do floating ceilings solve the usury rate problem?

10
~H OST states set maximum limits on interest rates which lenders may charge on residential mortgage loans. These usury laws are intended to protect bor- rowers from “exorbitant” interest rates which lenders might charge in the absence of such legal controls. Advocates of usury ceilings often express concern for borrowers who have little knowledge of prevailing in- terest rates or few alternative sources of credit. 1 In most states, usury ceilings on conventional resi- dential mortgage loans are set at fixed levels by state laws. When market interest rates rise above the usury ceilings, many individuals cannot find lenders who will finance their home purchases. Also, during such periods residential construction declines relative to that in states not subject to such restrictive usury ceilings. In recent years several states have raised their usury ceilings, eliminated usury ceilings entirely, or adopted floating ceilings which change periodical!>’ as other interest rates change. Floating usury ceilings are intended to protect individual borrowers from unusually high interest rates, while avoiding disrup- tions in the credit flow to home buyers and reductions in residential construction which can result when market interest rates approach or exceed usury ceil- ings. This paper evaluates whether floating usury rate formulas recently adopted by various states will avoid impeding the flow of credit to home buyers. 1 For a discussion of arguments in favor of usuiy ceilings, see Norman N. Bowsher, “Usury Laws: Harmful When Effective, this Review (August 1974), pp. 16-23, and Harold C. Nathan, “Economic Analysis of Usury Laws A Survey,” Working Paper 78-7, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. Page 10 Lenders typically make investments which, they hope, will maximize their profits. Consequently, they shift their assets among various investments in re- sponse to changes in relative rates of return, For instance, if yields on long-term U.S. Treasury bonds rise relative to yields on residential mortgages, lenders will reduce their mortgage investments and increase their holdings of government bonds. In so doing, they bring relative rates of return back in line. In addition, lenders can choose to invest in resi- dential mortgages on properties in different parts of the country. In the absence of usury ceilings, mort- gage interest rates in any section of the country can- not deviate too much from the national average rate for long. Lenders will make more credit available in areas with relatively high jnterest rates. Lenders usually are willing to make more risky mortgage loans if borrowers adequately compensate them for those risks by paying higher interest rates. This trade-off between risk and interest rates can be illustrated for the ratio of mortgage loan to house price, one aspect of risk. Since lenders assume owner- ship of mortgaged property if borrowers default on mortgage payments, the ratio of the loan to the market value of the house is an important consid- eration in evaluating risk. Lenders will make loans which are larger relative to the prices of homes being purchased if borrowers will pay sufficiently higher Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem? JEAN M. LOVATI and B. ALTON GILBERT

Upload: others

Post on 12-May-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

‘~H

OST states set maximum limits on interest rateswhich lenders may charge on residential mortgageloans. These usury laws are intended to protect bor-rowers from “exorbitant” interest rates which lendersmight charge in the absence of such legal controls.Advocates of usury ceilings often express concern forborrowers who have little knowledge of prevailing in-terest rates or few alternative sources of credit.1

In most states, usury ceilings on conventional resi-dential mortgage loans are set at fixed levels by statelaws. When market interest rates rise above the usuryceilings, many individuals cannot find lenders whowill finance their home purchases. Also, during suchperiods residential construction declines relative tothat in states not subject to such restrictive usuryceilings.

In recent years several states have raised theirusury ceilings, eliminated usury ceilings entirely, oradopted floating ceilings which change periodical!>’as other interest rates change. Floating usury ceilingsare intended to protect individual borrowers fromunusually high interest rates, while avoiding disrup-tions in the credit flow to home buyers and reductionsin residential construction which can result whenmarket interest rates approach or exceed usury ceil-ings. This paper evaluates whether floating usuryrate formulas recently adopted by various states willavoid impeding the flow of credit to home buyers.

1For a discussion of arguments in favor of usuiy ceilings, seeNorman N. Bowsher, “Usury Laws: Harmful When Effective,this Review (August 1974), pp. 16-23, and Harold C. Nathan,“Economic Analysis of Usury Laws A Survey,” WorkingPaper 78-7, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.

Page 10

Lenders typically make investments which, theyhope, will maximize their profits. Consequently, theyshift their assets among various investments in re-sponse to changes in relative rates of return, Forinstance, if yields on long-term U.S. Treasury bondsrise relative to yields on residential mortgages, lenderswill reduce their mortgage investments and increasetheir holdings of government bonds. In so doing, theybring relative rates of return back in line.

In addition, lenders can choose to invest in resi-dential mortgages on properties in different parts ofthe country. In the absence of usury ceilings, mort-gage interest rates in any section of the country can-not deviate too much from the national average ratefor long. Lenders will make more credit availablein areas with relatively high jnterest rates.

Lenders usually are willing to make more riskymortgage loans if borrowers adequately compensatethem for those risks by paying higher interest rates.This trade-off between risk and interest rates can beillustrated for the ratio of mortgage loan to houseprice, one aspect of risk. Since lenders assume owner-ship of mortgaged property if borrowers default onmortgage payments, the ratio of the loan to themarket value of the house is an important consid-eration in evaluating risk. Lenders will make loanswhich are larger relative to the prices of homes beingpurchased if borrowers will pay sufficiently higher

Do Floating Ceilings Solve the

Usury Rate Problem?

JEAN M. LOVATI and B. ALTON GILBERT

Page 2: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK or ST. LOUIS

Chart

Long-Term Interest Rates

APRIL 1979

1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971I,ote,t data plotted; March

Percent12

1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1919 1980

interest rates to compensate for the greater risks.Thus, lenders do not treat mortgage loans as a homo-geneous type of asset; they attach various degrees ofrisk to individual loans, depending upon borrowers’personal circumstances, credit histories, and prefer-ence for loan terms. The nature of the properties tobe mortgaged also affects risk, differing with theprospects for depreciation in market value.

These mortgage market characteristics indicate thatin the absence of government-imposed interest rateceilings:

(1)

(2)

The average level of interest rates on new residentin! mortgages will fluctuate with changes inother long-term interest rates,

Interest rates on new residential mortgages willtend to be similar in different parts of the coun-try, when adjusted for differences in the riskinessof loans, and

(3) Interest rates on new residential mortgages willvary in a given area, depending upon riskcharacteristics.

As Chart I indicates, yields on conventional resi-dential mortgages do change over time as changes inother long-term interest rates occur. The somewhatfixed differentials between these interest rates reflectthe investors’ perceptions of differential risks andtransactions costs on these types of investments.2

A recent study reports that the range of mortgageinterest rates among metropolitan areas averagesabout 75 basis points. However, the study’ also re-

2For evidence that lenders shift assets between residential mort-gage loans and other long-term investments when rela-tive interest rates change, see William L. Silber, PortfolioBehavior of Financial Institutions (New York: Holt, Rinehartand Winston, Irc., 1970, pp. 18-56). Silber found evidenceof such behavior for mutual savings banks, pension plans,life insurance companies, and property and casualty insur-ance companies. lie did riot find evidence of such substitutionamong assets by commercial banks and savings and loanassociations,

Percent12

11

9

8

7

TI

6

l0

5

9

4

8

7

6

$

3 3

~TTTTTTTTTTTTTTTTTT

4

0

Page 11

Page 3: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF St LOUIS APRIL 1979

average mortgage interest rates in individual metro-politan areas remain close to national average interestrates over time, when interest rates in those areasare not constrained by usury ceilings.

Several studies find that, during a given period oftime, the interest rates charged by mortgage lendersdepend upon the risks and costs associated with in-dividual loans. In general, mortgage interest ratestend to be higher on loans which are a larger per-centage of the purchase price of the house, and loweron loans with longer maturities and for homes ofhigher dollar value.4 One study also found that char-acteristics of the property influenced the mortgageinterest rate, with a higher interest rate for a propertyin poorer physical condition or in a neighborhoodwith greater risk of depreciation in value.5

3Mark Meador, “Interregional Mortgage Rate Differentials,”Federal Home Loan Bank Board Journal (September 1978),pp. 2-6.

41n one study, a researcher applied for mortgage loans at asample of savings and loan associations (S&Ls) and commer-cial banks in the Chicago area, providing each lender withthe same personal information and description of the houseto be purchased. The study was conducted in 1960 and re-peated in 1985. In both years he found variation in interestrates among lenders when proposing the same down payment.He also found that individual lenders offered to lend atlower interest rates if he wished to make a larger down pay-ment. See Allen F. Jung, “Terms on Conventional MortgageLoans — 1985 vs. 1980,” National Banking Review (March1966), pp. 379-84, Another study was based on a survey ofindividual mortgage loans made by a sample of S&Ls andcommercial banks in the Chicago area from April 1960through July 1963. Mortgage interest rates were found tobe higher on loans with higher ratios of loan to purchaseprice, lower on loans with longer maturities, and lower onloans for homes of higher dollar value. Mortgage interestrates also were found to be lower at lenders with greatertotal assets, and varied systematically by location of lenderswithin the Chicago area. See Alfred N. Page, “The Variationof Mortgage Interest Rates,” Journal of Business (July 1964),pp. 286-94. For additional evidence on interest rate differen-tials on residential mortgages, see Jack M. Guttentag, “Changesin the Structure of the Residential Mortgage Market: Analysisand Proposals,” Appendix A, in Irwin Friend, ed., Study ofthe Savings and Loan Industry, Vol. IV (Federal Home LoanBank Board, July 1969), pp. 1545-56. Loan commitment datareported by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board show thatinterest rates on mortgage loans with loan-to-price ratios of 95percent are 40 to 50 basis points above rates on loans withloan-to-price ratios of 75 percent. See Stephen T. Zahrenski,“New Measures of Mortgage Rates and Lending Policies,”Federal Home Loan Bank Board Journal (June 1978), pp.14-19.

5This study used data on about 550 residential mortgage loansmade by one large S&L in California from 1967 through 1971.The interest rate on each mortgage was measured as the differ-ence between the effective interest rate on the loan and theaverage interest rate that the S&L was charging at the timethe loan was made. That measure of the interest rate was used

Page 12

Studies of delinquencies and defaults on residentialmortgages indicate that lenders have a sound statis-tical basis for assigning different risks to mortgageloans, based upon characteristics of borrowers andloan terms. One study found the following factorspositively related to incidence of delinquency (loans90 days or more in arrears) in mortgage payments:

(1) Ratio of the loan to the purchase price of thehouse

(2) Occupation of borrower, with delinquency lowerfor professionals, executives, and managers, andhigher for salespersons

(3) Number of dependents.°

Another study on defaults on FHA-insured homemortgages finds that the incidence of default is posi-tively related to both maturity of loans and loan-to-value ratios, and negatively related to borrowers’income.7

A recent study by the U.S. League of Savings Asso-ciations indicates that the relatively young with mod-erate to low incomes are primarily the borrowers whobuy their first homes with low percentage down pay-ment loans (see Table I). As indicated in the studiescited above, these are the borrowers most likely tobecome delinquent or default on their mortgage loans,and, consequently, they are charged higher mortgageinterest rates.

as the dependent variable in regression analysis. The authorsfound that mortgage interest rates were positively related tothe ratio of the amount of the loan to the appraisal value ofthe home to be purchased, and negatively related to maturityand dollar amount of the loan. The authors also found thatcharacteristics of the property to be mortgaged influence themortgage interest rate. Dummy variables for properties inneighborhoods with poorer prospects for appreciation in valueand for properties in poorer physical condition had positiveregression coefficients which were statistically significant. SeeRichard L. Sander and Howard E. Sosin, “The Determinantsof Mortgage Risk Premiums: A Case Study of the Portfolio ofa Savings and Loan Association,” Journal of Business (January1975), pp. 27-38.

GJohe P. Herzog and James P. Earley, Home Mortgage Delin-quency and Foreclose (New York: National Bureau of Eco-nomic Research, 1970).

7George M. Von Furstenberg, “Default Risk on FHA-InsuredHome Mortgages as a Function of the Terms of Financing:A Quantitative Analysis,” Journal of Finance (June 1969),pp. 459-77, and “Risk Structure and the Distribution of Bene-fits Within the FHA Home Mortgage Insurance Program,”Journal of Money, Credit and Banking (August 1970), pp.303-22.

ports that about half of the variation in mortgageinterest rates can be explained by loan terms andusury ceilings. After adjusting for these factors, therange of unexplained variation in interest rates isonly about 25 basis points.3 Chart II indicates that

As mortgage interest rates in a state rise closerto a fixed usury ceiling, two general effects occur.

Page 4: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

FEDERAL RESERVE SANK OF ST. LOUIS APRIL 1979

- strictive usury ceilings indirectly chargeI abe I higher effective interest rates through

Distribution of First-Time Home Buyers by Age, Income, higher closing costs. This indicates thatand Percentage Down Payment on Mortgage Loans’ lenders circumvent usury ceilings to

Down payment as a perceniage of home purchase price - some extent by charging higher loan fees

Percentage when contract interest rates are restricted

Age of 5.1% 10.1% ~ ti~c.t~se by usury ceilings. However, other resultsfi,st-time to to than buyers in uf this study indicate that lenders do not

home buyers 5.0% 10.0% 19.9% 20% age qraupI ullv circumvent usury ceilings by charg-

18 to 29 5.5% 26.2% 20.0% 51.7% 62.9% ing higher fees, since usury ceilings in-30 to 39 5.9 19.6 17.0 42.5 26.2 fluence other loan terms. In particular,40 to 49 4.3 16.8 13.0 34.1 7.0 lenders require larger percentage down50 and over 0.8 11.0 10.2 22.0 3.9 payments when market interest rates rise

near or above usury ceilings. BorrowersDown payment as a percentage of home purchase price.. - —. — unable to meet the higher percentage

Pe”centaqeAnnual Total of first- down payments are rationed out of the

income of s.i% 10.1% less time home market.°first-time to to than buyers in

home buyers 5.0% 10.0% 19.9% 20% incame qroup— ..____ _._._ . The second predicted effect of usury

Less than $15,000 5.6% 23.2% is.c% 44.7% 22.0% ceilings — a decline in mortgage lending$15,000-524,999 6.4 27.4 20.7 54.1 49.3 in a state with a relatively low usury$25,000-$34,999 4.6 18.8 54.) 40.7 18.3

cedmg when market interest rates in535,000 or mare 2.9 11.6 49.3 29.3 10.4

—--. other states nse above the usury ceiling

u,,n nat fans] survey ni P.lr’fl p.srrhi-e’ .,~ s’,glc.rarnl) ..~,.. , — is substantiated by studies of mort—c’s,ssves:ti. nd t,.nge: s~t cas •~5 ~rcI I uLnL-,’ :_-.n-.L,—:s,w l:fl, gage lending in Georgia, New York, and

5511 RCi’ : !Icor.r..r,.,, s)’;p: :Ijj’.rdier, 0., Ssnu’~-jsushi ii’.mt. L S. Leanis,, sr Ss~s:.’e Pennsylvania)0 Other studies report that.\ssuc ut,. si. Ec’ss.o,nscp. LIL-;.a’lmLnL

usury ceilings affect residential construc-tion activity. Housing starts or permits

First, some borrowers are rationed out of the market in states with relatively low usury rates decline be-because lenders are not permitted to charge above- tween 11 and 20 percent for each 100 basis point riseaverage interest rates to compensate themselves for in market interest rates relative to usury ceilings.11

additional risk. Only lower-risk borrowers, such asthose who have accumulated sufficient savings tomake higher percentage down payments, or those 9Such rationing occurred m Canada dunng 1963-67, whenbuying houses in neighborhoods with less nsk of maximum rates on government-insured mortgages were setdepreciation in market value, receive credit. administratively, generally below interest rates on conventional

mortgages. Dunng this penod, only about 13 percent ofmortgages insured by the Canadian govermnent were made

Second, as interest rates on alternative long-term to individuals in the bottom third of the income distribution,investments rise relative to the state’s usury ceiling compared to 30 percent during 1971-75 when the ceiling

was removed entirely. Lawrence B. Smith, An Analysis or(and as average mortgage interest rates in other states the Effects of the Removal of the Yield Ceiling on Federallrise above the local ceiling rate), residential mort- Insured Mortgages in Canada,” Journal of Finance (Marc

1977), pp. 195-201.gage lending will declme relative to that in statesnot subject to such restrictive limits on interest rates. ‘°CharlesL, France, “Pennsylvania’s Floating Usury Ceiling:

Since mortgage financing is essential for most home ~ t9~~es~ti~buyers, home building activity in states subject to Carmen J. Carlo, and Bernard Kaye, “The Impact of New

relatively low usury ceilings will decline relative to ~

that in other states. James E. McNulty, “A Reexamination of the Problem ofState Usury Ceilings: The Impact in the Mortgage Market,”

One recent study confirms the first effect of usury n~97~aper#21, Federal Home Loan Bank Board,ceilings on loan terms.8 When market interest ratesrise above usury ceilings, lenders in states with re- ttOstas, “Effects of Usury Ceilings”; Philip K. Robins, “The

Effects of State Usury Ceilings on Single Family Home-building,” Journal of Finance (March 1974), pp. 227-35;and Kenneth Rosen, “The Impact of State Usury Laws on

SJames B. Ostas, “Effects of Usury Ceilings in the Mortgage the Housing Finance System and on New Residential Con-Market,” Journal of Finance (June 1976), pp. 821-34. struction,” Princeton University, 1978.

Page 13

Page 5: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

- ---

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS APRIL 1979

A”,og’m,rtpog,E,’t,o,sirot,oo,,,ff,ct~’~,,a’,, to, ‘5<, po’oho,, of p’e’Ioo,Iy-ocoopi,d ho,’,oL2 Etteoth’, J s,oa~y 977, <Iota a,, ba’S a, ,opa’d,d g,aa,opbic a’eas-

[3 ([nSa ,o’ a,,af]abf, p,[a, a 977Latest data p[atf’& Usury Rote.F,b,oary; Otim’s-MorcI, pr,I[,m[,ary

Percsst13

Pederaf Home mom Bo,,k Boo’d M’s’s

Percent‘3

Usury Ceilings and Average Mortgage Interest Rates

Q‘974 975 1916 ‘977 1918 ‘979

Page 14

Page 6: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

In recent years several states have established usuryceilings which are automatically adjusted at frequentintervals to changes in other interest rates (see TableII). Floating ceilings are intended to avoid the harm-ful effects of fixed ceilings on home financing andresidential construction, while still protecting bor-rowers from possible “exorbitant” interest rates. Thesefloating usury ceilings are tied to various interestrates, the most common being yields on long-termU.S. Government bonds and the Federal Reserve dis-count rate.

~:5- ~-~~r/

One issue that concerns advocates of usury ceil-ings is whether lenders would always charge themaximum interest rate permissible on residential mort-gages. Finance companies which make small loansto individuals often charge the maximum interestrates allowed by states and raise their loan rates when-ever the usury limits are raised. Do lenders in theresidential mortgage market respond similarly whenfloating usury ceilings rise?

Chart II provides evidence on this issue. Usuryceilings and average mortgage interest rates areplotted for five metropolitan areas in states whichhave had floating usury ceilings for several years.’2

The chart for the Cleveland, Ohio, area requiresspecial explanation, since average mortgage interestrates were above the usury ceiling during 1974-77.Savings and loan associations are exempt from theOhio usury law, and, therefore, can make mortgageloans at interest rates above the usury ceiling. Thesame explanation applies to mortgage interest ratesfor Columbus, Ohio, in 1977, when the survey of mort-gage interest rates began for that area. Since thesecond half of 1977, the usury ceiling has been aboveaverage mortgage interest rates, which indicates thatthe rates lenders charge are not determined by the

‘2The mortgage interest rates are those on existing homes,which tend to be higher than mortgage rates on newly-builthomes. Using the higher of these average interest rates isappropriate in determining whether lenders always chargeinterest rates equal to the legal maximums, because itintentionally biases the observations in the direction of find-ing such a pattern. Average mortgage interest rates for thePhiladelphia area are based upon a high percentage of mort-gage loans made by lenders outside of Pennsylvania. There-tore, observations are not presented for the Philadelphia area.

APRIL 1979

floating usury ceiling. Average mortgage interest ratesin Cleveland and in Columbus were approximatelythe same as the national average, both when mort-gage rates in those two cities were above the usuryceiling and when they were below.

In the Chicago area, mortgage interest rates appar-ently were constrained lower than national averagemortgage rates in the first half of 1974 by the 8 per-cent usury ceiling. Contract interest rates were equalto or below the usury ceiling, but effective interestrates were slightly higher due to initial fees. Sinceearly 1975, average mortgage interest rates in theChicago area have been below the state usury ceil-ing, following closely the national average mortgageinterest rate.

Mortgage rates in Minneapolis were substantiallybelow national average interest rates until early 1976,when the state usury rate was allowed to float at 2percentage points above the yield on ten-year U.S.Treasury bills.’3 Since then, average mortgage interestrates in the Minneapolis area have been below theusury ceiling and have followed the national averagemortgage interest rate. The same pattern holds forPittsburgh, with average mortgage interest rates inthat area remaining substantially below the floatingusury ceiling for Pennsylvania since 1977.

Use of a floating usury ceiling will avoid problems- in mortgage financing which occasionally result with

fixed ceilings only if the floating rate remains abovethe mortgage interest rates that would prevail in theabsence of usury ceilings, Relationships among interestrates vary over time, and, therefore, a floating usuryrate which is currently above mortgage interest ratesmay be below in the future. Also, a floating ceilingwhich remains above national average mortgage ratesmay not be high enough to enable relatively high-riskborrowers to obtain funds.

The prospects for the various floating usury ceilingsto remain above mortgage interest rates in the futurecan be assessed by examining past relationships be-tween interest rates on conventional residential mort-

13For a few months in 1974 and 1975, average contract interestrates on conventional residential mortgages on existing homesin the Minneapolis-St. Paul area were above 8 percent. Thisis probably due to an exemption from the usury laws forloans of $100,000 or more, and loans by some national banksat 1 percentage point above the Federal Reserve discountrate, a permissible interest rate for national banks. The dis-count rate was above 7 percent during that period.

Page 15

Page 7: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

-Il

~ loble ii

Floating State Usury CeilingsNumber of months since lanuory 3943 when the

— implied usury ceilings were oq.,al to or ~low-Notional Overage in

interest rote anconventional Nohianal overage Nationat nveroqe

Lhwy Ceiling residential mortgage interest moriqage intereston Rcsidenji~,l mongeqes for rate plus 25 rotc pIus 50

Sor:. Mo. lgaqe.s Exemptions Oats Prior ~eilinq newly-built homes basis points bass, points

—---- --5 neicentage paints loans aver $100 000 June 3976 4 Percentage po,nts 0 C~-bovo discaij,,t silo above discount rate ofof I 2’li Federal Reserve I 2th Federal Reserve 13District District

Dulawoic 4 poicsnt~o~points FFqA. VA, and loans August 1974 9% 0 1?obas,- fld-rcI R.-cwve over $I00,0~o

discount rots

Geargia 2 lb parc -ntac1c- pesnls ff4. VA. and loans March 1Q79 9% 0

above marl IhIy index of nyc, $3 0O,00QIon q- e.srr US, Govern,

mont band yieldsrounded •a tIn’ r,i-arpsl25 bas.~paints

Illinois 27, pc’cosnfoq~-points EHA and VA loan, January 1977 ~½ 0above niorrttilv ode;, oflanq-tersn US. Governmentband yk-Icis

2 percentage paints ff4 and VA iaon~ July 1978 c% 41 113above index oF 10- yearconstaisi molsrrity L.S.Government loins and

bonds. wth roilingchar fled 000rt.-rly

Minnesota 2 perrcntoqe pants ff4. VA, and loans May 1916 8% 6 125above maottnly index of aver £100,000Ionq-terrn U.S Gov”rnmentband yield,, iaunded totIne trourest 25 busi

5paint

Montana gronler of 100/,, 0,~ ~A loans~ April 3975 30% 0 0percentage poinnts above conventional anddiscount rate of 91), VA loon, over $300,000F.-d crc, I Recs-rye Districtan conventional mortgageand VA loosis up to$1 !iO.ODQ

greater of I o% or 5percentage Paints above -~

discount rate of 9thOn conventional mortgageFeth-rut Reserve Di strict Fand VA loan, between$150000 and $300,000 5/:

Page 8: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

11

Nevada - 2% a: 31,4 pn-rcentaqr FHA and VA loans June 1915 12% 0 0 0 IIIpoints above the lowestdoily gone rote at the1 largest U.S. banks, if

this raters c% or more rNew York 2 percentage points FHA, VA, and loans aver May 1Q79 9y,% 19 70 152

above index of 1 0-yoar $750,000 except those (I)constant maturity notes secured by I - to 2-and bonds, with ceiling to,nily residential propertyset quarterly and P1increased by no ma, e U)

than 25 basis pointstiom one quoutcr to the zneat

2

North Dakota greater of 10/0 on 3 FtIA and VA loans March 1969 7% 31 40 ‘1percentage points abovetie rate on 30-nsanlt, —1certifirsstes of deposit’ r

Ohio ‘J percentage point. FHA. VA loans, loans November 1975 8% 50 69 89 gabove discount rate of aver $100,000, and loans U)4tts Federal Rnserve by savings and loanDistrict associations

Pennsylvania 2 5/~ porrentogn points FHA and VA loans; January 1974 8% 0 0 Iabove the monthly index conventional mortgageof tnnq.tnrm U.S. loans over $50,000;

L.overnmnnt bond yields loans secured by realestota, 3 or mare units

Verinool i 5,4 percentage points F-HA and VA laans March 1979 Same at current ceiling, 112 160 179

above ttse ove.ragc: of the but sut,ject to maximumviel~af 3. to i-yea; U.S. rate of 9%%

~,avernment securities andthe -Fetd an seasonedmrfri--i ate bonds

West Virginia 1/, percertoge aoints HA and VA loans June 1978 8% 193 193 193

abase nnonlhly index otlong-terre U S. Governmenl band yields

WIll’!. t:tr,.et~r ~i’Lr_ , 1,:, - i:,’oiEis’:p.I :5 ‘Ins.tnig eClirig i.e -ii ii;,-nst’i41 nn:irlsncge ~i-t ,i.:ii.thl~-it::iu-ri-,-nt_-:’ piiini._.slinrse thi’ l.eitr.,sl ‘~ali,i~inLl2i1.:-”:_r:uri’A—-_,ir::sf:sii tl’NP.1 ‘s,wrt:,in “:cte Liii r,,is~:-i.t:,.n :s’ s,ii,ii_irnsir, - rI-nun-I it--i .isithii. ~,-E;--~ r:ir ‘I slim-—s-i i—ala.r,’ stir runs-it -i-intl sn,-i-tis:s’~t’’:’r :15; -r I-u—k si-iint. nsrs’ LEi7~.when tht’ I. \‘L].\ H’rit-~tic- ii: s ii.

5’I’tse ‘naVies usury reilrii’ ins vnsrb inn-ti, icr _‘hssl,,i. lh-!;Lsvnrr, Mnn:ia;snL. N,-vailns. and tThiu .Lfl’ base-it unii:n the- l:’,ster:cl Reserve-ilL s’,-snn:t’;stt’ cir p;-isnt ,:st,’s tif large rssnnnisc’rrirtl Iianlc’nfur js,’-nnnne nnnnth, I tsr fl,,nstnsg i n-vi:L5L’sn,,c-:Lc’hinnnth ?nr G,-vssinL. lllirii:is, Mius,e-ntsc. Vtqil,s%lva!:ilL. ‘,‘pniis,sn I, ;Lnd\’,-,t Vin~“ia us- hasp,

1on uppc’tseil isstene’st ate’ ins s-tIers

Iso, r,nii’iths “:~-.I_er ‘she tl,:-.iiir:r r:sE (‘Dr loss;s Es s-rissuLi-’rls’. Pin r’artn rnuisth irs a cal-aJar (sister, l,isi,’L’:i tl,s:sl,,,szistc’ is bait in tsr “prrit’sest itt-n-st .~ti-isis’t~s’r1is;:: nnunsltsslii icr In Use lit r_usi.ii.g ni.:nsjs i-f :t,.qij;ii ti’r ‘Unt’ rate’ ‘cr N,’ t’urkss rats-susIe,

tsirsiilasly, e’ceiit ttset itseseases ant’ hinshsit iii a ni-axint.insi u’. 2-i basis jinnsts, cml ttsat bc’ fin st i~Lsartvr

uf sub via: trim-ni I,-n-.inLrv so roe-i aiim ii ii slit’ tic’s: ii,, if hi’ N i’m y~,,. lImiting Inch less,2]lse Is-lu ry deities, - ins is’:. ‘tens iat 555cr(gs,:s_s is, •o, \‘urk slate v;Ls nir reast I is .1 ar,sirsrv i 979 frmn 8½% to 9½% , sv tb ttns Heal ing usury rats taking elrret ins tIne quarter be:si isa liiiMay 5970

‘Asipl,mn to ir,_:tineiina, dIr. ibis’:. uLvrsgs cml ban a-—s,.s’iati:ins’ icc lxi - (‘asssen:tionsal riu:r.gage lo’e,ns nnsade ha S&Ia an-u’ subject to a ceiling of 12%.4Annls,.. It’ sssnrigagc’ hosnini sin i—Is: ~_fntrns:Iyresislc’ntnnsl ursiperty.

‘U

r

F-i ‘I—1 to

Page 9: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

gages and interest rates to which the floating ratesare tied. Most floating ceilings have been adoptedonly since 1974. Suppose, however, they had been ineffect since 1983. Would the implied usury ceilingscalculated from the floating rate formulas have beenhigher than the average interest rates on conventionalresidential mortgages since 1963?14

Results of comparisons of implied nsnry ceilings tomortgage interest rates are presented in the last threecolumns of Table II. The first of these columns givesthe number of months since January 1963 when theimplied floating usury ceilings are equal to or belowthe national average interest rate on conventionalmortgages for newly-built homes. This table indicatesthat some states have set their floating usnry ceilingstoo low to avoid disruptions in the flow of credit tohome buyers. These observations are especially perti-nent for Vermont and West Virginia, which have settheir floating rate formulas so low that the impliedusury ceilings are below the national average interestrates on conventional mortgages for most monthssince 1963,15

Restrictions on the speed with which floating usuryrates are allowed to adjust to changes in marketinterest rates also create potential problems in homefinancing. Iowa restricts the speed of adjustment inits floating rate by setting its usury ceiling quarterly,at 2 percentage points above the yield on ten-yearU.S. Treasury bonds. The implied usury rates calcu-lated for Iowa are below the conventional mortgageinterest rate for six months since 1963. If the floatingceiling rate for Iowa were set monthly instead ofquarterly, the implied usury rate would have beenbelow the national average mortgage rate for onlyone month since January 1963.

The floating usury rate formula recently adoptedby New York state restricts the speed of adjustment

~4These comparisons may understate the effects of usury ceil-ings on the flow of credit to home buyers, since some of themortgage interest rates incorporated in the national averagerate were at times constrained by usury ceilings. One studyreports that when interest rates are relatively low, the aver-age mortgage interest rates in areas with relatively highusury ceilings are approximately equal to the national aver-age rate, hut when interest rates are high, increases in thenational average rate lag behind the increases in areas withrelatively high usury ceilings. See McNulty, “A Reexainina~tioa of the Problem of State Usury Ceilings,’ pp. 5-9.

t5Two other states with implied floating usury ceihngs whichwere below mortgage interest rates for a substantial numberof months are North Dakota and Ohio. - However, thosestates make exceptimu for S&Ls. In North Dakota, S&Ls aresubject to a 12 percent usury ceiling, and in Ohio, S&Ls areexempt from the usury ceiling. Therefore, the major effectof usury ceilings on residential mortgages in these states isto determine which financial institutions make mortgageloans during certain periods.

Page 18

APRIL 1979

to other interest rates even more than that of IosvaY~Under the New York law, the usury rate will be setquarterly at 2 percentage points above the yieldon ten-year U.S. Treasury bonds, but increases in theusury rate from one quarter to the next may be nogreater than 25 basis points. The implied usury ratesbased upon the New York specification are equal toor less than mortgage interest rates for nineteen monthsover the period since 1963, more than three times asoften as for Iowa which does not limit the quarterlychanges in its usury rate.

Minnesota has another type of restriction on thespeed of adjustment of its usury ceiling. The floatingceiling is adjusted monthly to a level 2 percentagepoints above the yield on ten-year U.S. Treasurybonds, but rounded to the nearest 25 basis points. If,for instance, the yield on ten-year U.S. Treasury bondsis 8.12 percent, the usury ceiling in Minnesota is 10percent; with a ten-year bond yield of 8.13 percent,the usury ceiling is 10.25 percent. Rounding to thenearest 25 basis points tends to delay the rise in theusury ceiling when long-term interest rates are rising,and to delay the decline in the usury ceiling whenlong-term rates are declining. Since January 1963, theimplied usury ceiling for Minnesota is less than thenational average mortgage interest rate for six months,whereas it would have been below for only one monthwithout rounding to the nearest 25 basis points.

To some extent these restrictions on the speed ofadjustment defeat the purpose for having a floatingusury rate. The restrictions occasionally cause theimplied floating usury rates for Iowa, Minnesota, andNew York to be below mortgage interest rates whenlong-term interest rates are rising rapidly.

The relatively low usury ceiling in Ohio during1976-77 illustrates the problem with tying a usury

ceiling to the Federal Reserve discount rate. WhenOhio initially adopted the floating usury ceiling inNovember 1975, the usury rate was increased 100basis points to only 25 basis points below the nationalaverage mortgage interest rate. However, the gapbetween the usury rate and the national averagemortgage rate began to widen almost immediately, asthe Federal Reserve twice lowered the discount rateduring 1976. Two major problems with tying usuryceilings on residential mortgage interest rates to thediscount rate are these: 1) the Federal Reserve gen-erally adjusts the discount rate to changes in short-term market interest rates, whereas mortgages are

10The New York usury ceiling on residential mortgages wasrecently raised to 9.50 percent, and beginning May 1, 1979,will be set quarterly according to a floating rate formula.

Page 10: Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate Problem?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS APRIL 1979

long-term investments, and there often are large gapsbetween short-term and long-term interest rates, and2) at times, the discount rate, being set by adminis-trative action and not by market forces, is allowedto remain out of line with other interest rates.

The potential for the floating usury rates to createmortgage financing problems for relatively high-riskborrowers can be assessed by adding 25 to 50 basispoints to the average conventional mortgage rate onnewly-built homes, and comparing that interest rateto the implied floating ceilings for each month since1963. Two recent studies indicate that a state’s usuryceiling must be at least 50 basis points above thenational average mortgage interest rate in order toavoid impeding the flow of credit to relatively high-risk borrowers.17

For several states, the floating usury rates are al-most always above the average mortgage rate, butare below the average mortgage rate plus 25 basispoints for a substantial number of months. Of course,the differences are even greater with 50 basis pointsadded. The frequency with which implied usuryceilings are below the average mortgage interest rateplus 50 basis points is especially great for states withrestrictions on the speed of adjustment of their floatingrates. For instance, the average mortgage interest rateplus 50 basis points is above the implied usury ratefor New York about 80 percent of the time since1963, and above the implied usury ceiling in Min-nesota about 65 percent of the time. Thus, floatingusury ceilings in several states are likely to rationrelatively high-risk borrowers out of the mortgagemarket much of the time. This is substantiated by astudy of Minnesota’s floating usury ceiling whichreports that conventional mortgage loans in that statecontinue to have relatively high percentage downpayments since the floating ceiling was adopted.’8

In contrast, states with usury ceilings 2.50 per-centage points above yields on long-term U.S. Govern-ment bonds, or 5 percentage points above the FederalReserve discount rate, and no restrictions on thespeed of response of usury ceilings to changes intt

One study finds that Georgia’s usury ceiling begins to affectmortgage loan originations by savings and loan associationsin Georgia when the market interest rate on mortgages risesto within 50 basis points of the usury ceiling. McNulty, “AReexamination of the Problem of State Usury Ceilings.” Asurvey of interest rates on loan commitments finds that in-terest rates on loans with loan-to-price ratios of 95 percentare 40 to 50 basis points above those on loans with loan-to-price ratios of 75 percent. Zabrenski, “New Measures ofMortgage Rates and Lending Policies.”

58David S. DahI, Stanley L. Graham, and Arthur J. Rolnick,“Minnesota’s Usury Law: A Reevaluation, Ninth DistrictQuarterly, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis (Spring1977), pp. 1-6.

the interest rates to which they are tied, are almostalways above the national average mortgage interestrate. This result holds even with additional basispoints added to the average mortgage rate to allowfor a risk premium for loans with higher-risk charac-teristics.19 These appear to be the minimum differen-tials above the yields on ten-year U.S. Treasury bondsand the Federal Reserve discount rate which are nec-essary to avoid impeding the flow of credit to homebuyers.

Since fixed usury ceilings on residential mortgageinterest rates, at times, have had adverse effects onhome financing and residential construction, severalstates recently have adopted floating usury rates in anattempt to avoid these adverse effects when mort-gage interest rates rise. These floating usury rates areincreased or decreased in specified relationships tovariou~other interest rates, the most common beingyields on ten-year U.S. Treasury bonds and the Fed-eral Reserve discount rate.

Two issues are raised concerning the effects of thefloating usury rates. The first is whether mortgageinterest rates equal the floating usury ceilings. Ingeneral, average mortgage interest rates charged bylenders in areas subject to floating usury ceilings re-main approximately equal to national average mort-gage interest rates, not the floating usury ceilings.

The other issue is whether the floating usury ratesadopted by various states have been set high enoughto remain above national average interest rates on res-idential mortgages over time. Based upon past relation-ships between mortgage interest rates and the otherinterest rates to which the floating usury ceilings aretied, floating usury rates for a few states were belownational average mortgage interest rates for substan-tial periods of time. Floating usury ceilings in severaladditional states are set so close to average mortgageinterest rates that relatively high-risk borrowers willfrequently be rationed out of the market for conven-tional residential mortgages. In contrast, states withusury rates set 2.50 percentage points above yields onten-year U.S. Treasury bonds or 5 percentage pointsabove the Federal Reserve discount rate appear tohave set their usury ceilings high enough to avoidimpeding the flow of credit to home buyers.

‘~Theresult also holds for Tennessee’s recently adopted floatingceiling (effective May 1, 1979) set at 2 percentage pointsabove the Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA)auction rate on conventional mortgages. The implied floatingceiling for Tennessee is above the conventional mortgage rateplus 50 basis points since 1972, when the FNMA seriesbegan.

Page 19