chapters 5: using consumer choice theory

32
1 Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

Upload: munin

Post on 15-Jan-2016

43 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory. Returning to the Concept of Consumer Surplus. Consumer surplus is a dollar measure of the extent to which a consumer (or many) benefits from participating in a transaction - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

1

Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

Page 2: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

2

Returning to the Conceptof Consumer Surplus

• Consumer surplus is a dollar measure of the extent to which a consumer (or many) benefits from participating in a transaction– Assuming that transactions occur voluntarily (implying that those engaging in them are better off than had the transactions not occurred), consumer surplus represents the difference in what one was willing to pay for a product/service and what one actually had to pay to obtain that product/service

• The concept of consumer surplus is key to evaluating public policies such as taxation/subsidization, price ceilings/floors, etc.

Page 3: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

3

Consumer Surplus

P*

Q

PConsumer’s surplus

Page 4: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

4

Algebra of Consumer Surplus

10

12

20

Consumer surplus before tax =

Consumer surplus after tax =

Change in C.S. after tax =

8 10

12 (20 10)10 50

12 (20 12)8 32

50 32 [(12 10)8] [1/2(12 10)(8 10)] 18

Page 5: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

5

Price Elasticity and Consumer Surplus

Elastic Demand

Inelastic Demand

S0

S1

Loss in C.S. for elastic demand

Loss in C.S. for inelastic demand

Page 6: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

6

Calculating Loss in Consumer Surplus

• Loss in Consumer Surplus

(P Q) .5(P Q)

P

Q

Q

Demand

Supply0

Supply1

Q

P

Page 7: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

7

Taxation

Tax RevenueLoss in C.S.

Loss in P.S.

Deadweight Loss

Q

P

D

S

ST

Page 8: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

8

Taxation on the Supply Side

D1

S1

S2

A B

CF

E D

Pc

Pno tax

Pp

Pc = Price paid by consumer Pp = Price received by producer

G

• Lost P.S. = FCDE• Lost C.S. = ABCF• Tax Revenue = ABDE • Deadweight Loss = BCD• Tax Paid By Consumer=ABFG• Tax Paid By Producer = FGDE

Page 9: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

9

Taxation on the Demand Side

D1D2

S

A B

C

D

E

FPno tax

Pc

Pp

• Lost P.S. = FCDE• Lost C.S. = ABCF• Tax Revenue = ABDE • Deadweight Loss = BCD• Tax Paid By Consumer=ABFG• Tax Paid By Producer = FGDE

Pc = Price paid by consumer Pp = Price received by producer

G

Page 10: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

10

Algebraic Example of Taxation

• The government imposes a $0.404/pack cigarette tax– What is the total amount of the tax?

– What percentage of the tax is paid by the consumers?

– What percentage of the tax is paid by the producers?

– What is the total deadweight loss of the tax?

$0.404 9,996 $4030.38

$0.40 9,996 $3,998.4 99% of Tax

$0.004 9,996 $39.98 1% of Tax

.5 ($0.404 4) $0.81

QD 10,040 10P

QS 6000 1000PSupply and Demand Before Tax

Page 11: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

11

Burden of Taxation: Elastic Demand

Loss in C.S.

Loss in P.S. D

SST

Q

P

Page 12: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

12

Burden of Taxation: Inelastic Demand

Loss in C.S.

Loss in P.S.

Q

P

D

S

ST

Page 13: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

13

Algebra of Taxation: Elastic and Inelastic

Demand

Supply : QS 850 P

Elastic Demand :Qd (e ) 1450 5P

Inelastic Demand : Qd (i) 1000 .5P

• Government imposes tax of $60

Supply Tax :QST 790 P

Elastic Demand : P eT 110, QeT 900 C.S. 9250

Inelastic Demand : P iT =140, QiT 930 C.S. 38,400

• Two demand curves (elastic & inelastic) have the same initial equilibrium price and quantity

P* 100, Q* 950

Page 14: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

14

Bias in Consumer Price Index

• Substitution Bias: The CPI does not take into account the fact that consumers will change their consumption basket as relative prices change. (Substitution Effect)

• Quality Change: The CPI holds a basket of goods as fixed, when in fact the quality of some of the goods may be changing dramatically over time (e.g. the efficacy of pharmaceuticals)

Page 15: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

15

CAFÉ Standards for Automobiles

• Justification for government intervention– Imperfect information about long-term benefits– Imperfect capital markets– Externalities (pollution and national security) - estimated to be 12 cents per gallon

• Government solution - regulations governing average fleet mileage– Fines imposed on those who don’t meet government standard

• (Possible) consequences– Increased lobbying expenditure– Increased fleet sales– “Rebound Effect”

Page 16: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

16

Graphical Depiction of CAFÉ Standards

Quantity of Automobiles

Price of Automobiles

Supply without CAFÉ Standards

Supply with CAFÉ Standards

Demand for automobiles

PC

QC

PE

QE

Marginal Social Cost (MSC)

Page 17: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

17

Alternative Way to Meet Objective: Tax and Rebate

Amount of rebate

Gasoline

$

Page 18: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

18

Strip Club Moratorium

• Justification for government intervention: negative externalities

• Government solution - restrict the number of strip clubs in Seattle to 4 (existing) clubs

• (Possible) consequences– Higher prices– Economic profits– Possible loss of consumer surplus

Page 19: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

19

Graphical Depiction of Strip Club Moratorium

market supply

market demand

Quantity of strip clubs

Price

Regulated

Supply = S 1

Regulated

Supply = S 2

Ps

QS

PE

QE

Page 20: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

20

Intertemporal Choice

• Just as consumers make decisions over the purchase of different combinations of goods, they make decisions about whether to purchase goods today or in the future

• We can examine consumer preferences over intertemporal choice using the tradition IC framework– Intertemporal ICs show combinations of current/future consumption for which consumers are indifferent

– The marginal rate of time preference (MRTP), which is the slope of the Intertemporal IC, shows the rate at which the consumer is willing to trade off consumption today versus consumption tomorrow

– Consumers may exhibit positive, negative, or neutral time preference (most exhibit positive)

Page 21: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

21

Factors Affecting Time Preferences

• Inidividual preferences

• Uncertainty about future events

• Value of anticipated future utility/disutility

• Preferences for a rising consumption standard

Page 22: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

22

Graphical Illustration of Time Preferences

C1C1 C1

C2 C2 C2

Impatience Neutrality Patience

Page 23: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

23

Intertemporal Budget Constraint

• The intertemporal budget constraint is determined by r, the interest rate

• Assuming consumers can borrow freely, the intertemporal budget constraint is represented by:

C1 C2

1 rY1

Y2

1 r

Page 24: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

24

Intertemporal Optimality

C1

C2

Y1 (1+r) + Y2

Y1+Y2(1+r)-1

C1*

C2*

Page 25: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

25

Changes in the Interest Rate and Optimality

Y1+Y2(1+r1)-1Y1+Y2(1+r0)-1

Y1 (1+r0) + Y2

Y1 (1+r1) + Y2

• Interest rate falls from r0

to r1

• Interest rate begins at r0

Page 26: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

26

Algebraic Example of Intertemporal Choice

If James earns $50,000 this year and will earn $60,000 next year, what is the maximum interest rate that would allow him to spend $100,000 this year?

What is the minimum interest rate that would allow him to spend $115,000 next year?

$50,000$60,000

1 r$100,000 r.2

$50,000(1 r) $60,000 $115,000 r.1

Page 27: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

27

Homo Economicus?

• Some people may function as perfect examples of Homo Economicus, but most only approximate this behavior– We are satisfiers not maximizers, but this is rational!

• Limitations of rationality– Asymmetric treatment of gains and losses (K-T value function)– Failure to appropriately ignore sunk costs– Judgmental heuristics and biases

• Availability• Representativeness• Anchoring and adjustment

• So long as people practice “bounded rationality” economic theory is useful

Page 28: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

28

Kahneman-Tversky Value Function

Losses Gains

Value

V(gain)

V(loss)

loss

gain

V(loss) V(gain)

Page 29: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

29

Sunk Costs

• James and AJ have the same preferences for movies. They’re both eager to see the latest summer blockbuster but work different schedules: James can only attend the matinee ($3.50) and AJ can only attend the evening show ($9.00). Halfway through the movie they both realize they hate it. Which is more likely to walk out?

• K-T value function helps explain failure to ignore sunk costs!

Page 30: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

30

K-T Value Function and the Market

• Sellers, gift givers, etc. can “manipulate” consumers by:– Segregating gains (e.g. separate lottery wins)– Combining losses (e.g. state and fed tax delinquency notices)

– Offsetting small loss with a larger gain (e.g. lottery and ink drop)

– Segregating small gains from large losses (e.g. car rebate)

• We see examples of all of these practices above in the marketplace

Page 31: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

31

Graphical Depiction of K-T Practices

1000

1000

A manufacturer offers a $1000 rebate on a car

purchase

Page 32: Chapters 5: Using Consumer Choice Theory

32

Judgmental Heuristics (Rules of Thumb)

• Availability - memory research shows that it is easier to recall an event the more vivid, sensational, or recent it is– As a consequence, we often put too much weight on these type of events (e.g. murders and suicides in NYC, “r” as first or third letter)

• Representativeness - we often overstate the importance of representative events– Judgments about muggings– Regression to the mean– Sophomore/SI jinx

• Anchoring and adjustment - we often overstate the importance of the anchor (e.g. which is larger 1x2x3…x9 or 9x8x7…1)