carbon copies: the united states, eu ets and linkage...carbon copies: the united states, eu ets and...

73
CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE by Benjamin Higham A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements For the degree of Master of Law Graduate Department of Law University of Toronto Copyright by Benjamin Higham 2009

Upload: others

Post on 29-May-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE

by

Benjamin Higham

A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements For the degree of Master of Law

Graduate Department of Law University of Toronto

Copyright by Benjamin Higham 2009

Page 2: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage

Benjamin Higham

Master of Laws

Graduate Department of Law University of Toronto

2009

Abstract

Although many nations have recognized the need to protect the Earth’s climate,

human activities are continuing to result in a change in greenhouse gas levels that

threaten to result in a detrimental change in the Earth’s climate in terms of ongoing

human life. The EU ETS has been developed and implemented in Europe as a key tool

to meet the goals set by the Kyoto Protocol. Much political debate has arisen in recent

years regarding the implementation of a carbon-trading regime in the United States.

Many commentators have recognized that the success of any proposed carbon regime will

be determined by how well it is tailored to fit certain economic realities in the United

States. However, the adequacy of proposed carbon trading frameworks with regard to

potential linkage to existing systems, namely the EU ETS, raises additional

considerations. My study seeks to expose these considerations for debate and determine

whether existing political considerations in the United States are adequate for the

establishment of future linkages or whether further measures are required.

ii

Page 3: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

Table of Contents

I.

II.

A.

B.

Purpose and Scope of the Article

Overview of Climate Change Science and Law

Climate Science

International Law 1.United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change 2.Kyoto Protocol 3.International Adoption and Compliance

Cap-and-Trade Primer 1.The Cap 2.The Trade

Broad Coverage

Linkage

The European Union Emissions Trading System

A. The European Model 1.Overview 2.The Market 3.Compliance and Enforcement

Domestic EU ETS issues

1. 2. 3.

C.

IV.

A.

1. 2. 3.

National Caps – What Went Wrong? Domestic Lobbying Looking Forward

Summary of Part III

A Comparison of the EU ETS, the Dingell-Boucher Draft and the Waxman-Markey Bill

The United States

US Administrative Intent Existing Federal Regulatory Approach Dingell-Boucher and Waxman-Markey Legislation

1

3

3

4 4 5 6

7 7 8

10

12

14

14 14 17 21

23

24 25 26

26

28

29

29 30 32

C.

D.

E.

III.

B.

iii

Page 4: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

i.

ii.

iii.

iv. v.

vi. vii. viii. ix.

B.

V.

A.

B.

Implementation Plan a.Implementation and Linkage Scope a.Scope and Linkage Currency of the U.S. ETS a.Currency and Linkage National Registry Allowance Allocation a.Allocation and Linkage Trading Monitoring and Reporting Compliance Pre-emption

33 35 36 39 40 42 43 45 47 48 50 50 51

52

53

53

55 55 57 57

59

60

61

Summary of Part IV

Conclusions on Linkage

Linkage Generally

Linkage Suggestions 1.Allocations 2.Price Control – Borrowing 3.Enforcement

Summary of Part V

Conclusion

Bibliography

C.

VI.

VII.

iv

Page 5: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

1

PART I Purpose and Scope of the Article

While many nations have recognized the need to act on global climate change by

implementing legislation to mandate reductions of greenhouse gas emissions, for various

reasons, the United States has delayed its participation in these efforts. Now, four year

after the Kyoto Protocol came into force and the EU ETS was commenced, the U.S.

Congress has taken its first steps toward delivering climate change legislation. While the

linkage of any U.S. carbon trading scheme to the EU ETS may offer economic

advantages, there will be serious compatibility issues that must be addressed in order for

these advantages to be realized. This paper presents these administrative concerns and

identifies areas where aspects of proposed legislation should be improved in order to

address these concerns.

This paper is structured as follows. Part II presents the prevailing view of global

climate change and discusses the legal backdrop. Part III has two primary objectives.

The first objective is to provide a detailed explanation of the EU ETS and the structural

mechanisms by which it is implemented. The second objective is to explain the causes

and effects of problems arising during the first phase of implementation. Part IV has three

primary objectives. The first objective is to describe the effect of the Massachusetts v.

EPA decision on the U.S. regulatory power to regulate CO2, and the importance of

legislative action. The second objective is to describe the Dingell-Boucher Draft

legislation recently released for discussion in the House of Representatives and then

access the similarities and differences of this proposal with the European approach

1

Page 6: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

2

discussed in Part III. The third objective is to describe the ways in which Waxman-

Markey Bill recently passed in the House of Representatives builds on the Dingell-

Boucher Draft. Part V conducts a preliminary assessment of the compatibility of the

proposed Dingell-Boucher Draft and Waxman-Markey Bill with the existing European

scheme with regards to the implementation of linkage between the systems. Part VI

concludes the article.

Page 7: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

3

PART II Overview of Climate Change Science and Law

Despite dire warnings in recent years from respected members of the scientific

community, many nations remain standing at the sidelines of global climate change

policy development. The European Union, however, has committed itself to an

environmental undertaking that is certainly unmatched by any other collective effort. This

undertaking, known as the European Union Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS),

resembles established market mechanisms. While the European concept of emissions

trading appears to be straightforward. It becomes clear, however, in the course of further

analysis of its implementation, that in order to succeed the European model requires

consideration and reconciliation of disparate national interests. In effect, nations must

not only work together, but also in order to realize the shared long term objective of

collective emission reduction they must sometimes implement climate legislation that is

not in their direct national interest.

A. Climate Science

In support of their position, critics of the theory of global climate change offer the

undisputed fact that the natural processes occurring on our planet have, for millions of

years, resulted in the emission of greenhouse gasses. Intelligent minds differ, however,

when assessing whether our relatively recent industrialization, resulting in increased

greenhouse gas emissions over the natural baseline, will result in a detrimental change in

3

Page 8: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

4

the Earth’s climate in terms of ongoing human life.1

Scientists issuing global climate warnings have undertaken much scientific work

to support their allegations. The World Meteorological Organization (WMO) is a prime

contributor to such a debate. Most recently, WMO provided a comment stating that the

collective scientific research of its members supports the conclusion that greenhouse gas

emissions have and are expected to continue to increase global temperatures.2 Although

some comment that warming may bring certain benefits to colder regions of the planet,

the WMO suggests that warming introduces collateral “reasons for concern” that will

detrimentally offset these benefits.3

B.

1.

Climate Change Law and Policy

International Law

Entering into force in 1994, the United Nations Framework Convention on

Climate Change4 (UNFCCC) is not legally binding on its signatories. Despite limits on

its enforceability, it is well worthy of note and indeed represents the legal philosophy and

underpinnings of ongoing attempts "to achieve stabilization of greenhouse gas

1 See Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Fourth Assessment Report, Climate Change 2007: Synthesis Report, Summary for Policymakers, online: IPCC http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessmentreport/ ar4/syr/ar4_syr_spm.pdf [Climate Change 2007] 2“The long-term upward trend of global warming, mostly driven by greenhouse gas emissions, is continuing. Global temperatures in 2008 are expected to be above the long-term average. The decade from 1998 to 2007 has been the warmest on record, and the global average surface temperature has risen by 0.74C since the beginning of the 20th Century”. See World Meteorological Organization, Info Note No. 44, online: WMO <http://www.wmo.int/pages/mediacentre/info_notes/info_44_en.html> 3Heightened risks to unique and threatened systems (ecosystems and communities); risks of extreme weather events (droughts, floods, and heat waves); distribution of impacts and vulnerabilities (economically disadvantaged and elderly will be more effected by climate change); aggregate impacts (net economic costs of impacts of increased warming are projected to increase over time); and risks of large scale singularities (global warming over many centuries would lead to sea level rise). See Climate Change 2007, supra note 1 4United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, “U.N. Doc. A/AC 237/18”, online: U.N. <http://unfccc.int/essential_background/convention/background/items/1349.php> [UNFCCC]

Page 9: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

5

concentrations in the atmosphere at a low enough level to prevent dangerous

anthropogenic interference with the climate system."5

While the UNFCCC does not provide mandatory limits or contain enforcement

provisions,6 some member industrialized and developed nations have openly expressed

concerns with the differential treatment of developing nations under the Convention.7

Despite these concerns, ratification and implementation of the UNFCCC framework

serves as the inevitable jumping off point for the discussion of the EU climate model.

UNFCCC’s importance in this regard is clearly evidenced by its provision of the more

widely recognized “protocols”, which establish binding reductions of national emissions

of greenhouse gases.

2. Kyoto Protocol

The Kyoto Protocol is likely one of the first pavlovian responses in the mind of a

typical person at the mention of climate change. The Kyoto Protocol has been a

somewhat globally contentious attempt to implement the policies of the UNFCCC. It is

also the motivator for the European climate regime discussed in the next part.

5 6 UNFCCC, supra note 4 at art 2 Article 4 sets out a number of non-binding commitments such as, “[d]evelop, periodically update, publish … national inventories of anthropogenic emissions by sources and removals by sinks of all greenhouse gases” and “[f]ormulate, implement, publish and regularly update national and … regional programmes containing measures to mitigate climate change by addressing anthropogenic emissions by sources and removals by sinks of all greenhouse gasses”. See ibid note 4, at art. 4 7For example the preamble to the UNFCCC states that “[t]he largest share of historical and current global emissions of greenhouse gases has originated in developed countries, that per capita emissions in developing countries are still relatively low and that the share of global emissions originating in developing countries are still relatively low and that the share of global emissions originating in developing counties will grow to meet their social and developmental needs.” See UNFCCC, supra note 4, at preamble

Page 10: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

6

By way of summary, the Kyoto Protocol, which entered into force in February

2005, commits industrialized countries to the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions8 by

an average of 5.2 percent9 from 1990 base year levels during the years 2008-2012.10

While there is more than one method of calculating the baseline from which these

reductions can be realized, Kyoto and resulting emissions reduction schemes seeking to

promote compliance with it, facilitate certainty by pegging all reduction targets on the

1990 base year, with ascertainable emission data.

3. International Adoption and Compliance

As mentioned, ratification of the Kyoto Protocol has proven to be a contentious

matter. While both the problem of climate change and its global nature have been

recognized, adoption of the protocol was plagued by national protectionism and a failure

to act. Some nations, such as Canada, signed on but will not meet their commitments.

Others, such as America, led the way with “alternate” approaches, discussed in Part IV.

Industrial nations who are signatories to the Kyoto Protocol are not required by

the agreement to implement any specific domestic policies.11 They are free to pursue

reductions in greenhouse gas emissions in accordance with their national circumstances.12

In recognition of the difficulty of such efforts, the Kyoto Protocol details three “flexible

8 Carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, sulfur hexafluoride, hydrofluorocarbons, and perfluorocarbons: See Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, U.N. Doc. FCCC/CP/197/L.7/Add. Annex A (Dec. 10, 1997), online: U.N. <http://unfccc.int/essential_background /kyoto_protocol/items/1678.php> [Kyoto Protocol] 9The EU is required to reduce emissions by 8 percent: ibid. at art. 3.7 10ibid. at art. 3.1 & Annex B 11ibid. at art. 2 12ibid.

Page 11: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

7

mechanisms” that industrialized nations may choose to employ to reduce greenhouse gas

emissions. Of the flexible mechanisms, the most well known and the topic of the

remainder of this article is “emissions trading”.13 The other two are the “clean

development mechanism”14 which creates tradable credits through investment in

emission reduction projects in developing countries15 and “joint implementation”16 which

creates tradable credits through investment in emission reduction projects located in a

developed member nation other than the nation of the entity seeking creation of the

credit.17

C. Cap-and-Trade Primer

In order to assess an emissions trading scheme, such as the EU ETS, or the

compatibility of multiple schemes, a basic comprehension of the types of undertakings

that comprise these systems is helpful. This section presents a general explanation of

these undertakings – capping emissions of CO2 and trading the right to emit CO2.

1. The Cap

When an emission trading regime is undertaken and a corresponding market is to

be relied on, the establishment of a scarce cap and corresponding pool of allowances is

fundamental. A cap represents a collective limit imposed by a state or several states that

13 14 Kyoto Protocol, supra note 8, at art 17 Kyoto Protocol, supra note 8, at art 12 15U.N., United Nations Convention on Climate Change, “clean development mechanism”, online: U.N. <http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/mechanisms/clean_development_mechanism/items/2718.php> 16Kyoto Protocol, supra note 8, at art 6 17U.N., United Nations Convention on Climate Change, Kyoto Protocol, online: <http://unfccc.int/ kyoto_protocol/mechanisms/joint_implementation/items/1674.php>

Page 12: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

8

restricts the overall CO2 emissions by members within the designated region.18 In

circumstances where multiple autonomous or semi-autonomous nations or states

contribute to a single cap, the total emissions reductions under the cap are usually

realized through parallel commitments to reduce emissions.19 In the case of the EU,

discussed in Part III, its member states have historically set their own emission limits

thereby creating the regional cap.20 In the US proposal, discussed later in Part IV, the

proponents envision a national cap that is distributed from the national level down, rather

than the bottom up approach in the EU.

In all emission trading regimes, overall caps are divided into tradable allowances

that are distributed to domestic entities.21 Each allowance can be visualized as a tradable

unit of the cap. It is common for an allowance to represent the right to emit one tonne of

CO2 or its equivalent during a specific period of time.22

2. The Trade

In the face of stiff penalties for failure to comply, emitters that find themselves

potentially releasing more of any particular greenhouse gas than permissible under their

permit, must choose between reducing emissions or purchasing allocations from other

18 Shapiro, S & Cheatham, C, “The Green Building Guide to Waxman-Markey”, Reuters, (26 June 2009), online: Reuters < http://www.reuters.com/article/gwmBuildings/idUS216473327920090626> 19See IHS, “FAQ on EU Emissions Trading and National Allocation Plans for 2008-2012”, online: <http://engineers.ihs.com/news/2006/eu-en-emissions-trading-faq-11-06.htm> 20See for a general discussion of the emission allocations: European Commission, online: Europa <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/06/2> 21Grubb, M. “The Economics of the Kyoto Protocol” World Economics, volume 4, number 3, (July- September 2003), p. 148, online: World Economics <www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php?doc ID=129> 22ibid.

Page 13: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

9

emitters covered under the regime or a linked regime.23 Fortunately, this results in the

creation of a market framework that incentivizes trading between emitters.24 Depending

on the regime, trading platforms often facilitate both direct and brokered trades and

exchanges.

When evaluating the benefits associated with a trade, each party to the trade

determines its position based in part on its own cost of compliance.25 As every individual

facility represents a different set of emission parameters, it follows that no two emitters

will incur the same cost per allocation of ‘actual’ reduction.26 For instance, the actual

cost per tonne of emission reductions in a U.K. manufacturing facility may be 50 Euros

while the same reductions implemented in another facility, even in the same sector, may

cost more. Such abatement cost heterogeneity facilitates market conditions by

encouraging emitters with low cost of compliance to lower emissions by investing in

abatement technologies, reducing output, or employing other control mechanisms.27

Emitters who lower their emissions can then sell surplus allowances to market

participants with a higher costs of compliance.28

The essence of cap-and-trade is its facilitation of reductions that are motivated by

the opportunity to sell excess allotments on the market at a price higher than the cost

23 See generally Thomson, V., “Early Observations on the European Union’s Greenhouse Gas Emission Trading Scheme: Insights for United States Policymakers” University of Virginia (19 April 2006), online: Pew Climate < www.pewclimate.org/.../Early_Observations_on_EUETS_Thomson.pdf> 24ibid. 25EU, “Greenhouse gas emission allowance trading scheme”, online: Europa < http://europa.eu/legislation_ summaries/energy/european_energy_policy/l28012_en.htm> 26Jaffe, J. and Stavins R., “Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture”, The Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements, Discussion Paper 08-07, September, online: Harvard <belfercenter.ksg.harvard.edu/.../linkage_of_tradable_permit_systems_in_ international_climate_policy_architecture.html> 27See EU, Emission Trading System (EU ETS), online: Environment <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/ climat/emission/citl_en.htm> 28Worldwatch Institute, State of the World 2009: Into a Warming World, (Washington, D.C.: Norton, W. W. & Company, Inc., 2009) at 104, online: Worldwatch <www.worldwatch.org/sow09>

Page 14: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

10

incurred to realize the emission reduction.29 In all regimes, there must be a liquid market

that pairs sellers with emitters who require additional allotments for compliance. It

follows, that such a system will contain emitters with a higher cost of compliance. With

high and low cost of compliance emitters entering the market for profit and to reduce

costs, emitters are free to make compliance decisions based on whether it is more cost

effective to reduce emissions or purchase carbon allocations at market price.30 Economic

theory supports the conclusion that the overall result of such an emission reduction

strategy is increased efficiency so long as a country’s national circumstances, sector

characteristics, and the strategies interaction with other policies allow emission

reductions to take place where they are cheaper.31

D. Broad Coverage

Although cap-and-trade can be an effective tool when appropriately implemented,

governments are not limited to carbon trading as a means of addressing climate change.

Other price mechanisms, such as carbon taxes, exist. A carbon tax differs from carbon

trading in that it allows government to directly establish the price of a quantity of

carbon.32 A carbon tax can be levied upstream at the source of the carbon rather than at

the point of consumption, where the administrative burden increases. A significant

29 30 See supra note 28 ibid. 31Stern, N. (2006): The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review; Cambridge University Press, New York, New York, ch. 15, <http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/ independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_change/sternreview_index.cfm> [Stern Report]. See also Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change Executive Summary; HM Treasury, online: < http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/Executive_Summary.pdf> 32Doelle, M, “Global Carbon Trading and Climate Change Mitigation in Canada: Options for the Use of the Kyoto Mechanisms” in Bernstein et al, eds., A Globally Integrated Climate Policy for Canada (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2007) p 179

Page 15: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

11

benefit of a carbon tax is that it can catch uses that could not be efficiently covered by

cap-and-trade, such as cars and domestic uses.33 This approach results in less certain

emission reductions, as compared with carbon trading where the total quantity of

emissions reductions is controlled directly.34

Efficiency implications, however, do not exist in a vacuum. For instance, national

policies “cannot be based on generalized notions of markets and governments, but must

be based on how institutions and individuals actually operate”.35 As a result, efficiency

implications are difficult to determine. This is compounded where “abatement costs

and/or benefits are uncertain, picking a carbon tax (price) can lead to the “wrong” level of

emissions reduction, while choosing a quantity can result in a mistake about the

forecasted” permit price.36

In 2006 the British government released a comprehensive study, the Stern Review

on the Economics of Climate Change [Stern Report]37, which addressed, in part, the

difficulty of determining implement efficiency. The Stern Report suggests that each

country should use the appropriate mix of taxes, trading, spending and regulation as

necessary to reach its emission reduction target.38 The Stern Report states that:

33 “Putting a Price on Carbon: An Emissions Cap or A Tax?” Opinion, Yale Environment 360, (07 May 2009) online: Yale Environment 360 <http://www. e360.yale.edu/content/feature.msp?id=2148> 34ibid. 35Green, A, “Bringing Institutions and Individuals into Climate Policy for Canada” in Bernstein et al, eds., A Globally Integrated Climate Policy for Canada (University of Toronto Press, 2007) p. 247 [Green] 36Weitzman, M.L., 1974 “Prices vs Quantities,” The Review of Economic Studies 41(October): 477-91, cited in van Kooten, G.C., 2003, “Smoke and Mirrors: The Kyoto Protocol and Beyond, Canadian Public Policy” 29: 397-415, online: University of Victoria <http://web.uvic.ca/~kooten/REPA/WorkingPaper2003 -04.pdf> 37 Stern Report, supra note 31 38House of Commons, “Stern Review: the implications for Treasury policy: Government Response to the Committee's Fourth Report of Session 2007–08” (22 April 2008), online: House of Commons <

Page 16: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

12

[t]he choice of policy tool will depend on countries’ national

circumstances, on the characteristics of particular sectors, and on the

interaction between climate-change policy and other policies. Policies also

have important differences in their consequences for the distribution of

costs across individuals, and their impact on the public finances. Taxation

has the advantage of delivering a steady flow of revenue, while, in the

case of trading, increasing the use of auctioning is likely to have strong

benefits for efficiency, for distribution and for the public finances. Some

administrations may choose to focus on trading initiatives, others on

taxation or regulation, and others on a mix of policies. And their choices may vary across sectors. 39

While the choice of instruments is difficult, in order to reduce global emissions, national

and regional policies should include a mix of carbon taxes, trading and/or regulations.40

E. Linkage

Linking exists where a carbon trading “system’s regulatory authority allows

regulated entities to use emission allowances or emission reduction credits from another

system to meet their domestic compliance obligations.”41 When all linked systems are

functioning properly, allowance trading between systems facilitates higher-cost

reductions in one system to be replaced by lower-cost reductions in another system.

http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200708/cmselect/cmtreasy/495/495.pdf> 39Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change Executive Summary; HM Treasury, p 18, online: < http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/Executive_Summary.pdf> 40Green, supra note 35 41Jaffe, J & Stavins, R, “Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture”, (Harvard Project on Int’l Climate Agreements, Discussion Paper 08-07, 2008) 7, online: Harvard – Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs <http://belfercenter.ksg.harvard.edu/ publication/18580/linkage_of_tradable_permit_systems_in_international_climate_policy_architecture.html > [Jaffe & Stavins], cited in Driesen, D.M. "Linkage and Multilevel Governance." 19 Duke J Comp & Int'l L 389, online: Duke Journal of Comparative and International Law < http://www.law.duke. edu/journals/djcil/> [Driessen]

Page 17: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

13

Thus, larger linked markets can facilitate greater cost savings that a smaller unlinked

market.42 While these cost savings serve as an incentive to link, carbon trading program

administrators must also consider the resulting concerns, including increased

complexity43 and most notably the impact global emissions and national control have

over allowance prices.44 For instance, administrators must pierce the veil of cost savings

to determine whether linkage is facilitating the “evasion of pollution control obligations or

simply control[ing] cost differentials between states.” 45

A noted climate commentator recently concluded that less focus should be placed

on linking different systems and more of a focus should be placed on innovations and

emission reduction maximization.46 The commentator believes that while well-designed

trading programs can contribute to lowering global carbon emissions, in order to

maximize reductions, governments must focus their efforts on encouraging development

and use of advanced technology in developing nations.47 However, as another

commentator has pointed out, even if linkage does not encourage the technology

development, in-kind side payments arising from linkage benefits poor countries by

providing resources to help manage the negative effects of climate change.48

42 Wiener, J.B., “Global Environmental Regulation: Instrument Choice in Legal Context”, 108 YALE L.J. 677, 701-04 (1999), cited in Driessen, supra note 41 at 391 43Driessen, supra note 41 at 391 44Jaffe & Stavins, supra note 41 at 1 45Driessen, supra note 41 at 396 46ibid at 411 47ibid at 409 48Wiener, J, “Think Globally, Act Globally: The Limits of Local Climate Policies”, Duke Law School Legal Studies, Research Paper Series, Research Paper No. 158 (May 2007), fn 53, online: Duke Law School <http://lsr.nellco.org/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1093&context=duke/fs>

Page 18: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

14

PART III

The European Union Emission Trading System

In 2003, the EU sought to meet its collective obligations under the Kyoto Protocol

by creating an emissions trading regime from the ground up.49 Known as the EU ETS,

the scheme has matured to facilitate market-based trading of CO2, by reliance on the cap-

and-trade model discussed in Part II. This part undertakes to provide a comprehensive

presentation of the EU ETS regime in order to adequately facilitate a subsequent

comparison of proposed U.S. emissions legislation.

A.

1.

The European Model

Overview

Phase I of the implementation of the EU ETS commenced in January of 2005 and

closed at the end of 2007. This phase represented the first of several distinct phases.50 By

design, the initial phase was non-binding, or a “learning phase”. Undertaking this phase

allowed stakeholders to implement the scheme without exposure to possibly significant

49 EC, Commission Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 October 2003 establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC [2003], online: <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/ emission/implementation_en.htm> [2003/87/EC] 50UK Dept. of Environment, “Early days of EU Emissions Trading System and the Response of Government and Business” (2008), online: UK Dept. of Environment <http://www.delkor.ec.europa.eu/ home/newsevents/events/document_files/Session2/Session23%2520Duggan.pdf>

14

Page 19: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

15

legal and financial consequences that resulted from embedded efficiency issues and a

lack of emissions data.51

Running parallel with the Kyoto compliance period, Phase II commenced on

January 1, 2008 and will close in 2012.52 As compliance with the EU ETS is now

mandatory, allotments from the prior non-binding phase were not carried forward.

Discussed in greater detail later in this part, this measure was necessary in order to avoid

an inevitable market dilution that would have occurred as a result of known over

allocation.53

Phase III is scheduled to begin in January of 2013. At the present time, the

European Commission is reviewing proposed changes and undertaking amendments.54

For example, the European Parliament recently amended the establishing directive55 to

include aviation after 2013, expanding the scope of the EU ETS.56 Lessons learned by

the Commission are reflected in the January 2008 proposed revisions to the scheme.57

As discussed, the implementation directive establishes the structure of the EU

ETS. Annex 1, of that same directive, lays out the regulatory reach of the EU ETS, or its

scope.58 In laying out this reach, Annex 1 specifically includes CO2 by reference within

51 Frauendorfer, “Clean Valuation with regard to EU Emission Trading” (2008), p.3, online: U.N. <http://www.finance.unisg.ch/org/finance/web.nsf/SysWebRessources/WP84/%24FILE/WP84.pdf> 52ibid at 2; 2003/87/EC, supra note 49 53Regulations prohibited the carrying over of emission rights between Phase I and II. Ibid at 3 54Defra, Dept. for Environment Food and Rural Affairs, “Phase III”, online: <http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/eu/operators/phase-3.htm>. 552003/87/EC, supra note 49 56Amended on July 8, 2008. European Parliament, “Air pollution: including aviation activities in the scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community (amend. Directive 2003/87/EC)”, online: EP <http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=-//EP//TEXT+TA+P6- TA-2008 0333+0+DOC+XML+V0//EN&language=EN> 57The E.U. intends to move from free allocation to auctioning: 2003/87/EC, supra note 49 at art 10 582003/87/EC, supra note 49

Page 20: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

16

its regulatory scope. 59 While the scope of Phase I was limited to the regulation of CO2

to simplify data and technology requirements, member states could voluntarily include

other greenhouse gases in their Phase II NAP’s.60

Compliance with the EU ETS, and implementation, is mandatory for all of the 27

EU member nations. Within their national boarders members are required to regulate

activities that produce a threshold amount of CO2. For instance, energy production

generally emits large amounts of CO2. If an energy installation has a critical mass

combustion capacity of 20 MW or greater the facility is included and must be regulated

by the member state in which it is situated. Of course, the regulation of CO2 is more

comprehensive than the regulation of energy facilities alone. 61

Annex I establishes the scope of the installations by specific reference to

categories of activities. In addition to the above, these categories include: mineral oil

refineries and coke ovens; production and processing of ferrous metals, such as metal ore

roasting and sintering and pig iron and steel including continuous casting; mineral

industry, such as cement clinkers, lime, glass (including fiber), bricks, ceramics; other

activities, such as industrial plants producing pulp, paper and board. 62

59 60 The Kyoto Protocol covers seven different greenhouse gases. See, Kyoto Protocol supra note 7 Ramakrishnan, J, “EU ETS”, International Environmental Science Center, online: IESC <http://www.internationalprofs.org/iesc/eu-ets.html> 61The main changes are the following: one EU-wide cap; annual cap will decrease along a linear trend line; larger share of allowances will be auctioned; harmonised rules governing free allocation; aluminium and ammonia producers will be included; so will nitrous oxide and perfluorocarbons; Member States will be allowed to exclude small installations from the scope of the system. See EC, Questions and Answers on the Commission's proposal to revise the EU Emissions Trading System, MEMO/08/35, 23 January 2008, online: EC <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/08/35&format= HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en> 622003/87/EC, supra note 49

Page 21: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

17

In Phase II, the EU ETS scope was expanded to incorporate certain CO2 emitting

installations not previously included. For example, installations that were granted opt-out

status during Phase I are now included. Also, Phase II grew to include additional sectors

that were not previously included and expanded the scope for certain facilities that were

already included. The majority of these changes affected installations that involved:

gypsum, rock wool, carbon black, petrochemical crackers, glass, offshore, and integrated

steelworks.63

Recent estimates place the total number of covered installations at around 10,500,

which includes installations in the E.U. as well as installations in Iceland, Liechtenstein

and Norway.64 While the EU ETS has experienced significant volatility in terms of the

price of credits, in 2007, its value was estimated to be 50 billion euros based on

prevailing market prices.65 In 2008, the EU ETS experienced continued growth and now

accounts for 70 percent of global trades.66

2. The Market

The market is largely a digital one. The EU has chosen to facilitate the transfer of

allocations as digital currency, rather than on paper.67 Known as European Union

63 Defra, “Final Methodology Guidance”, online: Defra <http://www.environment-agency.gov.uk/ commondata/acrobat/amrules_2070949.pdf. For definitions of new installations, online: <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission/pdf/etsworkinggroup/2007_03_08/5a.pdf> 64See EU, Environment Website, online: <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission/citl_en.htm> 65Ieta, “Market Developments in the EU ETS: An Exchange’s viewpoint”, online: Ieta <http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/gƒetfile.php%3FdocID%3D1338> 66In the first half of 2008, the value of the world market was estimated to be 38 billion euros. Mark Milner, “Pollution: Value of global carbon trading is nearly double last year’s figure at 30bn”, The Guardian”, July 9, 2008, online: Guardian <http://www.guardian.co.uk/environment/2008/jul/09/carbonemissions. carboncapturestorage#> 67See for a general discussion of the form of emission allocations: European Commission, Environment website, online: EC <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission/index_en.htm>

Page 22: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

18

Allowances (EUAs), each allowance entitles the holder the right to emit one tonne of CO2.68

The Kyoto Protocol creates two additional currencies, the CER69 and ERU.70 Each is

created via the CDM and JI mechanisms respectively. 71 Although the EUA is the only type

of credit currently traded in the EU ETS, CERs will be traded in the not so distant future.72

Credits must be stored. 73 By way of Decision 16/CP.10,74 the EU Commission

granted each member state the authority to create an independent national registry.75

These registries are tasked with facilitating storing, trading and authenticating EUAs. In

order to ensure a sound market, registries are required to employ data exchange

standards76 that govern the issuance, holding, transfer, and cancellations credits.77 Once a

trade is closed, registries are responsible for “settling” emissions trades. This is perhaps

one of the most important tasks; the registry removes credits from a seller’s account and

68 European Commission, “EU emissions trading — an open scheme promoting global innovation”, online: EC <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/pdf/emission_trading2_en.pdf> 69CERs are generated by climate-friendly, sustainable development projects in developing countries. They can be used by developed country Governments and companies to meet their reduction commitments under the Kyoto Protocol. See UNFCCC, First emission credits issued under the Kyoto Protocol, online: UNFCCC <http://cdm.unfccc.int/CDMNews/issues/issues/I_WJHSF1N67JGAORWII2BKVAI8O74B5A/ viewnewsitem.html> 70An ERU represents one tonne of CO2-equivalent greenhouse gas emissions reductions achieved through a Joint Implementation project. It can be used to meet an Annex B Party’s emission commitment or as the unit of trade in greenhouse gas emissions trading systems. See UNFCCC, A Glossary of Climate Change & Forestry, online: UNFCC <http://unfcccbali.org/unfccc/component/option,com_glossary/Itemid, 99/func,view/catid,31/term,Emissions+Reduction+Unit,+or+ERU/> 71Kyoto Protocol supra note 8 72Carbon Finance, “ITL link, EU ETS review key for 2008 prices”, online: Carbon Finance <http://www.carbon-financeonline.com/index.cfm?section=lead&action=view&id=10948&linkref=cnews> 73UNFCCC, “Registry Systems under the Kyoto Protocol”, online: U.N. <http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/ registry systems/items/2723.php> 74EC, Commission Decision16/CP.10, (Issues relating to registry systems under Art. 7(4) of the Kyoto Protocol) in FCCC/CP/2005/3/Add.3; See also EC, Commission Regulation of 21 December 2004 for a standardized and secured system of registries pursuant to Directive 2003/87/EC and Decision 280/2004/EC 75United Nations Convention on Climate Change, “Registry Systems under the Kyoto Protocol”, online: U.N. <http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/registry_systems/items/2723.php> 76UNFCCC, “Data Exchange Standards for Registry Systems Under the Kyoto Protocol” (2006), online: U.N. <http://unfccc.int/files/kyoto_mechanisms/registry_systems/application/pdf/des_techspec_v1_1.pdf> 77As well as credits from JI and CDM flexible mechanism projects under Kyoto: See supra note 8

Page 23: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

19

delivers those credits to the buyer’s account.78 This action is fundamental to any market,

but, as will be discussed, the integrity of the design of this particular process is

instrumental when contemplating cross regime trading.

Also instrumental to the facilitation of trading is the ability of each national

registry to communicate with every other registry. The UNFCCC created and manages

the International Transaction Log (ITL) as an administrative system link. The ITL is

utilized in every transaction, verifying and monitoring to ensure that the trade is in

compliance with the Kyoto rules.79 If a transaction is not compliant, the registries must

terminate the transaction.

Just as the 27 EU Member States participating in the EU ETS must create their

own national registry, each Member State is tasked with the development of its own

National Allocation Plan (NAP) that must be in harmony with the overall EU cap. While

the scope of EU ETS is limited to certain national economic sectors, for the purposes of

the NAP, when Member States calculate their overall cap they must include emissions

from all emitters.80

The creation of a NAP is often a complicated undertaking, compounded in part by

the fact that allocation mistakes can have serious consequences with regard to the overall

integrity of the EU ETS. The importance of the NAP in implementing Kyoto is clearly

78 National registries contain accounts that function similar to those in traditional financial banks. Accounts are created by businesses operating in sectors that are included in the scheme, as well as for individuals or non-governmental organizations that are authorized by a domestic government to hold and trade EUAs. See generally, supra note 73 79UNFCCC, “International Transaction Log –ITL”, online: UNFCCC <http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/ registry_systems/itl/items/4065.php> 80Both trading and non-trading sectors must be included. For example, non-trading sectors include household, commercial, agriculture, fisheries, and transport: See EC, “Impact Assessment” (27 February 2008), online: EC < http://ec.europa.eu/energy/renewables/doc/sec_2008_85-2_ia_annex.pdf>

Page 24: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

20

evident by its objectives, namely considering the amount of CO2 emissions from all

sectors in relation to a determination of how many allowances to allocate to trading

sectors. As one might imagine, since drafters of the NAP must further allocate

allowances specific to every facility in each sector the process is often fraught with

political wrangling.81

In order to counter this internal political pressure and other concerns, prior to each

phase, it is required that each NAP be submitted to the European Commission for

approval. In order to ensure transparency, assessment is based on 12 criteria set out in

Annex III of the ET directive.82 In its assessment, the Commission must insure that the

quantity and the method of allowance allocation conform to the 12 criteria83 and the EU

Treaty.84 In addition, the NAP must avoid discrimination between companies and sectors,

plan for new entrants, and make early reduction credits available. Following review the

Commission has the authority to approve, reject, request additional information, or

require changes to the NAP before a final decision issued.85

EU participants have several choices when planning and selecting a trading method.

81 82 See 2003/87/EC, supra note 49 See Annex III to Directive 2003/87/EC establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC. 83“[T]he proposed total quantity of allowances must be in line with a member state’s Kyoto Protocol target … member states [must] assess emissions developments and potentials for reductions in all sectors.” See IHS, “FAQ on EU Emissions Trading and National Allocation Plans for 2008-2012”, online: <http://engineers.ihs.com/news/2006/eu-en-emissions-trading-faq-11-06.htm> 84EC, Commission Communication COM(2003)830 of January 2004 on guidance to assist Member States in the implementation of the criteria listed in Annex III to Directive 2003/87/EC establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC, online: <http://www.epa.ie/downloads/advice/air/climate%20change/name,13125,en.html>; See also, Commission Communication COM(2005)703 of 22 December 2005 on further guidance on allocation plans for the 2008 to 2012 trading period of the EU Emission Trading Scheme, online: <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission/2nd_phase_ep.htm> 85EC, Council Directive 2003/87/EC, 2003 O.J. (L 275/32) (EC) p. 9; See further Europa, “Questions & Answers on national allocation plans for 2008-2012”, Press Release - 9 January 2006, online: <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/06/2&format=HTML&aged=0&langua ge=EN&guiLanguage=en>

Page 25: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

21

Similar to other trading that occurs with regard to traditional commodities, participants

may choose to trade:

Privately, moving allowances between operators within a company and

across national borders.

Over the counter, using a broker to privately match buyers and sellers.

Trading on the spot market of one of Europe's climate exchanges (the

most liquid being the European Climate Exchange). Like any other

financial instrument, trading consists of matching buyers and sellers

between members of the exchange and then settling by depositing an

allowance in exchange for the agreed financial consideration. Much like a

stock market, companies and private individuals can trade through brokers who are listed on the exchange.86

No matter what method is relied on, as in other markets, the price of a credit is

determined by supply and demand economics.87

3. Compliance and Enforcement

The permitting and subsequent monitoring of listed instillations occurs at the

national regulator level. The permitting process is commenced with the submission of a

permit application.88 An applicant must provide a monitoring plan that provides specific

technical details on the process by which the instillation will measure and report

86 See online: Open Carbon World <http://www.opencarbonworld.com/wiki/european-union-emission- trading-scheme.html> 87Although not yet developed to be fully accessible, the spot trading market will grow and provide liquidity once financial and delivery risks are lowered. See European Federation of Energy Traders, “June 2005 EFET Position on the EU ETS Review”, online: EFET <http://www.efet.org/Download.asp%3FFile %3D677> 88See Environment UK, “ETS1Application and Guidance”, online: UK <http://www.environment- agency.gov.uk/commondata/105385/ets_app_guide_624838.pdf>

Page 26: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

22

emissions.89 In addition to this, an applicant must draft its submitted monitoring and

reporting plans according to EU guidelines.90

Once a permit has been issued, instillations must commission verified emissions

reports. A private and independent accredited verifier must cross check emission data for

errors, omissions and consistency with the instillations monitoring and reporting plan.

Once submitted, the report is crosschecked against the emission data contained in the

registry and a verification opinion is sent to the Member State regulator.

As discussed above, the EU ETS is a flexible mechanism created in order to

facilitate Member States’ overall compliance with the Kyoto Protocol. In order to ensure

compliance, the EU ETS sets clear timetables for the surrender of allocations by covered

installations. In order to be determined in compliance, instillations must annually

surrender to the registry a quantity of EUAs equivalent to the actual verified amount of

CO2 emissions produced in that year.91 Failure to do so, results in the imposition of a

fine for each additional tonne of CO2 emissions.92 In addition, the names of installations

determined to be in non-compliance are published and, the following year, they must

purchase an amount of EUAs equivalent to the deficit.93

89 EU, “Phase 2 Monitoring Plan and Guidance”, online: UK <https://www.og.berr.gov.uk/environment/ MRplantemplate.xls> 90EU, Commission Decision of 29/01/2004, establishing guidelines for the monitoring and reporting of greenhouse gas emissions, adopted in regards to Article 14 of Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council; Commission Decision of 18/06/2007 to establishing guidelines for the monitoring and reporting of greenhouse gas emissions pursuant to Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council, online: <http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2007 :229:0001:0085:EN:PDF> 91EU, Commission Decision of 18 July 2007 C (2007/589/EC) establishing guidelines for the monitoring and reporting of greenhouse gas emissions pursuant to Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council (notified under document number C(2007) 3416). 92Under the EU-ETS the penalty was 40 euros per missing allowance under Phase I and 100 euros under Phase II. 93EEA, “Technical report No 2/2006, Application of the emissions trading directive by EU Member

Page 27: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

23

B. Domestic EU ETS issues

In order to meet the goals set by Kyoto, the Member States of the EU ETS must

have finely calibrated caps that are not too low, nor too high. These caps determine the

number of EAUs available on the European carbon market. According to free market

theory, when there is a larger supply of an item relative to the demand the price will fall,

of course the opposite result is true when there is a scarcity relative to demand. As

applied to the EU ETS, a larger cap results in over-allocation of EUAs. Excess EUAs, in

turn, result in the price of EUA sinking to levels where it is financially advantageous for

emitters to purchase EUAs and continue emitting without reduction, or perhaps increase

emissions.

As the EU ETS is presently structured similarly to the fiefdoms of old Europe,

there are several possible factors that could result in over-allocation. As it turns out, such

factors were realized, namely a ‘race to the bottom’ among Member States and

information failures with regard to emission data. It is widely accepted that the liquidity

of the EU ETS was indeed compromised.

Since January 1, 2005 the price of carbon in the EU has taken a wild ride.

Looking back commentators are in wide agreement that over-allocation occurred.94 It is

States”, http://reports.eea.europa.eu/technical_report_2006_2/en. This report provides an overview of all the unique penalty provisions in place in the 27 Member States. 94Review of the Independent Community Transaction Log containing EU Emission Trading Scheme’s 2005 verified emissions revealed the over-allocations in the following amounts: Belgium (3.5 Mt); Czech Republic (14 Mt); Denmark (11 Mt); Estonia (4 Mt); Finland (11.5 Mt); France (19 Mt); Germany (25 Mt); Hungary (4 Mt); Latvia (1 Mt); Lithuania (7 Mt); Netherlands (6 Mt); Slovak Republic (5 Mt); and Sweden (3 Mt): Carbon Market Data, Press Release, 2 June 2006, online: <http://www.carbonmarketdata.com/page s/Press%2520release%2520CMD%2520%2520EU%2520ETS%2520%25202%2520June%25202006.pdf>

Page 28: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

24

widely accepted that the drop in the EUA spot price that occurred at the Phase I midpoint

supports this conclusion.95

As discussed, Phase I was intentionally designed as a trial run. In accordance with

this, over-allocated EUAs obtained during Phase I could not be banked for use in Phase

II. This method of containment seems to have been effective, since the price of carbon

has risen. The lessons learned are valuable and applicable to any similar emission trading

system. The likely causes should be addressed before a trading scheme is put into place

in any other jurisdiction, especially if some form of cross jurisdictional exchange of

credits is contemplated.

1. National Caps – What Went Wrong?

The balance of power in terms of establishing the national cap was clearly in

favour of the Member States. When drafting its NAP, a Member State was free to start

high and, subject to review, work its calculations downward. The incentive is clear,

Member States that were successful in securing a larger cap were free to over-allocate

credits to its domestic industries. This in turn has obvious benefits when domestic

industries compete with companies in other Member States that did not secure this

advantage. A type of ‘green’ trade war emerges. This effect can be seriously

compounded if a company receiving surplus credits is able to sell these credits on the

market for windfall profits.

95 The spot price fell from over 30.00 euros to less than 1.00 euro between April 1, 2006 and 2007. Thompson, B., “Latest Developments in the EU ETS”, Carbon Expo, Cologne, 2 May 2007, online: <http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php%3FdocID%3D2294>

Page 29: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

25

Any emissions trading system, where there are competing national or regional

interests, must account for the likelihood or perhaps inevitability of a ‘race to the

bottom’. In the present case, Phase I caps in the EU did not create the scarcity necessary

to establish market liquidity. Market failure also occurred, as discussed in the next

section, as a result of the ‘wait and see’ practice of Member States who did not want to be

the first to make large emission cuts.

2. Domestic Lobbying

In sync with the desire on the part of Member States to maximize the national cap,

each nation’s domestic industry has strong motivations to avoid or minimize its

compliance obligations. It will come as no surprise then that many industries sought to

influence the national decision making process. In fact, efforts to lobby government and

apply other forms of political pressure in order to receive larger allocations of national

caps made news headlines in Europe.96

The most notable example of such lobbying efforts took place in Germany. When

Germany was undertaking to draft its NAP in order to comply with Phase I of the EU

ETS, German steelmakers cried foul, arguing that essentially that the science relied on

was flawed. These challenges were not taken lightly. In fact, German Chancellor

Schroeder had to personally intervene.97 It should come as no surprise then, that

Germany was not considered as progressive in terms of its national cap. Germany was

96 See generally Karlseng, T.H., “Decreasing German Climate Ambitiousness”, FNI Report 8/2006, online: FNI < http://www.fni.no/doc&pdf/FNI-R0806.pdf> 97Pew Center, “The European Union Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS) Insights and Opportunities”, p. 12, online: Pew <http://www.pewclimate.org/docUploads/EU-ETS%2520White%2520Paper.pdf>

Page 30: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

26

not the only country to be effected, however, as the French government also experienced

strong lobbying efforts domestically.98

3. Looking Forward

Now that Phase II is underway, it is clear that the EU Commission has increased

its willingness to regulate and demand that changes be made where Member States have

failed to plan for a sufficient Phase II cap.99 While it is likely that some of the national

issue discussed above will be resolved by transparency, access to information, and

through old fashioned shame, a strong EU-wide regulator will likely be necessary to

overcome these forces. In line with this foreseeable centralization of power, it is likely

that in the near future the EU Commission will reassess the bottom up, patchwork

method of creating a EU cap. In the future, the EU Commission will push for a EU cap

that is distributed rather than requested.

C. Summary of Part III

The analysis in this Part provides necessary background and further substance to

an understanding of the implementation of the EU ETS. In order to explain how the

system operates, a walk through of the mechanism in the context of an analysis of

national, EU and global issues and discretion put flesh on the bones of an otherwise

skeletal scheme.

98 99 See supra note 96 See further Europa, “Emissions trading: Commission decides on first set of national allocation plans for the 2008-2012 trading period”, Press Release - 29 November 2006, online: Europa <http://europa.eu/rapid/ pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/06/1650>

Page 31: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

27

With Phase II now underway, it will be interesting to see if the lessons learned

will be put into play. The EU Commission got off to an ambitious start by demanding

that most Member States tighten up their Phase II NAPs before being approved.

Although it is too early to make a final determination, if the price of carbon in the EU

continues to fall to below 15 euros it may become clear that the necessary scarcity and

related issues have not been realized. If that is the case, in the coming years the market

may lose confidence.

Looking forward, the EU Commission is now undertaking to make serious

revisions of the EU ETS prior to the commencement of Phase III in 2013. With new

rules due this year, many participants are eager for change. Part V of this paper discusses

one particular type of change, potential linkage to a developing U.S. system.

Page 32: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

28

PART IV A Comparison of the EU ETS, the Dingell-Boucher Draft and the Waxman-Markey Bill

In the midst of a global economic downturn, further implementation of the EU’s

‘grand experiment’ with cap-and-trade by North American nations is believed by some to

be risky business. Despite this implementation risk, such policies have resulted in EU

member states realizing competitive advantages over delayed participants, such as the

United States.100 Although a signatory to the UNFCCC, the record of the U.S. on

combating climate change has clearly demonstrated a lack of ambition. This section

presents a brief overview of the April 2007, United States Supreme Court decision

Massachusetts v EPA101 and a subsequent draft legislative proposal and bill to reduce

GHG emissions, known as the Dingell-Boucher Legislation Discussion Draft102 [Dingell-

Boucher Draft] and the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009103 [Waxman-

Markey Bill] respectively. With regards to the analysis of the proposed U.S. legislation,

the commentary provides a comparative analysis of the climate mechanism discussed in

Part III, the EU ETS, as well as providing significant consideration of foreseeable issues

arising from attempts to link the EU and proposed U.S. emission trading schemes in the

future.

10 0 See e.g. World Wildlife Fund, “EU ETS, Competitiveness and Employment”, online: WWF <http://www.wwf.fi/wwf/www/uploads/pdf/clearingthemist_summary.pdf> 10 1Massachusetts, et al, Petitioners v. Environmental Protection Agency, et al (2007), 549 U.S. 497, 127 S. Ct 1438 [EPA] 10 2Dingell-Boucher Legislation Discussion Draft, House Committee on Energy and Commerce, online: <http://energycommerce.house.gov>; See also, online: <http://www.instituteforenergyresearch.org/wp- content/uploads/2008/10/dingell-boucher-draft-cap-and-trade-bill.pdf> [Dingell-Boucher] 10 3American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009, H.R.2454 [Waxman-Markey Bill]

28

Page 33: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

29

A. The United States

Greenhouse gas reduction initiatives both proposed and implemented have

emerged on both the national and sub-national level in the United States. While the

scope of this paper is limited to background on the Massachusetts v. EPA104 decision, the

proposed Dingell-Boucher Draft and the Waxman-Markey Bill the reader is encouraged

to consider this federal proposal alongside sub-national plans already implemented.105

1. US Administrative Intent

On the federal level, despite several well-intentioned efforts by senior

politicians106 to introduce federal cap-and-trade legislation in Congress, there has been

little progress made on this issue up to this point in time. The previous administrative

regime, in attempting to fulfill UNFCCC obligations, relied primarily on voluntary

initiatives that resulted in limited success.107 The current administration has yet to act

decisively on the issue of greenhouse gas intensity reduction, through cap-and-trade or

another policy.108 Unlike its predecessor, however, the current administration may chose

to act and create a federal legal requirement to reduce GHG gasses. When and if the

current government does act on climate change, it must choose one of two paths to create

10 4 10 5 EPA, supra note 101 See Western Climate Initiative, online: WCI <http://www.westernclimateinitative.org/>; Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, online: RGGI <http://www.rggi.org/> 10 6S.2191, the Lieberman-Warner Climate Security Act, December 5, 2007 10 7Climate VISION (Voluntary Innovative Sector Initiatives: Opportunities Now) administered through the Department of Energy’s policy and international program, online: Climate Vision <http://climatevision.gov/> 10 8The legislation includes a cap-and-trade global warming reduction plan designed to reduce economy- wide greenhouse gas emissions 17 percent by 2020. For the Bill to become law, a similar version must next pass the Senate: See supra note 103

Page 34: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

30

a national program, namely: the existing Supreme Court sanctioned regulatory approach

or by working with Congress to enact new, comprehensive cap-and-trade legislation.

2. Existing Federal Regulatory Approach

As mentioned above, the U.S. federal government has yet to adopt climate change

legislation. Despite this, the current Administration has the existing authority to create a

national regulatory greenhouse gas reduction initiative, and possibly implement a cap-

and-trade policy. 109 Many commentators have remarked that the Supreme Court’s 2007

decision in Massachusetts v. EPA110 not only introduced important administrative law

changes,111 but also of potentially greater significance in the context of global climate

change, decided that the federal Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) has the existing

authority to regulate CO2 under the Clean Air Act.112

The Supreme Court remanded the matter back to the Agency to decide whether

CO2 causes or contributes to climate change.113 If it is indeed established in the

affirmative,114 Section 202(a)(1) of the reviewed legislation requires that:

10 9 Broder, J.M., “E.P.A. expected to Regulate Carbon Dioxide” The New York Times (18 February 2009), online: The New York Times: Environment <http://www.nytimes.com/2009/02/science/ earth/19epa.html>, quoting: Rep. John Dingell as saying that the regulation of CO2 by the E.P.A. under the Clean Air Act, as it stands, would set off a “glorious mess” that would resonate throughout the economy; and Senator John Barrasso likewise as warned Lisa P. Jackson (the new E.P.A. administrator) that the use of the Act to regulate carbon “a disaster waiting to happen.” 11 0EPA, supra note 101 11 1See e.g. Freeman, J., and Vermeule, A., “Massachusetts v. EPA: From Politics to Expertise” (Aug 2007), online: ssrn <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1008906> 11 2Clean Air Act (CAA), 40 U.S.C. ‘7401-7671q [CAA] 11 3EPA, supra note 101 at 26 11 4On April 22, 2009, the EPA proposed an “endangerment finding” for emissions of GHGs: See EPA, Proposed Endangerment and Cause or Contribute Findings for Greenhouse Gases under the Clean Air Act, online: EPA <http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/endangerment.html>

Page 35: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

31

The Administrator shall by regulation prescribe […] standards applicable

to the emission of any air pollutant from any class or classes of new motor

vehicles or new motor vehicle engines, which in his judgement causes, or

contribute to, air pollution which may reasonably be anticipated to

endanger public health or welfare.115

Although the EPA has not yet promulgated CO2 regulations under the Clean Air

Act,116 it recently issued a proposed finding stating, “[i]n both magnitude and

probability, climate change is an enormous problem. The greenhouse gases that

are responsible for it endanger public health and welfare within the meaning of

the Clean Air Act.”117

Once the EPA asserts its jurisdiction to regulate CO2 under Section 202, a

domino effect will ripple across similar Sections of the Clean Air Act.118 For instance, the

Administrator would be compelled to list CO2 as a pollutant under Section 108119 and

next establish National Ambient Air Quality Standards for CO2 under Section 109.120

While the complete regulatory implications of establishing a climate policy from

judicial construction are outside of the scope of this essay, suffice it to say, it is likely that

11 5 11 6 42 U.S.C. § 7521(a)(1) ibid. 11 7EPA, News Release, “EPA Finds Greenhouse Gases Pose Threat to Public Health, Welfare / Proposed Finding Comes in Response to 2007 Supreme Court Ruling”, (April 17 2009), online: EPA < http://yosemite.epa.gov/opa/admpress.nsf/0/0EF7DF675805295D8525759B00566924> 11 8CAA, supra note 111 11 942 U.S.C. § 7408 12 042 U.S.C. § 7409

Page 36: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

32

the current Administration will choose to supplement this route with new legislative

action that is tailored to the specific U.S. contribution to climate change.121

3. Dingell-Boucher and Waxman-Markey Legislation

Many commentators believed that the Dingell-Boucher Draft122 announced on

October 7, 2008 in the House of Representatives, by Representatives John Dingell123 of

Michigan, Chairman of the House Committee on Energy and Commerce, and

Representative Rick Boucher124 of Virginia, Chairman of the House Subcommittee on

Energy and Air Quality, represented the likely future legislative approach to addressing

greenhouse gas emission reduction in the United States. Part of the reason for this belief

was that the draft proposed to amend the existing Clean Air Act125, discussed above,

rather than attempt to create a standalone legislative regime from scratch. Another reason

was that the bill sets targets via hard caps, and boasts a CO2 emission reduction target of

80% below 2005 levels by 2050.126 The Dingell-Boucher Draft stimulated discussion.127

This discussion influenced the May 15, 2009, introduction and June 26, 2009, passage of

Rep. Henry Waxman128, Chairman of the House Committee on Energy and Commerce,

and Rep. Edward Markey129, Chairman of the Subcommittee on Energy and

Environment, climate change and clean energy bill entitled “American Clean Energy and

12 1 President Obama and Administrator Jackson have repeatedly indicated their preference for legislation action to address climate change: See supra note 116 12 2Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 12 3Congressman John Dingell, online: <http://www.house.gov/dingell/> 12 4Congressman Rick Boucher, online: <http://www.boucher.house.gov/> 12 5CAA, supra note 111 12 6Dingell-Boucher, supra note 73 at s. 711(e)(1) 12 7Memoranda from Rick Boucher, Chairman Subcommittee on Energy and Air Quality and John D. Dingell, Chairman Committee on Energy and Commerce (7 October 2008) U.S. House of Representatives [Executive Summary] 12 8Representative Henry A. Waxman, online: < http://waxman.house.gov> 12 9Representative Edward Markey, online: < http://markey.house.gov>

Page 37: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

33

Security Act of 2009”, or the Waxman-Markey Bill.130 The Dingell-Boucher Draft

provided a solid framework and a clear direction. As discussed below, the Waxman-

Markey Bill borrowed from the Dingell-Boucher Draft and addressed some unresolved

issues.

i. Implementation Plan

Like the EU ETS, the Dingell-Boucher Draft anticipates implementation in

distinct phases.131 A Dingell-Boucher cap-and-trade program would commence on 2012

and continue until 2050.132 The first distinct phase would begin with the 2012

commencement and run until 2017.133 As in the European model, its first phase

contemplates economic integration concerns. However, unlike the “learning phase”

which was conducted as trial by error, the Dingell-Boucher Draft plan would start by

implementing a binding and enforceable cap that would sanction increases in issuances of

allowances between 2012 and 2017 before beginning a steady decline each year

thereafter.134 For instance, the Dingell-Boucher Draft contemplates the following CO2

emission timeline: 4.987 billion tons in 2012; (increased to) 6.167 billion tons in 2017;

5.796 billion tons in 2020; 4.617 billion in 2025; 3.436 in 2030; 2.335 in 2040; and 1.233

billion in 2050.135 It is important to note, however, that increases in the early part of the

first phase were not included as “breathing room” for covered entities. Rather, the

130 13 1 Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 711(e)(1) 13 2ibid. 13 3Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 712(b) 13 4Pew Center on Global Climate Change, Statement, “Summary of the Dingell-Boucher Discussion Draft”, (7 October 2008), online: Pew Center <http://www.pewclimate.org/statement/dingell-boucher/10- 07-08> [Pew Center] 13 5ibid.

Page 38: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

34

drafters contemplated the need for additional allocations as various emitters were to be

brought with the scope of the trading regime in these years. For instance, natural gas

LCD emitters would not be initially included in the draft scheme.136 For this purpose,

although the creation of allocations would increase the cap, the act of bringing these

entities into the regulatory scheme would result in an overall reduction of the business as

usual emissions of this carbon heavy industry, thereby lowering overall global emissions.

Like the Dingell-Boucher Draft, the Waxman-Markey Bill establishes an

economy wide cap-and-trade program that commences in 2012 and starts with binding

and enforceable cap calculated from the 2005 baseline. The Waxman-Markey Bill,

however, contemplates greater up front reductions than those that would be made under

the Dinger-Boucher Draft. For instance, in 2012 the cap starts 3% below the baseline,

17% below by 2020, and 83% below by 2050.137

As discussed in Part III, banking of Phase I allocations was not permitted under

the EU ETS scheme. The U.S. proposed legislation took a different, and more flexible,

approach to this issue. Both the Dingell-Boucher Draft and Waxman-Markey Bill

contemplate full banking of allowances.138 Unlike in the EU, the use of banking will

result in pressure on the U.S. regulator to correctly determine the appropriate cap.

However, banking under the Dingell-Boucher Draft is subject to an overriding authority

on the part of the EPA to create limiting restrictions.139 For instance under the Dingell-

Boucher proposal, if over allocation of credits occurs early on the regulator would be

13 6 13 7 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 712(b)(2) Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 702(1) 13 8ibid 13 9Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 715

Page 39: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

35

forced to correct market dilution as these credits migrate to subsequent phases. EPA

authority to modify allowance rights must be approached with caution, since the exercise

of these rights would likely undermine liquidity and trust in the market.

a. Implementation and Linkage

The Dingell-Boucher Draft and Waxman-Markey Bill both propose an allowance

system that is different from the EU ETS in one significant respect, the use of future

allowances. Both propose that a U.S. covered entity may satisfy up to 15 percent of its

compliance obligations by borrowing allowances to be allocated in up to five future years

in order to meet current compliance obligations.140 On this issue, it is important to be

aware that the European Parliament, Policy Department Economic and Scientific Policy,

recently commented that “linking a system without borrowing to a regime that allows

borrowing may require restrictive provisions to be taken so as to maintain the

environmental effectiveness of the linked trading scheme.”141 For instance, the note

contemplates borrowing ‘excess’ credits from other emitters rather than their own future

allocations. On this issue, legislators must carefully balance the historic U.S. carbon

emission legislative precept to “not significantly harm”142 to the U.S. economy with

compliance with emission reduction requirements imposed by the EU as a condition of

participation and the likely economic benefits that might result as a consequence of

14 0 14 1 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 715(2); Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 725 EC, Policy Department Economic and Scientific Policy, Implications of Linking the EU ETS with other Emissions Trading Schemes, (2007), online: EP <http://www. Europart.europa.eu/activities/committees/ studies/download.do?file=19802> [Implications of Linking] 14 2For example: in 1997 the Senate unanimously passed a non-binding resolution stating that it would not ratify an international climate agreement (such as Kyoto) that would “do serious harm” and, second, not require developing nations to participate. See S. Res. 98, introduced by Senate Robert Byrd (D-WV) and Chuck Hagel (R-NE) passed on July 35, 1997

Page 40: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

36

linkage with the EU ETS. Although the exact conditions are not yet known, how this can

be done remains unclear since participation will inevitably have economic costs for the

U.S. 143

ii. Scope

Implementation of either the Dingell-Boucher Draft or Waxman-Markey Bill will

establish a cap-and-trade program that, like the EU ETS, results in the creation of an

economy-wide market for carbon that monetizes emissions. Like other similar schemes,

these proposals seek to establish a regime that has a dual effect of incentivizing carbon

reduction by emitters and the development of carbon reduction technologies.

Both proposed schemes would cover 85 percent or more of the U.S. economy’s

GHG emissions, which is significantly more ambitious than the EU scheme’s historical

coverage of 46 percent of CO2 emissions.144 However, in the short term, the Dingell-

Boucher scheme’s reduction goal is much more back loaded that the EU ETS’s

commitment. For instance, the proposed scheme pegs reduction goals to the 2005 base

year with a higher emission baseline. In addition, the draft contemplates only a six

percent reduction by 2020 from 2005 emission levels. While this represents a significant

move away from ‘business as usual’ in the U.S., the reductions will not match the

reductions of CO2 emitted if the EU goal of 20 percent by 2020 is realized.

14 3 National Center For Policy Analysis, News Release, No. 617, “Capping C02 Emissions, Boosting Energy Costs”, (14 May 2008), online: NCPA < http://www.ncpa.org/pub/ba617> 14 4Point Carbon, Press Release, (12 May 2006), online: Point Carbon <http://www.pointcarbon.com/wimages/Press release Point Carbon 12 May 2006 1.pdf>

Page 41: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

37

Unlike the Dingell-Boucher Draft, the Waxman-Markey Bill matches the 2020

EU 20 percent reduction goal on its face.145 While the Waxman-Markey Bill proposes a

goal of 20 percent, which is significantly tighter than the 6 percent Dingell-Boucher goal,

the reduction is also pegged to the 2005 baseline rather than the lower 1990 EU baseline.

The Waxman-Markey Bill maintains a scope comparable to the Dingell-Boucher Draft,

foreseeing the capture of 85 percent of US GHG emissions.146 If passed by the Senate in

its current form the Waxman-Markey Bill could result in a reduction of CO2 that is at

least 14 percent greater than the forecasted reduction under the Dingell-Boucher Bill in

2020.

As in Annex 1 of the EU ETS, the Dingell-Boucher Draft specifically captures ‘low

hanging fruit’. For instance, large direct emitters and other installations that significantly

contribute to U.S. emissions are specifically included in the draft scheme. By 2013, the

proposed scope of the Dingell-Boucher scheme would encompass the following GHG

emitting entities: 1) electric generators, 2) producers and importers of fossil-based fuels,

emitting more than 25,000 tons of GHG annually, 3) producers and importers of other bulk

gasses, and 4) geologic sequestration sites.147 In 2014, larger industrial facilities emitting

more than 25,000 tons of GHG annually are scheduled for inclusion.148 For example,

facilities in high emitting sectors such as aluminum, chemical, petroleum, iron and steel,

concrete, and pulp and paper industries are listed.149 Lastly, as proposed, between 2017 and

2021 emissions resulting from the domestic combustion of natural gas would be included in

the scope. The Dingell-Boucher proposal would implement staggered inclusion, based on

14 5 14 6 Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 702 EPA, “EPA Analysis of the Waxman-Markey Discussion Draft: The American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009” (20 April 2009), online: EPA < http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/economics/pdfs/WaxmanMarkeyExecutiveSummary.pdf> 14 7Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at ss. 700(8) and 712; See also Pew Center, supra note 133 14 8ibid. 14 9ibid at 712

Page 42: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

38

the overall delivery volume, at the distribution level by requiring distributors delivering more

than 46, 000 cubic feet of gas to participate in the scheme.150

In the Dingell-Boucher Draft’s executive summary, the drafters explain that the

EPA would be granted authority to establish emission standards for industries emitting less

than 25,000 tons per year.151 The EPA would initially consider standards for “nonroad

engine, transportation fuel, and aircraft standards ” and motor vehicle standards.152 As the

Dingell-Boucher Draft is written the U.S. climate regime would cast a wide net over smaller

point sources that comprise a larger share of net U.S. emissions than large emitters. For

example, the Draft’s statutory language specifically instructs the EPA to list smaller sources

that, in addition to covered large emitters, will comprise 95 percent of industrial

emissions.153 This proposal would cover a significantly greater share of total U.S. GHG

emissions than the share covered by the EU ETS scheme.154 In terms of smaller emitters, a

recent EC proposal may take the EU in the opposite direction of the U.S. by removing

installations from the scheme that emit low amounts of CO2.155

The Waxman-Markey Bill is remarkably similar to the Dingell-Boucher Draft in

terms of the scope of covered entities, capturing facilities emitting 25, 000 tonnes of GHG

annually.156 As in the Dingell-Boucher Draft, the compliance period commences in 2012 for

most covered entities, in 2014 large industrial sources and in 2016 for Local Distribution

15 0 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s.712; According to the Pew Center the draft incorrectly states the natural gas distribution threshold as 460,000 cubic feet: See Pew Center supra note 86. 15 1Executive Summary, supra note 126 15 2Alliance to Save Energy, “Summary of Dingell-Boucher Discussion Draft”, (October 2008), online: <http://www.ase.org> 15 3Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 811 15 4The EU ETS covers 50 percent of European CO2 emissions and 40 percent of European GHG emissions: See EC, Questions and Answers on the Commission’s proposal to revise the EU Emission Trading Scheme, (23 January 2008) MEMO/08/35 15 5Ibid. The Commission has proposed allowing Member States to remove installations with a rated thermal input below 25MW whose reported emissions were lover than 10,000 tonnes of CO2 equivalent in each of the three years preceding the year of application. 15 6Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 700(12)

Page 43: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

39

Companies of natural gas, a year earlier than in the Dingell-Boucher Draft.157 Also, the

Waxman-Markey Bill grants powers to the EPA to establish emission performance

standards for smaller stationary sources not caught by the 25,000 tonne cap.158 This

provision is not as broad as under the Dingell-Boucher Draft, since it does include moving

sources such as motor vehicles and aircraft. 159

a. Scope and Linkage

While the Dingell-Boucher Draft lacks aggressive ‘early’ emission reductions like

those imposed by the EU ETS on its constituents, it provides compensation for this by not

only ensuring that an absolute cap is in place, as opposed to an intensity based approach,

but also by implementing an approach that is more comprehensive in scope. The

Waxman-Markey Bill improves on the Draft by increasing early reduction requirements.

Despite differences between the percentage reductions made by the U.S. legislation and

the EU, both of the proposed U.S. proposals are designed to regulate almost twice the

total volume of annual emissions as compared to the EU ETS.

With varied government actors and ambitions, it is unlikely that the scopes of the

two enormous schemes will match each other in inclusions of covered entities. While

this possible reality could have many economic effects, perhaps the most troubling to the

EU may be the transfer of wealth that could result. Since a larger U.S. scope could result

in a greater number of allowances with lower abatement costs, more payments would be

15 7 15 8 Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 721(e) ibid at s. 811 15 9Dingell-Boucher, supra at s. 811

Page 44: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

40

made for U.S. allowances than for EU allowances. 160 As a result of this, “it is probably a

political precondition for linking that all sides demonstrate efforts to establish

comparable caps.”161

As mentioned, the Waxman-Markey Bill requires covered emitters to make

greater emission reductions between 2013 and 2020 than the Dingell-Boucher Draft

does.162 If passed by the Senate in its current form, the scope of the proposed U.S.

scheme will be greater than was contemplated under the Dingell-Boucher Draft. If this is

the case, then further expansion could result in an even greater number of payments being

made by Europeans for a larger pool of U.S. allocations. It is possible that the inflow of

these funds could incentivize U.S. companies, rather than their EU counterparts, to invest

in abatement technology that creates real emission reductions. The effect of this may

have a political impact on linkage, since euros would fund U.S. capital development.

iii. Currency of the U.S. ETS

The GHG emission allowance, as contemplated by the Dingell-Boucher Draft, is a

comprehensive approach to GHG reduction. The reason for this is that each allowance

entitles the holder the right to emit one tonne of CO2 or equivalent GHG.163 In this

respect, the U.S. approach would be substantially broader than that of the Europeans,

since allocations there are limited to trades in CO2 emissions.

16 0 European Parliament, Options and Implications of Linking the EU ETS with other Emissions Trading Schemes, p19, Policy Department Economic and Scientific Policy, p. 20, online: EP < http://www.europarl. europa.eu/activities/committees/studies/download.do?file=19802> 16 1Implications of Linking, supra note 91 16 2Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 702 16 3Dingell-Boucher, supra note 60 at s. 700(13)

Page 45: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

41

The Dingell-Boucher Draft is more progressive in another regard, the use of

offsets. While the EU ETS is only beginning to integrate credits created via the Kyoto’s

CDM and JI flexible mechanisms, the Dingell-Boucher Draft envisions significant use of

both domestic and international offsets to satisfy a U.S. covered emitters compliance

burden.164 It is worthy to note that the worldwide Kyoto credit market will benefit from

the U.S. markets involvement and demand for these units. In exchange, unlike the

“reduction at home” approach taken by Europe in the early years, the U.S. economy

would benefit from the purchase of an abundance of less expensive credits created in

emerging economies. This involvement is likely to please U.S. politicians who, in the

past, have lamented over Kyoto’s seeming free pass to developing economies. Yet it is

uncertain whether these same players will be concerned by the flow of U.S. dollars

overseas to meet domestic emission reduction obligations.

The Waxman-Markey Bill creates allowances identical to those contemplated by

the Dingell-Boucher Draft.165 As for the use of offset credits, the Waxman-Markey Bill

also allows covered entities to partially demonstrate compliance with their use. The Bill

provides an equation166 that calculates the permissible level offsets to be 27% to 31% of

the total obligation until 2025, increasing every year to over 60% by 2050. 167 On the issue

of offsets, the Waxman-Markey Bill goes further than the Dingell-Boucher Draft by

16 4 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at ss. 712(c), 741-750, 761-764; for instance, 2013-2017 5% of compliance may be met with any combination of domestic and international offsets; 2018-2020 15% of compliance may be met with any combination of domestic and international offsets; 2021-2024 30% of compliance may be met with a equal amount of domestic and international offsets; 2025- future 35% of compliance may be met with a 20%/15% mix of domestic and international offsets. 16 5Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 712 16 6The percent of offsets is computed by dividing 2 billion by the sum of 2 billion plus the prior year’s cap: ibid at s. 722(c) 16 7Congressional Research Service, Summary of Waxman-Markey Draft Greenhouse Gas Legislation (14 May 2009), p.20, online: CRS < http://lugar.senate.gov/services/pdf_crs/Summary_of_Waxman Markey.pdf>

Page 46: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

42

limiting the use of domestic and international offsets to a maximum of split of 50/50 of

the total percent allowed in each year.168 The Waxman-Markey Bill is more conservative

that its predecessor in this area, as the Bill requires the presentation of 1.25 offset credits

for each 1 emission allowance due.169

a. Currency and Linkage

Depending on what position the European Commission ultimately decides to take

with regards to carbon offsets in the coming years, any U.S. sanction of the use of

domestic and international offsets could pose a significant challenge to linkage of the two

systems. Although the EU ETS was recently revised to allow post 2012 participants to

satisfy up to 50% of target through the purchase of international offset credits,170 the

issue remains in play as the types of allowable offsets are not equal in nature. For

example, both the Dingell-Boucher Draft and Waxman-Markey Bill contemplate the

inclusion of domestic forestry offsets.171 The European Counsel recently revisited this

issue, determining that forestry offsets should not be included in the next stage of EU

ETS.172

16 8 16 9 Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 712 ibid. 17 0EC, Press Release, Climate change: Commission welcomes final adoption of Europe’s climate and energy package (17 December 2008), online: Europa<http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/08/1998&format=HTML&aged=08la nguage=EN&guiLanguage=en> 17 1Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s.742(b); Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at Title V 17 2EU, Press Release, “Questions and Answers on the revised EU Emissions Trading System Press Release MEMO/08/796” (17 December 2008), <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleaseAction.do?reference=MEMO /08/796&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN$guiLanguage=en>

Page 47: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

43

The Europeans will likely require some form of mediation on the issue, so as to

avoid the trade of these offsets from crossing over. Such measures may include a

prohibition being placed on U.S. companies selling surplus credits in the EU, if they

chose to make use of non EU approved offsets to meet their permit requirements. In

doing so, the integrity of the EU ETS would not be compromised by the sale of U.S.

credits that would not have been available had it not been for the use of these offsets.

Tracing the sale of these credits across several transactions involving multiple parties

would be difficult and could ultimately have the same effect as above, namely market

dilution in the EU scheme. In addition, the EU will likely require that any U.S. use of

offsets will not result in the creation of incentives to generate CO2. These areas will be

of special concern when contemplating linkage.173

iv. National Registry

Both Dingell-Boucher Draft and Waxman-Markey Bill require the creation of a

Federal GHG registry within one year of either’s enactment into U.S. law.174 Each

delegates the task of establishing the registry and issuing accompanying regulations to the

EPA Administer. In carrying out this mandate, the Administrator must draft regulations

that compel covered entities to submit to the EPA data on: “(i) greenhouse gas emissions

in the United States; (ii) the production and manufacture in the United States, and

17 3 17 4 See e.g., Mukerjee, M., "A Mechanism of Hot Air", Scientific American (June 2009), pp. 9-10

Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s 703; Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 713

Page 48: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

44

importation into the United States, of fuels and other products the uses of which result in

greenhouse gas emissions; and (iii) the sequestration of greenhouse gases.”175

In addition to reporting requirements, these sections go on to require the formation

and implementation of various protocols, practices, procedures, and publications by the

EPA necessary to regulate the Federal GHG registry. It is interesting to note, that both

require that the Administrator rely on GHG emission data collected by the Climate

Registry. Established in 2007, the Climate Registry is a nonprofit partnership that now

includes registered members form thirty-nine U.S. states and the District of Columbia,

seven Canadian provinces and territories, six Mexican states, and three tribal nations.

Climate Registry reporters register their organizations entire GHG emissions for

facilities, corporations and operations in U.S., Canada and Mexico.

The Climate Registry recently finalized of its General Reporting Protocol, “which

gives guidance on how to inventory greenhouse gas emissions for participation in the

Registry.”176 While standardization of reporting methodologies is necessary to ensure the

accuracy of data, allowing this Registry data collected on a voluntary basis may be risky,

considering the potential for miscalculation or lack of stringent oversight. Computer

programmers are fond of the phase “garbage in garbage out”. It will be interesting to see

if the Climate Registry data is sufficiently groomed to represent a value added approach

to the formulation of the initial national cap. In light of the informational problems that

developed during Phase I of the EU ETS, the Europeans would be wise to view the U.S.

17 5 17 6 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s 703; Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 713 Climate Registry, General Reporting Protocol, (May 2008), Climate Registry online: <http://www.theclimateregistry.org/downloads/GRP.pdf>

Page 49: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

45

reliance on this type of soft data as incomplete. In turn, any approach toward linkage

should mandate caution out of concern for dual market dilution if credits are over

allocated in the U.S. during the first phase. Failure to ‘wait and see’ could easily frustrate

the realization of gains made in Europe and negate any benefits associated with linking

the two systems.

Discussed in more detail below, the EPA’s recent announcement of its intention

to create a national GHG registry demonstrates a clear ambition on the part of the Agency

to be in position to implement and support Congressional cap-and-trade legislation in the

near future. Such an ambition is not only necessary for the success of such a proposal,

but also serves to drive the legislative process forward where in the past it has languished.

Much of this may be attributed to the recent political regime change in the U.S., and

perhaps an increased desire on the part of the American public to reenter the international

policy stage in a more positive, holistic way.

v. Allowance Allocation

As in the EU ETS scheme, participants in the U.S. will share a CO2 emissions

cap.177 The U.S. cap is comprised of allowances, like the EU, but unlike the EU, the

authority to issue and distribute allowances would be vested federally in the EPA rather

than collectively in the Member States.178 Rather than adopt ad hoc state-by-state

approach, consolidation of authority at the federal level will facilitate an annual linear

17 7 17 8 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 711; Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 721 The Commission recently proposed setting a single EU-wide cap post 2012, rather than allowing member states to determine the total quantity to be allocated and how. See: EC, Questions and Answers on the Commission’s proposal to revise the EU Emission Trading Scheme, (23 January 2008) MEMO/08/35, online: Europa <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleaseAction.do?reference=MEMO/08/796&format= HTML&aged=0&language=EN$guiLanguage=en>

Page 50: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

46

decrease of allowances. A cursory review of the U.S. proposals relieves doubt that the

framers learned valuable lessons from the market failures that resulted early on during the

European allocations.

At this time, neither the Dingell-Boucher Draft nor the Waxman-Markey Bill

contains details on the issue of allocation.179 Neither has chosen a method of allocation.

Rather than putting forward a single emission allocation proposal, the Dingell-Boucher

Draft contains descriptions of four different allocation options and requests comments.180

The Dingell-Boucher Draft Executive Summary clearly frames the proposed options: 1)

allocation of allowances without charge to covered sectors; 2 & 3) reduced allowances to

be provided without charge to and provide varying auction allowance amounts with

revenues funding adaptation programs; and 4) allocation of allowances entirely by way of

auction with the majority of revenue being rebated to U.S. consumers. The Dingell-

Boucher drafters included a provision to encourage Congressional reauthorization. The

provision would mandate auctioning of all allowance and distribution of the proceeds to

taxpayers if reauthorization is not successfully completed prior to 2026.181

Unique to the Waxman-Markey Bill is that it mandates that the EPA create a

“strategic reserve” to be created by the holding back of a percentage of allowances each

year.182 From this, on a quarterly basis, the EPA will make available allowances for

auction, with a reserve price that is 100% above the current market price.183 Unsold

17 9 18 0 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 721; Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at ss. 711 & 782 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 721 (options A-D) 18 1ibid. 18 2Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 726 18 3Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 726

Page 51: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

47

allocations accumulate in the reserve.184 The proceeds of the auction will be used to

purchase forestry offsets to replenish the reserve.185

a. Allocation and Linkage

Although the Dingell-Boucher Draft and the Waxman-Markey Bill have not taken

firm positions on the anticipated method of general allocation, this issue may not be as

controlling on the issue of linkage as it may first appear. If fact, “[d]ifferences in the way

allowances are distributed to the companies covered by ETS usually have no impact on

the system’s environmental effectiveness since this is solely determined by the overall

cap.” 186 Thus, “[b]eyond an initial transfer of wealth in the case of free allocation, the

method of initial distribution should not affect the competitiveness of the entities.”187 As

a result, no matter what method of allocation the U.S. legislature ultimately passes by

legislation, the economic effect will be limited to the U.S. economy. In turn, the choice

of allocation methodologies will not compromise the EU ETS. As such, whatever

method is chosen, linkage will not be prevented.

While the particular decision may not result in an economic bar to linkage, there

may certainly be political barriers to consider. As discussed, varying obligations between

similar industries operating in different jurisdictions inevitably results in lobbying

pressures as a result of perceived trade competition issues. Therefore, it would be

difficult to imagine the linking of a U.S. emission scheme that allocated credits in a

18 4 18 5 Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 726 ibid. 18 6Options and Implications of Linking the EU ETS with other Emissions Trading Schemes, p19, Policy Department Economic and Scientific Policy 18 7ibid.

Page 52: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

48

manner that is inconsistent with its counterpart. As such, if linkage is a U.S. objective, it

would be wise for the legislature to monitor proposed and realized allocation

amendments to the EU ETS.

Overall, the U.S. may elect to employ a different allocation method than the free

allocation method implemented during Phase I and II of the EU ETS. This could be moot,

however, as the EU Commission is also contemplating implementing options 2 & 3

above. Despite the lack of economic necessity, the best course of action in the U.S. is

clearly to foster a coordinated approach, as the result would generate greater similarities

between the two schemes in the future.

vi. Trading

Neither the Dingell-Boucher Draft nor the Waxman-Markey Bill establishes a

regulated framework to facilitate the trade of emission allowances. This approach, also

taken by the Europeans, is well suited for the development of market mechanisms that

grow freely with demand. The Draft specifically states that, “the lawful holder of an

emission allowance may, without restriction, sell exchange, transfer, hold for

compliance.”188 As discussed with regards to the EU ETS policy, participants will have

several choices when planning and selecting a trading method.

Although the Dingell-Boucher Draft contemplates an anything goes approach in

terms of transaction methods, the ‘place’ where such transactions occur must be

registered with Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (“FERC”) and approved as a

18 8 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s.714; Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at 724

Page 53: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

49

“carbon trading facility”. Such a facility is contemplated as being an entity “in which

multiple participants may execute or trade agreements, contracts, or transactions

involving a regulated instrument by accepting bids and offers made by other participants

that are open to multiple participants in the faculty or system.”189 The Draft goes on to

specify that such facilities may become ‘registered’ if they are able to demonstrate that

they are prepared to prevent market manipulation, ensure fair and equitable trading,

establish and enforce rules governing trading and financial integrity, must establish and

be capable of enforcing its own disciplinary procedures, and, lastly, the facility must

ensure its own ability, as well as the publics ability, to access information relating to

trading and trades.190 It is also very likely that under both the Dingell-Boucher Draft and

the Waxman-Markey Bill all brokers, dealers and traders would be regulated by FERC.191

Since the EU ETS, Dingell-Boucher Draft and Waxman-Markey Bill take near

identical positions in terms of trading, concerns regarding trading are premature. What

must be considered, however, is how the trading systems sync together despite their

similarities. Issues of foreign authentication, deposit, hold times after a deal closes, and

other elements may result in the realization of latent issues in the future. Although

having the potential to be significant, at this early stage such concerns cannot be

addressed in this article.

18 9 19 0 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 402(16) ibid, at s. 405(a)(2) 19 1ibid. at s. 405(b); The Federal Energy Regulatory Commissions will be charged with the regulation of the cash market in allowances and offsets: Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at 761

Page 54: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

50

vii. Monitoring and Reporting

As discussed, the scope of the Dingell-Boucher Draft and the Waxman-Markey

Bill specifically capture emission sources emitting 25,000 tonnes of GHG annually.192

Although plans have not been finalized, the public comment period recently closed on a

draft EPA regulation that seeks to establish a national annual reporting requirement

commencing in 2010 for GHG emitters or producers or importers of fossil fuels.193 The

proposed regulatory disclosure requirements closely maps on to the covered entities

thresholds framed by both pieces of proposed cap-and-trade legislation. For instance,

under the proposed regulation, the EPA would require annual submissions from faculties

that emit the equivalent of 25,000 metric tonnes or more of GHG equivalent.194 Whether

this draft regulation is a harbinger of a U.S. cap-and-trade program only time will tell. A

strict comparison of the EU and U.S. approaches reveals greater similarities than

differences in terms of the threshold for monitoring. Currently, the U.S. proposals lack

sufficient detail to undertake a point by point comparison. Suffice it to say, what has been

put forward in the U.S. is perhaps more progressive in nature. For instance, as discussed,

in both the proposed Draft and the Bill the EPA has been granted greater authority to draft

legislation catching smaller emitters.195

viii. Compliance

Under the Dingell-Boucher Draft, a new statutory office named the Office of

Carbon Market Oversight would be established within FERC.196 If created, this office

19 2 19 3 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at ss. 700(8) and 712; Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at 700(12) Environmental Protection Agency, Proposed Mandatory Greenhouse Gas Reporting Rule (10 March 2009), online: EPA <http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/emissions/ghgrulemaking.html> 19 4ibid. 19 5Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 811 196 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102

Page 55: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

51

would have administrative authority over the U.S. carbon market separate and distinct

from FERC and its Chairman. This authority would include regulatory authority over

issued credits, allowances and their derivatives.

Although the Waxman-Markey Bill does not create an independent office within

FERC, like the Dingell-Boucher Draft, the Bill grants FERC the authority to regulate the

carbon market.197 The Waxman-Boucher Bill takes a different approach on derivatives

by directing the President to delegate regulatory authority over this market to the

appropriate agency.198 If the Bill gains traction in the Senate this year, FERC will likely

follow the EPA’s lead and begin breaking ground on its own regulatory obligations.

ix. Pre-emption

The EU ETS was the first cap-and-trade regime to be put in place in Europe. As

such, it occupied the field and was unchallenged by competing regimes. The same cannot

be said in North America. Despite the hard work that has been done, the Dingell-Boucher

Draft and Waxman-Markey Bill intend to occupy the field in much the same way as the

EU ETS. While the Dingell-Boucher Draft will pre-empt all other trading programs

permanently199, the Waxman-Markey Bill initially limits the period of pre-emption to the

first five years of implementation. 200

19 7 19 8 Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 761 ibid. 19 9Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 707 20 0Waxman-Markey, supra note 103 at s. 861

Page 56: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

52

B. Summary of Part IV

While the current Administration has the authority under the Clean Air Act to

regulate CO2 emissions in the U.S., most agree that such an approach would not provide

a strong framework for a national emissions trading scheme. On the other hand, many of

the Dingell-Boucher Draft and Waxman Market Bill weaknesses, such as borrowing and

forestry offsets, discussed further in Part V, are perhaps political chips necessary to

commence the legislative ball rolling. The U.S. legislation represents an important step

toward not only a national approach, but also a multi-national GHG approach by

facilitating linking with the EU ETS.

Page 57: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

53

PART V

Conclusions on Linkage

In Part IV, the comparative analysis put forward focused on similarities and

differences of the approaches taken by the EU ETS and anticipated by the Dingell-

Boucher and Waxman-Markey emission regimes. While special attention was paid in

Part IV to the identification of area of concern in terms of linkage of future linkage of

these schemes, Part V will provide more thorough analysis of the obstacles and what can

be done to ensure compatibility in the years ahead.

A. Linkage Generally

It is without doubt that if the U.S. adopts any emission reduction scheme there

will be a major push domestically to work with other international players toward the

common goal of avoiding catastrophic climate change. That being said, any U.S.

legislative action should, at the drafting stage, look toward overcoming obstacles to

linkage in order to facilitate the transfer of allowances between schemes. Internalization

of such an objective not only externalizes a shared goal, it facilitates attainment of the

goal by dramatically improving liquidity and reducing each system’s economic costs

associated with its implementation. Although the U.S. prefers not to have its domestic

policy dictated, the potential for a ‘win-win’ should significantly motivate the legislature

and relieve some concerns regarding effects on the domestic economy. So long as each

scheme’s rules remains substantially similar, for instance if neither allows its allocation

pool to be a conduit for cheaper ‘hot air’ credits which create surplus credits that are sold

53

Page 58: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

54

for profit to participants in the linked scheme, the environmental outcome will not be

frustrated and market efficiency will prevail because emission allocations will be

exchanged on par.

If the U.S. legislative approach focuses on the reduction of GHG globally, not

only nationally, then drafters should look toward the EU. The EU has higher institutional

learning based on its early efforts, and its participants have had several years to

internalize the inevitability of compliance. In fact, this advance notice may facilitate

lower costs of compliance that may be passed on to U.S. covered emitters seeking short-

term purchases while emission reduction technologies develop and are ultimately

implemented. In short, the inchoate U.S. trading market would likely benefit from

linking to a market the size of the EU ETS.

Discussed in Part II, the Stern Report suggests that each country should use the

appropriate mix of taxes, trading, spending and regulation as necessary to reach its

emission reduction target 201 Following the Stern Report, as the U.S. moves toward

enacting a cap-and-trade regime, drafters should not solely determine the national

emission reductions that will be included in its scope, but also what portion of the overall

cap could be reduced in a more efficient or beneficial manner with other mechanisms.

For instance, does the U.S. want to encourage green technological improvements by

employing a carbon tax regime that establishes a fixed price for carbon? However, when

other types of regimes work “alongside emissions trading (tax, environmental, exchange

20 1 Stern Report, supra note 31

Page 59: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

55

regulation, corporate governance)” they “should be examined for potential distortions on

the link, which could lead to welfare losses exceeding welfare gains from linking”.202

B. Linkage Suggestions

Based on the comparisons of the EU ETS with the Dingell-Boucher Draft and

Waxman-Markey Bill, in Part IV, the following suggestions should be considered by the

legislature when moving forward.

1. Allocations

The first matter to be considered by a legislative drafter of an emission reduction

regime is – “what are we going to trade?” If the U.S. anticipates linking with the EU

ETS, then it has correctly relied on the established EU standard of an allocation being

equivalent to one tonne of CO2 or other equivalent volume of GHG.

If the US chooses to proceed with the Dingell-Boucher Draft or the Waxman-

Markey Bill, the scheme will cover not only CO2, but also other GHG. Such a position

represents a noble ambition to take the lead globally, since currently the EU ETS covers

CO2 alone. Given timeframe considerations and genuine concerns regarding potential

administrative lag time as the system gets up and running, the drafters may find current

20 2 Chapman, J., “Linking a US Greenhouse Gas Cap-and-Trade System to the EU ETS” (2009) Itn’l Law Seminar, online: wordpress < works.bepress.com/james_chapman/1/>

Page 60: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

56

proposals including other GHG advantageous, since Phase III EU ETS coverage will be

expanded to include to other gasses into the scheme. 203

While U.S. and EU ETS emission allocations may be roughly equivalent in terms

of the volume of CO2, the use and types of offsets available under the schemes is not. As

discussed above, the U.S. plans allow its covered entities to use a greater percentage of

offsets relative to emission allocations and, furthermore, more sources of offsets are

contemplated. Specifically, the U.S. legislature is contemplating domestic forestry

offsets, a type of offset that was only recently rejected by the European Commission.

The Europeans voiced their opposition after the first U.S. draft was released. When

approving the Waxman-Markey Bill, the U.S. legislature seemed to disregard these

concerns by allowing changes to several provisions that increased “the use of offsets,

especially domestic ones, and consequently lower the cost of the program”.204 Without

an agreement between the governments, the inclusion of domestic forestry credits in the

U.S. could enter the U.S. cap and allow U.S. allocations to be exported into the EU ETS.

Participants in the EU ETS would likely object, since the European Counsel has refused

to allow these offsets because of reliability concerns.

Before legislation is enacted, it would be wise for the current U.S. administration

to discuss the use of offsets further. While offsets are a valuable tool in the toolbox for

20 3 Coverage will be extended for Phase III of the EU ETS to include other sectors and GHG emissions, including CO2 emissions from petrochemicals, ammonia and aluminium and nitrous oxide emissions from the production of perfluorocarbons from the aluminium sector: See “The Waxman-Markey Bill and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme: The Basics” McDermott Newsletters (22 May 2009) online: McDermott < http://www.mwe.com/index.cfm/fuseaction/publications.nldetail/object_id/84e2f069-9d58-4fd1-8a7d- d8efdcd7f313.cfm> 20 4EPA, “Ways in Which Revisions to the American Clean Energy and Security Act Change the Projected Economic Impacts of the Bill” (17 May 2009), online: EPA <http://www.epa.gov/climatechange /economics/pdfs/EPAMemoonHR2454.pdf>

Page 61: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

57

mitigating the cost of compliance, they are not the only tool. Even in this modest

economy, the U.S. legislature has a large purse and may choose to spend on programs to

lower national emissions and create jobs rather than rely on offsets.

2. Price Control – Borrowing

While both pieces of legislation do not contemplate a price cap, which would

likely severely obstruct linkage with the EU, a U.S. scheme will likely permit borrowing

to meet obligations.205 The delay of emission reduction by a covered entity is not seen as

a best practice by environmental commentators. It is understood that emitters may either

not comply in the future or complain that the cost of compliance has become too great

and the regulator should offer a solution. The European Parliament recently released a

note addressing, among other issues, the issue of borrowing in an emission trading

scheme in the context of linking.206 In that note the authors suggests that if one system

allows borrowing and another does not, a condition for linking should be a restrictive

provision such as, “to allow purchases for the scheme with borrowing only after its

compliance period has been completed and only from companies that did not borrow, i.e.

to allow only ex-post purchases of surplus allowances.”207 The reason for such a

restriction is that emitters should not play the market, selling allocations in year one in an

attempt to, deliberate or not, profit from a lower price subsequent to the sale. Such a

transaction would resemble a short sale of securities.

20 5 20 6 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 715(2) Implications of Linking, supra note 141 20 7ibid.

Page 62: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

58

There should be discussion between the EU and U.S. if the legislature intends to

allow borrowing. While such borrowing may provide economic insurance, it may be

unnecessary given both the added liquidity brought about by linking and the relatively

low historical price of allocations. When drafting a final bill, the legislature should

consider dropping borrowing provisions. Rather, it should focus its legislative eye on

improvements to provisions supporting and funding mitigation technologies such as

carbon capture and storage and energy efficiency. In doing so, the legislature will better

prepare the U.S. economy and increase competitiveness with our global partners.

3. Enforcement

While it is too early in the legislative process to comment on the administration of

enforcement, it is fair to comment that the proposed legislative penalties for

noncompliance provisions show their teeth.208 How this is carried forward will

ultimately effect the EU position on liking to the regime, with perhaps more weight than

any other single factor. Indeed, the EU will likely wait for any U.S. regime to be up and

running to have time to measure not only the penalties themselves, but also how well the

Administrator enforces the sanctions for non-compliance. In all likelihood, as the

legislation will likely come with legislative support and fall within the new

administrations mandate, it will be enforced. That being said, so long as the final

penalties and sanctions are at least as stringent as those in the EU, the Commission could

favour approval of linkage on this basis.

20 8 Dingell-Boucher, supra note 102 at s. 713

Page 63: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

59

C. Summary of Part V

At present, the U.S legislative proposals are at odds with the EU ETS in several

respects. In some respects, the proposals are miles ahead of the EU ETS, for example by

the inclusion of GHGs other than CO2. However, other aspects, such as the use of

banking, fall short of the EU ETS mandate. It is without a doubt that the U.S. legislature

should be encouraged to draft legislation that is compatible with the EU ETS. The

benefits of a single price control provision should be weighed against the anticipated

benefits in liquidity and flexibility that could result as a consequence of linking. It is also

important to consider where both schemes are ultimately headed and how long it will take

to reach a common objective.

Page 64: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

60

PART VI Conclusion

The U.S. legislature must draft with a pen contemplating events that might not

occur until years in the future. Over the last decade the pace of climate change science

and the government response has regrettably both increased and failed to keep up with

the realities as they come into our collective view. Various government reports

concerning the effects and proposed approached are issued weekly, if not by the day.

Suffice it to say, information presented by this paper, timely as it may be, will likely be

out of date by the end of this year. It is tremendously difficult for any legislature to

govern effectively. Addressing climate change on the legislative level will be one of the

greatest challenges of any government dedicating itself to the task.

If it is accepted that we must act to address global climate change, then we must

act globally. The ‘go it alone’ approach that was presented by the United States during

the first half of the century is not compatible with a global effort. It is without a doubt

that the legislature must ensure that the U.S. economy remains strong enough to provide

for their constituents. Future action must be tempered by such a concern, not dictated.

If the U.S. legislature undertakes to enact legislation based on current proposals,

negotiation with the European Union should take place prior to enactment. Linkage

issues and potential solutions should be identified in advance. If the United States and

Europe accomplish this objective, it is likely that the rest of the world will follow. If that

is the case, the U.S. will be part of a global solution to a global problem.

60

Page 65: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

61

BIBLIOGRAPHY

SECONDARY MATERIAL: MONOGRAPHS

Jonathan H Adler, “Massachusetts v. EPA Heats Up Climate Change Policy No Less Than Administrative Law: A Comment on Professors Watts and Wildermuth” (2007) Northwestern University Law Review Colloquy, online: <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id+993511>

Thompson, Bill, “Latest Developments in the EU ETS”, Carbon Expo, Cologne, 2 May 2007, online: <http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php%3FdocID% 3D2294>

SECONDARY MATERIAL: ARTICLES

Alliance to Save Energy, “Summary of Dingell-Boucher Discussion Draft”, (October 2008), online: ASE <http://www.ase.org>

Chapman, J., “Linking a US Greenhouse Gas Cap-and-Trade System to the EU ETS” (2009) Itn’l Law Seminar, online: wordpress <works.bepress.com/james_chapman /1/>

Doelle, M, “Global Carbon Trading and Climate Change Mitigation in Canada: Options for the Use of the Kyoto Mechanisms” in Bernstein et al, eds., A Globally Integrated Climate Policy for Canada (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2007)

Driesen, D.M. "Linkage and Multilevel Governance." 19 Duke J Comp & Int'l L 389, online: Duke Journal of Comparative and International Law < http://www.law .duke.edu/journals/djcil/>

EEA, “Technical report No 2/2006, Application of the emissions trading directive by EU Member States”, http://reports.eea.europa.eu/technical_report_2006_2/en.

Frauendorfer, “Clean Valuation with regard to EU Emission Trading” (2008), online: U.N.<http://www.finance.unisg.ch/org/finance/web.nsf/SysWebRessources /WP84/%24FILE/WP84.pdf>

Freeman, J., and Vermeule, A., “Massachusetts v. EPA: From Politics to Expertise” (Aug 2007), online: ssrn <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers. cfm?abstract_id=1008906>

Green, A, “Bringing Institutions and Individuals into Climate Policy for Canada” in Bernstein et al, eds., A Globally Integrated Climate Policy for Canada (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2007)

Page 66: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

62

Grubb, M. “The Economics of the Kyoto Protocol.” World Economics, volume 4, number 3, (July-September 2003), online: World Economics <www.ieta.org/ieta/www/ pages/getfile.php?docID=129>

Jaffe, J. and Stavins R., “Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture”, The Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements, Discussion Paper 08-07, September, online: Harvard < belfercenter.ksg.harvard.edu/.../linkage_of_tradable_permit_systems_in_international_cli mate_policy_architecture.html>

John M. Broder, “E.P.A. expected to Regulate Carbon Dioxide” The New York Times (18 February 2009), online: The New York Times: Environment <http://www.nytimes.com/2009/02/science/earth/19epa.html>

Karlseng, T.H., “Decreasing German Climate Ambitiousness”, FNI Report 8/2006, online: FNI < http://www.fni.no/doc&pdf/FNI-R0806.pdf>

Mukerjee, M., "A Mechanism of Hot Air", Scientific American (June 2009)

Pew Center, “The European Union Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS) Insights and Opportunities”, online: <http://www.pewclimate.org/docUploads/EU- ETS%2520White%2520Paper.pdf>

Pew Center on Global Climate Change, Statement, “Summary of the Dingell- Boucher Discussion Draft”, (7 October 2008), online: Pew Center <http://www. pewclimate.org/statement/dingell-boucher/10-07-08>

“Putting a Price on Carbon: An Emissions Cap or A Tax?” Opinion, Yale Environment 360, (07 May 2009) online: Yale Environment 360 <http://www. e360.yale.edu/content/feature.msp?id=2148>

Ramakrishnan, J, “EU ETS”, International Environmental Science Center, online: IESC <http://www.internationalprofs.org/iesc/eu-ets.html>

“The Waxman-Markey Bill and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme: The Basics” McDermott Newsletters (22 May 2009) online: McDermott < http://www.mwe.com/ index.cfm/fuseaction/publications.nldetail/object_id/84e2f069-9d58-4fd1-8a7d- d8efdcd7f313.cfm>

Thomson, V., “Early Observations on the European Union’s Greenhouse Gas Emission Trading Scheme: Insights for United States Policymakers” University of Virginia (19 April 2006), online: Pew Climate < www.pewclimate.org/.../Early _Observations_on_EUETS_Thomson.pdf>

Page 67: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

63

Weitzman, M.L. 1974. “Prices vs Quantities,” The Review of Economic Studies 41(October)

Wiener, J, “Think Globally, Act Globally: The Limits of Local Climate Policies”, Duke Law School Legal Studies, Research Paper Series, Research Paper No. 158 (May 2007), online: Duke Law School <http://lsr.nellco.org/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article =1093&context=duke/fs>

Worldwatch Institute, State of the World 2009: Into a Warming World, (Washington, D.C.: Norton, W. W. & Company, Inc., 2009) , online: Worldwatch <www.worldwatch.org/sow09>

UNITED STATES MATERIALS

Cases

Massachusetts, et al, Petitioners v. Environmental Protection Agency, et al (2007), 549 U.S. 497, 127 S. Ct 1438

Legislative Materials

American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009, H.R.2454

S.2191, the Lieberman-Warner Climate Security Act, December 5, 2007

S. Res. 98, introduced by Senate Robert Byrd (D-WV) and Chuck Hagel (R-NE) passed on July 35, 1997

Clean Air Act (CAA), 40 U.S.C. 7401-7671q

Environmental Protection Agency, Proposed Mandatory Greenhouse Gas Reporting Rule (10 March 2009), online: <http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/emissions/ ghgrulemaking.html>

INTERNATIONAL MATERIALS

European Commission: Communications, Directives, Decisions, and Regulations

Amended on July 8, 2008. European Parliament, “Air pollution: including aviation activities in the scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community (amend. Directive 2003/87/EC)”,

Page 68: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

64

Annex III to Directive 2003/87/EC establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC.

EC, Commission Communication COM(2003)830 of January 2004 on guidance to assist Member States in the implementation of the criteria listed in Annex III to Directive 2003/87/EC establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC, online: <http://www.epa.ie/downloads/advice/air/climate%20change/name,13125,en.html>

EC, Commission Communication COM(2005)703 of 22 December 2005 on further guidance on allocation plans for the 2008 to 2012 trading period of the EU Emission Trading Scheme, online: <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission/2nd_phase_ ep.htm>

EC, Commission Decision16/CP.10, (Issues relating to registry systems under Art. 7(4) of the Kyoto Protocol) in FCCC/CP/2005/3/Add.3

EU, Commission Decision of 18 July 2007 C (2007/589/EC) establishing guidelines for the monitoring and reporting of greenhouse gas emissions pursuant to Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council (notified under document number C(2007) 3416), online: <http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/ LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2007:229:0001:0085:EN:PDF>

EU, Commission Decision of 29/01/2004, establishing guidelines for the monitoring and reporting of greenhouse gas emissions, adopted in regards to Article 14 of Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council

EC, Commission Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 October 2003 establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC [2003],

EC, Commission Regulation of 21 December 2004 for a standardized and secured system of registries pursuant to Directive 2003/87/EC and Decision 280/2004/EC

EC, Council Directive 2003/87/EC, 2003 O.J. (L 275/32) (EC)

Page 69: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

65

Treaties and Other International Agreements

Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, U.N. Doc. FCCC/CP/197/L.7/Add. (Dec. 10, 1997)

United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, “U.N. Doc. A/AC 237/18”

European Commission: Press Releases, Policies and Memos

EC, Policy Department Economic and Scientific Policy, Implications of Linking the EU ETS with other Emissions Trading Schemes, (2007), online: EP <http://www. Europart.europa.eu/activities/committees/studies/download.do?file=19802>

EC, Press Release, “Climate change: Commission welcomes final adoption of Europe’s climate and energy package” (17 December 2008), online: Europa <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/08/1998&format=HTML& aged=08language=EN&guiLanguage=en>

EC, Questions and Answers on the Commission’s proposal to revise the EU Emission Trading Scheme, (23 January 2008) MEMO/08/35, online: EC <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/08/35&format=HTM L&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en>

UNFCCC, A Glossary of Climate Change & Forestry, online: UNFCC <http://unfcccbali.org/unfccc/component/option,com_glossary/Itemid,99/func,view/catid, 31/term,Emissions+Reduction+Unit,+or+ERU/>

UNFCCC, First emission credits issued under the Kyoto Protocol, online: UNFCCC<http://cdm.unfccc.int/CDMNews/issues/issues/I_WJHSF1N67JGAORWII2B KVAI8O74B5A/viewnewsitem.html>

Europa, “Emissions trading: Commission decides on first set of national allocation plans for the 2008-2012 trading period”, Press Release - 29 November 2006, online: <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/06/1650>

European Commission, “EU emissions trading — an open scheme promoting global innovation”, online: EC <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/ pdf/emission_trading2_en.pdf>

Page 70: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

66

UN Documents

UNFCCC, “Data Exchange Standards for Registry Systems Under the Kyoto Protocol” (2006), online: U.N. <http://unfccc.int/files/kyoto_mechanisms /registry_systems/application/pdf/des_techspec_v1_1.pdf>

UNFCCC, “International Transaction Log –ITL”, online: <http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/registry_systems/itl/items/4065.php>

EU, “Greenhouse gas emission allowance trading scheme”, online: Europa < http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/energy/european_energy_policy/l28012_en.htm>

United Nations Convention on Climate Change, “Registry Systems under the Kyoto Protocol”, online: U.N. <http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/registry_systems /items/2723.php>

Other International Documents

Congressional Research Service, Summary of Waxman-Markey Draft Greenhouse Gas Legislation (14 May 2009), online: CRS < http://lugar.senate.gov/services/ pdf_crs/Summary_of_Waxman-Markey.pdf>

House of Commons, “Stern Review: the implications for Treasury policy: Government Response to the Committee's Fourth Report of Session 2007–08” (22 April 2008), online: House of Commons < http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm 200708/cmselect/cmtreasy/495/495.pdf>

IHS, “FAQ on EU Emissions Trading and National Allocation Plans for 2008- 2012”, online: <http://engineers.ihs.com/news/2006/eu-en-emissions-trading-faq-11- 06.htm>

Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Fourth Assessment Report, Climate Change 2007: Synthesis Report, Summary for Policymakers

Stern, N. (2006): The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review; Cambridge University Press, New York, New York, ch. 15, <http://www.hm- treasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_change/ sternreview_index.cfm>

Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change Executive Summary; HM Treasury, online: < http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/Executive_ Summary.pdf>

Page 71: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

67

UK Dept. of Environment, “Early days of EU Emissions Trading System and the Response of Government and Business” (2008)

EPA, “EPA Analysis of the Waxman-Markey Discussion Draft: The American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 ” (20 April 2009), online: EPA < http://www.epa. gov/climatechange/economics/pdfs/WaxmanMarkeyExecutiveSummary.pdf>

EPA, News Release, “EPA Finds Greenhouse Gases Pose Threat to Public Health, Welfare / Proposed Finding Comes in Response to 2007 Supreme Court Ruling”, (April 17 2009), online: EPA < http://yosemite.epa.gov/opa/admpress.nsf/0/0EF7DF6758 05295D8525759B00566924>

EPA, “Ways in Which Revisions to the American Clean Energy and Security Act Change the Projected Economic Impacts of the Bill” (17 May 2009), online: EPA <http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/economics/pdfs/EPAMemoonHR2454.pdf>

World Meteorological Organization, Info Note No. 44

INTERNET DOCUMENTS

Carbon Finance, “ITL link, EU ETS review key for 2008 prices”, online: <http://www.carbon-financeonline.com/index.cfm?section=lead&action=view&id =10948&linkref=cnews>

Carbon Market Data, Press Release, 2 June 2006, online: <http://www.carbonmarketdata.com/pages/Press%2520release%2520CMD %2520%2520EU%2520ETS%2520-%25202%2520June%25202006.pdf>

Climate Registry, General Reporting Protocol, (May 2008), Climate Registry online: <http://www.theclimateregistry.org/downloads/GRP.pdf>

Climate VISION (Voluntary Innovative Sector Initiatives: Opportunities Now) administered through the Department of Energy’s policy and international program, online: Climate Vision <http://climatevision.gov/>

Congressman John Dingell, online: <http://www.house.gov/dingell/>

Congressman Rick Boucher, online: <http://www.boucher.house.gov/>

Defra, Dept. for Environment Food and Rural Affairs, “Phase III”, online: <http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/eu/operators/phase-3.htm>

Page 72: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

68

Defra, “Final Methodology Guidance”, online: Defra <http://www.environment- agency.gov.uk/commondata/acrobat/amrules_2070949.pdf

Department of Energy and Climate Change, Phase 2 Monitoring Plan and Guidance, https://www.og.berr.gov.uk/environment/MRplantemplate.xls

Environment UK, “ETS1Application and Guidance”, online: http://www.environment-agency.gov.uk/commondata/105385/ets_app_guide_624838.pdf

Europa, “Questions & Answers on national allocation plans for 2008-2012”, Press Release - 9 January 2006, online: <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do? reference=MEMO/06/2&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en>

European Federation of Energy Traders, “June 2005 EFET Position on the EU ETS Review”, online: <http://www.efet.org/Download.asp%3FFile%3D677>

House Committee on Energy and Commerce, online: <http://energy commerce.house.gov

Ieta, “Market Developments in the EU ETS: An Exchange’s viewpoint”, online: Ieta <http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php%3FdocID%3D1338>

Memoranda from Rick Boucher, Chairman Subcommittee on Energy and Air Quality and John D. Dingell, Chairman Committee on Energy and Commerce (7 October 2008) U.S. House of Representatives

National Center For Policy Analysis, News Release, No. 617, “Capping C02 Emissions, Bousting Energy Costs”, (14 May 2008), online: NCPA < http://www.ncpa.org/pub/ba617>

Open Carbon World <http://www.opencarbonworld.com/wiki/european-union- emission-trading-scheme.html>

Point Carbon, Press Release, (12 May 2006), online: Point Carbon <http://www.pointcarbon.com/wimages/Press release Point Carbon 12 May 2006 1.pdf>

Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, online: RGGI http://www.rggi.org/

Shapiro, S & Cheatham, C, “The Green Building Guide to Waxman-Markey”, Reuters, (26 June 2009), online: Reuters < http://www.reuters.com/article/gwmBuildings/ idUS216473327920090626>

Page 73: CARBON COPIES: THE UNITED STATES, EU ETS AND LINKAGE...Carbon Copies: The United States, EU ETS and Linkage Benjamin Higham Master of Laws Graduate Department of Law University of

69

United Nations Convention on Climate Change, “clean development mechanism”, online:U.N.<http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/mechanisms/clean_development_mechanis m/items/2718.php>

United Nations Convention on Climate Change, Kyoto Protocol, online: http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/mechanisms/joint_implementation/items/1674.php

Western Climate Initiative, online: WCI <http://www.westernclimate initative.org/>

World Wildlife Fund, “EU ETS, Competitiveness and Employment”, online: WWF <http://www.wwf.fi/wwf/www/uploads/pdf/clearingthemist_summary.pdf