emp5

Upload: adnaan79

Post on 07-Apr-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    1/42

    Stock Market Reaction to Good and Bad Inflation News

    Johan KnifSwedish School of Economics and Business Administration (Hanken), Finland

    James Kolari*

    Texas A&M University, USA

    Seppo PynnnenUniversity of Vaasa, Finland

    Current draft: January 11, 2006

    *Correspondence: Professor James Kolari, Texas A&M University, Mays Business School,

    Finance Department, College Station, TX 77843-4218.

    Email address:[email protected]

    Office phone: 979-845-4803 Fax: 979-845-3884

    The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Center for International Business

    Studies, Mays Business School, Texas A&M University, Hanken Swedish School of Economics

    and Business Administration, and Academy of Finland. Helpful comments were received from

    seminar participants at the 2003 European Finance Association conference in Helsinki and 2003

    Financial Management Association conference in Denver. Also, we have benefited from

    comments by Tarun Chordia, Avinidhar Subrahmanyam, David Chapman, Robert Dittmar, Sorin

    Sorescu, Eric Kelley, Jaap Bos, Schmuel Baruch, Rune Hglund, Markus Jntti, Gunnar

    Rosenqvist, and Paulo Renato Soares Terra.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    2/42

    Stock Market Reaction to Good and Bad Inflation News

    Abstract

    This paper shows that differentiating between good and bad inflation news is important to

    understanding how inflation impacts stock market returns. Summing positive and negative inflation

    shocks as in previous studies tends to wash out or mute the effects of inflation news on stock

    returns. We also find that, depending on the economic state, positive and negative inflation shocks

    can produce a variety of stock market reactions. We conclude that inflations effect on stock

    returns is conditional on whether investors perceive inflation shocks as good or bad news in

    different economic states.

    JEL Classification: E31, G00, G14

    Key Words: Inflation; Stock Market; Event Study

    2

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    3/42

    Stock Market Reaction to Good and Bad Inflation News

    I. Introduction

    Hess and Lee (1999) show that the relation between stock returns and inflation in the

    United States, United Kingdom, Japan, and Germany depends on whether inflation arises from

    supply or demand shocks. Using quarterly data and time series decomposition empirical

    methods, they find that demand disturbances associated with monetary shocks increase inflation

    and stock returns. Conversely, supply disturbances due to real output shocks lower inflation and

    raise stock returns. Thus, positive versus negative stock-return/inflation relationships are

    explained by positive and negative inflation shocks, respectively.

    Related work by McQueen and Roley (1993) finds that stronger relationships between

    stock prices and macroeconomic news occur at different stages of the business cycle. For

    example, defining economic output as high, medium, or low, aggregate U.S. stock returns

    significantly respond negatively to consumer price index (CPI) shocks in the medium state and

    to producer price index (PPI) shocks in the high state. Relevant to the present study, the authors

    posit that positive surprises in industrial production would be perceived by stock investors as

    good news during the Great Depression but bad news in 1969 when output and employment

    were high. However, their empirical analyses do not directly test for good news versus bad

    news effects of positive or negative macroeconomic surprises on stock returns.

    This paper seeks to extend the aforementioned studies by using event study methods to

    further investigate the impact of positive (demand driven) and negative (supply driven) inflation

    shocks on U.S. aggregate stock returns. We contribute new empirical evidence on the stock-

    return/inflation relation by differentiating between good and bad news associated with positive

    and negative inflation shocks. Following McQueen and Roleys logic, a positive inflation shock

    3

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    4/42

    can have different meaning to investors depending on the state of the economy. If the economy

    is in a recession, and news of higher than expected inflation is released, we hypothesize that

    stock investors would interpret this as good news (e.g., higher prices due to increasing consumer

    confidence and demand for goods and services). By contrast, a positive inflation shock in an

    expansionary economy is hypothesized to be perceived as bad news by investors (e.g., an

    increased likelihood of potential central bank intervention to increase interest rates, decrease

    inflation rates, and slow the economy). Precedent for differential market responses to good and

    bad macroeconomic news can be found in Boyd, Hu, and Jagannathan (2003), who observe that

    rising unemployment is perceived as good news by stock investors during economic expansions

    but bad news during economic contractions. Also, theoretical work by Veronesi (1999) argues

    that investors react differently to bad news in good times as opposed to good news in bad times.

    Thus, theory and evidence supports that notion of differential market responses to good and bad

    news.

    Using the consumer price index (CPI) and producer price index (PPI), we examine in this

    study the impact of good and bad inflation news announcements on aggregate U.S. stock returns.

    In general, our results indicate that differentiating between good and bad news with respect to

    inflation shocks is important to more fully understanding how inflation affects stock returns.

    For example, we find that positive and negative inflation shocks can have fairly strong cumulative

    effects on aggregate stock returns in the weeks surrounding inflation news events. However,

    summing positive and negative inflation shocks as in previous studies tends to wash out or mute the

    effects of inflation news on stock returns. Also, given the economic state, positive and negative

    inflation shocks can produce a variety of stock market reactions due to good and bad news

    effects. For example, similar to Hess and Lee, we find that inflation shocks and stock returns are

    not always inversely related as previously believed. We conclude that, consistent with our

    4

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    5/42

    research hypotheses for the most part, inflations effect on stock returns is conditional on whether

    investors perceive positive or negative inflation shocks as good or bad news in different economic

    states.

    Section II overviews related literature. Section III gives definitions of inflation news and

    economic states. Section IV provides details of our event study methodology. Section V reports

    the empirical results. Section VI contains conclusions and implications.

    II. Previous Event Studies of Inflation News

    Despite being the subject of intensive empirical and theoretical research for many years,

    the relationship between inflation news and stock market returns remains a controversial issue

    (Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002)). Many regression studies1 conclude that there is a

    negative short-run relationship between inflation and common stock returns. Because these

    results contradict the well-known Fisher (1930) effect, a variety of theoretical arguments2 have

    been proposed to explain this anomalous result.

    Early event studies designed to more closely examine the issue of stock price reactions to

    inflation news generally found that the negative relationship is so weak as to be economically

    insignificant. For example, Castanias (1979) reports that actual inflation data series did not

    affect the S&P 500 index around announcement days. Also, Schwert (1981) examines the S&P

    500s daily reaction to a measure of unexpected inflation and finds only weak market responses.

    Additionally, he finds that aggregate stock market returns appear to anticipate inflation news

    announcements and that the post-event market reaction is relatively slow requiring numerous

    days to fully respond. In an attempt to explain weak market response to inflation, he cites

    Famas (1981) argument that the high correlation between inflation and other macroeconomic

    variables obscures empirical efforts to discern the relationship between stock returns and

    5

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    6/42

    inflation. Pearce and Roley (1985) use survey data to estimate market expectations but again

    find little or no evidence of daily stock market reaction to either anticipated or unanticipated

    inflation news.

    By contrast, later event studies have found significant relationships between stock returns

    and inflation news. For example, extending event studies to hourly stock returns, Jain (1988)

    finds a significant stock market response to CPI news but not PPI news. He attributes the former

    finding to the lower variance of hourly data compared to daily data and comments that most of

    the information contained in inflation news is fully captured within a one-hour timeframe.

    Another study by McQueen and Roley (1993) finds that, consistent with Famas proxy

    argument, while the S&P 500 Index generally did not respond to a variety of macroeconomic

    information, a larger conditional response occurs with respect to different economic states [see

    also Boudoukh, Richardson, and Whitelaw (1994)]. As mentioned above, their study reveals

    significant, negative one-day stock market responses to consumer price (CPI) inflation shocks in

    medium economic states but not high and low economic states. One-day producer price (PPI)

    inflation shocks are significant in the high economic state but not other states. These results

    suggest that inflation shocks have differential effects in different economic states.

    Finally, Adams, McQueen, and Wood (2004) extend Jains daily analyses by using high

    frequency daily data and find that both PPI and CPI news significantly affect stock returns,

    especially those of large firms. For example, a 1 percentage point PPI (CPI) surprise is

    associated with a 0.70 percent (-1.29 percent) stock return response among large firms within

    15 minutes of the markets opening after morning inflation announcements. They find that most

    of the stock market reaction takes place within 10-20 minutes. Also, stronger stock market

    responses occur in the high economic state (as opposed to normal and low states) and with

    respect to positive (as opposed to negative) inflation shocks.3 In the high economic state, for

    6

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    7/42

    example, a 1 percent CPI surprise is associated with a 3.52 percent market reaction within 15

    minutes of the markets open among large firms.

    This paper contributes to the inflation/stock return literature in two ways. First,

    we show that positive and negative inflation news can have different good and bad news effects

    on stock market returns. Second, we show that market responses to positive and negative

    inflation news can differ across different economic states. When positive and negative shocks

    are pooled for any particular economic state, their effects on aggregate stock returns are washed

    out or muted and become insignificant for the most part. This result helps to explain the

    disparity between regression studies (see footnote 1) finding an inverse stock-return/inflation

    relation and event studies reporting a weak or no significant relationship.

    III. Inflation News and Economic States

    Ederington and Lee (1993) point out that inflation news is closely watched and regularly

    forecasted by market participants. Inflation news released in financial media regularly captures

    headlines due to its important implications fornumerous other macroeconomic variables, including

    monetary policy actions with respect to interest rates and money supply, economic growth, cost of

    debt and equity capital, etc. Private forecasts of macroeconomic variables are produced by virtually

    every firm investing funds in the stock market e.g., securities firms typically hire professional

    forecasters to provide in-house future estimates of key economic indicators, many firms sell

    econometric modeling services, and most large financial organizations employ economists to

    predict economic developments. In this regard, due to the large number of private inflation

    forecasters, some organizations develop and publish consensus forecast information (e.g., the

    Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphias Survey of Professional Forecasters and Livingston Survey,

    7

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    8/42

    Council of Economic Advisors, Congressional Budget Office, Blue Chip Economic Indicators,

    etc.).

    We measure monthly unexpected inflation news (or shocks) as the difference between

    median predicted forecasts of both CPI(U) and PPI published in MMS Internationals (a

    subsidiary of Standard & Poor's) Weekly Economic Survey and actual CPI(U) and PPI compiled

    by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.4 Survey forecasts are normally released four or five days

    before the release of actual data by the BLS. It is based on the forecast of the upcoming

    monthly inflation rate by business economists at brokerage houses, commercial banks, and some

    private consulting firms and major business schools in the U.S. Actual PPI is announced in the

    middle of each month and actual CPI is announced about one week later. Since the forecast

    series starts in January 1980, our sample period begins in this month and ends in September

    2004.McQueen and Roley (1993) classify economic states in terms of quartile bands around

    the trend of the (log) level of industrial production to delineate low, medium, and high periods

    of economic activity. They also employ manufacturing capacity utilization and unemployment

    to classify economic states. In the present paper we define economic states in two ways. First,

    similar to McQueen and Roley, we use the level of U.S. manufacturing capacity utilization to

    define economic states. However, we do not use industrial production as in their study because

    it is an I(1) series with drift, whereas manufacturing capacity utilization is bounded between 0

    and 100. Regarding industrial production, this implies that bounds around the trend will be

    sensitive to the specific sample period. For manufacturing capacity utilization the bounds will

    be more stable because the series is mean reverting.5 Second, extending previous work, we also

    classify the economy as rising, stable, or slowing. In this way we capture the direction of the

    economy and discern between an economy that is (for example) entering versus exiting a recession.

    8

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    9/42

    Changes (levels) in manufacturing capacity utilization are used to define dynamic (static) economic

    states. The rationale for using both approaches is that investors may not only be concerned about

    the overall level of economic conditions but changes in economic conditions too.

    Figure 1 shows U.S. seasonally adjusted monthly manufacturing capacity utilization for

    the period January 1980 to September 2004. We use changes (levels) between high and low

    quartile bands to represent stable (normal) economic activity, above the upper quartile bank to

    define rising (high) economic activity, and below the lower quartile to define slowing (low)

    economic activity. The shaded areas are periods classified as recession by the National Bureau

    of Economic Research (NBER). Figure 1 also displays changes in U.S. manufacturing capacity

    utilization over the sample period. As we will see, the CPI results are virtually unchanged when

    economic states are defined in terms of either levels or changes in manufacturing capacity

    utilization. That is, investors interpret good and bad inflation news in the same way for the most

    part in both static and dynamic economic states. However, the PPI results are more significant

    for changes than for levels of economic states. To conserve space we focus primarily on the

    results for changing economic states and discuss results for levels of economic states as

    appropriate. Complete results for levels of economic states are available upon request from the

    authors.

    Table 1 reports sample statistics for S&P 500 monthly rates of return for the entire

    sample period as well as rising, stable, and slowing economic states. The October crash month

    of 1987 when the S&P 500 dropped 24.5 percent is excluded. The overall, rising, stable, and

    slowing economy average monthly market stock returns (and standard deviations) are 0.82

    percent (4.41 percent), 0.23 percent (4.79 percent), 0.84 percent (3.96 percent), and 1.42 percent

    (4.87 percent), respectively. Notice that monthly volatility is about the same in all economic

    states and that the kurtosis statistics are not significant. Skewness measures indicate that the

    9

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    10/42

    distributions are fairly symmetric. Average monthly inflation rates, both actual and predicted,

    are almost the same for all economic states and overall at around 0.31 (0.20) percent monthly for

    CPI (PPI). Also, during our sample period, the estimated correlation coefficient between CPI

    and PPI shocks was only 0.044. Thus, we infer that CPI and PPI shocks contain different

    inflation information and should be separately examined.

    IV. Methodology

    We follow Schwerts (1981) regression event study approach but modify it to control for

    other macroeconomic news announcements when measuring the cumulative effects of inflation

    shocks on stock market returns. Importantly, this methodology allows us to measure inflation

    effects on stock returns conditional on other macroeconomic events. By taking into account

    other contemporaneously correlated macro news events, we mitigate the proxy problem

    observed by Fama and recognized by later researchers.

    As discussed above, unexpected inflation is defined as the difference between the actual

    and the median predictions of CPI(U) and PPI changes as published by MMS Internationals

    weekly Economic Survey. The October 23, 1987 CPI announcement was excluded due to the

    strong outlier effect of the market crash. Table 2 gives the numbers of positive, zero, and

    negative inflation shock in terms of CPI(U) and PPI during rising, stable, and slowing economic

    states. Using Schwerts approach, we estimate the regression

    t

    k

    n

    tk

    n

    k

    k

    p

    tk

    p

    k

    p

    j

    tjjt uuXR

    ++++=

    = == ==

    3

    1

    10

    10

    ,,

    3

    1

    10

    10

    ,,

    1

    , )()( , (1)

    where )ln(ln100 1= itt IIR , tI = the S&P 500 value on day t , tjX , are control

    variables including daily dummies (if needed) and a dummy variable for zero inflation shock

    (i.e., when there is an announcement but no shock), )0,max()(,pred

    t

    actual

    t

    p

    tk CPICPIu ++ = is

    10

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    11/42

    thepositive inflation shock in economic state k(k=1 rising economy, k=2 stable economy, and

    k=3 slowing economy), and )0,min()(,pred

    t

    actual

    t

    n

    tk CPICPIu ++ = is the negative inflation

    shock in economic state k.

    The regression coefficients measure the marginal effect of an inflation shock such that

    a 1 percent shock has a magnitude of percent change in the stock return. Analogous to

    traditional event study Abnormal Returns (AR), s can be interpreted to measure the Abnormal

    Marginal Return (AMR). As in traditional event studies, summing upAMRs gives Cumulative

    Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMR) that measure the cumulative return effect for a 1 percent

    inflation shock.

    It is well known that stock returns exhibit modest autocorrelation and (asymmetric)

    conditional heteroscedasticity (for which an asymmetric GARCH(1,1) process has proven to be a

    useful description).6 Since utilizing the conditional heteroscedasticity in the estimation increases

    the accuracy of the estimates over traditional least squares, we model the residual term in

    equation (1) as:

    [ ] 112

    12

    2

    111

    1

    Var

    ,

    +++==

    +=

    ttttttt

    ttt

    hdwwwh

    w

    , (2)

    where, conditional on information up to time t-1, ),0(~ tt hNw with th the GARCH(1,1)

    variance, and 11 =td if 01

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    12/42

    In stable or medium economic times we expect that the results would parallel those for good

    economic times, as normalcy itself is likely to be viewed by investors as more closely associated

    with good than bad economic times. While peripheral to the main purpose of this paper, our

    empirical results may provide some insight into Veronesis (1999) theoretical hypothesis that

    investors overreact to bad news in good times (i.e., positive inflation shocks in high or rising

    economic states) but underreact to good news in bad times (i.e., positive inflation shocks in low

    or declining economic states).

    V. Empirical Results

    A. CPI Inflation News

    Tables 35 report the daily CPI event study results using a 21-day window for rising,

    stable, and slowing economic change periods, respectively. The CAMR results in each economic

    state are broken down by positive and negative inflation shocks as discussed in the previous

    section. Pooled results for both positive and negative inflation shocks are reported also. Figure

    2 summarizes the information in Tables 35 for the changing economic states in a series of

    CAMR graphs. Figure 3 shows the results using high, normal, and low economic states are

    almost identical to those using changing economic states. We infer that investors respond

    similarly to good and bad inflation news across economic states defined in terms of both levels

    and changes in manufacturing activity.

    Table 6 provides the results for the macroeconomic control variables. Here we see that

    only day 0 PPI shocks are significant at the five percent level or higher.

    Rising and High Economic States. Table 3 shows that, in periods of rising economic

    activity, positive economic shocks significantly affect aggregate stock returns but not negative

    inflation shocks. Positive economic shocks have a negative and significant (at the 10 percent

    12

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    13/42

    level) CAMR equal to 6.08 on day 0. This result means that a 1.0 percent unexpected increase

    in inflation is associated with a 6.08 percent decline in stock market returns. After the event day

    CAMRs are significant (at the 5 and 10 percent levels) for days +1 to +10, with a maximum of

    10.11 on day +8. Panel A of Figure 2 illustrates these findings. Note that the results shown in

    panel A of Figure 3 for the high economic state measured in levels (e.g., the CAMR equals -8.91

    on day +10) are virtually the same as those for the rising economic state (e.g., the CAMR equals

    -9.16 on day +10). Thus, our results for both high and rising economic states are almost

    identical. Importantly, the results strongly confirms our hypothesis that positive inflation shocks

    are bad news for stocks in good economic times.

    With respect to negative inflation shocks, notice that none of the results reported in Table

    3 are significant. Figures 2 and 3 visually confirm this general finding. Thus, these findings do

    not support our research hypothesis that negative inflation shocks are perceived by investors as

    good news in good economic times.

    It is worthwhile to evaluate our results in the context of previous CPI/stock returns event

    studies. Schwert reports a CAMR for days -9 to +5 of 2.38. He concludes that the reaction of

    stock returns to unexpected inflation news is weak and, as a partial explanation, cites Famas

    argument that unexpected inflation shocks are contemporaneously correlated in real

    macroeconomic shocks (e.g., capital expenditures and gross national product). For positive

    inflation shocks we obtain a CAMR for days -9 to +5 of -8.23, which is considerably larger than

    Schwert. McQueen and Roley measure one-day stock market responses to inflation news events

    and find a 1.0 percent shock in inflation is associated with a decline in stock prices of about 0.78

    percent. This result is much smaller in magnitude than Schwerts and therefore suggests little or

    no relationship between stock returns and inflation shocks. By comparison, for positive inflation

    13

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    14/42

    shocks we find an aggregate stock market response on day 0 of -1.70, which is larger than

    McQueen and Roley.

    One possible reason for our finding of relatively larger market responses to inflation

    shocks (besides a different sample period) is that our methodology controls for other

    macroeconomic news events and therefore diminishes the proxy problem observed by Fama,

    which tends to obscure the relationship between inflation news and stock returns. However, our

    results were little changed when we re-ran the analyses by dropping the other macroeconomic

    news shocks from our regression model (see Table 6). Little or no change in results was found

    in other economic states also.

    Another potential explanation for the larger market response to inflation shocks is that

    we distinguish between positive and negative shocks, rather than lumping them together as in

    previous studies. As shown in Table 3, when we ran pooled positive and negative inflation

    shocks in the rising economic state, no significant stock market response measured in CAMRs is

    found. Hence, negative stock market responses to positive inflation shocks are washed out by

    combining them with negative inflation shocks. Although not reported, the results for the high-

    level economic state are muted also namely, summing results for positive and negative shocks

    yields a negative and significant CAMR of -2.27 for day 0 but other event window CAMRs are

    insignificant. Results for sub-windows at the bottom of Table 3 also reveal that pooling positive

    and negative inflation shocks mutes the relatively strong impact of positive inflation shocks on

    stock returns. In general, we infer that these results help to explain the relatively mild or

    absence of stock market responses to inflation shocks reported in early event studies.

    Lastly, casual inspection of panel A of Figure 2 as well as panel A of Figure 3 confirm

    Schwerts finding of market anticipation and post-event market reaction to inflation news. It is

    obvious that market reaction to inflation news occurs over a number of days, rather than only on

    14

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    15/42

    day 0 or +1. In the event windows shown at the bottom of Table 3 for the rising economy,

    significant (at the five percent level) negative CAMRs occur in the -5 to -1 event window and the

    1 to +1 event window. Although further significant market reaction is not found in post-event

    windows +1 to +5 and +6 to +10, aggregate stock returns drift slowly lower during this 10-day

    period. We infer that, rather than focusing on the traditional narrow event windows of day 0 or

    days 0, +1, which is popular in many event studies of financial announcements, the cumulative

    market response more fully captures the effect of inflation shocks on aggregate stock returns. In

    this respect, our results in Table 3 show that aggregate stock returns can cumulatively fall as

    much as 10 percent on days -5 to +10 in response to a 1 percent positive inflation shock.

    Clearly, positive inflation shocks in economic expansions are perceived to be bad news by

    investors.

    Stable and Normal Economic States. Table 4 reports the results for positive and

    negative inflation shocks in the stable economic state. Here we see that positive shocks

    negatively impact stock returns, with a few statistically significant (at the 10 percent level)

    cumulative shock effects on days +3 and +9. For negative shocks, significant (at the 5 and 10

    percent levels) CAMRs are found for days +4 to +10, with a maximum CAMR of 6.34 on day

    +8. Results for the sub-windows at the bottom of Table 4 confirm a negative market response to

    both positive and negative inflation shocks. Panel B of Figure 2 shows that positive and

    negative inflation shocks have almost identical effects on aggregate stock returns in the stable

    economic state. Thus, as expected, positive inflation shocks are viewed as bad news by

    investors in times of economic normalcy, which is similar to the results for rising and high

    economic states. However, contrary to our research hypotheses, negative inflation shocks in

    stable and normal economic states are perceived by investors as bad news for stocks, as opposed

    to good news.

    15

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    16/42

    An interesting finding here is that inflation shocks are not necessarily inversely related to

    stock returns (i.e., negative inflation shocks are associated with a decline in stock market

    returns), which is contrary to the common finding of an inverse relationship between stock

    returns and inflation shocks reported in regression studies (see footnote 1). Similar results are

    obtained for the normal-level economic state in panel B of Figure 3. Apparently, in the stable or

    normal economic state, any CPI surprise may be viewed as bad news by investors (e.g., investors

    interpret higher than expected inflation may trigger central bank initiatives to increase interest

    rates and slow inflation, while lower than expected inflation may be interpreted as a signal that

    consumer spending is falling which will slow the economy). Upon re-running the analyses by

    pooling positive and negative inflation shocks, Table 4 shows that none of the CAMRs are

    significant. Although not reported (but available upon request), this finding is confirmed for

    normal-level economic states also.

    Slowing or Low Economic States. Table 5 gives the results for the slowing economic

    state. None of the CAMRs are significant in this economic state. Negative shocks appear to be

    good news for the stock market, as CAMRs change from negative prior to day 0 to positive

    thereafter (see panel C of Figure 2). For negative shocks a maximum CAMR of 5.59 is obtained

    on day +10 but it is not statistically significant. However, in the sub-window for days -1, +1, the

    CAMR is 3.64, which is significant at the five percent level. The results for the low-level

    economic state also yield a positive stock market response to negative shocks, with a significant

    CAMR on day 0 equal to 1.34. Thus, contrary to our research hypothesis, negative inflation

    shocks in bad economic times are perceived by investors as good news. One possible

    interpretation is that lower goods and services prices may help to stimulate consumer demand

    and, subsequently, stimulate economic recovery. We infer that mild market responses to

    inflation shocks occur in slowing or low economic states.

    16

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    17/42

    B. PPI Inflation News

    Aggregate stock return reactions to PPI inflation shocks were all insignificant when the

    levels of economic states were used. For changes in economic states, we did find some

    significant results for PPI shocks. Thus, to conserve space we report the results for changing

    economic states. Figure 4 illustrates the CAMR results in different economic states and for

    positive and negative inflation shocks for changes in economic states. Tables 7-9 report CAMRs

    and test statistics for rising, stable, and slowing economic states, respectively. Table 10 reports

    the results for the macroeconomic control variables. Similar to Table 6s results for CPI

    inflation news, only day 0 CPI shocks are significant at the five percent level or higher.

    Summarizing the results in Tables 7-9, neither positive nor negative inflation shocks are

    significant in the rising economic state. By contrast, recall that CPI positive shocks in the rising

    economic state were associated with large, negative stock return responses. In the stable

    economic state, positive PPI shocks appear to be anticipated as good news, rather than bad news

    as in the case of positive CIP shocks. Table 8 shows that CAMRs are significant for days -7 to

    +1, as well as on days +3 and +5. It is obvious that PPI and CPI shocks have different inflation

    information content in terms of their effects on stock returns. Like our finding of a negative

    market response to negative CPI shocks in stable economic states, the positive market response

    to positive PPI shocks in the stable economic state contradicts the common notion that inflation

    shocks are inversely related to stock returns. Finally, in the slowing economic state negative PPI

    shocks are good news, as Table 9 shows that CAMRs are positive and significant on days -1 to

    +10, which is similar to the market reaction to negative CPI shocks. Overall, the PPI results are

    normally different from those for CPI and tend to be somewhat less pervasive (i.e., compared to

    17

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    18/42

    the CPI results, we find no significant PPI results for positive shocks in the rising economic state

    and negative shocks in the stable economic state).

    Thus, even though PPI data is announced one week before CPI data, investors appear to

    gain different information from wholesale versus retail price news. And, investors appear to be

    somewhat more concerned about changes in the final prices of goods and services rather than

    producer input prices. Similarly, Adams, McQueen, and Wood find smaller (but more

    significant) stock market reactions to PPI than CPI shocks using intra-day data.

    18

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    19/42

    C. Information Uncertainty and Inflation Shocks

    Slow, large market reactions to news events have been the subject of considerable

    research in behavioral finance (e.g., see Chan, Jegadeesh, and Lakonishok (1996), Barberis,

    Shleifer, and Vishny *(1998), Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998), and others).

    Theoretical work by Veronesi (1999) suggests that investor beliefs change slowly over time in

    response to new information that can increase uncertainty about the true economic state. In this

    regard, recent empirical work by Zhang (2006) finds that price continuation following the

    release of new public information increases with information uncertainty. He interprets these

    findings to mean that the degree of incomplete market reaction to new public information is

    positively associated with the level of information uncertainty.

    In the present context it is possible that inflation shocks are associated with increased

    investor uncertainty about the posterior probability of the economic state. For example, news of

    higher than expected CPI in a rising economic state (i.e., bad news in good times) decreased

    stock returns considerably over a two-week period of time, due in all likelihood to increased

    investor concern about a potential economic slowdown (as the central bank could be expected to

    raise interest rates to control rising inflation). Does this uncertainty manifest itself in the slow

    market responses as well as differential responses depending on the economic state or state,

    direction of the inflation shock, and consumer versus producer price inflation shock? In this

    regard, we find that negative CPI and PPI shocks are associated with higher stock returns (i.e.,

    good news in bad times). Interestingly, this evidence can be tentatively interpreted as consistent

    with Veronesis hypothesis of overreaction to bad news in good times and underreaction to good

    news in bad times that is, we find a stronger market reaction to bad news in good times than

    good news in bad times. This potential explanation for our findings is beyond the scope of the

    present work but is recommended for further study in future research.

    19

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    20/42

    VI. Conclusions and Implications

    Consistent with Hess and Lee (1999), this study finds that distinguishing between positive

    and negative inflation shocks is important to understanding their impact on stock returns.

    Extending their empirical work as well as research by McQueen and Roley (1993) to good and bad

    inflation news, we find that inflation shocks can have relatively large cumulative effects on

    aggregate stock returns depending both on the economic state and on whether inflation

    announcements are viewed as good or bad news by investors. For example, in the rising economic

    state a 1 percent positive (negative) CPI shock in the rising economic state is associated with about

    a 10 percent decline (no significant decline) in aggregate stock returns within a two-week event

    window. Like Schwert, we find that CPI shocks are anticipated by investors and have slow post-

    event effects on stock returns that continue for a week or more. Importantly, when positive and

    negative shocks are pooled across economic states, their effects on aggregate stock returns are

    washed out or muted and become insignificant. This result helps to explain the disparity

    between regression studies that typically found an inverse stock-return/inflation relation and

    event studies reporting a weak or no significant relationship.

    Similar to Hess and Lee, we find that inflation shocks can have a variety of effects on

    aggregate stock returns, rather than only an inverse relation as previously believed. For example,

    we find that positive (or negative) inflation shocks can be either positively or negatively related to

    stock returns depending on whether they are perceived as good or bad news by investors. In stable

    or normal economic states, negative CPI shocks are associated with a decrease (not increase) in

    stock market returns, and positive PPI shocks are associated with an increase (not decrease) in stock

    market returns. Thus, we conclude that, consistent with our research hypotheses for the most part,

    20

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    21/42

    inflations effect on stock returns is conditional on whether investors perceive positive and negative

    inflation shocks as good or bad news in different economic states.

    While beyond the scope of the present study, we find evidence that appears to support

    Veronesis theoretical hypothesis that investors overreact to bad news in good times and underreact

    to good news in bad times. Specifically, we find a strong, negative market reaction over a two-

    week period to positive CPI shocks in rising and high economic states (i.e., bad news in good

    times), and a significant but less pronounced positive market response to negative CPI and PPI

    shocks in declining and low economic states (i.e., good news in bad times). Further research in this

    behavioral area of asset pricing is recommended.

    Lastly, an important implication of our findings is that the weak effects of other

    macroeconomic variables on stock returns reported in previous studies (e.g., see Chen, Roll, and

    Ross (1986)) could be due to not distinguishing between good and bad news in different economic

    states. Further work is recommended on the impact of other macroeconomic good and bad news

    on stock returns, such as Boyd, Hu, and Jagannathans (2003) study of unemployment news.

    21

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    22/42

    Footnotes

    1. For example, see Oudet (1973), Branch (1974), Cagan (1974), Lintner (1975), Bodie (1976),

    Fama and Schwert (1977), Jaffe and Mandelker (1976), Nelson (1976), Cohn and Lessard

    (1981), Schwert (1981, 1990), Geske and Roll (1983), Hardouvelis (1987), Boudoukh and

    Richardson (1993), Boudoukh, Richardson, and Whitelaw (1994), Ely and Robinson (1997),

    Sharpe (2000), Anari and Kolari (2001), and others.

    2. For example, see Nelson (1976), Modigliani and Cohn (1979), Feldstein (1980), Summers

    (1981), Fama and Gibbons (1983), Geske and Roll (1983), James, Koreisha, and Partch

    (1984), Kaul (1987), Pindyck (1984), Pearce and Roley (1985), Stulz (1986), Boudoukh,

    Richardson, and Whitelaw (1994), Thorbecke (1997), and others.

    3. Adams et al. sum positive and negative inflation shocks across economic states using high-

    frequency, intra-day data. By contrast, in the present study we examine positive and

    negative inflation shocks conditional on the economic state on a daily basis. Previous work

    by Glosten, Jagannathan, and Runkle (1993) also shows that stock returns are differentially

    affected by negative and positive information. Moreover, studies of debt securities (i.e., Li and

    Engle (1998) and Christie-David, Chaudhry, and Lindley (2003)) have reported asymmetric

    market responses to negative and positive information.

    4. Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002) use the same source and methodology for computing

    inflation shocks.

    5. Flannery and Protopapadakis have criticized the definition of economic states in

    McQueen and Roley on the grounds that alternative measures of the macroeconomy (e.g., the

    index of industrial production, unemployment rates, an index of help wanted ads in major

    newspapers, and the University of Michigans Survey Research Centers Index of Consumer

    Sentiment) yielded different definitions of economic states and, subsequently, different

    22

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    23/42

    results in tests of how a wide variety of macroeconomic shocks affected daily stock returns.

    Our approach mitigates this ambiguity to some extent. Using daily data, the index of

    industrial production and manufacturing capacity utilization give similar definitions of

    economic states when using the change in the direction of economic activity.

    6. See Bollerslev, Chou, and Kroner (1992) for a review of this literature.

    23

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    24/42

    References

    Adams, G., G. McQueen, and R. Wood, 2004, The effects of inflation news on high frequency

    stock returns,Journal of Business 77, 547-74.

    Anari, A., and J. Kolari, 2001, Stock prices and inflation,Journal of Financial Research 26,

    587-601.

    Barberis, N., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 1998, A model of investor sentiment, Journal of

    Financial Economics 49, 307-43.

    Blanchard, O. J., 1981, Output, the stock market, and interest rates,American Economic Review

    71, 13243.

    Bodie, Z., 1976, Common stocks as a hedge against inflation, Journal of Finance 31, 459-70.

    Bollerslev, T., R. Chou, and K. Kroner, 1992, ARCH modelling in finance: A review of the

    theory and empirical evidence,Journal of Econometrics 52, 5-59.

    Bollerslev, T., and J. M. Wooldridge, 1992, Quasi-maximum likelihood estimation and inference

    in dynamic models with time varying covariances,Econometrics Reviews 11, 143-72.

    Boudoukh, J., and M. Richardson, 1993, Stock returns and inflation: A long-horizon perspective,

    American Economic Review 83, 1346-55.

    Boudoukh, J., M. Richardson, and R. F. Whitelaw, 1994, Industry returns and the Fisher effect,

    Journal of Finance 49, 1595-1615.

    Boyd, J. H., J. Hu, and R. Jagannathan, 2003, The stock markets reaction to unemployment

    news: Why bad news is usually good for stocks, EFA Annual Conference Paper No.

    699, http://ssrn.com/abstract=423982.

    Branch, B., 1974, Common stock performance and inflation: An international comparison,

    Journal of Business 47, 48-52.

    24

    http://ssrn.com/abstract=423982http://ssrn.com/abstract=423982
  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    25/42

    Castanias, R. P., II., 1979, Macroinformation and the variability of stock market prices, Journal

    of Finance 34, 439-50.

    Cagan, P., 1974, Common stock values and inflation The historical record of many countries,

    National Bureau Report Supplement(National Bureau of Economic Research, New

    York, NY).

    Chan, L, N. Jegadeesh, and J. Lakonishok, 1996, Momentum strategies,Journal of Finance 51,

    1681-713.

    Chen, N. F., R. Roll, and S. Ross, 1986, Economic forces and the stock market,Journal of

    Business 59, 383-403.

    Christie-David, R., M. Choudhry, and J. T. Lindley, 2003, The effects of unanticipated

    macroeconomic news on debt markets,Journal of Financial Research 26, 319-39

    Cohn, R. A., and D. R. Lessard, 1981, The effect of inflation on stock prices: International

    evidence,Journal of Finance 36, 277-89.

    Daniel K., D. Hirshleifer, and A. Subrahmanyam, 1998, Investor psychology and security

    market under- and overreactions,Journal of Finance 53, 1839-85.

    Ederington, L. H., and J. H. Lee, 1993, How markets process information: News releases and

    volatility,Journal of Finance 48, 1161-91.

    Ely, D. P., and K. J. Robinson, 1997, Are stocks a hedge against inflation: International evidence

    using a long-run approach,Journal of International Money and Finance 16, 141-67.

    Fama, E. F., 1981, Stock returns, real activity, inflation, and money, American Economic

    Review 65, 269-82.

    Fama, E. F., and M. R. Gibbons, 1982, Inflation, real returns and capital investment,Journal of

    Monetary Economics 9, 297-323.

    25

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    26/42

    Fama, E. F., and G. W. Schwert, 1977, Asset returns and inflation,Journal of Financial

    Economics 5, 115-46.

    Feldstein, M., 1980, Inflation and the stock market, American Economic Review 70, 837-47.

    Fisher, I., 1930, The Theory of Interest(Macmillan, New York, NY).

    Flannery, M. J., and A. A. Protopapadakis, 2002, Macroeconomic factors do influence aggregate

    stock returns,Review of Financial Studies 15, 751-82.

    Geske, R., and R. Roll, 1983, The fiscal and monetary linkages between stock returns and

    inflation,Journal of Finance 38, 1-33.

    Glosten, L, R. Jagannathan, and D. Runkle, 1993, On the relation between the expected value

    and the volatility of the nominal excess return on stocks,Journal of Finance 48, 1779-

    1801.

    Hardouvelis, G., 1987, Macroeconomic information and stock prices, Journal of Economics and

    Business 39, 131-40.

    Hess, B. J, and B. S. Lee, 1999, Stock returns and inflation with supply and demand

    disturbances,Review of Financial Studies 12, 1203-18.

    Jaffe, J., and G. Mandelker, 1976, The Fisher effect for risky assets: An empirical

    investigation,Journal of Finance 31, 447-58.

    Jain, P., 1998, Response of hourly stock prices and trading volume to economic news, Journal

    of Business 61, 219-31.

    James, C., S. Koreisha, and M. Partch, 1984, A VARMA analysis of the causal relations among

    stock returns, real output, and nominal interest rates,Journal of Finance 40, 1375-84.

    Li, L., and R. Engle, 1998, Macroeconomic announcements and volatility of Treasury futures,

    Discussion paper 98-27, University of California, San Diego.

    Lintner, J., 1975, Inflation and security returns,Journal of Finance 30, 259-80.

    26

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    27/42

    McQueen, G., and V. V. Roley, 1993, Stock prices, news, and business conditions, Review of

    Financial Studies 6, 683-707.

    Modigliani, F., and R. A. Cohn, 1979, Inflation, rational valuation, and the market, Financial

    Analysts Journal35, 3-23.

    Nelson, C. R., 1976, Inflation and rates of return on common stocks,Journal of Finance 31,

    471-83.

    Orphanides, A., 1992, When good news is bad news: Macroeconomic news and the stock

    market, Working paper, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

    Oudet, B. A., 1973, The variation of the return on stocks in periods of inflation,Journal of

    Financial and Quantitative Analysis 8, 247-58.

    Pearce, D. K., and V. V. Roley, 1985, The reaction of stock prices to unanticipated changes in

    money: A note,Journal of Finance 25, 1323-33.

    Pindyck, R. S., 1984, Risk, inflation, and the stock market,American Economic Review 74, 335-

    51.

    Schwert, G. W., 1981, The adjustment of stock prices to information about inflation,Journal of

    Finance 36, 15-29.

    Schwert, G. W., 1990, Stock returns and real activity: A century of evidence, Journal of

    Finance 45, 1237-57.

    Sharpe, S. A., 2000, Reexamining stock valuation and inflation: The implications of analysts

    earnings forecasts, Working paper, Federal Reserve Board, Division of Research and

    Statistics.

    Stulz, R. M., 1986, Asset pricing and expected inflation,Journal of Finance 41, 209-23.

    Summers, L. H., 1981, Inflation and the valuation of corporate equities, Working paper no. 824,

    National Bureau of Economic Research.

    27

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    28/42

    Thorbecke, W., 1997, On stock market returns and monetary policy,Journal of Finance 52,

    635-54.

    Veronesi, P., 1999, Stock market overreaction to bad news in good times: A rational

    expectations equilibrium model,Review of Financial Studies 12, 975-1007.

    Zhang, X. F., forthcoming 2006, Information uncertainty and stock returns,Journal of Finance

    60.

    28

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    29/42

    FIGURE 1

    U.S. Seasonally Adjusted Monthly Manufacturing Capacity Utilization

    and Changes in Capacity Utilization with Quartile Bands

    Seasonally Adjusted US Manufactu

    Utilization

    75

    80

    85

    90

    Month

    Utilization(%

    Changes of Seasonally Adjus

    Manufacturing Capacity Utili

    -1

    0

    1

    2

    3

    Change(%

    )

    Source: Federal Reserve Board (www.federalreserve.gov ). The sample period covers January 1980 to September 2004. Theshaded periods, January 1980 to November 1980, July 1981 to November 1982, July 1990 to March 1991, and March 2001 to

    November 2001 were declared recessions by the NBER (for further details, seewww.nber.org/cycles.html ).

    29

    http://www.federalreserve.gov/http://www.nber.org/cycles.htmlhttp://www.nber.org/cycles.htmlhttp://www.nber.org/cycles.htmlhttp://www.federalreserve.gov/http://www.nber.org/cycles.html
  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    30/42

    FIGURE 2

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) with Respect to CPI Inflation Shocks:Different Economic States Defined As Changes in Manufacturing Capacity Utilization

    Panel A. Positive manufacturing utilization change periods (rising economy)

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    810

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    Panel B. Neutral manufacturing utilization change periods (stable economy)

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    Panel C. Negative manufacturing utilization change periods (slowing economy)

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    30

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    31/42

    FIGURE 3

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) with Respect to CPI Inflation Shocks:

    Different Economic States Defined As Levels of Manufacturing Capacity Utilization

    A. High manufacturing utilization level periods (high economy)

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    B. Normal manufacturing utilization level periods (normal economy)

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    C. Low manufacturing utilization level periods (low economy)

    -4-2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    31

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    32/42

    FIGURE 4

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) with Respect to PPI Inflation Shocks:

    Different Economic States Defined As Changes in Manufacturing Capacity Utilization

    Panel A. Positive manufacturing utilization change periods (rising economy)

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    Panel B. Neutral manufacturing utilization change periods (stable economy)

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    Panel C. Negative manufacturing utilization change periods (slowing economy)

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2

    Positive shock

    Negative shock

    32

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    33/42

    TABLE 1

    Monthly Descriptive Statistics for the Whole Sample Period and Economic States

    Defined As Rising, Stable, and Slowing U.S. Manufacturing Capacity Utilization

    Monthly Monthly CPI Changes Monthly PPI Changes CPI PPI

    Panel A. Overall sample S&P500 Actual Predicted Actual Predicted Shock Shock

    Mean (%) 0.82 0.31 0.32 0.20 0.27 -0.01 -0.06

    t(mean = 0p-value) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.27 0.00

    Standard deviation (%) 4.41 0.28 0.22 0.51 0.30 0.15 0.33

    Excess kurtosis 3.50 3.07 4.63 2.23 3.27 1.60 2.36

    Skewness -0.87 1.16 1.58 -0.01 0.95 0.08 0.06

    Minimum (%) -24.54 -0.40 -0.30 -1.90 -0.65 -0.60 -1.30

    Maximum (%) 11.88 1.40 1.40 1.80 1.40 0.50 1.20

    Observations (months) 296 296 296 296 296 296 296

    Panel B. Rising economy

    Mean (%) 0.23 0.30 0.31 0.17 0.28 -0.02 -0.11

    t(mean = 0p-value) 0.68 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.28 0.00

    Standard deviation (%) 4.79 0.20 0.16 0.39 0.22 0.14 0.31

    Excess kurtosis 9.00 2.52 8.42 2.18 3.82 -0.03 4.44Skewness -1.90 0.88 2.29 0.28 1.26 -0.19 0.66

    Minimum (%) -24.54 -0.20 0.10 -1.00 -0.10 -0.40 -1.10

    Maximum (%) 10.68 1.00 1.00 1.60 1.20 0.30 1.20

    Observations (months) 75 75 75 75 75 75 75

    Panel C. Stable economy

    Mean (%) 0.84 0.31 0.31 0.22 0.27 -0.01 -0.05

    t(mean = 0p-value) 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.54 0.04

    Standard deviation (%) 3.96 0.28 0.22 0.49 0.30 0.13 0.31

    Excess kurtosis 0.58 3.52 5.05 1.12 3.90 1.61 1.51

    Skewness -0.41 1.44 1.68 0.73 1.31 0.53 0.41

    Minimum (%) -11.66 -0.30 -0.20 -0.90 -0.50 -0.40 -0.80

    Maximum (%) 10.37 1.40 1.40 1.80 1.40 0.50 1.20

    Observations (months) 150 150 150 150 150 150 150

    Panel D. Slowing economy

    Mean (%) 1.42 0.32 0.33 0.20 0.24 -0.01 -0.04

    t(mean = 0p-value) 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.74 0.40

    Standard deviation (%) 4.87 0.33 0.29 0.64 0.37 0.18 0.40

    Excess kurtosis 0.14 1.65 2.17 2.16 1.54 1.72 2.12

    Skewness -0.42 0.74 1.14 -0.84 0.49 -0.22 -0.64

    Minimum (%) -12.13 -0.40 -0.30 -1.90 -0.65 -0.60 -1.30

    Maximum (%) 11.88 1.40 1.30 1.70 1.40 0.50 0.90

    Observations (months) 71 71 71 71 71 71 71

    Panel E. Correlation of CPI and PPI shocksCorrelationCoefficient t-value p-value

    Rising economy -0.072 -1.24 0.216

    Stable economy 0.077 1.34 0.182

    Slowing economy 0.074 1.27 0.204

    Overall 0.044 0.75 0.454Monthly rates of return for the S&P 500 are calculated as 100 times the log price differences. The sample period for theS&P500 covers January, 1980 to September, 2004. The S&P 500 return for the crash month October, 1987 is discarded as anoutlier from the return sample statistics. Rising, stable, and slowing economic activity periods are defined using quartile

    bands around the median percent changes in U.S. monthly manufacturing capacity utilization.

    33

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    34/42

    TABLE 2

    Number of Inflation Shock Event Months in

    Slowing, Stable, and Rising Economic Activity States

    Panel A. CPI shocksCPI inflation shocks

    Economy Positive ZeroNegativ

    e Total

    Rising 22 25 28 75Stable 40 50 60 150Slowing 24 21 26 71Total 86 96 114 296

    Panel B. PPI shocksPPI inflation shocks

    Economy Positive ZeroNegativ

    e Total

    Rising 17 17 41 75

    Stable 53 18 79 150Slowing 27 11 33 71

    Total 97 46 153 296

    The sample covers the period January 1980 to September 2004. Positive (negative) inflation shocks consist ofactual monthly CPI/PPI changes greater than (less than) zero difference from the median survey forecast. Zeroinflation shock is the case where the prediction equals the actual. The CPI and PPI announcements of October1987 were excluded due to the strong outlier effect of the stock market crash. Rising, stable, and slowingeconomic activity periods are defined using quartile bands around the median percent changes in U.S. monthlymanufacturing capacity utilization.

    34

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    35/42

    TABLE 3

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) in Response to Different CPI Shocks in

    Positive Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Change Periods (Rising Economic State)

    Positive inflation shock Negative inflation shockPooled positive and

    negative shocks

    Day CAMR Std p-value

    CAM

    R Std p-value CAMR Std p-value-10 -1.03 0.93 0.269 1.65 0.90 0.064 -1.42 0.67 0.034

    -9 1.73 1.34 0.199 1.63 1.31 0.214 -0.24 1.00 0.814

    -8 1.33 1.92 0.488 0.72 1.52 0.637 0.10 1.24 0.938

    -7 1.68 2.18 0.441 -0.04 1.77 0.981 0.68 1.42 0.632

    -6 0.72 2.44 0.767 -0.19 1.99 0.925 0.30 1.58 0.851

    -5 -1.09 2.70 0.686 -2.05 2.16 0.344 0.60 1.70 0.722

    -4 -2.84 3.04 0.350 -2.99 2.40 0.212 0.34 1.87 0.855

    -3 -1.58 3.21 0.623 -2.55 2.57 0.321 0.49 2.01 0.808

    -2 -2.47 3.38 0.464 -1.52 2.85 0.594 -0.53 2.17 0.808

    -1 -4.38 3.50 0.211 -0.35 3.06 0.909 -2.00 2.29 0.381

    0 -6.08 3.72 0.102 0.38 3.23 0.906 -3.14 2.40 0.190

    1 -7.94 3.84 0.039 -0.44 3.35 0.895 -3.50 2.46 0.155

    2 -9.25 3.93 0.019 -0.88 3.54 0.804 -3.79 2.56 0.138

    3 -8.06 4.08 0.048 -1.12 3.71 0.763 -3.17 2.69 0.238

    4 -9.10 4.20 0.030 -1.56 3.79 0.681 -3.37 2.73 0.217

    5 -9.26 4.32 0.032 -1.71 3.95 0.664 -3.36 2.82 0.233

    6 -7.75 4.44 0.081 -3.57 4.05 0.379 -1.66 2.87 0.564

    7 -8.86 4.60 0.054 -2.41 4.19 0.565 -2.87 2.95 0.331

    8 -10.11 4.75 0.033 -2.99 4.23 0.479 -3.08 2.99 0.302

    9 -8.45 4.81 0.079 -3.43 4.33 0.428 -2.16 3.05 0.479

    10 -9.16 4.91 0.062 -3.07 4.42 0.487 -2.65 3.11 0.395

    Sub-windows

    -5 -1 -5.10 2.34 0.029 -0.17 2.21 0.940 -2.30 1.64 0.1610 -1.70 1.19 0.154 0.73 0.95 0.441 -1.14 0.75 0.130

    -1 +1 -5.46 1.83 0.003 1.08 1.71 0.528 -2.97 1.25 0.017

    +1 +5 -3.18 2.16 0.140 -2.10 2.09 0.317 -0.21 1.54 0.890

    +6 +10 0.10 2.57 0.970 -1.35 1.80 0.451 0.71 1.56 0.648

    The sample covers the period January 1980 to September 2004. Cumulative abnormal marginal returns (CAMR) are sums ofthe regression coefficients in equation (1). We also included additional macro announcements (see Table 6 for the estimationresults). Positive (negative) inflation shocks consist of actual CPI greater than (less than) the median survey forecast. Stddenotes the standard error ofCAMR, where the Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992) corrections are used.

    35

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    36/42

    TABLE 4

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) in Response to Different CPI Shocks inNeutral Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Change Periods (Stable Economic State)

    Positive inflation shock Negative inflation shockPooled positive and

    negative shocks

    Day CAMR Std p-value

    CAMR Std p-value

    CAMR Std p-value

    -10 0.52 0.60 0.385 0.17 0.41 0.676 0.15 0.35 0.668

    -9 1.50 0.89 0.091 -0.67 0.90 0.456 1.03 0.65 0.115

    -8 1.44 1.01 0.153 -1.18 1.18 0.318 1.26 0.80 0.117

    -7 1.41 1.19 0.236 -2.55 1.30 0.050 1.98 0.89 0.026

    -6 0.05 1.32 0.972 -1.49 1.54 0.334 0.73 1.04 0.483

    -5 0.22 1.56 0.889 -1.05 1.97 0.595 0.63 1.27 0.620

    -4 0.60 1.65 0.714 -2.43 1.73 0.160 1.64 1.18 0.167

    -3 -0.22 1.80 0.904 -3.57 1.83 0.051 1.85 1.25 0.140

    -2 -0.63 1.98 0.749 -3.34 1.91 0.081 1.51 1.33 0.257

    -1 -1.43 1.99 0.472 -2.86 2.02 0.157 0.91 1.36 0.502

    0 -2.28 2.08 0.272 -2.53 2.09 0.225 0.33 1.40 0.811

    1 -3.00 2.31 0.193 -2.50 2.22 0.259 0.06 1.50 0.970

    2 -3.58 2.41 0.136 -2.16 2.32 0.353 -0.35 1.56 0.823

    3 -4.47 2.50 0.074 -3.14 2.41 0.193 -0.13 1.61 0.935

    4 -4.21 2.60 0.106 -5.24 2.47 0.034 1.16 1.65 0.483

    5 -3.61 2.73 0.187 -5.18 2.54 0.041 1.34 1.73 0.440

    6 -3.64 2.84 0.201 -5.57 2.69 0.038 1.55 1.81 0.392

    7 -4.02 2.90 0.166 -6.13 2.94 0.037 1.77 1.87 0.344

    8 -4.43 2.98 0.137 -6.34 3.02 0.036 1.73 1.91 0.367

    9 -5.38 3.03 0.075 -6.15 3.12 0.049 1.25 1.96 0.521

    10 -4.78 3.16 0.130 -6.25 3.18 0.050 1.51 2.01 0.452

    Sub-windows-5 -1 -1.48 1.59 0.351 -1.37 1.36 0.314 0.18 1.04 0.860

    0 -0.87 0.70 0.213 0.33 0.47 0.487 -0.58 0.40 0.148

    -1 +1 -2.37 1.37 0.083 0.84 1.07 0.434 -1.46 0.84 0.084

    +1 +5 -1.32 1.58 0.404 -2.64 1.32 0.045 1.00 1.06 0.345

    +6 +10 -1.18 1.53 0.443 -1.07 1.53 0.485 0.18 1.04 0.864

    The sample covers the period January 1980 to September 2004. Cumulative abnormal marginal returns (CAMR) are sums ofthe regression coefficients in equation (1). We also included additional macro announcements (see Table for the estimationresults). Positive (negative) inflation shocks consist of actual CPI greater than (less than) the median survey forecast. Stddenotes the standard error ofCAMR, where the Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992) corrections are used.

    36

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    37/42

    TABLE 5

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) in Response to Different CPI Shocks in

    Negative Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Change Periods (Slowing Economic State)

    Positive inflation shock Negative inflation shock

    Pooled positive and

    negative shocks

    Day CAMR Std p-value

    CAMR Std p-value

    CAMR Std p-value

    -10 0.88 0.91 0.331 0.29 0.95 0.760 0.22 0.66 0.737

    -9 0.27 1.19 0.820 -0.25 1.30 0.845 0.18 0.89 0.842

    -8 0.29 1.58 0.853 -0.47 1.54 0.762 0.29 1.11 0.797

    -7 0.47 1.95 0.811 -1.45 1.67 0.385 0.89 1.29 0.491

    -6 1.83 2.26 0.416 -1.38 1.98 0.487 1.52 1.52 0.317

    -5 0.89 2.43 0.714 -0.95 2.09 0.648 0.83 1.61 0.605

    -4 2.28 2.72 0.404 -2.11 2.35 0.370 2.06 1.80 0.252

    -3 1.07 3.02 0.722 -2.07 2.68 0.441 1.44 2.03 0.477

    -2 1.36 3.14 0.664 -0.33 2.86 0.909 0.67 2.13 0.754

    -1 0.02 3.22 0.994 -0.63 2.92 0.830 0.21 2.15 0.923

    0 -1.38 3.37 0.683 2.15 3.29 0.514 -1.95 2.34 0.404

    1 -0.05 3.54 0.988 3.31 3.53 0.348 -1.95 2.47 0.429

    2 -0.19 3.67 0.958 4.01 3.82 0.294 -2.44 2.61 0.348

    3 -0.27 3.78 0.944 3.28 3.93 0.403 -2.06 2.67 0.441

    4 -0.47 4.00 0.906 3.48 4.60 0.449 -2.27 3.01 0.451

    5 0.17 4.32 0.969 2.69 4.66 0.564 -1.53 3.11 0.622

    6 0.00 4.50 1.000 2.89 4.71 0.540 -1.72 3.18 0.588

    7 0.32 4.61 0.945 4.76 4.69 0.309 -2.56 3.20 0.423

    8 0.18 4.70 0.970 4.60 4.75 0.333 -2.56 3.24 0.430

    9 0.72 4.82 0.880 4.86 4.86 0.317 -2.47 3.32 0.456

    10 1.16 4.89 0.812 5.59 4.78 0.242 -2.59 3.29 0.430Sub-windows

    -5 -1 -1.81 2.24 0.418 0.75 1.84 0.682 -1.31 1.42 0.357

    0 -1.40 1.00 0.160 2.77 0.82 0.001 -2.16 0.63 0.001

    -1 +1 -1.42 1.57 0.365 3.64 1.50 0.015 2.62 1.06 0.013

    +1 +5 1.55 2.37 0.514 0.54 2.44 0.824 0.42 1.67 0.801

    +6 +10 0.99 2.14 0.644 2.90 2.26 0.198 -1.06 1.60 0.508

    The sample covers the period January 1980 to September 2004. Cumulative abnormal marginal returns (CAMR) are sums ofthe regression coefficients in equation (1). We also included additional macro announcements (see Table 6 for the estimationresults). Positive (negative) inflation shocks consist of actual CPI greater than (less than) the median survey forecast. Stddenotes the standard error ofCAMR, where the Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992) corrections are used.

    37

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    38/42

    TABLE 6

    Estimates of the Constant Term (Non-Event Mean), MA, and GARCH Parameters for the

    CPI Inflation Event Regression Model with Macroeconomic Control Variables

    Coeff std p-value

    Constant 0.046 0.016 0.003

    CPI zero shock 0.104 0.077 0.175

    Leading indicator 0.057 0.134 0.670

    PPI(3) -0.106 0.164 0.518

    PPI(2) 0.084 0.158 0.596

    PPI(1) 0.102 0.163 0.531

    PPI(0) -0.573 0.174 0.001

    PPI(-1) -0.279 0.151 0.064

    PPI(-2) -0.138 0.222 0.534

    PPI(-3) -0.170 0.139 0.220

    PPI zero shock 0.179 0.122 0.142

    Housing starts 0.555 0.600 0.355

    Personal income 0.022 0.182 0.905

    Industrial production 0.081 0.144 0.577Durable goods: New orders -0.011 0.016 0.505

    Retail sales -0.120 0.071 0.091

    Trade balance 0.040 0.025 0.104

    Unemployment 0.345 0.314 0.272

    AR(1) 0.037 0.013 0.005

    Variance equation

    C 0.013 0.003 0.000

    RESID(-1)2 0.023 0.008 0.004

    RESID(-1)2*(RESID(-1)

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    39/42

    TABLE 7

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) in Response to Different PPI Shocks in

    Positive Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Change Periods (Rising Economic State)

    Positive inflation shock Negative inflation shockPooled positive and

    negative shocks

    Day

    CAM

    R Std p-value

    CAM

    R Std p-value

    CAM

    R Std p-value-10 -0.02 0.54 0.972 0.07 0.25 0.772 -0.08 0.24 0.732

    -9 0.49 0.75 0.518 0.12 0.45 0.791 -0.03 0.40 0.947

    -8 0.50 0.86 0.561 -0.19 0.54 0.727 0.22 0.46 0.632

    -7 1.43 1.02 0.160 -0.59 0.67 0.380 0.77 0.57 0.174

    -6 1.72 1.10 0.119 -0.56 0.74 0.449 0.83 0.61 0.175

    -5 1.42 1.24 0.250 -0.68 0.81 0.402 0.86 0.68 0.203

    -4 1.25 1.55 0.421 -0.68 0.87 0.431 0.87 0.75 0.242

    -3 0.57 1.63 0.726 -0.94 0.94 0.317 0.87 0.80 0.275

    -2 0.55 1.73 0.749 -0.70 1.02 0.492 0.64 0.86 0.458

    -1 -0.17 1.93 0.928 -0.72 1.05 0.490 0.47 0.91 0.606

    0 -0.78 2.01 0.698 -0.50 1.13 0.660 0.16 0.95 0.870

    1 -0.75 2.07 0.718 -0.43 1.18 0.715 0.12 0.99 0.901

    2 -1.49 2.10 0.479 -0.20 1.22 0.868 -0.24 1.01 0.811

    3 -0.82 2.14 0.700 -0.16 1.27 0.899 -0.08 1.05 0.937

    4 -1.15 2.23 0.606 -0.50 1.30 0.699 0.07 1.07 0.950

    5 -1.15 2.26 0.611 -0.55 1.35 0.686 0.11 1.11 0.921

    6 -1.06 2.40 0.658 -1.26 1.40 0.370 0.63 1.15 0.582

    7 -0.88 2.43 0.715 -1.81 1.46 0.214 1.10 1.18 0.352

    8 -0.28 2.47 0.911 -1.97 1.50 0.187 1.42 1.22 0.243

    9 0.24 2.59 0.925 -1.73 1.54 0.262 1.42 1.26 0.260

    10 0.89 2.65 0.738 -1.74 1.56 0.266 1.62 1.29 0.210

    Sub-windows

    -5 -1 -1.89 1.55 0.223 -0.17 0.75 0.826 -0.37 0.69 0.5990 -0.61 0.54 0.265 0.23 0.36 0.535 -0.31 0.30 0.293

    +1 +5 -0.37 1.06 0.728 -0.05 0.66 0.942 -0.05 0.56 0.935

    +6 +10 2.04 1.30 0.117 -1.19 0.74 0.109 1.51 0.67 0.024

    The sample covers the period January 1980 to September 2004. Cumulative abnormal marginal returns (CAMR) are sums ofthe regression coefficients in equation (1). We also included additional macro announcements (see Table 6 for the estimationresults). Positive (negative) inflation shocks consist of actual CPI greater than (less than) the median survey forecast. Stddenotes the standard error ofCAMR, where the Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992) corrections are used.

    39

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    40/42

    TABLE 8

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) in Response to Different PPI Shocks in

    Neutral Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Change Periods (Stable Economic State)

    Positive inflation shock Negative inflation shockPooled positive and

    negative shocks

    Day CAM

    R Std p-value

    CAM

    R Std p-value

    CAM

    R Std p-value

    -10 0.50 0.25 0.049 -0.02 0.21 0.929 0.17 0.16 0.276

    -9 0.92 0.44 0.037 -0.05 0.36 0.894 0.34 0.28 0.221

    -8 0.84 0.54 0.123 0.04 0.46 0.922 0.29 0.35 0.419

    -7 1.78 0.68 0.009 0.49 0.52 0.349 0.33 0.43 0.452

    -6 1.80 0.82 0.029 0.52 0.59 0.375 0.34 0.50 0.503

    -5 1.95 0.91 0.032 0.17 0.67 0.796 0.62 0.55 0.263

    -4 2.16 0.97 0.026 0.10 0.77 0.897 0.75 0.60 0.212

    -3 2.69 1.09 0.013 0.26 0.82 0.756 0.84 0.66 0.205

    -2 4.30 1.35 0.001 0.06 0.89 0.946 1.43 0.73 0.051

    -1 4.96 1.47 0.001 -0.32 0.93 0.732 1.89 0.78 0.016

    0 3.95 1.42 0.005 -0.05 0.97 0.961 1.42 0.79 0.0701 3.05 1.46 0.036 0.20 1.00 0.845 0.98 0.81 0.225

    2 2.40 1.46 0.101 0.03 1.06 0.976 0.85 0.81 0.293

    3 2.61 1.50 0.082 0.22 1.10 0.840 0.80 0.83 0.337

    4 2.37 1.54 0.124 0.51 1.17 0.661 0.56 0.88 0.526

    5 3.03 1.60 0.058 0.59 1.20 0.622 0.73 0.91 0.423

    6 2.53 1.64 0.123 0.67 1.24 0.587 0.56 0.92 0.542

    7 1.86 1.67 0.266 0.57 1.30 0.661 0.47 0.95 0.617

    8 1.75 1.74 0.315 0.87 1.34 0.515 0.24 0.97 0.805

    9 2.50 1.80 0.164 0.81 1.37 0.554 0.52 1.01 0.607

    10 3.08 1.89 0.103 0.63 1.42 0.658 0.85 1.05 0.422

    Sub-windows

    -5 -1 3.16 1.14 0.006 -0.84 0.67 0.210 1.55 0.59 0.008

    0 -1.00 0.61 0.098 0.27 0.24 0.259 -0.47 0.26 0.073

    +1 +5 -0.92 1.16 0.425 0.64 0.62 0.301 -0.69 0.58 0.229

    +6 +10 0.05 0.92 0.960 0.04 0.65 0.956 0.12 0.53 0.823

    The sample covers the period January 1980 to September 2004. Cumulative abnormal marginal returns (CAMR) are sums ofthe regression coefficients in equation (1). We also included additional macro announcements (see Table 6 for the estimationresults. Positive (negative) inflation shocks consist of actual CPI greater than (less than) the median survey forecast. Stddenotes the standard error ofCAMR, where the Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992) corrections are used.

    40

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    41/42

    TABLE 9

    Cumulative Abnormal Marginal Returns (CAMRs) in Response to Different PPI Shocks in

    Negative Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Change Periods (Slowing Economic State)

    Positive inflation shock Negative inflation shockPooled positive and

    negative shocks

    Day CAM

    R Std p-value

    CAM

    R Std p-value

    CAM

    R Std p-value

    -10 -0.12 0.68 0.857 0.01 0.38 0.977 -0.03 0.33 0.932

    -9 -0.09 0.81 0.910 0.25 0.51 0.628 -0.16 0.42 0.711

    -8 1.04 0.89 0.245 0.36 0.61 0.556 0.07 0.50 0.881

    -7 1.63 1.04 0.115 0.52 0.72 0.470 0.15 0.60 0.800

    -6 1.48 1.08 0.170 0.47 0.80 0.554 0.16 0.65 0.800

    -5 1.36 1.14 0.235 1.10 0.87 0.209 -0.29 0.71 0.683

    -4 1.79 1.23 0.146 0.78 0.98 0.427 0.13 0.80 0.874

    -3 2.02 1.39 0.147 1.44 1.15 0.213 -0.30 0.96 0.755

    -2 1.32 1.47 0.367 1.94 1.25 0.121 -0.86 1.04 0.409

    -1 0.80 1.56 0.607 2.30 1.32 0.081 -1.26 1.11 0.257

    0 0.03 1.69 0.984 3.45 1.38 0.012 -2.22 1.16 0.0551 0.48 1.74 0.783 3.87 1.43 0.007 -2.40 1.21 0.047

    2 0.17 1.81 0.927 3.72 1.48 0.012 -2.43 1.26 0.053

    3 0.02 1.91 0.993 4.50 1.54 0.004 -2.98 1.32 0.024

    4 0.74 2.00 0.711 5.07 1.68 0.003 -3.12 1.41 0.027

    5 1.39 2.04 0.496 4.83 1.69 0.004 -2.69 1.42 0.058

    6 2.02 2.14 0.343 5.21 1.86 0.005 -2.79 1.56 0.074

    7 1.37 2.20 0.533 5.14 1.90 0.007 -2.95 1.59 0.063

    8 1.16 2.23 0.603 6.12 1.96 0.002 -3.65 1.61 0.023

    9 -0.06 2.25 0.978 6.35 1.92 0.001 -4.14 1.59 0.009

    10 0.74 2.28 0.746 6.06 1.95 0.002 -3.70 1.60 0.021

    Sub-windows

    -5 -1 -0.67 1.16 0.563 1.83 0.97 0.059 -1.42 0.83 0.086

    0 -0.77 0.57 0.179 1.14 0.29 0.000 -0.96 0.27 0.000

    +1 +5 1.35 1.15 0.241 1.38 0.85 0.104 -0.47 0.70 0.501

    +6 +10 -0.65 1.06 0.540 1.23 0.82 0.135 -1.02 0.67 0.130

    The sample covers the period January 1980 to September 2004. Cumulative abnormal marginal returns (CAMR) are sums ofthe regression coefficients in equation (1). We also included additional macro announcements (see Table 6 for the estimationresults). Positive (negative) inflation shocks consist of actual CPI greater than (less than) the median survey forecast. Stddenotes the standard error ofCAMR, where the Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992) corrections are used.

    41

  • 8/4/2019 emp5

    42/42

    TABLE 10

    Estimates of the Constant Term (Non-Event Mean), MA, and GARCH Parameters for the

    PPI Inflation Event Regression Model with Macroeconomic Control Variables

    Coeff std p-value

    Constant 0.017 0.015 0.259

    PPI zero shock 0.163 0.126 0.196

    Leading indicator 0.081 0.125 0.518

    CPI(3) -0.001 0.343 0.997

    CPI(2) -0.553 0.373 0.137

    CPI(1) -0.779 0.362 0.031

    CPI(0) -1.071 0.324 0.001

    CPI(-1) -0.280 0.341 0.411

    CPI(-2) -0.371 0.313 0.237

    CPI(-3) 0.262 0.322 0.415

    CPI zero shock 0.133 0.077 0.085

    Housing starts 0.637 0.580 0.272

    Personal income 0.040 0.183 0.829

    Industrial production 0.099 0.145 0.495Durable goods: New orders -0.011 0.016 0.483

    Retail sales -0.106 0.069 0.125

    Trade balance 0.044 0.025 0.073

    Unemployment 0.302 0.323 0.349

    AR(1) 0.036 0.013 0.006

    Variance equation

    C 0.012 0.002 0.000

    RESID(-1)2 0.019 0.008 0.019

    RESID(-1)2*(RESID(-1)