capitalism and global poverty. david ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under...

15
CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY

Upload: zoe-parks

Post on 30-Dec-2015

213 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY

Page 2: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money wage), owing inter alia to their being produced on a fixed or not-easily-augmentable land mass, had visualized a fall in the rate of profit with the progress of capital accumulation.

• The generalization of a fall in the rate of profit from such sectors to the economy as a whole, was supposed to occur through terms of trade movements (prices in other sectors falling relative to those with increasing supply price).

Page 3: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• To illustrate: suppose only circulating capital is used and wages are paid at the end of the period; then using w for the wage rate in terms of a money commodity (itself one of the produced commodities), we have (where other symbols have their usual meaning):

• p’ = w.l’ [I – (1+r)A]-1 • If labour- or input-coefficients, or both, increase for the n-th sector,

and if its output enters directly or indirectly as inputs into all other sectors, then r will fall for a given w and the n-th good’s price will rise relative to every other good.

• Ricardian theory would thus predict a secular shift in the terms of trade in favour of primary commodities which are the ones typically subject to increasing supply price, vis-à-vis manufactured goods which are not.

• But this is the very opposite of what has historically occurred.

Page 4: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• The theory is not just historically invalidated but logically flawed too. A secular shift in the terms of trade in favour of primary commodities which are subject to increasing supply price is incompatible with a money-using capitalist economy for wealth-holders will then shift from holding money to holding these commodities, which will replace the money commodity in its role as money.

• Such commodities no doubt have a carrying cost unlike money. But there is no reason for the elasticity of price expectation for such commodities to be less than unity in this case. Hence if some people shift from money to a primary commodity, there would be a cumulative divergence, and the role of the money commodity will be supplanted.

• Likewise if the money price of the primary commodity does not change but that of the manufactured good falls, then money will replace the manufactured good as the object of accumulation.

Page 5: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• Hence a money using capitalist economy is impossible under Ricardian conditions, i.e. if there are some commodities whose prices are expected to increase persistently.

• Sectors subject to increasing supply price at given money wages, must therefore experience decreasing money wages over time as more output is produced by them, so that their prices do not rise in terms of other commodities and in terms of the money commodity, even as the money wages in the latter commodities remain constant.

• The existence of increasing supply price in some sectors (at given money wages) must entail therefore, for the viability of capitalism, that the basic assumptions of free competition capitalism, namely equal money wages and equal rate of profit in all sectors, must not hold. There cannot be free competition capitalism if there are sectors with increasing supply price.

Page 6: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• Taking a two-good model where good 2 is subject to “diminishing returns” the price equations, instead of being:

(a11 + p2.. a21) (1+ r) + w. l1 = 1(a12 + p2. a22 ) (1+ r) + w. l2 = p2 (i)

which for any given w determine r and p2 and where a rise in l2 or a12 or a22 lowers the rate of profit, we actually have two wage rates and the following price equations:

(a11 + p2.. a21) (1+ r) + w1. l1 = 1(a12 + p2. a22 ) (1+ r) + w2. l2 = p2 (ii)

Given w1 and p2, r and w2 get determined. As input coefficients in sector 2 rise, only w2 falls; neither the terms of trade nor r fall, despite the latter being endogenously determined;.

• But this presupposes that sector 2 labour is not used to produce the sector 1 good.

• This arrangement is exactly what colonialism entailed.

Page 7: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• The problem of fixity of land related primarily to the tropical land mass, which got colonized (not settled) by metropolitan capitalism. The colonial State shunned “land augmenting” investments or technological progress such as irrigation; it imposed instead “income deflation” on the tropical population to squeeze local demand, to obtain directly (or by diverting land use) the goods needed by metropolitan capitalism.

• The two main ways of income deflation were: “deindustrialization” and the “drain of surplus” through the colonial tax system.

• Labour from the “periphery” was not allowed to move to the metropolis. And metropolitan capital did not move there to produce the goods it manufactured in the metropolis. Local capital was also not allowed to produce with local cheap labour the goods manufactured in the metropolis.

• Colonialism thus overcame the Ricardian problem without either a shift in the terms of trade in favour of primary commodities or a fall in the rate of profit.

• But the result was large-scale absolute poverty in these regions.

Page 8: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• This poverty, by my argument, had a tendency to increase, as capital accumulation occurred in the metropolis, raising the demand for tropical products. The difficulty in increasing the outputs of a range of products required by capitalism, owing to the fixity of land (“the niggardliness of nature”), led neither to an increase in their relative prices, nor a fall in the general rate of profit; it led rather to a squeeze on the absolute living standards of the working population engaged in such production (or more generally of those living in the tropical and sub-tropical regions).

• Deprivation no doubt existed in tropical societies before the advent of colonialism. But modern mass poverty which must be distinguished from mere deprivation, as it is associated with individual insecurity, came to these societies through capitalist incursion via colonialism.

• Secondly, that, with capital accumulation in the metropolis, the tendency was for the level of absolute poverty of the working population to increase.

• With globalization, this tendency, for absolute poverty to increase as capital accumulation occurs in the metropolis, itself gets globalized: the working population in the metropolis too, not just in the periphery, now becomes a victim of this tendency.

Page 9: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• With globalization, labour from the periphery does not move freely to the metropolis, but capital from the metropolis now moves to the periphery, to locate plants there for producing for the global market. Likewise the constraints upon local capital’s producing goods hitherto produced only in the metropolis, and exporting them to the latter, become relaxed.

• What this means is that w1 is no longer independent of w2; the two may not actually get equalized, but they get linked, i.e.

• w1 = α.w2 (a)

where α is a constant greater than 1, reflecting the resistance (whether consumer resistance or metropolitan capitalists’ resistance) that has to be overcome before the production of metropolitan products shifts to the periphery.

Page 10: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• If (a) holds, then not just w2 but w1 too becomes flexible; hence there is no question of the rate of profit falling on account of rising input coefficients in sector 2.

• But in this case, the rate of profit in the two sectors will no longer be equal, which in turn can be possible only because of the existence of monopoly in the production of non-primary products.

• Our system of price equations, after incorporating (a), will be:(a11 + p2.. a21) (1+ r1) + α.w2. l1 = 1(a12 + p2. a22 ) (1+ r2) + w2. l2 = p2 .. (iii)

• If p2 is fixed, say, at the pre-globalization level, i.e. there is no reason for any secular shift in the terms of trade on account of globalization, and if r2 is also fixed (say, at the pre-globalization level, to ensure that sector 2 output keeps increasing to meet the demand for it), then w2 and r1 get determined by the two equations in (iii).

• Here, as the input coefficients in sector 2 rise with increasing output, because of the “niggardliness of nature”, the wage rates in both sectors decline over time, while the profit rate in sector 1 increases over time.

Page 11: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• Globalization in other words brings about a decline in money wages (and in real wages) in both the sectors because of a rise in the input coefficients in sector 2.

• Or, putting it concretely, the consequence of the fixity of the tropical land mass, the demand for whose products increases owing to the process of capital accumulation in the world economy, is a rise in input coefficients in such products. But this causes an absolute impoverishment of all the workers, those in the periphery as well as those in the metropolis.

• Globalization thus globalizes the tendency towards absolute impoverishment of the working population.

Page 12: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• For the workers in the periphery, globalization does not entail anything new compared to the colonial period. Even when there is a diffusion of activity from the metropolis to the periphery, the wage rate of the work-force in these new activities, tethered to the wage rate of workers in the primary producing activities, does not increase, and in fact declines as the input coefficients rise in primary production.

• Of course, globalization, though not making a difference to the position of the workers in the periphery compared to the colonial period, does make a difference compared to the immediate pre-globalization era, i.e. the era of dirigiste development, which had seen “land augmenting” investment and technical progress, undertaken by a post-colonial State. Such “land augmentation” had cut the link between capital accumulation and absolute impoverishment. This link gets re-established under globalization when land augmentation ceases under a regime of “sound finance”.

• Where globalization does make a difference is to the workers of the metropolis who now also face absolute impoverishment.

Page 13: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• The mechanisms of income deflation imposed on the working population in the era of globalization are different from those in the colonial period, owing to the absence of any direct political control by the metropolis.

• “De-industrialization”, defined broadly as the displacement of several petty producers and traders from their traditional activities by competition from the metropolis or from activities established within the periphery in imitation of the metropolis, continues to be a mechanism of income deflation; but, instead of the colonial tax system, an alternative mechanism is used, and that consists in expenditure deflation by the State.

• The pursuit of neo-liberal policies imposes such expenditure deflation upon the State in the name of “sound finance”; and it causes income deflation for the working population within the periphery.

Page 14: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• We thus have two counter-intuitive propositions relating to the era of globalization: first, a rise in the input coefficients in the primary production sector, owing, above all, to the fixity of the tropical land mass, has the effect of lowering the money and real wage rates of workers in the metropolis too, and not just of the working population in the periphery.

• Second, it also has the effect of raising the rate of profit in the metropolis.

• A diametrically anti-Ricardo conclusion thus emerges: the existence of “diminishing returns” causes not a fall in the rate of profit but a rise.

Page 15: CAPITALISM AND GLOBAL POVERTY. David Ricardo, aware that certain commodities were produced under conditions of increasing supply price (for a given money

• If there is an increase in labour productivity in the metropolis, then this has the effect not of raising the wages of workers in the metropolis, but of raising the rate of profit there even further (if we assume away, as Ricardo did, any problem of deficiency aggregate demand).

• The absolute wage rate of the workers in the metropolis are unaffected by the level of labour productivity; even the tendency towards absolute impoverishment of metropolitan workers is unaffected by the pace of increase in their labour productivity.

• Joseph Stiglitz has suggested that the real income of a male worker

in the U.S. in 2011 was lower than in 1968. The increase in labour productivity during this period has simply caused a sharp decline in the share of wages. And what is true of the U.S. is also true of other advanced capitalist countries.