econometrics amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.obtain point...

86
Econometrics A Handout 6: IV Estimation and its Limitations Weak Instruments and Weakly Endogenous Regressors Laura Mayoral IAE and BGSE February 2020

Upload: others

Post on 29-May-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Econometrics AHandout 6: IV Estimation and its Limitations

Weak Instruments and Weakly Endogenous Regressors

Laura Mayoral

IAE and BGSE

February 2020

0-0

Page 2: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Roadmap

1. Deviations from the standard framework:

Irrelevant and weak instruments

Endogeneous and weakly endogeneous regressors

2. Testing for deviations from the standard framework

Testing the exclusion restrictions: J-test of overidentification

Detection of weak instruments

Inference robust to weak instruments

0-1

Page 3: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

General advice for a good implementation ofIV methods

The following is a list of the steps you should follow for acorrect implementation of IV techniques

The literature is still under construction– in a few years thislist can become obsolete!

Each of the steps in this list is explained in this handout,

see also Murray 2006 and references throughout this handout.

0-2

Page 4: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

General advice for a good implementation ofIV methods

(See Murray, 2006)

1. Check the significance and estimated signs of the instrumentsin the troublesome variables reduced form and in the dependentvariables reduced form for consistency with the instruments ratio-nale.

2. Avoid bad instruments. Build a case for the validity of the in-strument, using the nine strategies described and illustrated below.

3. Test for weak instruments using Stock-Yogo critical values(Stock and Yogo (2004)). If weakness is not rejected, proceedto (4). If weakness is rejected, either turn to 2SLS or, preferably,proceed to (4).

0-3

Page 5: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

4. Conduct hypothesis tests using the conditional likelihood ratio(CLR) test (Moreira (2003)) or its robust variants.

5. Build confidence intervals based on the CLR test or its robustvariants.

6. Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using 2SLS.

7. You can also check how robust your results are to violations ofthe exclusion restriction by using Conley (2012) approach

8. Interpret the IV results with care.

Most of the tests/estimation procedures above can be imple-mented in STATA using ivreg2. See also additional commandsmentioned below.

0-4

Page 6: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

1. The standard IV framework

Consider the following model

y = xβ + ε; (1)

x = zΠ + v; (2)

corr(ε, v) 6= 0 (3)

The IV setup:

• x is endogenous since corr(ε, v) 6= 0

• Unless otherwise stated it’s assumed throughout that z isexogenous (E(z′ε) = 0)

• Without loss of generality, we omit exogenous regressors (ifthey exist, they can be partialled out)

0-5

Page 7: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

1.1. Violations to the IV set up: Irrelevant instruments

Recall that if there is just one IV then

β̂iv = β +̂cov(z, y)̂cov(z,x)

If cov(z,x) = 0 −→ z is irrelevant.

General case (more instruments): if E(z′x) = 0 −→ z is irrele-vant.

Using the notation above: Π = 0 −→ z is irrelevant

0-6

Page 8: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Irrelevant instruments, II

What happens when z is irrelevant?

β̂2sls is not identified.

β̂2sls is inconsistent (we knew this already!)

The distribution of (β̂2sls − β) is Cauchy-like

The bias of β̂2sls tends to that of β̂ols: The distribution of β̂2slsis centered around the plim(β̂ols).

0-7

Page 9: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

1.2. Weak instruments

Recall that if there is just one IV then

β̂2sls = β +̂cov(z, y)̂cov(z,x)

If cov(z,x) > 0 but close to zero: z is weak.

Why? if ̂cov(z,x) is close to zero −→, the bias of β̂2sls will bevery large!

0-8

Page 10: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Weak instruments, consequences

Although strictly speaking the conditions for consistency ofβ̂2sls are met (since E(x′z) 6= 0) standard asymptotic theory yieldvery poor approximation to the finite-sample distributions wheninstruments are weak.

The main problem derives from the fact that the finite-sampledistribution is very different from the asymptotic one (and remem-ber that 2SLS’s justification is asymptotic!).

As a result β̂2sls is weakly identified, (i.e., its distribution is notwell approximated by their standard asymptotic distribution).

0-9

Page 11: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Consequences, II

The source of the problem is not small-sample problems in aconventional sense, but rather, limited information, (see Bound etal. 1995).

To evaluate how severe is the weak instrument problem, weneed to have analytical expressions that approximate better thefinite sample properties of the estimators when instruments areweak.

0-10

Page 12: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Analytical approximations to the finite sample distribu-tions of IV estimators when instruments are weak

Different approaches:

Approach 1: Assume errors are normal and z is fix. Then wecan derive the exact distribution

Define:

µ2 = Π′z′zΠ/σ2v

µ2: concentration parameter, is a measure of the strength ofthe instruments.

(Recall that σ2v is the variance of v, defined in the linear projectionof x on z.)

(more specifically µ2: it measures the share of the variance of xexplained by z –normalised by the variance of v–).

0-11

Page 13: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Nelson and Startz (1990) show that

µ(β̂2sls − β) = Λ

µ plays the role that is usually played by√N (sample size).

If µp−→ ∞: instruments are strong, Λ is the usual normal dis-

tribution

If µ is small: then Λ is not standard and estimates will be verybiased.

0-12

Page 14: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

How big is the bias? VERY big if µ is small.

The following graph plots Λ for different values of µ

In this example: β = 0, ρ = .95 is the degree of endogeneity(correlation between the endogeneous regressor and the innova-tion).

0-13

Page 15: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-14

Page 16: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Approach 2: Weak instrument asymptotics

Approach 1 is developed under very demanding assumptions:normality, fixed z.

Staiger and Stock (1997): showed that very similar resultscan be obtained (i.e., same distribution of β, Λ) under generalconditions (z not fixed, errors non normal).

0-15

Page 17: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Approach 2: Weak instrument asymptotics, II

Their approach: assume Π = ΠN = C/√

(N), where N is thenumber of obs., such that

y = xβ0 + ε; (4)

x = zΠ + v; (5)

Π = ΠN = C/√

(N) (6)

corr(ε, v) 6= 0 (7)

estimate β and compute the asymptotic distribution of β underΠ = ΠN = C/

√(N)

−→ weak instrument asymptotics.

0-16

Page 18: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Weak instrument asymptotics

As mentioned before, weak instruments should not be thoughtof a finite sample problem!

Staiger and Stock show that:

for each sample size (even for a very large one) there will existsome values of correlation between the instrument and the regres-sor such that the quality of normal approximation is poor

0-17

Page 19: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

What’s the meaning Π = ΠN = C/√

(N)?

This is a just ’trick’ to obtain analytical expressions that ap-proximate the distribution in finite samples in a better way.

That is, we don’t really believe that Π = ΠN = C/√

(N), but itis useful to assume this setup.

Why?

0-18

Page 20: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Why?

We saw before that for any Π arbitrarily close to zero (but > 0),standard asymptotic theory will not be informative as the limitedinformation problem will be eventually overcome by an infinite sam-ple size.

This solution is not satisfactory as we never have such a thing!

By choosing Π = ΠN = C/√

(N), µ2 remains constant as thesample size increases (rather than going to ∞ as it would for afix Π > 0 as the sample size increases) (so the weak instrumentsproblem remains even if N −→∞)

In this case

µ2 = Π′z′zΠ/σ2v = C′(z′z/N)C/σ2v

which will converge to a constant as N increases.

0-19

Page 21: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Summary of weak IV asymptotic results (Staiger andStock, 1997).

β̂2sls is not consistent and non-normal

The analytical expressions obtained under weak IV asymptotics:provide very good approximations of the finite sample distributionswhen the correlation between the instruments and the endogenousregressor is small.

Test statistics (including J-test of overindentifying restrictions)do not have standard distributions.

0-20

Page 22: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Summary of weak IV asymptotic results, II.

Bias of β̂12sls :

If z is irrelevant (E(Z’X)=0) −→ β̂2sls is centered around theplim(β̂ols)

Note. Remember [plimβ̂ols = β +E(X ′X)−1E(X ′ε)]

If z is weak: the bias of β̂2sls tends to the bias of β̂ols

0-21

Page 23: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

1.3. Violations to the exclusion condition: Setup

Let’s now consider violations to the exclusion restriction

Setup

y = xβ + ε; (8)

x = zΠ + v; (9)

ε = zγ + ε∗ (10)

corr(ε∗, v) 6= 0 (11)

Unless otherwise stated, assume z is strong i.e. Π 6= 0 and islarge.

If γ 6= 0 −→ z is endogenous, (exclusion restriction is violated)

0-22

Page 24: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Endogeneous instruments, consequences

β is not consistent.

The bias (1 endogenous variable, 1 instrument):

β̂2sls − βp−→

cov(z, ε)

cov(z,x)=γ

Π

Very important:

Any correlation between z an ε will be magnified if the correla-tion between z and x is small (i.e., if Π is small)

0-23

Page 25: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

An example: Estimating the causal effect of yearsof education on lifetime earnings, Angrist and Krueger(1991).

Education is likely to be endogenous. Why?

Omitted variable: innate ability.

More talented people will tend to remain in school longer.

Also, more talented people will tend to earn more money.

Angrist and Krueger (1991)’s approach: use “quarter of birth”as IV.

0-24

Page 26: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Their argument: US compulsory schooling laws are in terms ofage, not number of years of schooling completed. If compulsoryschooling age is 16, you can drop out on your 16th birthday (evenif in the middle of the school year).

School entry is once a year, and cutoffs are based on birthdays.Beginning school: kids that are 6 years olds by Sep. 1st

The combination of these two generates variation in schoolingfor those who drop out as soon as they can.

Consider two students, one born on August 31st and anotherborn on Sep. 1st: by the time they turn 16, the second has had 1additional year of education.

0-25

Page 27: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Instrument validity

Do birthdays satisfy the exclusion restriction, or could birthdaysbe correlated with earnings for other reasons than their effect onschooling?

Birthday affects, e.g., age rank in class?.

Do birthdays indeed affect schooling? −→ Check the first stage.

0-26

Page 28: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Angrist and Krueger data

Huge dataset.

Data are from the 1980 US Census. 329,509 men born 1930 to1939 (i.e. in their 40s when observed). For these men we haveyear of birth, quarter of birth, years of schooling, and earnings in1979.

0-27

Page 29: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Do birthdays satisfy the exclusion restriction?,

Bound, Jaeger and Baker (1995): argue that z might not beexogenous:

Some evidence that quarter of birth is related to school atten-dance rates, performance in reading, maths, etc.

Differences in physical and mental health of individuals born indifferent times of the year.

Key point:

Although the correlation between z and ε is likely to be small,it gets magnified by the very small correlation between quarter ofbirth and education!!.

As a result, the bias can be very large.

0-28

Page 30: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Bound et al: used Angrist and Krueger data but instead ofusing the actual quarter of birth, they randomly assigned a quarterof birth to each observation.

This ’random’ quarter of birth is exogenous but also, totallyuncorrelated with education.

However, the results using this instrument were very similarthan those obtained with the true quarter of birth!

Nothing in the second stage regression could suggest that thenew Z was totally irrelevant!

Another important point: the weak instrument problem wasimportant even if the sample size was huge!!

0-29

Page 31: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Many weak instruments

Angrist and Krueger used as instruments the interactions be-tween quarter of birth and year of birth and quarter of birth andstate of birth.

Adding many weak instruments makes the problem even worse:the F statistic of the first stage gets smaller −→the bias gets worse.

The next three tables are from Bound et al..

The first table shows that by increasing the number of (weak)instruments, the F statistic that tests the joint significance of theinstruments in the the first stage decreases.

0-30

Page 32: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-31

Page 33: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Table 2: many weak instruments –contains instruments basedon quarter of birth interacted with state of birth and year of birth.

Table 3: uses the randomly generated quarters of birth (i.e.,all instruments are irrelevant).

Compare Tables 1/2 with 3: just by looking at the secondstage regression you won’t be able to detect that instruments areirrelevant: both tables look similar!

but the first stage shows that the regressions are problematic–look at the F’s!

Notice that the OLS estimates and those obtained with irrele-vant instruments are very similar, as the theory predicts.

0-32

Page 34: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-33

Page 35: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-34

Page 36: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Weakly endogeneous regressors

In practice, it is very likely that z and ε have some correlation.

Thus, as before, it is useful to study local violations to theexclusion restriction

Set up

y = xβ + ε; (12)

x = zΠ + v; (13)

ε = zγ + ε∗ (14)

γ = γn = B/√

(N) (15)

corr(ε∗, v) 6= 0 (16)

0-35

Page 37: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Interpretation:

We don’t believe that γ is as described,

this is just a trick to find analytical expressions to the finitesample distributions under mild violations of the endogeneity re-striction (and it works very well!).

0-36

Page 38: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Summary of asymptotic results under endogeneity of Z

1. Recall that γ 6= 0 −→ β̂2sls is not consistent

2. But if γ = γn = B/√

(N), β̂2sls is consistent!

3. Asymptotic distribution of β̂2sls is normal with the same variance-covariance matrix but centered on a ’wrong’ value.

T 1/2(β̂2sls − β0)d→ N(

B

Π,

σ2εΠ2E(Z′Z)

) (17)

0-37

Page 39: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Some implications

Under mild violations of the exclusion restriction: point esti-mates might still be ok! (IF sample size is large, estimates arestrong and violation is mild!!)

Inference is wrong even under mild violations: we’ll tend toreject the null hypothesis of no significance too often when it istrue (size is wrong).

If B is small relative to Π: the bias will be small.

If we knew B or (it could be consistently estimated), we couldcorrect the distribution and use it to obtain valid inference.

But B cannot be consistently estimated!

An alternative approach: Conley et al. (2012)

0-38

Page 40: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Plausibly exogeneous, Conley et al. (2012)

Main idea: Relax the exclusion restriction by adopting a Bayesianapproach

Set up

y = xβ + zγ + ε; (18)

x = zΠ + v; (19)

corr(ε, v) 6= 0 (20)

where x can contain various endogenous regressors (s) and z con-tains r instruments (r≥ s).

0-39

Page 41: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Plausibly exogeneous, II

Bayesian approach: incorporate beliefs about γ

The IV exclusion restriction is equivalent to the dogmatic beliefthat γ = 0.

New belief: γ is close to zero, but maybe not identical to zero.

To implement this technique in STATA: ssc install plausexog

0-40

Page 42: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Plausibly exogeneous, III

4 inference strategies that use prior information about γ

1. The research specifies the support of γ.

2 and 3: The research specifies some prior information aboutthe distribution of γ

and 4: Full Bayesian approach, with priors over all parameters.

Their strategy allows to compute confidence intervals for βconditional on any potential value of γ

This allows to evaluate the robustness to deviations from theexclusion restriction.

0-41

Page 43: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Example (from Conley et al.,)

Price elasticity of Demand for margarine.

log(share) = βlog(retailprice) + controls+ vt

Instrument: log wholesale prices. Why? they should primar-ily vary in response to cost shocks and be less sensitive to retaildemand shocks than retail prices.

The following picture shows that there can be substantial vi-olations of the exclusion restriction and the estimates won’t varymuch.

δ measures how large is the deviation from the exclusion re-striction (i.e., δ = 0 −→ exclusion restriction holds). Its precisedefinition varies depending on the method employed.

0-42

Page 44: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-43

Page 45: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-44

Page 46: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Example 2: Returns to schooling

Data from Angrist and Krueger (1991), 300.000+ observations

log(wagei) = β1educationi + controls+ ui

Conley use some of Bound’s arguments/calculations to set uppriors for the parameters.

0-45

Page 47: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-46

Page 48: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-47

Page 49: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Last remark:

The stronger the instruments, the more robust your estimateswill be to deviations from the exclusion restriction

Since the strength of the instruments is something that can beevaluated (as opposed to the “exogeneity”) is important to haveinstruments as strong as possible!

0-48

Page 50: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

What you should do in practice?

[Advice from Mostly Harmless...]

• Report the first stage and think about whether it makes sense.Are the magnitude and sign as you would expect?

• Report the F-statistics on the excluded instruments. Thebigger it is the better. Use a proper test

• Pick your best single instrument and report just-identified es-timates using this one only. Just-identified IV is approximatelymedian-unbiased

• Check over-identified 2SLS estimates with LIML. If the LIMLestimates are very different, or standard errors are much big-ger, worry.

See also Murray (2006) for more practical advice!

0-49

Page 51: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

2. Testing for deviations from the standardframework

Detection of weak instruments

Inference robust to weak instruments

Software: ivreg2 (STATA)

Examples

0-50

Page 52: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Testing for deviations from the standardframework

Testing for the failure of the exclusion restriction: notpossible to test, unless the model is overidentified (i.e., thereare more instruments that endogenous variables), but strongassumptions are needed (basically you need to assume whatyou want to test!)

Testing for the failure of the relevance condition/weakinstruments: different tests are available, most of them basedon the F statistic of the null hypothesis that Π = 0 in the firststage.

0-51

Page 53: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Detection of weak instruments

0-52

Page 54: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Detection of weak instruments

Two types of test

Tests of underidentification: test whether instruments areirrelevant (Π=0)

Tests of weak identification: test whether instrument areweak.

Always interpret tests of underidentification with caution:

if you reject underidentification, it can still be the casethat your model is only weakly identified since instrumentsare weak.

0-53

Page 55: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Detection of weak instruments, II

Goal: determine when instruments are irrelevant (test ofunder identification) or weak (tests of weak identification).

For the 1 endogenous variable case, consider the reduced-form regression

X = ZΠ +Wδ + v

where W are exogenous regressors.

0-54

Page 56: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Using F to test for weak instruments

The concentration parameter µ2 = Π′Z′ZΠ/σ2v is closelyrelated to the F statistic associated to testing H0 : Π = 0.

More specifically (under conditional homoscedasticity) F '1+ µ2/K, where K is the number of instruments.

weak instruments −→ a low value of µ2 −→ a low value ofF.

But: this relation relies heavily on the assumption of con-ditional homoscedasticity of the error term.

0-55

Page 57: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Staiger and Stock’s rule of thumb

Staiger and Stock (1997) showed that the weak instru-ment problem can arise even if the hypothesis of Π = 0 isrejected at standard t-tests at conventional significance lev-els.

Staiger and Stock’s Rule of thumb (1 endogenous vari-able):

Reject that your instruments are weak if F≥10,

where F is the F-statistic testing Π=0 in the regression of yon Z and W (where W are the exogenous regressors includedin the equation of interest).

0-56

Page 58: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Stock and Yogo (2005)’s bias and size methods

Stock and Yogo (SY, 2005) formalise Staiger and Stock’sprocedure.

They show that their rule of thumb is not always enough!(see below)

SY’s tests can be used with multiple endogenous regres-sors and multiple instruments.

0-57

Page 59: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

How weak is weak?

We need a cutoff value for µ2 such that for values smallerthan µ2, instruments are deemed to be weak.

Since (under conditional homoscedasticity) the F statisticof the first stage regression and µ2 are related, the cutoff valueis usually compared with it.

There are different ways in which we can define this cutoffvalue, depending what we want to control (bias of β, size oft-test), etc.

The value of the cutoff depends on the method employed.

This means that the same instrument can be weak for oneestimation method but not for other!

2SLS is one of the least robust

0-58

Page 60: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

How weak is weak, II

Stock and Yogo propose two methods to select the cut-offs:

The bias method: find a cutoff value for µ2 such that therelative bias of the 2SLS with respect to OLS doesn’t exceedcertain quantity.

The size method: find a cutoff value for µ2 such that themaximal size of a Wald test of all the elements of β doesn’texceed a certain amount.

0-59

Page 61: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Stock and Yogo (2005)’s bias method

Let µ210%bias

be the value of µ2 such that if µ2 ≥ µ210%bias

,the maximum bias of the 2SLS estimator will be no morethan 10% of the bias of OLS.

Decision rule is (5% significance level )

Reject that your instruments are weak if F > J10(k),

where J10(k) is chosen such that P (F > J10(k);µ2 = µ210%bias

) =0.05

0-60

Page 62: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Stock and Yogo (2005)’s bias method, II

Test statistic:

1 endogenous regressor: computed using F from the firststage regression.

more than 1 endogenous regressor: Cragg- Donald (1993)statistic (multivariate version of the F statistic).

Stock and Yogo (2005) provide critical values that dependon

the number of endogenous regressors,

the number of instruments,

the maximum bias.

The estimation procedure (2SLS, LIML, ...)

ivreg2 (STATA): gives you the critical values.

0-61

Page 63: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Stock and Yogo (2005)’s size method

Similar logic but instead of controlling bias, control thesize of a Wald test of β=β0

Use F statistic first stage if 1 endogenous regressor orCragg-Donald if more than 1

Decision rule:

Reject weak instruments if statistic is larger than the crit-ical value

Have a look at the critical values (and compare to Staigerand Stock’s rule of thumb!)

0-62

Page 64: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-63

Page 65: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

 

0-64

Page 66: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Detecting weak instruments, final commentsAs mentioned before, the logic of using the first-stage

using the F statistics relies heavily on the assumption of con-ditional homoscedasticity.

Solution: ongoing research

Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald statistic: ivreg2 reports this testas a test for weak instruments when robust options are calledfor.

However, this test is not formally justified in the contextof weak instruments.

It is justified in the case of under identification and if errorsare i.i.d., it becomes the Cragg-Donald test (but not underweak instruments!).

0-65

Page 67: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Olea Montiel and Pflueger (2013) and (2014): tests validunder heteroskedasticity, autocorrelation, and clus- tering ro-bust weak instrument tests, for 2SLS and LIML.

But only applicable if there is only 1 endogenous regressor.

Stata: weakivtest (you need to install the package first).

See also Andrews 2014

0-66

Page 68: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Angrist and Pischke (2009) introduced first-stage F statis-tics for tests of under- and weak identification when there ismore than one endogenous regressor.

In contrast to the Cragg-Donald and Kleibergen-Paap statis-tics, which test the identification of the equation as a whole,the AP first-stage F statistics are tests of whether one of theendogenous regressors is under- or weakly identified.

0-67

Page 69: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Inference methods robust to weak instru-ments

Problem: is it still possible to test hypothesis about β ifinstruments are weak?

YES!

But, why do you want to do that?

If you know your instruments are weak, you should lookfor better instruments!

But there are cases where the literature on weak IV de-tection is still limited (non i.i.d. errors for instance) so maybeyou don’t know.

0-68

Page 70: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Two approaches to improving inference:

Fully robust methods: Inference that is valid for any valueof the concentration parameter (including zero!), at least ifthe sample size is large, under weak instrument asymptotics.

For tests: asymptotically correct size (and good power!)

For confidence intervals: asymptotically correct coveragerates

Partially robust methods: Methods are less sensitive toweak instruments than 2SLS (e.g. bias is “small” for a“large” range of values of µ2 )

0-69

Page 71: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Fully Robust Testing

Results are much more developed for the case of 1 en-dogenous regressor

If more than 1 endogenous regressor: still an open econo-metric problem.

The model (1 endogenous regressor).

y = xβ + ε

where x is (a scalar) and endogenous, Z is a matrix of instru-ments, maybe weak. We want to test H0 : β = β0.

0-70

Page 72: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Two approaches

Approach 1: use a statistic whose distribution does notdepend on µ2

Two statistics here: The Anderson-Rubin (1949) test andLM statistic (Moreira 2002 and Kleiberger 2002).

Approach 2: Use statistics whose distribution depends onµ2, but compute the critical values as a function of anotherstatistic that is sufficient for µ2 under the null hypothesis.

Conditional likelihood ratio test (Moreira 2003).

Both approaches have advantages and disadvantages. Wediscuss both.

0-71

Page 73: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Tests robust to Weak instruments: Approach 1

The Anderson-Rubin test

Set up: y = Xβ + ε, X endogenous, Z is a matrix (N × k) ofinstruments. We want to test H0 : β = β0.

AR’s test: F test in the regression of (y−Xβ0) on Z.

AR(β0) =(y−Xβ0)′Pz/(y−Xβ0)/k(y−Xβ0)′Mz(y−Xβ0)

/(N − k)

where Pz = Z′(Z′Z)−1Z and Mz = I − Pzunder H0, y−Xβ0 = ε, so (if ε is iid)

AR(β0) =ε′Pzε/k

ε′Mzε/(N − k)d−→ χ2

k/k

0-72

Page 74: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Advantages and disadvantages of AR

Advantages

Easy to use (entirely regression based)

Uses standard F critical values (asymptotic distributiondoesn’t depend on µ2

Works for m > 1 (more than 1 endogenous regressor).

Disadvantages

Difficult to interpret: rejection arises for two reasons: H0

is false or Z is endogenous!

Power loss relative to other tests (we shall see)

Is not efficient if instruments are strong –under stronginstruments, not as powerful as TSLS Wald test—.

0-73

Page 75: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Approach 1, cont. Kleibergen’s (2002) LM test

Kleibergen developed an LM test that has a null distribu-tion that is also χ2

1 (doesn’t depend on µ2)

Advantages

Fairly easy to implement

Is efficient if instruments are strong

Disadvantages

Has very strange power properties (power function isn’tmonotonic)

Its power is dominated by the conditional likelihood ratiotest

0-74

Page 76: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Tests robust to Weak instruments. Ap-proach 2: Conditional maximum likelihoodtests

Recall your probability and statistics courses:

Let S be a statistic with a distribution that depends on θ

Let T be a sufficient statistic for θ

Then the distribution of S|T does not depend on θ

0-75

Page 77: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Conditional maximum likelihood tests

Moreira (2003):

LR will be a statistic testing β = β0 (LR is “S” in notationabove)

QT will be sufficient for µ2 under the null (QT is “T”)

Thus the distribution of LR|QT does not depend on µ2

under the null

Thus valid inference can be conducted using the quantilesof LR|QT ; that is, using critical values that are a function ofQT

Implementation: condivreg (STATA)

0-76

Page 78: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Advantages

More powerful than AR or LM

Disadvantages

More complicated to explain and write down

Only developed (so far) for a single included endogenousregressor

As written, the software requires homoskedastic errors;extensions to heteroskedasticity and serial correlation havebeen developed but are not in common statistical software

0-77

Page 79: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Constructing confidence intervals

It is possible to construct confidence intervals for β byinverting the robust tests described above.

How?

Test all the hypotheses of the form H0 : β = β0 for differentvalues of β0

Examine the set of values for which H0 could not be re-jected.

Inverting the AR test: see Dufour and Taamouti (2005).

0-78

Page 80: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Inverting the Conditional test: see Mikusheva (2005)–only available for 1 endogenous regressor.

the CI based on conditional test is more efficient thanthat based on AR.

Extensions: More than 1 endogenous regressor.

This literature is still very incomplete

Kleiberger (2007) provides an extension of the AR testwhen the interest in testing a joint hypotheses on β.

0-79

Page 81: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Partially Robust Estimators

Estimation under weak instruments is much harder thantesting or confidence intervals

Estimation must be divorced from confidence intervals(ie., use robust methods!).

k-class estimators

β̂ = [X ′(I − k∗MZX)−1[X ′(I − k∗MZ)y]

2SLS: k∗ = 1

LIML: k∗ = kliml (smallest root of some matrix A)

Fuller: k∗ = kliml−H, (where H is a function of exogenousregressors)

0-80

Page 82: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Under strong instruments, LIML, 2SLS and Fuller will besimilar

Under weak instruments, 2SLS has greater bias and largerMSE

LIML has the advantage of minimizing the AR statistic–thus, will be always contained in the AR (and CLR) confi-dence set.

These properties make LIML be a reasonable good choiceas an alternative to 2SLS

0-81

Page 83: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Take away

When applying IV estimation:

1. Always test formally for weak instruments (but be awarefrom the limitations of the existing theory)

2. Divorce estimation and testing (i.e., it’s not enough totest the significance of β using the standard errors of theestimators.)

3. Conduct hypothesis testing using the conditional likelihoodratio (CLR) test or its robust variants.

4. Build confidence intervals based on CLR.

0-82

Page 84: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Testing the exclusion restriction: J testsof overidentifying restrictions

0-83

Page 85: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

Testing the exclusion restriction: J testsof overidentifying restrictions

In an exactly identified model we cannot test the hypoth-esis that the instrument is valid, i.e. that the exclusion re-striction is a valid one−→ the assumption that the instrumentis valid will essentially have to be taken on faith.

See Murray (2005, 2006) for tips that will help you tomotivate this “faith”

If the model is overidentified, it’s possible to test for thevalidity of the overidentifying restrictions.

Strong assumption: you need to assume that a set ofinstruments (enough to identify the parameters) are valid andyou can test whether the remaining ones are also one.

0-84

Page 86: Econometrics Amayoral.iae-csic.org › econometrics_insead20 › handout6.pdf · 6.Obtain point estimates using Fullers estimators with a = 1 or 4 (Fuller (1977)) rather than using

If you reject the null that the remaining instruments areexogenous: there is something wrong in your model–you needto reconsider the validity of the instruments

But not rejecting the null doesn’t mean that your instru-ments are valid!!

Sargan test: you don’t need to specify which instrumentsare the valid ones and which are the dubious ones.

But still, you need as least G instruments that are valid!(G=number of endogenous variables). Otherwise the test isnot consistent.

0-85