currency pegs and unemployment

Upload: stephenfidler

Post on 29-May-2018

227 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    1/23

    Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martn Uribe

    This draft: August 3, 2010Preliminary and incomplete

    1 Introduction

    Countries can find themselves confined to a currency peg in a number of ways. For instance,

    a country could have adopted a currency peg as a way to stop high or hyperinflation in

    a fast and nontraumatic way. A classical example is the Argentine Convertibility Law of

    April 1991, which, for a decade mandated a one-to-one exchange rate between the Argentine

    peso and the U.S. dollar. Another route by which countries arrive at a currency peg is the

    joining of a monetary union. Recent examples include Eastern European and Mediterranean

    emerging countries, such as Greece, that joined the Eurozone.

    The Achilles heel of currency pegs is that they hinder the efficient adjustment of the

    economy to negative external shocks, such as drops in the terms of trade or hikes in thecountry interest-rate premium. The reason is that such shocks produce a contraction in

    aggregate demand that requires a decrease in the relative price of nontradables, that is, a

    real depreciation of the domestic currency, in order to bring about an expenditure switch

    away from tradables and toward nontradables. In turn, the required real depreciation may

    come about via a nominal devaluation of the domestic currency or via a fall in nominal prices

    or both. The currency peg rules out a devaluation. Thus, the only way the necessary real

    depreciation can occur is through a decline in the nominal price of nontradables. However,

    if nominal prices, especially factor prices, are downwardly rigid, the real depreciation will

    take place only slowly, causing recession and unemployment along the way.

    This paper investigates the question of how costly are currency pegs in terms of unem-

    ployment and welfare for an emerging economy facing external shocks. To this end, the

    paper embeds downward nominal wage rigidity into a dynamic, stochastic, disequilibrium

    Columbia University, CEPR, and NBER. E-mail: [email protected] University and NBER. E-mail: [email protected].

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    2/23

    (DSDE) model of a small open economy with traded and nontraded goods. The key feature

    that distinguishes our theoretical framework from existing models of nominal wage rigidity

    is that in our formulation wage rigidity gives rise to occasionally binding constraints that

    prevent the real wage from falling to its efficient level. In turn, these constraints, when bind-

    ing, produce involuntary unemployment. A second distinguishing feature of our model ofdownward wage rigidity is that it does not rely on the assumption of imperfect competition

    in product or factor markets. This feature of the model has implications for the wage setting

    process, which, as explained below, affects form of the optimal exchange-rate policy.

    We show that in our DSDE model, the optimal monetary policy takes the form of a

    time-varying rate of devaluation that allows the real wage to equal the efficient real wage at

    all times. The resulting optimal exchange-rate policy is highly asymmetric in nature. The

    central bank devalues the nominal currency only in periods in which the full-employment real

    wage rate experiences a sizable decline. These are typically periods in which the economy

    suffers negative external shocks. In all other periods, the monetary authority keeps the

    nominal exchange rate constant. It follows that under the optimal policy, the devaluation

    rate is positive on average. As a consequence, the optimal rate of inflation is also positive on

    average. In this way, our DSDE model captures Oliveras (1960, 1964) concept of structural

    inflation.

    The first main quantitative result of this paper is that in a calibrated version of our

    model, the average optimal rate of inflation is high, about 5 percent per year. This result

    is important in light of the difficulties that the existing literature on the optimal rate of

    inflation has faced in rationalizing actual inflation targets, which in virtually all inflationtargeting countries are at least two percent. In this literature, the optimal rate of inflation

    is typically negative or insignificantly above zero (see Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe, 2010, for

    a survey). The reason why the present DSDE model has the ability to generate sizable

    optimal inflation rates is threefold. First, in our model labor markets are competitive. This

    implies that no economic agent internalizes the downward rigidity of wages. By contrast, in

    an environment in which wage setters do internalize the wage rigidity, nominal (and real)

    wages tend to rise less during booms. Therefore, the central bank has an incentive to revalue

    during booms and less need to devalue during recession, both of which tend to reduce the

    average level of inflation. Second, our model of wage rigidity imposes asymmetric costs of

    changing nominal wages. Firms face resistance only to nominal wage cuts, but not to nominal

    wage increases. This asymmetry creates an incentive for the central bank to inflate away

    the purchasing power of past real wages when they exceed the current full-employment real

    wage. On the other hand, the fact that nominal wages are flexible upward implies that the

    central bank has no incentives to deflate when the current full-employment real wage exceeds

    1

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    3/23

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    4/23

    goods.

    2.1 Households

    The economy is populated by a large number of infinitely-lived households with preferences

    described by the utility function

    E0

    t=0

    tU(ct), (1)

    where ct denotes consumption, U is a utility index assumed to be increasing and strictly

    concave, (0, 1) is a subjective discount factor, and Et is the expectations operator

    conditional on information available in period t. Consumption is assumed to be a composite

    good made of tradable and nontradable goods via the aggregation process

    ct = A(cTt , c

    Nt ), (2)

    where cTt denotes consumption of tradables, cNt denotes consumption of nontradables, and

    A denotes an aggregator function assumed to be homogeneous of degree one, increasing,

    concave, and to satisfy the Inada conditions. These assumptions imply that consumption of

    tradables and nontradables are normal goods.

    Households are assumed to be endowed with an exogenous and stochastic amount of

    tradable goods, yTt , and a constant number of hours, h, which they supply inelastically to

    the labor market. Because of the presence of nominal wage rigidities in the labor market,

    households will in general only be able to work ht h hours each period. Households take

    ht as exogenously determined. Households also receive from the government a lump-sum

    transfer t and profits from the ownership of firms, denoted t. Both t and t are expressed

    in terms of tradables. Following Mendoza and Yue (2010), we assume that households

    do not directly participate in financial markets. Instead, the government does so on their

    behalf by choosing transfers in a benevolent fashion. We make this assumption for technical

    reasons, as it greatly facilitates the characterization and computation of equilibrium in an

    economy with occasionally binding constraints and possibly incomplete asset markets. The

    households budget constraint in period t is then given by

    cTt + ptcNt = y

    Tt + wtht + t + t, (3)

    where pt denotes the relative price of nontradables in terms of tradables in period t and

    wt denotes the real wage rate in terms of tradables in period t. The household takes the

    right-hand side of the budget constraint as exogenously given.

    3

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    5/23

    In each period t 0, the optimization problem of the household consists in choosing

    cTt and cNt to maximize (2) subject to the budget constraint (3). The optimality conditions

    associated with this maximization problem are the budget constraint (3) and

    A2(cT

    t

    , cNt

    )

    A1(cTt , cNt ) = p

    t,

    where Ai denotes the partial derivative of A with respect to its i-th argument. Intuitively,

    the above expression states that an increase in the relative price of nontradables induces

    households to engage in expenditure switching by consuming relatively more tradables and

    less nontradables. The maintained assumptions on the form of the aggregator function A

    guarantee that the left-hand side of this expression is an increasing function of the ratio

    cTt /cNt .

    2.2 Firms

    The nontraded good is produced using labor as the sole input by means of an increasing and

    concave production function

    yNt = F(ht),

    where yNt denotes output of nontradables. The firm operates in competitive product and

    labor markets. Profits, t, are given by

    t = ptF(ht) wtht.

    The firm chooses ht to maximize profits. The optimality condition associated with this

    problem is

    ptF(ht) = wt.

    This first-order condition implicitly defines the firms demand for labor. It states that firms

    are always on their labor demand curve. Put differently, in this model firms never display

    unfilled vacancies nor are forced to keep undesired positions. As we will see shortly, this will

    not be the case for workers, who will in general be off their labor supply schedule and will

    experience involuntary unemployment.

    2.3 Employment and Wages with Downward Nominal Rigidity

    Let Wt denote the nominal wage rate and Et the nominal exchange rate, defined as the

    domestic-currency price of one unit of foreign currency. Assume that the law-of-one-price

    4

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    6/23

    holds for traded goods and that the foreign-currency price of traded goods is constant and

    normalized to unity. Then, the real wage in terms of tradables is given by wt Wt/Et.

    Nominal wages are assumed to be downwardly rigid in the spirit of Olivera (1960, 1964).

    Specifically, in any given period nominal wages can at most fall by a factor [0, 1].

    Formally, we impose thatWt Wt1.

    This setup nests the cases of absolute downward rigidity, when 1, and full wage flexi-

    bility, when 0. The presence of nominal wage rigidity implies the following restriction

    on the dynamics of real wages:

    wt wt1

    t,

    where t Et/Et1 denotes the gross nominal depreciation rate of the domestic currency.

    The presence of downwardly rigid nominal wages implies that the labor market will in

    general not clear at the inelastically supplied level of hours h. Instead, involuntary unem-

    ployment, given by h ht, will be a regular feature of this economy. Actual employment

    must satisfy

    ht h

    at all times. Finally, at any point in time, real wages and employment must satisfy the

    slackness condition

    (h ht)

    wt

    wt1t

    = 0.

    2.4 Price and Quantity Determination in the Private Sector

    Given the level of government transfers, t, and the devaluation rate, t, which are both

    determined by government policy and taken as exogenous by households and firms, and

    given the past real wage, wt1, which is a predetermined variable, relative prices, pt and

    wt, and quantities, cTt , c

    Nt , and ht, are determined by the following system of equations and

    inequalities:

    cNt = F(ht), (4)

    cTt = y

    Tt + t, (5)

    A2(cTt , c

    Nt )

    A1(cTt , cNt )

    = pt, (6)

    ptF(ht) = wt, (7)

    (h ht)

    wt

    wt1t

    = 0, (8)

    5

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    7/23

    ht h, (9)

    and

    wt wt1

    t. (10)

    Consider first the real wage that would obtain in a full-employment equilibrium in whichht equals h. Setting ht = h and using equation (4) to eliminate c

    Nt , equation (5) to eliminate

    cTt , and equation (6) to eliminate pt, the labor demand equation (7) can be written as

    wf,t =A2(y

    Tt + t, F(h))

    A1(yTt + t, F(h))F(h) f(y

    Tt + t);

    f > 0, (11)

    where wf,t denotes the full-employment real wage. The assumed properties of the aggrega-

    tor function A guarantee that the full-employment real wage is increasing in after-transfer

    tradable income yTt + t. The intuition behind this result is that an increase in tradable

    income makes households feel richer. Because nontradables are normal goods, the demand

    for this type of good goes up. The supply of nontradables, however, cannot increase because

    the labor market is already in full employment. Therefore, the relative price of nontradables

    must rise. This increase in the relative price of nontradables raises the value of the marginal

    product of labor, which translates into an increase in the real wage.

    Using the above expression for the full-employment wage, equation (11), and condi-

    tion (10), we have that the real wage rate satisfies

    wt =

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    max

    wt1t ,

    f(yTt + t)

    ; 1, 2 0. (12)

    Having derived the real wage rate that will prevail in each period, one can use expres-

    sions (4)-(7) to obtain the value of all other variables determined in the private sector. In

    particular, employment is implicitly give by

    A2(yTt + t, F(ht))

    A1(yTt + t, F(ht))F(ht) =

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    .

    The normality of tradable and nontradable consumption guarantees that the left-hand side

    of this expression is monotonically decreasing in ht. This fact in combination with the

    assumptions that A satisfies the Inada conditions and that F is concave implies that, given

    yTt + t and wt1/t, there exists a unique solution of the above expression for employment,

    ht, which satisfies ht h. We therefore can express employment as a function ofyTt + t and

    6

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    8/23

    wt1/t as follows:

    ht = H

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    ; H1 0; H2 0.

    The results that H is nondecreasing in yTt + t and nonincreasing in wt1/t follows from the

    properties of the functions A and . The intuition for why employment is nondecreasingin tradable income is that an increase in this source of income produces a positive wealth

    effect that raises the demand for both tradable and nontradable goods. If the economy is

    operating below full employment, the increase in the demand for nontradables translates

    directly into an increase in employment in that sector. If the economy is already operating

    at full employment, the increase in the demand for nontradables causes a rise in the price

    of this type of good but leaves employment unchanged. Consider now an increase in the

    lower bound for real wages, wt1/t. If this lower bound is binding an increase in wt1/t

    will depress employment, because firms are always operating on the labor demand schedule

    (i.e., employment is demand determined). On the other hand, if the economy is at full

    employment, then an increase in wt1/t is in general not binding and has no effect on

    employment.

    Finally, one can express the relative price of nontradables, consumption of nontradables,

    and total consumption as functions of tradable income and the real value of the lagged wage

    rate as follows:

    pt =A2

    yTt + t, F

    H

    yTt + t,wt1t

    A1

    (yT

    t + t, F

    H

    yT

    t + t,wt1

    t P(yTt + t,

    wt1t

    ); P1 > 0, P2 0,

    cNt = F

    H

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    CN

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    ; CN1 0; C

    N2 0,

    ct = A

    yTt + t, C

    N

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    C

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    ; C1 0, C2 0,

    where Pi, CNi , and Ci denote, respectively, the partial derivatives of the functions P, C

    N,

    and C with respect to their i-th arguments, for i = 1, 2. The signs of the partial derivatives

    of these three functions follow directly from the previous analysis, with the exception of

    P1, the partial derivative of the relative price of nontradables, pt, with respect to traded

    income, yTt + t. The reason why the sign of this partial derivative is not obvious is that

    the relative price of nontradables depends on the ratio of the consumptions of tradables and

    nontradables. In turn, both tradable and nontradable consumption increase with tradable

    income. It is possible to show, however, that an increase in tradable income will always induce

    a proportionally larger increase in tradable consumption than in nontradable consumption.

    7

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    9/23

    Figure 1: The Effect of Transfers and Devaluations on the Private Sector

    h

    Transfer, t

    Hours, ht

    wt1

    t

    Transfer, t

    Real Wages, wt

    Transfer, t

    Price of Nontradables, pt

    Transfer, t

    Aggregate Consumption, ct

    h

    Devaluation Rate, t

    Hours, ht

    wt1

    t

    Devaluation Rate, t

    Real Wages, wt

    Devaluation Rate, t

    Price of Nontradables, pt

    Devaluation Rate, t

    Aggregate Consumption, ct

    8

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    10/23

    To see this, consider first a situation in which the economy is at full employment. In this case,

    consumption of nontradables cannot increase with tradable income, because nontradable

    production is at its upper bound F(h). Tradable consumption, however, increases one for

    one with tradable income. Hence, given the assumed properties of the aggregator function

    A, the ratio A2/A1, which equals pt, must rise. Consider now a situation in which theeconomy is operating below full employment. Suppose that in response to an increase in

    tradable income cN increases by the same or a larger proportion than cTt . By equation (6)

    and the assumptions made about the aggregator A, this is the only scenario under which

    the relative price of nontradables, pt, will not rise. This scenario, however, is impossible.

    To see this, note that the rise in cNt must be accompanied by a rise in ht (by equation (4)),

    and, hence by a decline in the marginal product of labor (by the assumed concavity of the

    production function F). Now, the fact that pt does not increase and that F(ht) falls, implies,

    by the labor demand given in (7), that the real wage must fall. But because the economy

    is operating below full employment, the real wage is at its lower bound wt1/t and thus

    cannot fall further. It follows that pt must rise.

    Figure 1 provides a graphical summary of the dependence of hours, the real wage rate,

    the relative price of nontradables and total consumption on the real transfer t and the

    devaluation rate t. The left column of figure 1 displays qualitatively the effect of changes

    in transfers on the private sector. If the economy is operating below full employment, an

    increase in transfers brings about a reduction in involuntary unemployment, a real appreci-

    ation (i.e., an increase in the relative price of nontradables), and an expansion in aggregate

    consumption. Note that in this case, employment increases even though real wages are un-changed and firms are on their demand schedule. The reason is that the relative price of

    nontradables increases, thereby boosting the value of the marginal product of labor.

    Consider now the macroeconomic effect of a devaluation, starting from a situation in

    which the economy exhibits involuntary unemployment. The effects are illustrated in the

    right column of figure 1. The primary effect of a devaluation is to lower the real wage when

    wage rigidities are binding. In this case, the devaluation boosts employment by reducing

    labor costs. The resulting increase in the supply of nontradables causes their relative price

    to fall, allowing consumers to switch expenditures toward this type of good. The ability of

    devaluations to stimulate private spending ceases once the economy reaches full employment.

    We note that figure 1 considers partial equilibrium effects in which either transfers or

    the devaluation rate are held constant. In general equilibrium, these two variables are

    endogenously determined by the governments transfer and exchange rate policies. We turn

    now to a characterization of the governments policy problem.

    9

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    11/23

    2.5 The Government

    The government is assumed to choose the process for transfers, t, in a benevolent fashion,

    in the sense of maximizing the welfare of private households. The governments objective

    function is to maximize the lifetime utility of the representative household taking into account

    the resource allocations that result in the private sector through the optimizing behavior of

    households and firms. Formally, the objective function of the government is given by

    E0

    t=0

    tU

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    , (13)

    where U is an indirect utility function given by

    UyTt + t, wt1t

    UCyTt + t, wt1t

    ; U1 > 0; U2 0.The optimal transfer process will depend, in general, on the assumed structure of financial

    markets and on the monetary policy implemented by the central bank. The central focus of

    this paper is the interaction between financial structure and the effectiveness of monetary

    policy in an economy with downward nominal wage rigidity. We turn next to a description

    of monetary policy.

    3 Full-Employment Exchange-Rate Policy And Cur-

    rency Pegs

    We consider two polar exchange-rate arrangements. The first one is a currency peg. This

    policy regime is meant to capture, for example, the monetary policy in place in Argentina

    prior to the default episode of 2001 and the monetary restrictions faced by the small emerging

    economies that are members of the Eurozone, such as Greece and Portugal. Under a currency

    peg the government commits to keeping the nominal exchange rate constant over time,

    Et = Et1 for t 0. As a result, the gross rate of devaluation equals unity at all times:

    t = 1,

    for t 0.

    Under a currency peg, relative prices and quantities in the private sector are determined

    10

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    12/23

    as functions of t and wt1 only as follows:

    wt =

    yTt + t, wt1

    , (14)

    ht

    = HyTt

    + t, w

    t1 , (15)

    pt = P

    yTt + t, wt1

    , (16)

    cNt = CN

    yTt + t, wt1

    , (17)

    cTt = yTt + t,

    and

    ct = C

    yTt + t, wt1

    . (18)

    The second exchange-rate arrangement we consider is one in which the central bank

    always sets the devaluation rate to ensure full employment in the labor market. We refer

    to this monetary arrangement as the full-employment exchange-rate policy. Formally, this

    policy amounts to setting the devaluation rate to ensure that the real wage equals the full-

    employment wage rate, wf,t, at all times. We assume that, if wf,t is greater than wt1,

    then the monetary authority keeps the nominal exchange rate constant, that is, t = 1.

    There is no need for a devaluation in this case, because the nominal wage rate will adjust

    upward on its own accordrecall that nominal wages are fully flexible upward. If, on the

    other hand, wf,t is lower than wt1, then the monetary authority chooses t to ensure

    that wf,t = wt1/t. In this case, if the central bank chose not to devalue, the economywould experience unemployment, because downward wage rigidities would prevent the real

    wage from falling to the flexible-wage level wf,t. It follows that under the full-employment

    devaluation policy, the devaluation rate is given by

    t = max

    wt1wf,t

    , 1

    .

    This exchange-rate policy ensures that in every period t > 0, the real wage rate equals the

    full-employment real wage:

    wt = f(yTt , t). (19)

    Thus, using equation (11), we can write

    t = max

    f(yTt1 + t1)

    f(yTt + t), 1

    ; t > 0. (20)

    Because f is a strictly increasing function of tradable income, this expression states that

    11

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    13/23

    the central bank will devalue the domestic currency only when tradable income falls. Be-

    cause in equilibrium traded consumption equals tradable income, we have that the monetary

    authority devalues only when tradable expenditure falls.

    The full-employment exchange-rate policy guarantees that the labor market is always at

    full employment:ht = h, (21)

    for all t 0. This means that output of nontradables is constant, at yNt = F(h), and therefore

    so is nontraded consumption,

    cNt = F(h). (22)

    We then have, using equation (6), that the relative price of nontradables under the full-

    employment exchange-rate policy is given by

    pt = f(yTt + t)

    F(h). (23)

    Finally, aggregate consumption is determined by

    ct = A(yTt + t, F(h)). (24)

    We have demonstrated that the full-employment exchange-rate policy completely eliminates

    any effect that downward nominal wage rigidities may have on the real allocation. Put

    differently, under the monetary regime assumed here, the economy becomes identical to one

    with full wage flexibility. Indeed, in the context of our model, the full-employment exchange-

    rate policy is always optimal. The reason is that, when the nontraded sector operates at full

    employment, the equilibrium real allocation depends only on the level of transfers, which, in

    turn, as will become clear shortly, is independent of the devaluation rate process.

    4 Devaluation Incentives Under Complete Asset Mar-

    kets

    As a useful benchmark environment, we consider an economy with access to a complete

    array of state-contingent claims. The main purpose of studying this type of asset structure

    is to show that in emerging economies in which external shocks play an important role, the

    countrys ability to insure against such shocks greatly simplifies the monetary-policy problem.

    This benchmark will then be contrasted with environments featuring different forms of asset-

    market incompleteness in which monetary policy will play a central stabilizing role.

    12

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    14/23

    Under complete asset markets, the budget constraint of the government is given by

    t + dt = Etq

    t,t+1dt+1, (25)

    where dt+1 is a state-contingent payment of the government to its international creditors

    chosen in period t. The random variable dt+1 can take on positive or negative values. A

    positive value of dt+1 in a particular state of period t + 1 can be interpreted as the external

    debt due in that state and date. The variable qt,t+j denotes the period-t price of an asset

    that pays one unit of tradable good in one particular state of period t + j divided by the

    probability of occurrence of that particular state conditional upon information available in

    period t. It follows that Etq

    t,t+1dt+1 is the period-t price of the state-contingent payment

    dt+1. The government faces a borrowing limit of the form

    limjEtq

    t,t+jdt+j 0, (26)

    which prevents Ponzi schemes.

    The government chooses processes {t, dt+1, wt} to maximize the indirect utility func-

    tion (13) subject to (12), (25), and (26), given d0, w1, the process q

    t,t+1, the endowment

    process yTt , and a monetary policy regime. The first-order condition with respect to dt+1 is

    tq

    t,t+1 = t+1,

    where t denotes the Lagrange multiplier on the governments budget constraint (25). For-eign households are assumed to have access to the same array of contingent claims available

    to domestic agents. Thus, the following Euler equation holds abroad:

    t q

    t,t+1 =

    t+1,

    where t denotes the marginal utility of tradable consumption of foreign residents. Note

    that we assume that domestic and foreign residents have the same subjective discount fac-

    tor. Because the above two expressions hold on a state-by-state and date-by-date basis,

    they imply that the domestic and foreign marginal utilities of consumption of tradables areproportional to each other at all dates and states:

    t =

    t ,

    where > 0 is a constant reflecting a wealth differential between the domestic and the

    foreign economies. We will assume that the country faces no systemic uncertainty from

    13

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    15/23

    abroad. Therefore, we set t = , where is a positive constant. It then follows that t

    is constant as well:

    t = .

    We wish to show that when financial markets are complete, full-employment at all times

    is a solution to the governments problem independently of whether the government follows

    an exchange-rate peg or a full-employment exchange-rate policy. To this end, we solve the

    governments maximization problem without imposing restriction (12) and then show that

    the solution to the less-constrained optimization problem indeed satisfies this constraint.1

    The first-order condition with respect to the transfer t is given by

    U(ct)

    A1(c

    Tt , c

    Nt ) + A2(c

    Tt , c

    Nt )C

    N1

    yTt + t,

    wt1t

    = . (27)

    Now consider a solution in which cNt = F(h) for all t. In this case, first-order condition (27)

    implies that consumption of tradables, cTt = yTt + t, is constant across states and time,

    at a level that we denote by cT. Replacing t by cT yTt in the sequential budget con-

    straint of the government, equation (25), iterating forward, and imposing the no-Ponzi-game

    constraint (26), one obtains

    cT = (1 )

    d0 + E0

    t=0

    tyTt

    .

    Let the wage rate be constant over time and given by:

    wt =A2(c

    T, F(h))

    A1(cT, F(h))F(h). (28)

    The right-hand side of this expression is the full-employment wage rate associated with

    yTt + t = cT. What remains to be shown is that the suggested path of wages given in

    equation (28) satisfies the omitted constraint (12) for both monetary policies considered.

    This amounts to verifying that wt wt1/t for t 0 when wt is given by (28). Notice

    that for any t > 0, wt = wt1. Note also that t = 1 for t > 0 under both a currency peg and

    the full-employment exchange-rate policy. The fact that t = 1 under the full-employment

    exchange-rate policy follows from equation (20) and the facts that < 1 and that, because

    yTt + t = cT is constant, the full-employment real wage rate is also constant constant for

    t 0. Therefore, because 1 for any t > 0, equation (12) holds for both monetary regimes.

    1Alternatively, it is possible to impose (12) as a constraint and show that under the proposed full-employment solution, the Lagrange multiplier associated with (12) is nil.

    14

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    16/23

    It remains to show that under our proposed real wage rate, equation (12) holds at t = 0.

    Suppose monetary policy takes the form of an exchange rate peg. Then equation (12) holds

    in period 0 as long as w1 w0. We will assume that the initial condition, w1, is such

    that this condition is satisfied.2 Alternatively, if the central bank follows a full-employment

    exchange rate policy, then equation (12) will be satisfied if and only if w1/0 w0. Thegovernment can always pick 0 so that this condition is met.

    We have shown that, when asset markets are complete, the full-employment allocation

    results under both monetary policies. The intuition for this result is that the fact that

    the benevolent government has access to complete asset markets allows households to com-

    pletely smooth consumption across dates and states. In this case stochastic variations in

    tradable output only affect the transfer payments, but not consumption allocations. With

    consumption constant over time, nominal rigidities no longer play any role in equilibrium

    determination. We summarize this result in the following proposition:

    Proposition 1 When financial markets are complete, the optimal transfer policy guarantees

    full employment at all dates and times regardless of whether monetary policy is characterized

    by a currency peg or by the full-employment exchange-rate-policy.

    The stochastic environment considered in this section, featuring a single shock to tradable

    output, was deliberately constructed to yield the strong monetary-policy-irrelevance result

    of proposition 1. Our main interest is not however, the message of the proposition in its

    strongest sense, but rather to build a benchmark scenario that is analytically tractable and

    transparent to convey the main idea of the present study, namely that when key nominalprices are downwardly rigid, the real consequences of monetary policy are greatly influenced

    by the underlying financial structure. The usefulness of this strategy will become apparent in

    the next section when the macroeconomic consequences of a currency peg in an environment

    with complete asset markets are contrasted with its consequences in an environment of

    financial autarky.

    5 Devaluation Incentives Under Financial Autarky

    Under financial autarky, the government is unable to borrow or lend internationally. As a

    result, transfers equal zero at all times

    t = 0,

    2One can show that if this initial condition is not satisfied, then a currency peg gives rise initially toinvoluntary unemployment. However, after a finite number of periods, the economy reaches full employmentforever. In this case, therefore, a currency peg yields full employment up to a finite initial transition.

    15

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    17/23

    and consumption of tradables equals tradable output

    cTt = yTt .

    This represents a sharp contrast with the case of complete asset markets, in which consump-

    tion of tradables is perfectly constant across dates and states.

    More importantly for the purpose of our study is that under financial autarky, unlike in

    the case of complete asset markets, the dynamics of the nontraded sector depend crucially

    upon the assumed exchange-rate regime. Under the full employment exchange-rate policy,

    nontraded consumption is constant over time and equal to F(h). This perfect smoothness

    in nontradable consumption is the result of optimal monetary policy, which deflates the real

    value of past wages whenever the efficient allocation requires a reduction in the equilibrium

    real wage by a factor greater than 1 , a situation that happens when the tradable sector

    is contracting. Formally, setting t = t1 = 0 in equation (20), we obtain the followingexpression for the optimal devaluation rate under financial autarky

    t = max

    f(yTt1)

    f(yTt ), 1

    ; t > 0. (29)

    Because the function f is strictly increasing, this expression states that the central bank

    optimally devalues the domestic currency only when tradable output falls, yTt < yTt1.

    These devaluations are designed to undue nominal frictions in states in which they would

    otherwise be binding. Because in this economy devaluations occur when the economy is

    contracting, non-micro founded statistical analysis would conclude that devaluations are

    contractionary. However, the role of devaluations in this model is precisely the opposite,

    namely, to prevent the contraction in the tradable sector to spill over into the nontraded

    sector. It follows that in this economy devaluations are indeed expansionary in the sense that

    should they not take place, aggregate contractions would be even larger. Thus, under the

    optimal exchange-rate regime, our model with downward nominal rigidities turns the view

    that devaluations are contractionary on its head and instead predicts that contractions are

    devaluatory.

    Under the optimal monetary policy, the average devaluation rate is positive (Et > 1).This result follows directly form the fact that, by equation (29), the equilibrium gross deval-

    uation rate is time varying and bounded below by unity. The inflation rate in the nontraded

    sector is also positive on average. To see this, notice that the relative price of nontradables,

    pt, is given by the ratio of the nominal price of nontradables and the nominal exchange

    rate. Because in our model the relative price of nontradables is a stationary variable and

    16

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    18/23

    the nominal exchange rate grows on average at a positive rate, it follows that the nominal

    price of nontradables must also grow on average at a positive rate, which means that the

    inflation rate in the nontraded sector must be positive on average. The aggregate rate of

    inflation is then also positive on average, because it is a weighted average of the inflation

    rates of the traded and nontraded sectors. Therefore, our model formalizes Oliveras (1960,1964) structural or nonmonetary theory of the optimality of positive inflation.3

    When the exchange-rate policy takes the form of a currency peg, macroeconomic dynam-

    ics are characterized by equations (14)-(18) evaluated at t = 0 for all t. As in the case

    of the optimal exchange-rate-policy, consumption of tradables equals tradable output at all

    times, cTt = yTt . But the dynamics of employment, wages, and the real exchange rate are

    quite different across the two monetary regimes. Under a currency peg, the economy will

    display involuntary unemployment whenever the full employment wage rate, f(yTt ), falls

    below wt1. Because f is strictly increasing, it follows that involuntary unemployment is

    more likely to emerge the larger is the contraction in the tradable sector.

    To illustrate the predictions of our model we perform a numerical simulation. We assume

    a CRRA form for the period utility function, a CES form for the aggregator function and

    an isoelastic form for the production function of nontradables:

    U(c) =c1 1

    1 ,

    A(cT, cN) = a(cT)11 + (1 a)(cN)1 1

    1

    ,

    and

    F(h) = h.

    We calibrate the model at a quarterly frequency using data from Argentina. Reinhart and

    Vegh (1995) estimate the intertemporal elasticity of substitution to be 0.21, using Argentine

    quarterly data. We therefore set equal to 5. We normalize the steady-state levels of

    output of tradables and hours at unity. The parameter a then represents the share of traded

    consumption in total consumption. We set this parameter at 0.26, which is the share of

    traded output observed in Argentine data over the period 1980:Q1-2010:Q1. This approachto calibrating the share of tradable consumption is justified in the context of a model without

    investment and with financial autarky. We set the elasticity of substitution between traded

    and nontraded consumption, , to 0.44 following the estimates of Stockman and Tesar (1995).

    Following Uribes (1997) evidence on the size of the labor share in the nontraded sector in

    Argentina, we set equal to 0.75.

    3See also Tobin (1972).

    17

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    19/23

    Table 1: Calibration

    Parameter Value Description 5 Inverse of intertemporal elasticity of consumptiona 0.26 Share of tradables

    0.44 Elasticity of substitution between tradables and nontradables 0.75 Labor share in nontraded sectorh 1 Labor endowment

    yT 1 Steady-state tradable output 0.90 Serial correlation of log tradable output

    T 0.0355 Standard deviation of innovation to log of tradable output 0.953 Quarterly subjective discount factorr 0.02 Quarterly world interest rate 0.0002 Debt sensitivity of country premium 0.99,0.95,0.9 Degree of downward nominal wage rigidity

    The driving force in our model is the stochastic process for tradable output. Our empirical

    measure ofyTt is Argentine GDP in agriculture, forestry, fishing, mining, and manufacturing.

    After removing a log-quadratic time trend, we estimate the following AR(1) process using

    data over the period 1980:Q1 to 2010:Q1:

    ln(yTt /yT) = ln(yTt1/y

    T) + Tt, (30)

    where t is white noise with mean zero and variance equal to one. Our OLS estimates of

    and T are, respectively, 0.90 and 0.0355.A key parameter in our model is , which measures the ability of firms to cut nominal

    wages without facing worker resistance. To our knowledge, no econometric estimate of this

    parameter exists. One difficulty in estimating is that it belongs to an occasionally binding

    constraint. Therefore, the econometrician cannot rely on an equation that holds in every

    period and features among its parameters. Also, empirical evidence on the observed

    frequency of nominal wage cuts, taken in isolation, is in general not informative about the

    size of. The reason is that the frequency of observed wage cuts in general depends on the

    underlying monetary regime. For example, in the calibrated economy studied here, when

    equals 0.95, nominal-wage cuts occur 60 percent of the time under an exchange-rate peg,

    and 50 percent of the time under the optimal policy. These figures could erroneously be

    interpreted as meaning that in the currency-peg economy nominal wages are less rigid than

    in the optimal-monetary-policy economy. These arguments suggest that must be estimated

    in the context of a fully-specified general equilibrium model featuring a full description not

    only of the incentives of households, workers, and firms, but also of government policy.

    18

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    20/23

    Table 2: Inflation, Unemployment, and Welfare

    Wage Mean Inflation Mean Unemployment Std. Dev. log(ct) WelfareStickiness Optimal Currency Optimal Currency Optimal Currency Cost

    Policy Peg Policy Peg Policy Peg of PegA. Complete Asset Marketsall 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    B. Financial Autarky0.99 12.01 0.01 0.00 7.08 2.10 5.47 4.880.95 5.60 0.00 0.00 1.33 2.10 2.88 0.840.90 1.66 0.00 0.00 0.26 2.10 2.25 0.16

    Note. The inflation rate is expressed in percent per year. The mean unemployment rate and the

    standard deviation of the log of consumption is in percent. The welfare cost of a peg is calculated

    as the percentage increase in the entire consumption path associated with a peg required to yield

    the same level of welfare as under the optimal monetary policy.

    Therefore, we perform our simulations for three alternative values of , 0.99, 0.95, and 0.9.

    We consider a value of of 0.9 to represent a case of high wage flexibility. For in this case

    every firm in the economy can cut nominal wages by 40 percent each year without incurring

    any cost or resistance on the part of workers. On the other hand, we interpret the case of

    = 0.99, as representing a situation of relatively high downward nominal rigidity. For in

    this case firms face high resistance to any wage cuts larger than 4 percent per year. The

    case of = 0.95 represents a situation of intermediate nominal wage rigidity, in which firms

    can cut nominal wages by 20 percent in one year, without facing much resistance. Table 1summarizes the calibration of the model.

    Table 2 displays model predictions for the average inflation rate, the average rate of

    unemployment, consumption volatility, and the welfare cost of a currency peg. Panel A of the

    table presents the results derived theoretically for the economy with complete asset markets.

    In this economy, agents are able to fully smooth consumption. As a result, monetary policy is

    irrelevant, and, in particular, the welfare cost of a currency peg is nil. By contrast, in the case

    of financial autarky, shown in panel B of table 2, monetary policy can play an important role

    in moderating the aggregate effects of external shocks when nominal wages are downwardly

    rigid. Under the optimal policy regime, the average rate of inflation is 5.6 percent per year

    at the intermediate level of downward wage rigidity ( = 0.95). As explained earlier, the

    optimality of positive average inflation is explained by the central banks policy of inflating

    away the purchasing power of nominal wages when equilibrium in the labor market requires

    cuts in real labor costs.

    By contrast, the average rate of inflation is virtually zero under a currency peg regardless

    19

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    21/23

    of the degree of downward wage rigidity. To see why inflation is near zero under a currency

    peg, we note that with a CES aggregator of tradables and nontradables, the consumer price

    index is given by

    Pt = aE1t + (1 a)

    PNt1

    1

    1

    ,

    where Pt denotes the nominal price of one unit of the composite consumption good in period

    t, and PNt denotes the nominal price of one unit of nontradable consumption in period

    t. It follows from this expression that the gross rate of consumer-price inflation, denoted

    t Pt/Pt1, is given by

    t =

    a + (1 a)pt

    1

    a + (1 a)pt11

    11

    t.

    Because the relative price of nontradables, pt, is a stationary variable, it follows that under a

    currency peg (i.e., when the central bank sets t = 1 at all times), the rate of inflation must

    be approximately nil on average.

    The low and stable rate of inflation induced by the currency peg comes at the cost of

    poorer real macroeconomic performance. In particular, the currency peg causes unemploy-

    ment, which ranges from 7 percent in the high-wage-rigidity case to about 0.25 percent in the

    low-wage-rigidity case, and an elevated volatility of consumption, which reaches 5 percent

    with high wage rigidity and 2 percent with low wage rigidity. The last column of table 2

    shows that the welfare cost of a currency peg can be large. It shows that in the high-wage-

    rigidity case, households require an increase of 5 percent in their consumption stream to feelas happy as in the economy with optimal monetary policy. The welfare cost of a peg is also

    sizable in the economy with intermediate wage rigidities, reaching 1 percent. When firms

    are allowed to cut nominal wages by 40 percent per year or more (i.e., when is less than

    or equal to 0.9), the economy behaves virtually as an economy with full wage flexibility. We

    conclude that in the economy under study, the central bank faces a clear tradeoff between

    inflation on the one hand, and unemployment and aggregate instability on the other hand.

    Moreover, this tradeoff can involve large numbers for both inflation and unemployment for

    relatively mild levels of downward nominal rigidities. For instance, we have shown that when

    firms can costlessly cut nominal wages y up to twenty percent per year, the rate of inflation

    ranges from 6 percent per year under the optimal exchange-rate policy to zero percent under

    a peg, and structural unemployment ranges from zero under the optimal policy to 1.3 percent

    under a currency peg.

    In the present model, the employment-inflation tradeoff is trivially resolved in favor of

    inflation. This is because, for simplicity, we have assumed that inflation is costless. However,

    20

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    22/23

    in a more realistic setting in which in secular price increases are costly, such as in models that

    introduce a demand for liquidity or models with upwardly rigid product prices, the structural

    inflationary pressures highlighted in this paper would give rise to a nontrivial resolution of

    the employment-inflation tradeoff.

    [TO BE CONTINUED]

    21

  • 8/9/2019 Currency Pegs and Unemployment

    23/23

    References

    Mendoza, Enrique G., and Vivian Z. Yue, A Solution to the Disconnect between Country

    Risk and Business Cycle Theories, working paper, University of Maryland, April 2010.

    Olivera, Julio H. G., La Teora No Monetaria de la Inflacion, El Trimestre Economico 27,

    October-December 1960, 616-628.

    Olivera, Julio H. G., On Structural Inflation and Latin-American Structuralism, Oxford

    Economic Papers 16, November 1964, 321-332.

    Reinhart, Carmen M., and Carlos A. Vegh, Nominal interest rates, consumption booms,

    and lack of credibility: A quantitative examination, Journal of Development Economics

    46, April 1995, 357-378.

    Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie, and Martn Uribe, The Optimal Rate of Inflation, Handbook

    of Monetary Economics, edited by B. Friedman and M. Woodford, 2010 forthcoming.

    Stockman, Alan C., and Linda L. Tesar, Tastes and Technology in a Two-Country Modelof the Business Cycle: Explaining International Comovements, American Economic

    Review 85, March 1995, 168-185.

    Tobin, James, Inflation and Unemployment, American Economic Review 62, March 1972,

    1-18.

    Uribe, Martn, Exchange-Rate-Based Inflation Stabilization: The Initial Real Effects of

    Credible Plans, Journal of Monetary Economics 39, June 1997, 197-221.