 2014;

    Damro2012).

    By employing empirical data and a multi-angled theoretical perspective, this

    thesisrespondstotheproposedquestionswhilegivingspecialattentiontothevarietyof

    actors present in the policy process, their interests and their interactions with each

    other.Additionally,theproposedframingofthequestionsguaranteesreachingbeyond

    the mere analysis of the process within the EU structures, but allows additional

    importantactorstobeinvolved.Thisisduetotheglobalcharacterofclimatechangeand

    theregulatoryarchitectureof internationalaviation,whichisbasedonICAO’sprimary

    roleandconsensualdecision-making.Thisresearchconsidersthusstates,industry,non-

    governmental and trans-governmental organisations as well as less formal venues of

    decision-making. Furthermore, this framing takes into account the theoretical

    underpinningsemployedandprovidesspace foranalysisof thenon-stateactors’roles

    and their importance for shaping international emissions policies. In this way, it

    contributestoexamininginterdependenceanddecentralization(Bevir&Rhodes2003).

    In a similar manner, it explores interactions between markets and political actors

    (Pierre2000).Thisisdonebyofferinganin-depthanalysisofthecaseandbydrawing

    onliteraturesconcerningstakeholders’participation(Newell2000).Thisthesisinstead

    ofanalysingthevariousactorsofthepoliticalsceneseparatelyadvancesthedebateby

    examining all the stakeholders’ networks at the same time. Furthermore, special

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    21

    attention is given to venues of decision-making and by this governance theories are

    better sited in a tangible, institutional context (EU institutions, ICAO, national

    governments, sectoral organisations, non-governmental organisations). Finally,

    theoreticaladvancement isofferedbyan innovativeapproachtoglobalenvironmental

    governance,which issupplementedby interpretivepolicyanalysisandpolicynetwork

    analysis.

    1.3 Structureofthethesis Taking into account all the premises mentioned above and responding to the

    argumentsoutlined,thethesissetsoutfirstlytoexaminetheliteraturesconcerningthe

    EUETSandthepolicy-makingintheEuropeanUnion.Thesecondchapteristhustasked

    with introducing concepts relevant to emissions trading and also provides an

    introductiontotheregulatorycontextof internationalaviation,which is important for

    the contextualization of inclusion. The latter part of the chapter outlines the main

    assumptionsbehindtheinclusion,basedontheEUregulations.Asawhole,thechapter

    indicatesthemainshortcomingsoftheavailablestudiesandsuppliesacontextforthe

    analysedissues.

    Inchapter3themaintheoreticaldiscussionispresented.Thekeycontributionof

    thechapterisbasedonproposinganewwayofinvestigatinggovernance:byinvolving

    interpretivepolicyanalysis(IPA)andpolicynetworkanalysis(PNA).Firstly,drawingon

    the scholarship ofMarsh andRhodes (Rhodes 2006;Rhodes&Marsh 1991;Marsh&

    Rhodes1992),abriefaccountofdevelopmentofbothtypesofanalysisispresented.The

    rationaleofthisnewapproachisbasedoninterestinthewidercontextofgovernancein

    action.ThisisfollowedbytheexplanationofblendingIPAandPNA.Itisexplainedhow

    multi-level governance succeeds in grasping a macro perspective while network

    analysisprovidesarobustframeworkforinvestigatingstakeholders’relationsandtheir

    institutionalised contexts. Additionally, the chapter draws from Yanow (2000) and

    Wagenaar (2011) to explain the importance of interpretive policy analysis for

    supplementingmulti-levelgovernancewithexaminationofbeliefsandmeaningmaking

    practices, which are crucial if an effective answer to the research questions is to be

    provided. Lastly, this part gives consideration to the issue of power in the conducted

    researchandanswersthequestionofhowpowerissituatedinthegovernancecontext.

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    22

    Inchapter4themethodology isexplainedand justified.Thischapter is focused

    onthetwowavesoffieldworkconductedinBrusselsandWashington,DCthatinformed

    theresearch.Itclarifieshowacasestudydesignhasbeenemployedtoprovideamulti-

    angle perspective and also to be able to answer the “how” and “why” questions. The

    chapterexplainstheinterviewingprocess,fromdraftingtheinterviewschedulethrough

    toapproachingpotentialinterviewees,conductingtheinterviews,transcribingthemand

    finallyanalysingtheinterviewdata.Italsoexplainshowotherdata(policydocuments,

    media content and grey literature) contributed to increasing the quality of the study.

    Equallyimportantly,itbrieflydiscussesethicalissuespertainingtotheresearch.

    Chapter5,thefirstanalyticalchapteroffersanswerstoresearchquestions1and

    2. It provides an historical account of ICAO’s involvement with environment-related

    regulationandexplainshowtheEUcametoadecisiontoleadglobaleffortsbydenting

    ICAO’s primacy in aviation regulation. Not only does it draw from documents and

    policies, but alsoemploys first-handaccounts and judgements from intervieweeswho

    either worked at ICAO or have been close to the ICAO decision-making processes.

    Additionally,thechapteraddressesanimportantgapidentifiedbytheinterviewees:the

    disagreements between different parts of the European Commission with regards to

    howtheinclusionofaviationshouldproceed.

    Chapter6focusesonUSperceptionsoftheinclusionofaviationintotheEUETS

    and theUS’sactionsagainst theEUETS, andhencedrawsmostlyondatagathered in

    Washington DC. It continues answering research question 2 and starts answering

    research questions 3 and 4. It also responds to question 5. The chapter provides a

    unique blend of accounts provided by policy-makers, representatives of sectoral

    organisations and non-governmental organisations as well as policy think-tank

    representatives.ItisarguedthattheEUETShasbeentoalargeextentinterpretedasa

    politicalratherthanalegaloreconomicissuefortheUSandsectoralorganisationswere

    abletoemploysovereigntyargumentstounderminetheEU’splantoextenditsscheme.

    It is also shown how venue shopping has played a role in amplifying counter-ETS

    arguments.ThisthemeiscloselyrelatedtotheEUandUShavingdifferentapproachesto

    ICAO’spositionconcerningaviationregulation.

    Chapter 7 positions the debate on the EU ETS in the context of global

    environmental governance while focusing on opposition to the scheme coming from

    non-EU countries. It thus concludes the response to questions 2 and 4. The chapter

  • Chapter1:Introduction

    23

    further unpacks the dynamics of a global policy of aviation emissions and provides

    accountsofnon-materialvenuesforinternationalpolicy-making.Whiletheattentionof

    this chapter is directed towards states’ actions, it does not neglect the sectoral

    organisationsandinfluencesofindividualcompanies.Byofferinganin-depthanalysisof

    aircraftmanufacturer involvementwith the case it contributes tounderstandingwhat

    typesofleveragecanbeeffectivelyusedtopromotecertainpolicysolutions.

    Inchaptereighttheoreticalaspectsofthisresearchareexaminedbybuildingon

    theempiricalmaterialpresentedinthewholethesis.Itdrawstogetherdiscussionsthat

    werestartedinchapters5,6and7andspeakstodebatesonEU’sinternationalposition.

    It discuses also the mechanisms enabling effective stakeholder participation and

    considershowmulti-levelgovernanceisabletocontributetounderstandingachangein

    policy that isregardedascontroversial. In its finalpartchaptereightoffersadditional

    reflectionsonaviation’sspecialregulatorypositioninthecontextofEUmobilitiesand

    globalregulatoryapproachesforaviation’sregulation.

    Finally, chapter nine reflects on the results that the study brings. By providing

    conciseanswerstotheresearchquestionsaskedatthebeginningofthisthesis,thispart

    summarizesthemostimportantfindingsandonceagainconnectsthemtotheon-going

    scholarlydebates.Thethesissuggestsalargerfocusonpolicylearningprocessthatthe

    EUshouldconsider.SecondlyitproposesamoreintenseinvolvementoftheEuropean

    External Action Service in issues pertaining to international climate regulation. The

    chapterconcludeswithsuggestionsofresearchthatcanbebuiltonthefoundationslaid

    inthisthesis.

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    24

    2 LiteratureReviewandContextualization2.1 Introduction

    Thepreviouschapterhasoutlinedthemainissuesthisthesisisaspiringtotackle

    andtheRQsitseekstoanswer.Thischapteroffersmoredetailedcontextualinformation

    regarding the problemspresented in Chapter 1. It introduces existing knowledge and

    pointsatthegapsthatarefilledinthefollowingchapters.Italsoaimsatevaluatingthe

    existing scholarship in the field of EU studies, governance andmorebroadly, political

    science.

    Thechapterisdividedintofoursections.Firstly,emissionstradingisanalysedas

    aconceptformitigatingclimatechange.InthispartattentionisalsogiventotheKyoto

    Protocolthatintroducedtheflexiblemechanismsonaglobalscale.Thesecondsection

    focusesontheEUETS.Itisconsideredwithregardstoitsinitiation,implementationand

    issuesthatitfacedinthefirstyearsofoperation.

    The third section examines aviation from two distinct perspectives: as a GHG

    producing sector and as an internationally regulated areawhosepolicypatternshave

    developedovertheyears.Theexistingresearchonenvironmentalimpactsofaviationis

    presentedtoelucidatetherationaleforengagingmarketbasedsolutionstotheproblem.

    Finally, the fourthsectionoffersacloserexaminationof theaviationregulation

    over the period between the production of the Chicago Convention in 1945 and the

    introductionoftheEUETSforaviation.Thisallowsidentificationofthedeterminantsof

    policy-makingintheareaandcircumstancesunderwhichthesectorisoperating.These

    considerationsdirecttheargumenttowardstheissueof“exceptionalism”(see:Section

    2.6) that is enjoyed by the sector and its consequences for global environmental

    regulationsofaviation.Finally,theissueofpolicychangeisconsidered.

    2.2 Emissionstrading TheproblemofGHGemissionshasbeenpresentinternationallyasearlyasatthe

    UnitedNationsWorldSummitinRiodeJaneiroin1992.ItwashoweveronlytheKyoto

    Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC)

    thatproposedbindingemissions targets.Theseweresupposed tobe reached through

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    25

    various initiatives 2 aiming at reducing the volumes of emissions released to the

    atmosphere,butitalsoofferedsocalledflexibleormarket-basedmechanisms3:

    “AnyPartyincludedinAnnexImaytransferto,oracquirefrom,anyothersuchParty emission reduction units resulting from projects aimed at reducinganthropogenic emissions by sources or enhancing anthropogenic removals bysinks of greenhouse gases in any sector of the economy” (Kyoto Protocol Art.6.1).

    TheKyotoProtocolassumedthatthisideacouldbeimplementedthroughthree

    policy instruments: Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), Joint Implementation (JI)

    andEmissionsTrading (ET).TheProtocolhas alsooutlined that these shouldbeonly

    supplemental to domestic actions (Art 6.1d), and shouldnot form the onlymitigation

    effortofthepartiestotheConvention.AccordingtoGrubb,VrolijkandBrack(1999)the

    ideaof emissions tradingwasan issue that almostkilled,but saved theProtocol. It is

    hardtodisagreewiththem,as the flexiblemechanismswereat thecentreofaheated

    debate in Kyoto and without them, the Protocol would have been much weaker.

    Simultaneously, they caused a heated debate and led to disagreements between the

    PartiestotheProtocol.

    ThediscussiononmarketbasedmechanismsanimatedwithintheKyotoProtocol

    frameworkwouldnothavebeenpossiblehoweverwithoutintellectualfoundationslaid

    wellbeforetheclimatechangeissueswereofinterestfortheinternationalcommunity.

    Whenlookingattheoriginsofemissionstrading,Convery(2009:p.396)looksbackto

    Pigou’s “The economics of welfare” (1920) seeing the underpinnings of emissions

    marketintheideaofavoidinginternalisingexternalcostsviaextrataxes.Anotherwork

    quoted when it comes to inspiration for emissions trading is “The Problem of Social

    Cost”, where it is claimed that property rights and elimination of transaction costs

    would allow more efficient use of environmental endowments (Coase 1960). These

    ideaswerebroughtfurtherbyCrocker(1966)andDales(1968),howevertheystilldid

    notproposea spatially fixedETSandrather speculatedonmarket-basedpossibilities.

    2TheKyotoProtocollistsamongthemenhancementofenergyefficiency,protectionandenhancementofsinks and reservoirs of greenhouse gases not controlled by the Montreal Protocol, promotion ofsustainableformsofagriculture,Researchon,andpromotion,developmentandincreaseduseof,newandrenewableformsofenergy,ofcarbondioxidesequestrationtechnologiesandofadvancedandinnovativeenvironmentallysoundtechnologies,reductionorphasingoutofmarketimperfections,fiscalincentives,taxanddutyexemptionsandsubsidiesinallgreenhousegasemittingsector(Art.2.1a)3Keohane, Revesz and Stavins(1998, p.317) include in the term flexible mechanisms also taxes andrevenue-neutraltaxes,howeverinthisthesisthedefinitionreferstoemissionstrading.

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    26

    Soonafter,Montgomery(1972)advocatedexplicitandtransferablepropertyrights(the

    rights to release emissions), so that the allocation of permits is efficient and also

    independent fromthe initialallocation.Thesetheoreticalunderpinningsallowedmore

    concreteexperimentswithemissionstradinginthe1970sthatstartedintheUS.

    Emissions trading mechanisms are based on the assumption that providing

    economic incentives will result in a decrease in the volume of any given emitted

    substance. In principle, there is a total number of allowances issued by the authority

    running a given scheme and these allowances are later traded between the parties

    involvedinthescheme.Inacasethataninvolvedentitycannotmeetthetargetsgiven

    by the authorities operating the system, it is obliged to acquire permits, usually from

    emitters whowere able to decrease their emissions below the pre-given target. This

    meansthatiftheabatementcostswerehigh,oneindustrywouldratherbuyallowances

    fromanotherindustrywhoseabatementscostsarelow.Inthiswaytheenvironmental

    benefitcanberealizedatthelowestpossiblecost.

    2.2.1 Benefitsofflexiblemechanisms TherationalesforETSarecentrallyconcernedwiththemeritsandrealizationof

    economicefficiency.Policy-makersassumethatbyallowingheavilypollutingsectorsto

    surrender their emissionswhere it ismore cost-efficient, they are able to incentivise

    reductions happening across a range of industries. It is argued that in this way

    reductionsaremadeinthemostcost-efficientwayandalsothecostsforsocietyarelow

    (Hansjürgens2005,p.3).Whatismore,theregulatorycostsarepresumablylowerthan

    in the case of control and command policies that usually are more cumbersome to

    implement and monitor (Baldwin 2008; Tietenberg 1996; Harrington & Morgerstern

    2007). Ithasbeenalsoarguedthatemissionstradingdiscourages litigationand in the

    caseofcontroversies,itisfairlyeasytodealwiththemincasetheyarise(Ackerman&

    Stewart1985,p.1342).Thisisparticularlyimportantinthecaseofinternationalpolicy-

    making and the EU context, where there is a visible turn towards more general

    principles,insteadofpreciserulesthattheMemberStateshavetocomplywith.

    Ackerman and Stewart (1985, p.1342) also consider that in the US context,

    emissionstradingreducesbureaucraticburdensandcostsforthefederalgovernment.It

    is also added that if examined from a total-cost perspective, emissions trading is less

    expensivethanemissionstandards(Keohaneetal.1998,p.348).Onecanseehowthis

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    27

    mighthavemeritsinthecaseofaviation,asemissionstandardscouldmeanextremely

    highcostsforlessgreenairlinesbecausetheywouldhavetoupdatetheirentirefleets,

    or if the processwas to be introduced in phases, theywould need to consider a long

    fleet’slifeandthusimplementcarbonreductionswithconsiderabledelays.

    Furthermore, the Stern Review4has endorsed emissions trading as it gives an

    international price for emissions and via market interaction indicates the most cost-

    efficientlocationforabatement.Consequentlytheywerecalleda“verypowerfultoolin

    the framework for addressing climate change at an international level” (Stern 2007,

    p.327). This is claimed to hold true also domestically, while choosing flexible

    mechanismscanyieldpoliticaladvantages–emissions trading is regularlybelieved to

    bemorewelcomedby theregulatedentities than forexample fuel tax (Baldwin2008,

    p.196). In linewith this argument, Ackerman and Stewart (1988) consider emissions

    trading as enhancing democratic bargaining because flexible mechanisms are more

    focusedonthelevelofreductionsthataretobeachievedinsteadofdiscussingatlength

    issues such as best available technology or how to set standards. At the same time

    however, it is argued that “emissions trading is not a system in which ‘market’ and

    ‘democratic’checksandbalancescanbebroughtintolinewithanyease”(Baldwin2008,

    p.209).Similarly, the technicalcomplexityofdesigning, implementingandrunningthe

    scheme has led to a situation in which the industry has managed to establish an

    extremely strong position in all three processes mentioned above (Bailey & Maresh

    2009).

    There is also an assumption that emissions trading allowsmaking the value of

    reducing emissions apparent via putting a price tag on each tonne emitted(Vis 2006,

    p.48). This realization affects then the economic reasoning. As explained by Braun

    (2009,pp.470–471)“emittinggreenhousegasesbecomespartofeconomiccalculations

    asadirectorasanopportunitycost”.

    Finally, emissions trading is claimed to foster innovation in controlling air

    pollution as there is a direct linkbetween abatement and cost-efficiency embodied in

    allowances that can be sold (Goulder et al. 1999; Ackerman & Stewart 1985; Stavins

    2002). What is more, in the aviation sector it has been claimed that market based

    4TheSternReviewisareportcommissionedbytheBritishgovernmentandauthoredbyNicholasStern,whichexaminestheeffectsofclimatechangeoneconomy.Thereporthasbecomeoneofthebeaconsofdiscussionabouttheclimatechange/economyinteraction. Itsconclusionsunderlinetheneedforearlyactiononclimatechangeandalsoadvocateintroducingapriceoncarbon.

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    28

    mechanismsare“manifestlythemoreflexibleandlessburdensomealternatives”when

    comparedwithcommandandcontroltools(Havel&Sanchez,2012,p.376).

    2.2.2 Challengesfacedbytheemissionstradingconcept In the previous section, the advantages of emissions trading were presented,

    howevertheconceptisnotfreefromchallengesandproblems.Theseusuallypertainto

    issuesrelatedtoallocationofallowances(Butzengeiger&Michaelowa2004;Svendsen

    2005), which can easily translate to over-allocation, extremely low prices of carbon

    creditsaswellaswindfallprofitsthatparticipatingcompaniesareabletoharness.The

    literature also suggests difficulties in revisions of once established schemes, claiming

    that emissions trading is a “cheap fix” that actually weakens endeavours addressing

    pollution especially if prices of allowances are low and companies would prefer to

    rendersmallfees(oftenpassedontocustomers)ratherthaninnovate(Driesen,1998).

    In the same manner, instead of investing in often-expensive technological upgrades,

    highlypollutingsectorscanpurchasetheirallowanceswheretheupgradesarelesscost-

    intensive. A similar argument is made by Lohmann who says: “why bother making

    expensive long term structural changes if you can meet your pollution rights from

    operators that can cut their carbon cheaply?” (2006b, p.18). Also the advocates of

    imposingstandardsusetheargumentconcerning low-costsolutionsagainstemissions

    trading.Ifastandardisimposedbyauthorities,thesectorscoveredbyitneedtocomply

    withthelimitsregardlessofthepricehenceenvironmentalbenefitisrealizedinspiteof

    financialcircumstances.Thestandardswouldalsoprovidequickerresultscomparedto

    trading.

    Besides this,Hayward (2007) lookingmostlyatanation-state levelargues that

    the idea of treating emissions as alienable rights is ethically controversial and he

    maintains that there is a significant difference between carbon emission rights

    (understoodaspropertyrights)andotherfundamentalrights.Althoughheseescarbon

    emissionsessentiallyneededforprovidingsubsistence,hedisagreeswithgrantingthem

    a human rights status since that would oppose the individual’s right to a healthy

    environment. In a similarway Lohmann stresses that “if there is not enoughpolitical

    pressuretoreduceemissionsinthefirstplace,theresultwillbemerelyagamingofthe

    systemandcontinualover-allocationofpollutionrights.Carbontradingdoesnotoffera

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    29

    way around tough political decisions”(Lohmann 2006a, p.90), hence market

    mechanismsarepoliticallyvulnerable.

    Contrary to the advocates of flexible mechanisms – opponents believe that

    emissionstradingdoesnotencourageinnovationaseffectivelyascommandandcontrol

    policies (Driesen 1998;2003;2007; Fischer 2005). They also claim that at times, the

    public debate about a market-based mechanism may last long and therefore delay

    implementation and possible reductions for years (Colby 2000, p.650). Furthermore,

    there are some scholars who give accounts of situations, in which after introducing

    emissions trading, the regulated entities would hold off from investments in

    infrastructureaddressingemissionsuntiltheyarecertainofhowtheschemewillwork

    andwhatthepricesofallowanceswillbe(Sullivan&Blyth2006;Ben-Davidetal.2000;

    Leiteretal.2011).Undersuchscenariosthereductionswouldlikelyhappenwithgreat

    delays.

    Anothersetofargumentsagainstemissionstradingcomefromtheproponentsof

    theenvironmentaljusticeframework.Thisperspectivefocusesmoreonlow-incomeas

    well as minority communities rather than on cost-efficiency of emissions abatement

    (Chinn, 1999; Hayward, 2007; Lam, 2012). Firstly, it is reported that its proponents

    believethattradingschemescancontributetothecreationofareaswhereairpollution

    is high, mostly with regards to nitrogen oxides (NOx) and sulphur oxides (SOx)

    emissions, affecting local communities (Solomon & Lee 2000). These areas can be

    created if “ahigh concentrationof emissions credits [is]purchased in anecologically

    sensitivearea”(Solomon&Lee2000,p.40).Forexample,inacasestudyofLosAngeles

    pollution market it is claimed that thanks to allowing emissions trading, marine

    terminals were able to release volatile organic compounds to the atmosphere while

    acquiring credits from initiatives addressing scrapping high-polluting vehicles (Chinn

    1999).Thismeanthoweverthatthecreditsweregainedfromallovertheregionwhere

    themarketwasoperatingandthemarineterminalemissionswereaffectingonlycertain

    communities residing in the plants’ neighbourhood. In this way, emissions trading

    remains blind to spatial distribution effects. On a global scale, these inequalitiesmay

    translate into cheap allowances being generated in developing countries where

    monitoring and enforcing of the schemes is poor and then sold in the developed

    countries(Richman2003).

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    30

    Carbontradinghasalsobeencalled“aformofmodern-daycolonialism”(Rising

    Tide, 2011) and Christian Aid UK has underlined that it can “defraud developing

    countries of their rights to use the global atmosphere” (Whittington 2009). Baldwin

    (2008)alsopresentsadevelopmentperspectiveofMehmet(2002)andRichman(2003)

    who explain that trading emissions often happens between wealthy and developing

    countries,whichmayleadtoasituationwhereeventhoughthereistransferofmoney

    towards the developing world, these countries bear costs in the form of lost

    opportunities.Thepollutersare thenstillable tomaximize theirprofitson thecostof

    developingcountriesholdingcarbonallowances.Richmanwouldmaintainfurtherthat

    “emissionstradingmayconflictwiththepost-Riodevelopedcountryleadershipprincipleinseveralways.Mostobviously,itallowsdevelopedcountriestoclaimthat they are meeting their reductions obligations through trading and to‘doublecount’tradesasbothdomesticreductionsandassistancetodevelopingcountries”(2003,p.170).

    Itisthroughsuchcolonialnarratives,thatthespatialreachofemissionstradingsystems

    hasbeenchallenged.Asthisthesiswillgoontoexplain,theissueofspatialextensionof

    theEUETSraisesahostofothergovernanceissuestoo,whichareratherlessexamined

    intheexistingliterature.Thesearerelatedtooverlappingspacesofauthoritybetween

    international organisations andnation states, spatial reach of the ICAO regulations or

    thereachofregulationsissuedbythestatesthemselves.Furthermore,emissionstrading

    especially ifdiscussed in thecontextof theEUETScalls forspecialattentionto issues

    related to justicenotonlyof the tradingprocesses themselves,butalsowhiledrafting

    therules.Thisrelatestoproceduraljustice(Tyler&Blader2003)(i.e.providingfairness

    intheprocessesrelatedforexampletoburden-sharingof theconsequencesofclimate

    change) andparticipatory justice for example via community-basedprojects (Shepard

    2002)aswellastheimportanceofbroadinvolvementinglobaldecision-making.Ithas

    alsobeenunderlinedthatpublicparticipationislimitedinthecaseofemissiontrading

    schemesas theyareverymuch industry-centred (Kaswan,2008;2011).Finally, some

    authors draw attention to the ethical framework,which ensues the emissions trading

    concept while asking about the common but differentiated responsibilities principle

    withregardstothesystemsorbylookingathowtheraisedfinanceisused(Light2012;

    Caney2010;Ott&Sachs2002).

    Another important issue that pertains to emissions trading is so called carbon

    leakage, whichmeans that carbon-intensive activities can be relocated outside of the

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    31

    territory that is covered by a given scheme (van Asselt & Brewer 2010; van Asselt

    &Biermann2007;Levy&Newell2005).This,inanobviousmannerlimitseffectiveness

    ofascheme.Anotherresultofcarbonleakagecanbethedisplacementofproductsmade

    under stricteremission regimesby imported substitutes thatare cheaperdue tonon-

    existentclimate-relatedfees.Althoughtheseadverseconsequencescanbeaddressedby

    additional regulatory measures such as border adjustments for imported goods or

    mitigating the costs of compliance for the producers (Neuhoff 2008) they themselves

    have disadvantages. For example they create threats to energy security or internal

    energymarkets (Kama2014) andwould require considerable cooperation and policy

    learningbetweenregions(vanAsselt&Brewer2010).

    The arguments pertaining to carbon leakage need to be also considered for

    investigatinghowcarbonmarketsarearrangedspatially.Theonlywayof factoring in

    thespatialaspectofwherethereductionsarebeingmadeisbasedontheassumptionof

    introducing carbon border measures. These can potentially mitigate effects of some

    countrieshavingcarbonpolicieswhereasothershavingtheminarudimentaryformor

    notatall(vanAsselt&Brewer2010).Althoughsuchasolutioncouldintheoryreduce

    the negative aspects of differentiated policies, they may be challenged by the World

    TradeOrganisation regimeas creatingobstacles for free trade.Furthermore, it is also

    notentirelyclearhowvariouscarbonmechanismsshouldinteractwitheachotherandif

    such interactions would not water down the regulations and decrease effectiveness.

    Linkage can create various issues and so far no substantial links have been created

    between major emissions trading schemes (Pustelnik 2013; Flachsland et al. 2008;

    Tuerketal.2009).

    Thedebate concerning space andboundaries in theEUETShas been reflected

    also within the EU. As some claim responding to the EU ETS meant a conflict:

    “negotiations on the scheme involved an intense struggle between the differing

    territorial logics of the European Commission, themember states and industry NSAs

    [non-stateactors],withstateandindustryactorsformingdefensive-territorial‘alliances’

    thatstressed‘fairness’innationalandsectoralemissionsallocations”(Bailey&Maresh

    2009,p.447).ThesealliancesnegativelyaffectthelevelofambitionoftheETSandledto

    a situation, inwhichat thedesign stage, theMemberStates and industrieshavebeen

    creating coalitions that would advocate for “national territorial interests” (Bailey &

    Maresh 2009, p.452). What is more, these coalitions were able to influence the

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    32

    territorial distribution of the EU ETS allowances (Smale et al. 2006) and in this way

    establish business-state alliancesworking against the legislation produced at the EU-

    level(Bailey&Maresh2009,p.457).Asitwillbeshown,theterritorialinterestsplayed

    animportantroleintheEUETSforaviationfilewhileMemberStatestriedtosafeguard

    long-lastingallianceswiththeairlinesbasedwithintheirterritories.

    This section has reviewed the ways in which emissions trading systems are

    claimed to work, and different approaches and evaluations of the concept. The

    introduction allowed situating the issue analysed in a wider area of climate change

    mitigationstrategies.ThisallowsdelvingfurtherintothedetailsoftheEUETSitself.The

    nextsectiongivesafurtheroverviewofthemechanism.

    2.3 TheEuropeanUnionEmissionsTradingSystem Once the emissions trading concept hasbeen sketched, the thesis can continue

    withthepresentationoftheEUETS.Between1990and1997,theEuropeanCommission

    wasmostly interested in exploring possibilities to introduce a carbon tax (Boasson&

    Wettestad2013,p.1)andtheideasrelatedtothecarbontradingsystemhadtowaitfora

    more favourable period. Given that the preliminary proposals regarding a European

    carbon tax presented by the Commission (Commission of the European Communities

    1992; Commission of the European Communities 1991) met with unprecedentedly

    fiercelobbyingactivitiesagainsttheproposal(Skjaerseth&Wettestad2008;Svendsen

    2005),quitesoonitbecameobviousthattheCommission’splanswouldnotberealized.

    Opposition was coming both from the industry, worried about the potential costs

    relatedtothescheme,butalsofromtheMemberStateswhodidnotwanttograntthe

    EUanopportunity todecideaboutanEU-wide tax (Convery2009,p.392).Asaresult,

    the EU had to decide on an alternative way of tackling the issue of excessive CO2

    emissions.TheideaofcarbontaxfailedbuttheshapeoftheKyotoProtocoldirectedthe

    EU to look at theUS experienceswith emissions trading for other types of pollutants

    (mostlyNOxandSOx),andlatertoconsiderimplementingsuchmarket-basedmeasures

    onEuropeanground.

    Paradoxically,theEUwasdrawingitsownschemelookingatacountrythatdid

    not ratify theKyoto Protocol, even if theUS’s endorsement for emissions trading has

    been always evident. The EU did not however regard the US’s lack of action

    internationallyasamajorissue.TheCommissiontookadvantageoftheUSexperiences

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    33

    withemissionstradingdesigngoingbacktothe1960s(Voß2007;vanAsselt2010)and

    learnt from their successful implementation in the 1970s (Ellerman, Convery, &

    Harrison,2003;Stavins,2001).TheUSAcidRainPrograminitiatedwithCleanAirAct

    Amendmentsin1990wasaflagshipinitiativethataimedatreducingnitrogenoxideand

    sulphuroxideemissions(EnvironmentalProtectionAgency2013).Anotherexample is

    theRegionalCleanAirIncentivesMarket(RECLAIM),whichhadamoreregionalscope

    and was the first regional emissions trading scheme (Harrison 1998). These two

    schemes received considerable academic attention (Hahn & Noll, 1990; Joskow,

    Schmalensee,&Bailey,1998;Schmalensee,etal.,1998;Stavins,1995)andlaterinspired

    theEUwhentheEUETSlegislationwasunderconstruction.

    Atthebeginningof2000theEuropeanCommissionputforwarda“GreenPaper

    on greenhouse gas emissions trading within the European Union” with the aim of

    establishing an EU scheme for trading carbon (Commission of the European

    Communities 2000; Viguier 2001). The paper asked the following question: “Should

    there be a common emissions trading scheme within the European Community for

    certain sectors in the interest of fair competition, maximum transparency and legal

    certaintyforcompanies?”CountriessuchasNorway(notanEUMemberStatethough),

    United Kingdom and Denmark (probably the most disposed towards flexible

    mechanisms in theEU) that insomeformwerealreadyexperimentingwithemissions

    trading domestically would answer positively to the idea. Also Sweden, France and

    Germany were interested in realizing Kyoto commitments through carbon trading

    (Ellerman 2000, p.12). However the German industry lobby was concerned about

    competitivenessissuesrelatedtocarbontrading(Convery,2009,p.402).InitiallytheEU

    ETSwasplannedasavery centralized systemwith strongcontrol from theEuropean

    Commission and wide auctioning of allowances but the EU eventually yielded to the

    pressurescomingfromindustryandMemberStatesandlimiteditsambition(Boasson&

    Wettestad2013,p.54;Skjaerseth&Wettestad2008).

    In1999theCommissionwouldconsidertheKyotomechanisms“fundamentally

    differentfromthewaytheEuropeanCommunityanditsMemberStateshaveorganised

    theirenvironmentalpolicyoverthelastdecades”butwouldstillencourageinvestigating

    them closer (European Commission 1999b). Shortly after, a threat for the binding

    commitmentsincludedintheProtocolwasembodiedbyaspectacularfailureofCOP6

    thattookplacein2000inTheHague(Grubb&Yamin2001).Later,inMarch2001,the

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    34

    USwithdrew from theKyoto Protocol but this step gave theEU another argument to

    push for a European emissions market to save the Kyoto regulations (Cass 2005).

    Following theUSwithdrawal and revival theKyoto Protocol experienced through the

    Bonn Agreement5, the EU ratified the Protocol in May 2002 and encouraged other

    countries to follow its steps (EuropeanCommission2002a).Without theUSonboard

    andwithaweakresponsefromthethenEUMemberStatesandEUcandidatecountries,

    the Kyoto Protocol would have become a major climate regulation failure. After the

    CanadianandRussianratificationsin2002oftheProtocol,itenteredintoforcein2005

    with its firstcommitmentperiodset for2008-20126.TheEUgovernmentsunderstood

    that an emissions trading systemwas needed in order to fulfil the obligations of the

    Protocol (Ellerman&Buchner2007). TheKyotoProtocol togetherwithdisagreement

    foraEU-widecarbontaxcanbeconsideredthelargestEUETScatalysts(Braun2009).

    TheEUETSprovidedthenaplatformfortheEUMemberStatestofurtherinvolvewith

    theKyotoProtocolflexiblemechanisms(CDM,JI)sincetheirallowancesareconsidered

    compliancetoolsfortheEUETS.

    Asaresultofthepolicydebatedocumentedingreatdetailelsewhere(Skjaerseth

    & Wettestad 2008; Delbeke 2006; Lefevere 2005; Egenhofer 2007) the EU ETS was

    establishedin2005andthenquicklybecameaflagshipoftheEuropeanUnion’sClimate

    ActionProgramme. It is the first internationalcap-and-tradescheme in theworld that

    operates at the company level. The EU ETS has been nicknamed “a parade horse”

    (Peeters & Deketelaere 2006, p.8), the “eight-hundred-pound gorilla” (Ghaleigh 2010,

    p.48) and “a political pet that the EU has aggressively implemented and promoted”

    (Parker&Karlsson2010,p.930).Itspioneeringrolewasvisiblenotonlythroughitssize

    intermsoftonnesofcarbontradedbutalsointermsofthesectoralscopeoftheproject.

    Althoughatthebeginningofitsoperationthe“flagshipseemedlostinthesea”(Boasson

    & Wettestad 2013, p.53), following the revisions introduced in 2008 many

    commentatorsbelievedithadmadeprogress(Juergensetal.2013;Wråkeetal.2012).

    5The BonnAgreement has been reach in July 2001 and established operational rulebook for the 1997KyotoProtocol. Inthisway, thepartiesmanagedtocometoanagreementoncarbonsinks,compliance,concern of the developing countries, implementation of the Protocol’s flexiblemechanisms and furtherstepsregardingthenegotiations.ThemeetinginBonnconcludedtheadjournedCOP6.Thepoliticalwillofthe Bonnmeeting has been later translated into concrete decisions during COP 7 inMarrakech, whenMarrakechAccordswerereached.6AccordingtoArticle25oftheProtocolitentersintoforcewhen"ontheninetiethdayafterthedateonwhich not less than 55 Parties to the Convention, incorporating Parties included in Annex I whichaccountedintotalforatleast55%ofthetotalcarbondioxideemissionsfor1990oftheAnnexIcountries,havedepositedtheirinstrumentsofratification,acceptance,approvaloraccession”.

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    35

    Until2008theEUETSincludedspatially-fixedplantsgeneratingheatandpower,

    energy intensive industries such as oil refineries, steelworks and production of iron,

    aluminium, metals, cement, lime, glass, ceramics, pulp, paper, cardboard, acids and

    severalorganicchemicals,whichalltogetheraccountedformorethan45%oftheEU’s

    greenhousegasemissions(EuropeanCommission2013b).TheprincipleruleoftheEU

    ETSis thepremisethat it isacapandtrademechanismbasedonbothgrandfathering

    andauctioningof theallowances.Thismeans that thecompaniesreceiveapartof the

    allowancesforfreeandacertainshareofcreditsisauctioned.InPhaseIIIofthescheme

    (2013-2020) the Commission estimates that at least 48% of allowances will be

    auctioned(EuropeanCommission2013b)comparedwith10%inPhaseII(Hepburn,et

    al.,2006)andalmostallallowancesgivenforfreeinPhaseI(2005-2007).Whatismore,

    theoverallaim is tostopthe freeallocationno later than2027(Official Journalof the

    EuropeanUnion, 2011).One exceptionhas been established though: for aviation only

    15%of allowanceswill be auctioned through thewhole of Phase III and85%will be

    giventotheaircraftoperatorsforfree(EuropeanCommission2013a).

    FromitsverybeginningtheEUETShasattractedabroadscholarlyinterestboth

    intermsofitdesignandfunctioningaswellasintermsofitseconomicdimensions.An

    important review of the research on the EU ETS can be found in works by

    Convery(2008)andZhangandWei(2010).

    There are several approaches fromwhich the EU ETS has been viewed in the

    existingliterature:thestructureofthesystem(allocations,decision-making,monitoring,

    implementation,etc.),thepriceoftheallowances,issuesrelatedtotheseparatetrading

    periods,competitiveness,andpossiblelinksbetweentheEUETSandothermechanisms.

    The allocation process of the EU ETS has attracted greatest attention. This is

    related to the initial overallocation of allowances (McAllister 2009) and dramatic

    decline in carbon prices and consequentlywindfall profits of participating companies

    (Sijm et al. 2006). These profits, caused mostly by free allowances awarded to the

    industries,weregatheredforexamplebythepowerproducers,whoincreasedpricesby

    12-27%comparedwithnoemissionstradingscenarios(Liseetal.2010,p.42).Theyalso

    estimatethatthepass-throughrates(costsofcomplyingwiththeEUETS)arebetween

    70-90%,which indicates thatbothproducersandend-pipeconsumersareaffectedby

    the scheme (Liseetal. 2010,p.42).Buchner,CarraroandEllerman (2006) lookat the

    initial mechanism of allocating allowances. This picture is complemented by

  • Chapter2:LiteratureReviewandContextualization

    36

    Georgopoulouandcolleagues(2006)whofocusontheallocationissuesthattheywere

    projectinginthesecondphaseofEUETSoperation.

    Through lookingatcreditsdistributionwithintheEUETSonecanalsoobserve

    howseparateMember Statesweredealingwith this issue in theirNationalAllocation

    Plans (NAPs) (Gilbert et al. 2004).With regards to this issue it has been claimed for

    example that theNAPswere importantas theyset the levelofreductionsandonlyby

    lookingat themcantheeffectivenessofETSasapolicy toolcanbeevaluated(Soleille

    2006).Even though therewereproblemswith thenumberof allowancesavailableon

    themarket,thereisconsensuswithregardstothesuccessofthefirsttradingperiod:the

    implementation was effective, no major technical issues arose, first changes in the

    energyproductiontowardsgreenersourceswereobserved(Anderson&DiMaria,2011;

    Delarue,Voorspools,&D’Haeseleer,2008;Ellerman&Buchner,2008).

    The experiences from allocating credits for stationary sources are crucial for

    more advanced analysis of the EU ETS for aviation, whose dynamics are inherently

    differentasaviationreceivesase