dynamics and stability in retail competition

18
Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition Marcelo J. Villena and Axel A. Araneda * August 15, 2018 Faculty of Engineering & Sciences, Universidad Adolfo Ibáñez Avda. Diagonal las Torres 2640, Peñalolén, 7941169, Santiago, Chile. Retail competition today can be described by three main features: i) oligopolistic com- petition, ii) multi-store settings, and iii) the presence of large economies of scale. In these markets, firms usually apply a centralized decisions making process in order to take full advantage of economies of scales, e.g. retail distribution centers. In this paper, we model and analyze the stability and chaos of retail competition considering all these issues. In particular, a dynamic multi-market Cournot-Nash equilibrium with global economies and diseconomies of scale model is developed. We confirm the non-intuitive hypothesis that retail multi-store competition is more unstable that traditional small business that cover the same demand. The main sources of stability are the scale parameter and the number of markets. Keywords: Multi-market Oligopoly, Cournot-Nash competition, Economies of Scale, Stability, Bifurcations, and Chaos. 1 Introduction In an oligopolistic setting under a Cournot scheme [1], the strategy of each economic player depends on its own quantity decision, and on its rival’s reaction. Puu was the first to explicitly show the complex dynamics of the oligopolistic setting under simple assumptions (isoelastic demand function and constant marginal cost) for two and three players [2–4]. This kind of analysis has grown significantly during the last decade in both, the mathematics and complex systems literature, as well as in the economically-oriented journals. Indeed, since the Puu’s approach, several games has been developed for the study of the market stability, focusing on: different demand or price function [5, 6], number of players [7, 8], behavioral assumptions (naive [9–11], versus adaptive [12, 13], bounded rationality [6, 14, 15] or heterogeneous expectations [16–19]). In terms of the cost function definition, several developments has been proposed as well, as non-linear cost function [6, 13, 15, 19, 20], capacity constraints |[13, 21–23] and some spillover effects [24–27]. * Email: [email protected], Tel.: +56 2 23311416 arXiv:1510.04550v2 [q-fin.EC] 17 Mar 2016

Upload: others

Post on 01-Jan-2022

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

Marcelo J. Villena and Axel A. Araneda∗

August 15, 2018

Faculty of Engineering & Sciences, Universidad Adolfo IbáñezAvda. Diagonal las Torres 2640, Peñalolén, 7941169, Santiago, Chile.

Retail competition today can be described by three main features: i) oligopolistic com-petition, ii) multi-store settings, and iii) the presence of large economies of scale. In thesemarkets, firms usually apply a centralized decisions making process in order to take fulladvantage of economies of scales, e.g. retail distribution centers. In this paper, we modeland analyze the stability and chaos of retail competition considering all these issues. Inparticular, a dynamic multi-market Cournot-Nash equilibrium with global economies anddiseconomies of scale model is developed. We confirm the non-intuitive hypothesis thatretail multi-store competition is more unstable that traditional small business that coverthe same demand. The main sources of stability are the scale parameter and the numberof markets.

Keywords: Multi-market Oligopoly, Cournot-Nash competition, Economies of Scale,Stability, Bifurcations, and Chaos.

1 IntroductionIn an oligopolistic setting under a Cournot scheme [1], the strategy of each economicplayer depends on its own quantity decision, and on its rival’s reaction. Puu was thefirst to explicitly show the complex dynamics of the oligopolistic setting under simpleassumptions (isoelastic demand function and constant marginal cost) for two and threeplayers [2–4]. This kind of analysis has grown significantly during the last decade in both,the mathematics and complex systems literature, as well as in the economically-orientedjournals.

Indeed, since the Puu’s approach, several games has been developed for the studyof the market stability, focusing on: different demand or price function [5, 6], numberof players [7, 8], behavioral assumptions (naive [9–11], versus adaptive [12, 13], boundedrationality [6, 14, 15] or heterogeneous expectations [16–19]). In terms of the cost functiondefinition, several developments has been proposed as well, as non-linear cost function[6, 13, 15, 19, 20], capacity constraints |[13, 21–23] and some spillover effects [24–27].

∗Email: [email protected], Tel.: +56 2 23311416

arX

iv:1

510.

0455

0v2

[q-

fin.

EC

] 1

7 M

ar 2

016

Page 2: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

Most works in this line of research have concentrated in single markets with linearproduction structures (i.e. assuming constant returns to scale). Nevertheless, oligopolis-tic competition today seems to present multi-market phenomena and, in some cases, theyshowcase important economies of scale, especially in the retail industry. Indeed, super-market chains and retailers of food, gasoline, supplies and services all compete for marketshare through multi-store formats over geographically separated markets. This localizedcompetition is presented in different levels: city, region, or country. In this context,companies segment their strategies, tailoring their selected outcome for different types ofconsumers and competitors, which vary by geographical location. On the other hand, onthe supply side, multi-market retailers usually try to take full advantages of their size, inother words, their economies of scale. For instance, through the development of distri-butions centers that attend most of the stores in an specific territory. Thus, as the coststructure of multi-market retails depends on the total volume of the produced goods, theindividual cost structure of each store is usually coupled with the whole business. It isimportant to point out that, this system of production, implies a centralized decisionsmaking process, which become in practice an extremely difficult task. Summing up, retailcompetition today can be described by three main features: i) oligopolistic competition,ii) multi-store setting, iii) the presence of economies of scale.

Applications of the Cournot scheme into the multi-market problem has been proposedbefore by economists, for example, in the case of international trade. Some of theseworks modeled the presence of economies of scale, for the domestic and foreign markets,considering the size (quantity produced) and other properties of firms [28–35]. Thus, forinstance in a work of Krugman [30], a multi-market Cournot model with economies ofscale was used to explain the successful performance of Japan as an exporting country atthe beginning of the 1980s.

In theoretical terms, the multi-market oligopoly framework was revisited and general-ized in the seminal paper by Bulow, Geanakoplos and Klemperer [36]. One of their mainremarks is that the presence of a multi-store firm in a market may affect the position inthe others for the presence of demand and/or supply spillovers. In the same line, Bern-heim and Whinston, [37], show that with scale economies, the multi-market contact mayproduce “spheres of influence” [38], that occurs when each of the multi-market competingfirms may be more efficient in some subset of these markets and less efficient in others(symmetric advantage) or when one firm is more efficient in all markets (absolute ad-vantage). Despite these multi-market analysis, this literature has focused mainly on thedemand side of the problem, not the supply side. Specifically, they refer to multi-marketcontact, when demands curves recognize substitution and complementarity of differentproducts.

In terms of the analysis of the dynamics of the multi-market Cournot problem, wefound only a few papers [39–42], focusing on different products and scope.

In this context, this research deals with the analysis of stability and chaos of multi-market competition in the presence of economies and diseconomies of scale, extending thisway the analysis of the dynamics of the oligopolistic competition. Thus, we model themain characteristics of the retail competition today, analysing the dynamics and stabilityof this particular dynamic system, and we compare these results with the stability analysisof traditional small business that cover the same demand, the classic Pu’s formulation.

The main hypothesis of the paper is that non-linear cost structures in multi-marketsetting are important sources of instability in the game outcome. Particularly, we study

2

Page 3: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

the stability of a multi-market Cournot-Nash equilibrium with global economies of scale,that is, the scale level that is related to the total production of firms, in all markets,as opposed to local economies of scale presented at each store individually or linearproduction structures. In this setting, the internal organization of a firm may affect itsperformances over the markets and the global equilibrium [43]. For example, multi-marketfirms that buy their products in a centralized manner, storing them in a distributioncenter, to be redistributed afterwards to their retailers store in all markets usually operatethis way to obtain economies of scale in the process of buying and distribution. In thispaper, we assume this type of centralized structure where companies takes advantage oftheir size, under economies of scale, that allow them to decrease the cost structure [44].

This papers is organized as follows: in section 2 classical models of the Cournotproblem are described and extended to the multi-market framework. In the section 3 aMulti-market-Cournot problem is presented, considering interrelated cost structures andeconomies of scale. In section 4, the study of the stability of the system is addressed andgeneralized for the duopoly case. In the fifth section, the complex dynamics of the gamefor different numbers markets and values of the scale parameter are shown by path graph-ics and bifurcation diagrams. Finally, the main conclusions for this work are presented.

2 Baseline: Single market oligopoly modelsThe well-known Cournot-Theocharis model [45–48] proposed a Cournot Oligopoly modelwith inverse lineal demand function and constant marginal cost, that is:

P = a−∑

qi (2.1)

Ci = ciqi (2.2)

where i = 1, . . . , N identify the player, P is the price of the good, C is the total cost andq is the quantity.

The profit is obtained subtracting the revenues by total cost:

πi = qiP(q1, . . . , qN

)− ciqi

The optimization problem (maximization of profit) arrives to:∗qi= a− ci

2 −∑k 6=i

qk

2 (2.3)

With solution (Cournot-Nash equilibrium point):

∗qi=

a− ci +N(c− ci

)N + 1

3

Page 4: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

with c = (1/N)∑

i ci

In order to transform the static game 2.3 into a dynamic one, the Cournot or naivestrategy is used (see Cournot [1] and Puu [2])1. Thus, the long run map as an iterativeprocess is given by:

qi(t+ 1) = a− ci

2 −∑k 6=i

qk(t)2 (2.4)

The dynamical system of N reaction functions defined by 2.4 has a stable equilibrium(fix point) for n ≤ 2 . For n = 3 the equilibrium is neutrally stable (stationary oscillations)and for n ≥ 4 the equilibrium becomes unstable.

A generalization of the Cournot-Theocharis problem was developed by Fisher [49].This research allows to work with increasing or decreasing returns to scale (i.e., economiesor diseconomies of scale). In order to get this result, we need to add a non-linear term tothe traditional linear cost function:

P = a−∑

i

qi

Ci = ciqi + d(qi)2

Thus, the profit takes the following form:

πi = qiP(q1, . . . , qN

)− ciqi − d

(qi)2 (2.5)

Some restrictions for avoiding non-negativity of outputs, price, profits and marginalcost are considered: c > 0, a ≥ c and d > −1/2.

Thus, the maximization of the profit (eq. 2.5) leads to the best response of the ith-firm:

∗qi=

a−∑k 6=i

qk − ci

2 (1 + d) (2.6)

Then, the Cournot-Nash equilibrium is given by:1In this strategy, it is assumed that a player at time of the decision making process, it takes into

account the rival’s previous output, e.g, managers use past information and supposes it doesn’t changeat this moment.

4

Page 5: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

(a− ci

)(1 + 2d) +N

(c− ci

)4d2 + 2 (N + 2) d+N + 1

Hence, the naive dynamics takes the form:

qi(t+ 1) =

a−∑k 6=i

qk(t)− ci

2 (1 + d) (2.7)

Finally, this dynamical system becomes stable when (N − 3) /2 < d . Thus, if thereare two players the game has a stable equilibrium if d > −1/2.

The approaches revised above (Teocharis and Fisher), were design to model a single-market oligopoly problem (for example the rivalry between “mom-and-pop” stores). Inthis case, both the prices and the costs don’t depends upon the behavior of the players inother markets, because they did not consider the case of large corporations, with multipleoperations in various locations.

In the next section, and taking as baseline the models presented above, we will developa multi-market Cournot model with economies of scale that will allow us to describe themodern retail competition.

3 The ModelLet us consider a multi-market oligopoly where N single-product firms compete in Mmarkets. All markets are very far away, so there not exist arbitrage possibilities. Eachmarket has its own price (from a linear demand function). Then, if qi

j is the quantity ofthe ith company at the market j and Qj the market supply, the selling price at the jth

market is given by,

Pj = aj −∑

i

qij = aj −Qj (3.1)

We assume a centralized managerial structure, where the production costs dependsof the total outputs of each firm. Besides, due both their size and specialization thecompany can have economies of scale. So we have:

Ci = ci∑

j

qij + d

∑j

qij

2

= ciQi + d(Qi)2 (3.2)

with ci greater than zero. Depending of the value of d the companies operates undereconomies of scale (d < 0) or diseconomies of scale (d > 0). The allowable range for theparameter d will be analyzed later.

5

Page 6: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

The square form of the production cost was used previously for other scholars in asingle-market context [6, 49–51]. However, for this multi-market scheme we use the non-linearity for to couple the costs and to enable the existence of economies (diseconomies)of scale. This is a realistic approach for the retails firms, because they produce or buy inlarge scale.

Under this cost structure, ci > 0 and dQimax > −ci/2 , where Qi

max is the maximumlevel of production of firm i. The theoretical maximum production (extreme case) isachieved when a company becomes a monopoly in all the markets (i.e. Qj = qi

j ,∀j). AsPj ≥ 0, we have

∑j aj > Qi

max, and then we have 2d > ci/∑

j aj .Thus the profit function of each firm depends upon each market price, the quantity

sold by the firm in that particular market, and the total cost of the firm, that considersthe sum of the global cost and the local cost:

πi =∑

j

qijPj − Ci (3.3)

=∑

j

qij

(aj − bj

∑i

qij

)− ciQi − d

(Qi)2 (3.4)

The managerial decision of each firm is to choose the quantity qij that maximizes its

profits. In other words, the ith company which produces a total output of Qi divided overthe M different markets according to the output vector Qi =

{qi

1, qi2, . . . , q

iM ,}needs to

fix the optimal allocation given by∗Qi=

{ ∗qi

1,∗qi

2, . . . ,∗qi

M

}, where each one of the

∗qi

j is asolution of theM×N simultaneous equations which comprising the first order conditionsof this game given by:

∂πi

∂qij

= aj −Qj − qij − ci − 2dQi = 0 (3.5)

Defining the residual market supply for i as Qij = Qj − qi

j , and the participation ofthe firm i in other markets different to j as Qi

j = Qi − qij , the equilibrium quantity take

the value:

∗qi

j=aj − Qi

j − ci − 2dQij

2 (1 + d) (3.6)

Clearly, the allocation decision depends on the decision of the other players on thismarket, and also depends on the participation of the firm in other markets (or the totalfirm supply). This results is consistent with the Cournot intuition and consistent toprevious results for the single-market problem2 [20, 49, 52].

2When Qi = 0

6

Page 7: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

In order to keep the game on rails, we have that∗qi

j is a maximum if and only if d > −1.Also the marginal profit for zero output must be non-negative [49], so aj ≥ ci,∀i. Thisconditions joined with the previous restrictions arrives to:

d > − 12m (3.7)

The profit of each firm at the equilibrium point is given by:

πi =∑

j

( ∗qi

j

)2

+ d

∑j

∗qi

j

2 (3.8)

The Jacobian matrix at the equilibrium is given by:

J =

∂∗Q1

∂Q1∂∗Q1

∂Q2 · · ·∂∗Q1

∂QN

∂∗Q2

∂Q1∂∗Q2

∂Q2 · · ·∂∗Q2

∂QN

... . . . ...

∂∗QN

∂Q1∂∗QN

∂Q2 · · ·∂∗QN

∂QN

(3.9)

where each one of the N ×N entries of J is a M ×M block matrix, that represents thechange of the i-firm’s reaction functions with respect to the outputs of j, with:

∂∗Qi

∂Qk=

∂∗q

i

1∂qk

1

∂∗q

i

1∂qk

2· · · ∂

∗q

i

1∂qk

M

∂∗q

i

2∂qk

1

∂∗q

i

2∂qk

2· · · ∂

∗q

i

2∂qk

M... . . . ...∂∗q

i

M

∂qk1

∂∗q

i

M

∂qk2· · · ∂

∗q

i

M

∂qkM

(3.10)

According to our optimal outputs (Eq. 3.6), we have:

∂∗Qi

∂Qk={− 1

2(1+d)IM×M , for i 6= j

H , for i = j(3.11)

where I is the identity matrix and H is a zero-diagonal matrix with all the off-diagonalentries equal to −d/(1 + d).

7

Page 8: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

4 Dynamic Analysis of the EquilibriumFor the dynamic modeling, we use naive expectations. Thus, the game is developed ondiscrete time as follow3:

qij(t+ 1) =

aj − Qij(t)− ci − 2dQi(t)

2 (1 + d) (4.1)

When there are two players competing over M different markets, the long-run mapproposed in 4.1 is defining for the following 2m equations:

q11(t+ 1) =

a1 − q21(t)− c1 − 2d

(q1

2(t) + q13(t) + . . .+ q1

M (t))

2 (1 + d) (4.2)

......

q1j (t+ 1) =

aj − q2j (t)− c1 − 2d

(q1

1(t) + . . .+ q1j−1(t) + q1

j+1(t) . . .+ q1M (t)

)2 (1 + d)

......

q1M (t+ 1) =

aM − q2M (t)− c1 − 2d

(q1

1(t) + q13(t) + . . .+ q1

M−1(t))

2 (1 + d)

q21(t+ 1) =

a1 − q11(t)− c2 − 2d

(q2

2(t) + q23(t) + . . .+ q2

M (t))

2 (1 + d)...

...

q2j (t+ 1) =

aj − q1j (t)− c2 − 2d

(q2

1(t) + . . .+ q2j−1(t) + q2

j+1(t) . . .+ q2M (t)

)2 (1 + d)

......

q2M (t+ 1) =

aM − q1M (t)− c2 − 2d

(q2

1(t) + q23(t) + . . .+ q2

M−1(t))

2 (1 + d)

The nontrivial Cournot-Nash equilibrium point for the previous set of equations (staticsolution) is given by:

3The dynamic proposed in 4.1 can lead to negative outputs without economic sense. Following [53],we will differentiate between two types of trajectories: admissible and feasible. Calling T the map definedby the 2m equations of the game, the set of admissible (S) and feasible points (F ) is defined respectivelyby:

S ={(

q11 , q1

2 , . . . , q1M , q2

1 , q22 , . . . , qM

2)∈ R2M

+ : T n(

q11 , q1

2 , . . . , q1M , q2

1 , q22 , . . . , qM

2)∈ R2M ∀n > 0

}F =

{(q1

1 , q12 , . . . , q1

M , q21 , q2

2 , . . . , qM2)∈ R2M

+ : T n(

q11 , q1

2 , . . . , q1M , q2

1 , q22 , . . . , qM

2)∈ R2M

+ ∀n > 0}

Then, the mathematical results are based on the admissible trajectories. However, in the economiccontext, only the feasible points will be considered.

8

Page 9: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

∗qi

j=(aj − ci

)(1 + 2Md) + ck − ci

3 + (2M)2d2 + 8Md

+ 23M (aj − a)

(2Md2 + d

)3 + (2M)2

d2 + 8Md, d 6= − 3

2M ,− 12M(4.3)

Using the equations3.9, 3.10 and 3.11 the Jacobian matrix for the system is definedby:

J2xM =

Mtimes

0 − d1+d · · · − d

1+d

− d1+d 0 · · · − d

1+d... . . . ...

− d1+d − d

1+d . . . 0︸ ︷︷ ︸

− 12(1+d) 0 · · · 0

0 − 12(1+d) · · · 0

... . . . ...0 0 · · · − 1

2(1+d)

Mtimes− 1

2(1+d) 0 · · · 00 − 1

2(1+d) · · · 0... . . . ...0 0 · · · − 1

2(1+d)

0 − d1+d · · · − d

1+d

− d1+d 0 · · · − d

1+d... . . . ...

− d1+d − d

1+d 0

(4.4)

The characteristic equation of 4.4 takes the form:

(λ− 1

22d+1(1+d)

)m−1 (λ− 1

22d−1(1+d)

)m−1 (λ+ 1

22(m−1)d+1

(1+d)

)(λ+ 1

22(m−1)d−1

(1+d)

)= 0 (4.5)

Thus, we have four4 different eigenvalues:

λ1 = −2 (m− 1) d+ 12 (1 + d) (4.6)

λ2 = −2 (m− 1) d− 12 (1 + d)

λ3,...,m+1 = 2d+ 12 (1 + d)

λm+2,...,2m = 2d− 12 (1 + d)

The local stability of equilibrium is achieved only if each eigenvalue is within the unitcircle. According to 4.6 this is fulfilled when:

4If we fix M = 1, we have only the two first eigenvalues.

9

Page 10: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

−0.4 −0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6123456789

1011121314151617181920

d

m

Figure 4.1: Stabililty zone (blue lines) for a duopoly depending of the number of marketsand the values for d.

− 1

2m < d <1

2 (m− 2) , m 6= 2

d > −14 , m = 2

(4.7)

By 4.7 is clear that stability of the duopoly game depends on both the scale parameter (d)and the number of markets (m). In the fig. 4.1 the relationship betweenm and d, in orderof to arrive to the stability of the game is shown. When m=1,2 the equilibrium becomesunstable only if d>-1/(2m). However, if m>3, we need to put an upper bound for thestability condition. We see that when the number of markets increases, the stability isachieved only if d tends to zero.

5 Numerical simulationsUsing numerical simulations we can see how the complex dynamics of the equilibriumdepends on the scale parameter (d), using a scheme of duopolists competing on threemarkets (2 × 3 game). The results of our model (blue) will be compared with the basemodel (red) proposed by Fisher (see section 2) under identical parameter values.

In the figs. 5.1 and 5.2 we show the dynamic of the quantity allocated by player 1 inmarket 1 according to several values of d.

For d = −0.1 and d = 0.2 (figs. 5.1b and 5.2a) we have that the equilibrium undernaive expectations reaches the equilibrium in both models.

When d = 0 (fig. 5.1c), the models no longer have advantages/disadvantages ofscale production, being both the same schemes that the Cournot-Teocharis approach (seesection 2).

10

Page 11: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

As seen in the fig. 5.2b, for the critical point d = 1/2, the dynamic goes to station-ary oscillations (neutrally stable) for the retail competition while for the single-marketapproach arrives quickly to the equilibrium .

For the case of figs. 5.1a and 5.2c the dynamic of the Fisher model remains stable butin our model lead to a chaotic behavior.

The figure 5.3 show the complex dynamic of the the quantity q11 by means of bifur-

cation diagrams, using values of d from the interval [−0.17; 0.52] . The decentralizedmodel shows stability of the equilibrium for all the values examined. By contrast, in ourmodel the chaos is achieved outside the critical points (d < −1/6 and d > 1/2, as it waspredicted by the analytical results of the duopoly case, see eq. 4.7). In the stability zone(fig. 5.3b), we can observe how the centralized managerial decision takes advantage interms of production when the company operates under economies of scale in relation tothe disaggregated model; while at diseconomies of scale, the production performance ofthe local model are less affected than the multi-market scheme.

6 ConclusionsIn this work, we analyze the stability of a multi-store retail competition model. Specifi-cally, we model an oligopoly system with multi-market competition. The model considersthe impact of the firm’s economies or diseconomies of scale. In one extreme, the multi-store retail maintain a centralized decision making process, optimizing global economiesof scale due to its global size. On the other hand, we have local oligopolistic competition,where the same demand is served by different firms that compete in only one market.Our model confirms the fact that economies and diseconomies of scale make the Cournotequilibrium very unstable for certain values of the scale parameter of the producers. Ad-ditionally, the number of markets, as expected, tends to contribute to this instability.One very interesting further research is to expand the multi-market oligopolistic modelto a multi-product setting.

7 AcknowledgmentsAid from the Fondecyt Program, project Nº 1131096, is grateful acknowledged by MarceloVillena. Axel Araneda thanks as well Faculty of Engineering & Science of the UniversidadAdolfo Ibáñez for financial support.

References[1] Antoine-Augustin Cournot. Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie

des richesses. chez L. Hachette, Paris, 1838.

[2] Tönu Puu. Chaos in duopoly pricing. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, 1(6):573–581,1991.

11

Page 12: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

100

200

300

400

500

600d=−0.20

t

q1 1(t

)

s2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

0

100

200

300

400

500

600d=−0.20

t

q1 1(t

)

(a) d = −0.2

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2030

40

50

60

70

80

90

100d=−0.10

t

q1 1(t

)

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2030

40

50

60

70

80

90

100d=−0.10

t

q1 1(t

)

(b) d = −0.1

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2030

35

40

45

50

55

60

65

70

75d=0.00

t

q1 1(t

)

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2030

35

40

45

50

55

60

65

70

75d=0.00

t

q1 1(t

)

(c) d = 0

Figure 5.1: Dynamic of q11 (solid line) and Cuornot equilibrium (dots), for different values

of d, under the proposed retail competition (blue) and the Fisher approach (independentsellers) (red); with a1 = 200, a2 = 150, a3 = 100, c1 = 20, c2 = 40.

12

Page 13: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2030

35

40

45

50

55

60

65d=0.20

t

q1 1(t

)

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2030

35

40

45

50

55

60

65d=0.20

t

q1 1(t

)

(a) d = 0.2

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2025

30

35

40

45

50d=1/2

t

q1 1(t

)

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2025

30

35

40

45

50d=1/2

t

q1 1(t

)

(b) d = 0.5

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2015

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

55

60d=0.55

t

q1 1(t

)

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 2015

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

55

60d=0.55

t

q1 1(t

)

(c) d = 0.55

Figure 5.2: Dynamic of q11 (solid line) and Cuornot equilibrium (dots), for different values

of d, under the proposed retail competition (blue) and the Fisher approach (red); witha1 = 200, a2 = 150, a3 = 100, c1 = 20, c2 = 40.

13

Page 14: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

−0.17 −0.168 −0.166 −0.164 −0.162 −0.16

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20x 10

4

d−0.17 −0.168 −0.166 −0.164 −0.162 −0.16

78.1

78.2

78.3

78.4

78.5

78.6

78.7

78.8

78.9

79

79.1

d

q1 1

(a) d ∈ [−0.17;−0.16]

−0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.40

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

d

q1 1

(b) d ∈ [−0.16; 0.45]

0.45 0.46 0.47 0.48 0.49 0.5 0.51 0.5246.5

47

47.5

48

48.5

49

d

q1 1

(c) d ∈ [−0.45; 0.52]

Figure 5.3: Bifurcation diagrams for the quantity of the player 1 over market 1 using theproposed retail competition model (blue) and the Fisher approach (red) with a1 = 200,a2 = 150, a3 = 100, c1 = 20 and c2 = 40.

14

Page 15: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

[3] Tönu Puu. Complex dynamics with three oligopolists. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals,7(2):2075–2081, 1996.

[4] Tönu Puu. The chaotic duopolists revisited. Journal of Economic Behavior & Or-ganization, 33(3):385–394, 1998.

[5] SS Askar, Ahmad M Alshamrani, and K Alnowibet. Dynamic cournot duopoly gameswith nonlinear demand function. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 259:427–437, 2015.

[6] Ahmad K. Naimzada and Lucia Sbragia. Oligopoly games with nonlinear demandand cost functions: Two boundedly rational adjustment processes. Chaos, Solitons& Fractals, 29(3):707 – 722, 2006.

[7] E Ahmed and HN Agiza. Dynamics of a cournot game with n-competitors. Chaos,Solitons & Fractals, 9(9):1513–1517, 1998.

[8] Tönu Puu. On the stability of cournot equilibrium when the number of competitorsincreases. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 66(3):445–456, 2008.

[9] Liang Chen and Guanrong Chen. Controlling chaos in an economic model. PhysicaA: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 374(1):349–358, 2007.

[10] Akio Matsumoto. Controlling the cournot-nash chaos. Journal of optimization theoryand applications, 128(2):379–392, 2006.

[11] Gian Italo Bischi, Ahmad K Naimzada, and Lucia Sbragia. Oligopoly games withlocal monopolistic approximation. Journal of economic behavior & organization,62(3):371–388, 2007.

[12] Gian Italo Bischi and Michael Kopel. Equilibrium selection in a nonlinear duopolygame with adaptive expectations. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,46(1):73–100, 2001.

[13] Gian Italo Bischi and Fabio Lamantia. Routes to complexity induced by constraintsin cournot oligopoly games with linear reaction functions. Studies in NonlinearDynamics & Econometrics, 16(2), 2012.

[14] HN Agiza, AS Hegazi, and AA Elsadany. Complex dynamics and synchronization of aduopoly game with bounded rationality. Mathematics and computers in Simulation,58(2):133–146, 2002.

[15] LU Yali. Dynamics of a delayed duopoly game with increasing marginal costs andbounded rationality strategy. Procedia Engineering, 15:4392–4396, 2011.

[16] HN Agiza and AA Elsadany. Nonlinear dynamics in the cournot duopoly gamewith heterogeneous players. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications,320:512–524, 2003.

[17] HN Agiza and AA Elsadany. Chaotic dynamics in nonlinear duopoly game withheterogeneous players. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 149(3):843–860, 2004.

15

Page 16: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

[18] Natascia Angelini, Roberto Dieci, and Franco Nardini. Bifurcation analysis of a dy-namic duopoly model with heterogeneous costs and behavioural rules. Mathematicsand Computers in Simulation, 79(10):3179–3196, 2009.

[19] Junhai Ma and Xiaosong Pu. Complex dynamics in nonlinear triopoly market withdifferent expectations. Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society, 2011, 2011.

[20] Tomasz Dubiel-Teleszynski. Nonlinear dynamics in a heterogeneous duopoly gamewith adjusting players and diseconomies of scale. Communications in NonlinearScience and Numerical Simulation, 16(1):296–308, 2011.

[21] Tönu Puu and Anna Norin. Cournot duopoly when the competitors operate undercapacity constraints. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, 18(3):577–592, 2003.

[22] Tönu Puu and Manuel Ruíz Marín. The dynamics of a triopoly cournot game whenthe competitors operate under capacity constraints. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals,28(2):403–413, 2006.

[23] Fabio Lamantia. A nonlinear duopoly with efficient production-capacity levels. Com-putational Economics, 38(3):295–309, 2011.

[24] Gian-Italo Bischi and Fabio Lamantia. Nonlinear duopoly games with positive costexternalities due to spillover effects. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, 13(4):701–721, 2002.

[25] Gian-Italo Bischi and Fabio Lamantia. Chaos synchronization and intermittency in aduopoly game with spillover effects. In Oligopoly Dynamics, pages 195–217. Springer,2002.

[26] Gian Italo Bischi and Fabio Lamantia. A dynamic model of oligopoly with r&dexternalities along networks. part ii. Mathematics and Computers in Simulation,84:66–82, 2012.

[27] Gian Italo Bischi and Fabio Lamantia. A dynamic model of oligopoly with r&dexternalities along networks. part i. Mathematics and Computers in Simulation,84:51–65, 2012.

[28] James A Brander. Intra-industry trade in identical commodities. Journal of inter-national Economics, 11(1):1–14, 1981.

[29] James Brander and Paul Krugman. A reciprocal dumping model of internationaltrade. Journal of international economics, 15(3):313–321, 1983.

[30] Paul Krugman. Import protection as export promotion: International competitionin the presence of oligopoly and economies of scale. In Henryk Kierzkowski, editor,Monopolistic Competition in International Trade, chapter 11, pages 180–193. OxfordUniversity Press, Oxford, UK, 1984.

[31] Avinash Dixit. International trade policy for oligopolistic industries. The EconomicJournal, 94:pp. 1–16, 1984.

[32] Elhanan Helpman. Increasing returns, imperfect markets, and trade theory. In R.W.Jones and Kenen P.B., editors, Handbook of International Economics, volume 1,pages 325–365. Elsevier Science Publishers B.V., 1984.

16

Page 17: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

[33] Shmuel Ben-Zvi and Elhanan Helpman. Oligopoly in segmented markets. WorkingPaper 2665, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1988.

[34] Dermot Leahy. Import protection as export promotion in oligopolistic markets withr & d. The Economic and Social Review, 23(1):93–103, 1991.

[35] Tracy Murray and Nurlan Turdaliev. Universal dumping of homogeneous products.Review of International Economics, 7(4):580–589, 1999.

[36] Jeremy I Bulow, John D Geanakoplos, and Paul D Klemperer. Multimarketoligopoly: Strategic substitutes and complements. The Journal of Political Econ-omy, 93(3):488–511, 1985.

[37] B Douglas Bernheim and Michael D Whinston. Multimarket contact and collusivebehavior. The RAND Journal of Economics, 21(1):1–26, 1990.

[38] Corwin D Edwards. Conglomerate bigness as a source of power. In Business concen-tration and price policy, NBER Conference report, pages 331–359. Princeton Univer-sity Press, 1955.

[39] Fang Wu and Junhai Ma. The chaos dynamic of multiproduct cournot duopoly gamewith managerial delegation. Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society, 2014, 2014.

[40] E Ahmed and MF Elettreby. Controls of the complex dynamics of a multi-marketcournot model. Economic Modelling, 37:251–254, 2014.

[41] Joaquín Andaluz and Gloria Jarne. On the dynamics of economic games based onproduct differentiation. Mathematics and Computers in Simulation, 113:16–27, 2015.

[42] AK Naimzada and Fabio Tramontana. Dynamic properties of a cournot–bertrandduopoly game with differentiated products. Economic Modelling, 29(4):1436–1439,2012.

[43] Juan Carlos Barcena-Ruiz and Marıa Paz Espinosa. Should multiproduct firms pro-vide divisional or corporate incentives? International Journal of Industrial Organi-zation, 17(5):751–764, 1999.

[44] Yingyi Qian and Chenggang Xu. Why china’s economic reforms differ: the m-formhierarchy and entry/expansion of the non-state sector. The Economics of Transition,1(2):135–170, 1993.

[45] Reghinos D Theocharis. On the stability of the cournot solution on the oligopolyproblem. Review of Economic Studies, 27(2):133–134, 1959.

[46] Tord Palander. Instability in competition between two sellers. In papers presented atthe research conference on economics and statistics held by the Cowles Commissionat Colorado College, Colorado College Publications, General Series, number 208,1936.

[47] Tönu Puu. Rational expectations and the cournot-theocharis problem. DiscreteDynamics in Nature and Society, 2006, 2006.

17

Page 18: Dynamics and Stability in Retail Competition

[48] José S Cánovas, Tönu Puu, and Manuel Ruíz. The cournot–theocharis problemreconsidered. aaaa, 37(4):1025–1039, 2008.

[49] Franklin M Fisher. The stability of the cournot oligopoly solution: The effects ofspeeds of adjustment and increasing marginal costs. The Review of Economic Studies,pages 125–135, 1961.

[50] Jian-guo Du, Tingwen Huang, and Zhaohan Sheng. Analysis of decision-making ineconomic chaos control. Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications, 10(4):2493–2501, 2009.

[51] Hong-Xing Yao and Feng Xu. Complex dynamics analysis for a duopoly advertisingmodel with nonlinear cost. Applied mathematics and computation, 180(1):134–145,2006.

[52] EM Elabbasy, HN Agiza, and AA Elsadany. Analysis of nonlinear triopoly game withheterogeneous players. Computers & Mathematics with Applications, 57(3):488–499,2009.

[53] Anna Agliari and Tönu Puu. A cournot duopoly with bounded inverse demandfunction. In Tönu Puu, , and Irina Sushko, editors, Oligopoly Dynamics, pages171–194. Springer, 2002.

18