brumfield y fox 1994. factional competition (1).pdf

Upload: fenix862

Post on 01-Jun-2018

228 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    1/31

    actional competition

    and political

    development

    in the

    New World

    dited by

    E L I Z B E T H M B R U M F I E L

    and

    J O H N W FO X

    BIQUC VC L V n

    OdUS UEZ

    M B R I D G E

    U N I V E R S I T Y

    P R E S S

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    2/31

    32256

    P U B L I S H E D B Y T H E P R E S S SY N D I C A T E O F T H E U N I V E R S I T Y O F C A M B R I D G E

    Th e Pitt Building, Trumpington Street, Cambridge, United Kingdom

    C A M B R I D G E U N I V E R S I T Y P R E S S

    Th e Edinburgh Building, Cambridge CB 2 2RU, UK

    40 West 20th Street, New

    York

    NY

    lOOI

    I-4211, USA

    477 Williamstown Road, Port Melboume, V I C 3207, Australia

    Ruiz

    de larcn 13,28014

    Madrid,

    Spain

    Dock House, The Waterfront, Cape Town 8001, South

    Africa

    http ://www.Cambridge.org

    Cambridge University Press 1994

    This

    book is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception

    and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,

    no reproduction of any part may take place without

    the written permission of Cambridge University Press.

    First

    published 1994

    Firstpaperback edition2003

    catalogue

    record for

    this book

    is

    available

    from the ritish Library

    Library of Congress

    catalogiiing

    in

    publicationdata

    Factional competition and politicaldevelopmentin the New

    Worid/edited by Elizabeth M. Brumfiel and John W. Fox.

    p. cm. - New directions in archaeology)

    I S B N O521 38400 I hardback

    I Indians- Polities andgovemment.2. Political anthropology-

    America.3. Social archaeology - America.

    4. Indians - Antiquities.

    5.America- Antiquities. I Brumfiel, Elizabeth M.

    II Fox, John W., 1947- .I II Series.

    E59.P73F33 1993

    306.2-dc20 92-32371 CIP

    I S B N O521 38400 I hardback

    I S B N O521

    54584

    6 paperback

    j . ,

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    3/31

    1

    Factionalcompetition and

    political

    development in the

    NewWorld:an introduction

    E L I Z A B E T H M B R U M F I E L

    This

    volume calis attention to the importance of fac

    tional

    competitionas a

    forc

    of

    social

    transformation. It

    rges

    that factional competition is implicated in devel-

    opments as diverse as the spread of ceramic technology

    and maize agriculture, the origins of permanently insti-

    tuted

    leadership offices, the

    exp nsin

    and collapse of

    States

    and the European domination

    o f

    indigenous New

    Wor ld peoples.

    Although

    this volumefocusesupon the

    New Wor ld its perspective is relevant to the social

    histories of other re sof thewor ldas well becauseall

    non-egalitarian societies, both ancient and modern, are

    shapedby the dynamics of

    factional

    competition. Bring-

    ing

    an agent-centered perspective to the study of

    pol i

    tical

    development, this volume also contributes to a

    general understanding ofsocialstabilityand change. An

    agent-centered perspective maximizes the amount of

    datadrawn into the analysis and thus permits the most

    detailedand complete account of specificcasesofpol i

    tical

    continuity

    and transformation.

    Our

    studies

    o ffactional

    competitionboth complement

    and

    critique

    the

    two prevailingapproaches

    to prehistoric

    social

    change: cultural ecology and

    Marxism.

    Cultural

    ecologyfocusesupon the dynamic interactions

    o f

    human

    populations and their

    local

    environments. As a com

    plement to this, the studies in this volume examine the

    intemaldynamics of

    local

    populations, dynamics that

    help to shape the strategy of resourceexploitation.

    Marxist theory focuses upon the dynamics of

    class

    struggle: a model postulating solidaritywithin classes

    and struggle between them. As a complement to

    class

    struggle, theessaysi nthis volume emphasize the import

    ance

    of conflicts

    within

    classesand alliances between

    them.As critiques ofculturalecology and (particularly

    structural)Marxism,

    the studies in this volume

    d emn

    strate

    the necessity of replacing a theory of strict

    syste-

    micor structural determination of human behavior

    with

    a theory that integrales agent-centered and system-

    centered

    analyses

    into a single framework. Most of the

    studies in this volume employ versions of an

    agent-

    centered practice theory developed in theworkof

    Barth

    (1966),Giddens (1979), and Ortner (1984).

    Practice theory is especially suited to the analysis of

    factional

    competition.Factions are characterized by an

    informal,

    leader-focused organization (Nicholas 1965,

    Bujra 1973, Silverman1977);thus, itseemsreasonableto

    initiateanalysis by examining the goals and strategies

    employedby factionleadersas

    individual

    social actors.

    Furthermore, factions are groups whose singlefunction

    appears

    to be gainingaccess to limited physical and

    social resources

    (Bailey 1969:52), and

    these

    goals are

    best

    achieved through the application of a pragmatic,

    advantage-seeking, maximizing strategy such as that

    imputed

    to

    agents

    in practice theory.

    Finally,

    factions

    are structurally and

    functionally

    similar groups that

    compete for

    advantages

    withina larger social

    unit

    such

    as a kin group, ethnic group, village or chiefdom.

    Prac

    tice

    theory anticipates

    conflict

    between

    individuis

    simi-

    larly

    positioned within society

    while

    cultural ecology

    and

    Marxism

    do not. As argued below, this internal

    competition supplies the dynamic for

    political

    devel

    opment.

    This

    introduction

    begins bydefiningfactions and fac

    tionalcompetition. Then, it

    discusses

    the relationship

    between factional competition and ecological vari

    ables such as population, warfare, agricultural pro-

    duction,and long-distance trade.Th i rd itproposeshow

    factional

    competition and

    class

    struggle interact to

    produce the social formations discussed in the

    case

    studies that follow.

    F o r t h

    it considers how factions

    and factional competition can be

    identified

    in the

    archaeological record.

    Finally,

    i t examines the wider

    theoretical

    implications of an agent-centered per

    spective.

    What

    are factions?

    Aside from a few briefdiscussions of factions prior to

    1955 (Lasswell 1931, L in ton 1936:229, French 1948,

    Fenton 1955), anthropological interest in factions devel

    oped as part of aneffort to expand thescopeof social

    anthropology beyond the description and analysis of

    formal social structure. This was accomplished rst

    through

    the recognition of the many

    informal,

    non-

    corporate groups

    present

    in contemporary non-Western

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    4/31

    4 Elizabeth M. Brumfiel

    societies (including action groups, diques, networks,

    factions, and patron-client dyads). andsecond,through

    the investigation of how social structure isgeneratedby

    individuis acting to maximize their self-interest given

    their particularsetsofculturaland material constraints

    (Whitten and Whitten 1972;Cohn 1974:40-3; Vincent

    1978). From the mid-1960s to the mid-1970s, the con

    struction of modeis of

    informal

    groups and individual-

    centered social transactions was aflourishing, if

    some-

    what insular, enterprise

    within

    social anthropology, and

    factionsbecamethe object of considerable interest.

    A t issue was the definition of factions (Lewis and

    Dhil lon

    1954;

    Firth

    1957; Boissevain 1964; Nicholas

    1965),

    whether factions served positive social functions

    or were a

    form

    of social pathology (Siegel and Beals

    1960; Schwartz 1969); the relationship between factions

    and

    classconflict

    in

    peasant

    societies (Sandbrook 1972;

    Alavi 1973; Gross 1973; Schryer 1977), and whether

    factions were an obstruction or an

    mpetus

    to social

    change (Bujra 1973; Silverman and Salisbury 1977).

    However, this interest in factions abruptly collapsed in

    the late 1970swhen anthropologists turned away from

    local-level, agent-centered studies to pursue theissues

    raised by the wor ldsystemsperspective. Although fac

    tionshavecontinued toserveas a basicconstruct for

    analyzing peasant polities (e.g., Hegland 1981; Green-

    berg 1989; Munson 1989), the theoreticaldebates sur-

    rounding factionshaveceased.

    There are two

    reasons

    for resuscitating whatappears

    to

    be a

    dead horse.

    First, in the

    sudden

    move away

    from

    factions

    fifteen

    years

    ago, a number of theoretical

    issues

    concerning factions were left underdeveloped or

    unresolved. Second, while factional competition was

    analyzed extensively in relation to contemporary

    peasant

    polities, its usefulness for understanding the

    polities of prehistoric societies has not beenexplored.

    Dealing firstwiththe most important of the unresolved

    questions, we can ask, how should factions bedened

    During the 1960s, factions were defined in terms of

    their characteristics as a group. Factions were said to be

    politically oriented conflict groups whose membership

    was recruited and maintained through the efforts of a

    leader

    (Nicholas 1965; Bujra 1973; Silverman 1977). In

    such groups, unity derives

    from

    ties betweenleadersand

    followers; lateral ties among followers are poorly devel

    oped (Nicholas 1965:28-9; Bujra 1973:134). This was

    said to account for the loosely structured, personalistic

    character

    of factions

    F i r th

    1957:292). Factions were

    also

    said to be

    based

    upon calculations of self-interest

    rather than moral commitment to the group (Bailey

    1969:52), to be transitory groups with membership

    recruited on many differentbases(Nicholas 1965), and

    to be lacking in corporate property, frequent meetings,

    structural

    complexity,

    and rules governingsuccessionto

    leadership (Boissevain 1964; Bujra 1973). Explicitly or

    implicitly, factions were contrasted with corporate

    groups, the traditional focus of structural-functional

    analysis in social anthropology.

    Thesedefinitions are quite useful for investigating the

    character

    of factions as a type ofinformal group, but

    they divert attention from the most interesting dynamic

    property of factions, namely the competitive relation-

    ships

    between them. I f the object of investigation is to

    discover how factional competitionacts as a

    forc

    of

    social transformation, it is preferable to view factions in

    terms of what they do rather than in terms of what they

    are (Salisbury and Silverman 1977). Therefore, in this

    volume,

    factions are defined as

    structurallyandfunc-

    tionallysimilar groups which,byvirtueo theirsimilarity,

    competefor

    resources

    and positions

    o

    power

    or

    prestige.

    In this

    definition,

    factions are understood to be groups

    engaged in

    political

    competition which are neither

    classesor functionally differentiated interest groups.

    The lack of structural and functionaldiTerentiation

    between factions has

    been

    frequently noted. In a South

    India village, Siegel and Beals (1960:396) found

    "few

    indicationsof consisten differences

    between them in

    terms of

    policy

    or kinds of people who belonged. In

    Boissevain's (1964:1276) view, a faction is a loosely

    ordered group inconflict wi tha similar group.

    Simi-

    larly,

    Sandbrook (1972:111) defines a faction as a

    segment

    of a clientage network organized to compete

    with

    a unit or units ofsimilartype.

    Bujra (1973:136-8) provides an excellent theoretical

    account of the structural

    similarity

    of factions. She

    explains that faction leaderscome from similar social

    backgrounds because while social distance restricts

    competition, social contiguityengendersit . . . Conflicts

    thus often begin between people who are more socially

    alike than different. Inaddition,factionleaderstend to

    come from the dominant sectorsof society, since it is

    these individuis who have the resources needed to

    recruit large

    followings.

    Coming from the

    same

    privi-

    leged

    sector

    of society, faction

    leaders

    are

    likely

    to

    share

    similarpolitical goals, and

    these

    goals are not

    likely

    to

    challenge the

    basic

    structure of society.

    Bujra

    (1973:137)addsthat

    leaders,

    wishing to enlarge

    their

    followings,

    will

    seek

    supporters in all the different

    sectorsof society,claimingallegiance on many different

    bases:pastor future patronage,

    proximity

    of

    kinship,

    a

    common religinor ethnic identity, etc. Therefore, the

    individuisforminga faction lack an identityof interests

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    5/31

    Introduction

    that

    would engender

    common political goals beyond

    winningadvantages

    for their own faction. or arethere

    clear differences between themembersof different fac

    tions that might result in

    policy

    differences between

    them.

    Thus,

    while

    factions compete for

    resources,

    their

    structural

    similarity insures

    that they

    w i l l hold

    similar

    ideas

    about what the

    wo r l d

    is

    l ike

    and what it should be

    l ike. Factional competition

    tends

    to be non-

    revolutionary

    in intent. The objective of factional com

    petition

    is to achieve a favorable allocation of existing

    benefits;

    each

    faction

    hopes

    to gain more

    while

    its com-

    petitors gain

    less.

    Participants conceptualize factional

    competition as a zero-sum

    game

    in

    which

    one party's

    gain is

    another's

    loss. Thus, in factional competition,

    debategenerally

    centers

    upon the relative legitimacy of

    each

    faction's claims rather than the merits of

    substan-

    tivelydifferent social programs.

    Given

    the lack of structural differences between com-

    peting

    factions, it is at

    firstdifficult

    to see how they might

    act as vehicles of social transformation.

    Because

    fac

    tional

    competition is non-revolutionary in intent, it has

    often been

    regarded as non-revolutionary in con

    sequence

    (Siegel and Beals 1960,

    Gross

    1973, Sandbrook

    1972).

    However, Salisbury and Silverman (1977:6-7)

    observe

    that factionalism has an inherent dynamism

    grounded in competitive strategizing: Each confront-

    ation[between factions]

    changes

    the terms on

    which

    the

    next confrontation

    w i l l

    take place . . . [T]he strategy of

    one side .. .

    does

    not produce an exact or mirror-image

    strategy . . . Relations are, in fact, systematically oblique

    and groupings are systematically unalike. Factionalism,

    in short,

    produces

    actions and reactions that do not

    simplybalance

    o u t . . .

    The

    issue

    of whether, as Silverman and Salisbury

    suggest,

    factional competition could

    serve

    as a

    mechanism of social transformation has not

    been

    thoroughly

    explored. A major obstacle to gauging the

    transformative power of factional competition has

    been

    that, prior to this volume, factions

    have been

    studied in

    contemporary communities under the dominance of a

    state:

    Native American communities supervised by the

    Burean of Indian

    AlTairs

    and

    peasant

    communities in

    colonial

    or recently post-colonial nations. In such com

    munities,

    the

    state

    constrains both thescaleof

    conflict

    and thedegreeof structural

    change

    resulting from fac

    tional

    competition. For this

    reason,

    previous

    studies

    may easily

    have

    underestimated the transformative

    power of factional competition. Almost certainly, fac

    tionalcompetitionwas a more dynamicforcin

    pre-state

    societies than it is in the modern w o r l d.

    Anotherissuethat has notbeenthoroughly explored

    is the proper scaleof analysis for the study of factional

    competition. In the ethnographic literature, outside

    forces

    have

    sometimes

    beenseen

    as influencing factional

    competition.

    For example, the rise of factions is often

    attributed

    to the decline of traditional, power-holding

    corporate groups under the impact of Western contact

    (French 1948; Siegel and Beals 1960; Nicholas 1965;

    Nagata 1977). And several

    observers have suggested

    that

    the strength of factions and faction

    leaders

    varied

    according to their

    access

    to outside

    sources

    of

    revenue

    and influence, most often supplied by the

    state

    (Schwartz

    1969; Sandbrook 1972; Bujra 1973;

    Gross

    1973; Schryer

    1977; Salisbury 1977). Nevertheless, factions

    have been

    regarded as an

    aspect

    of

    local

    level polities (Schwartz

    1968),

    impinged upon by regional or national polities

    but not affecting them in

    reverse.

    I n contrast, severalessaysin this bookinvestgatethe

    interplay

    of local and regional

    processes

    in

    tribal po l i -

    ties.

    Spencer

    (Chapter 3)

    arges

    convincingly that the

    internal

    and external dimensions of

    tribal

    leadership are

    intertwined.

    The formation

    o f

    competing factions w i th i n

    communities

    goes

    hand in hand

    w i t h

    the development of

    alliances between faction

    leaders

    in different communi

    ties. The net effect of this

    process

    is to turn an entire

    regin

    into a single

    political

    arena,

    a community

    wi th i n

    which

    competing coalitions of faction

    leaders

    vie

    for resources.

    In a similar fashion, it

    becomes

    extremely

    difficult

    to

    di erentiate

    between local,internal dimen

    sions

    of

    political

    violence (the suppression of rebellion)

    and regional, external dimensions of

    political

    violence

    (the pursuit of warfare)

    once

    communities

    became

    enmeshed

    in intervillage alliances that compete at the

    regional

    level (see Anderson, Chapter 6, for Mississip

    pian societies and Pohl and Pohl, Chapter 13, for the

    Classic Maya).

    I n

    examining factional competition and

    political

    development in prehistoric societies, the

    essays

    in this

    volumeraise

    a number of

    issues,

    most of

    which

    are new

    to

    archaeology.

    These

    include: the opportunities and

    constraints

    presented

    by different

    mdiums

    of com

    petition including

    feasting (Clark and Blake, Chapter 2),

    external alliances and

    trade (Spencer,

    Chapter 3), and

    warfare (Redmond, Chapter 4; Helms, Chapter 5); the

    sourcesof factional competition in the kinship and po l i -

    tical

    structures of chiefdoms (Anderson, Chapter 6),

    t tes (Byland and Pohl, Chapter 11; Pohl and Pohl,

    Chapter 13; Fox, Chapter 14) and empires (van Zant

    w i j k

    Chapter 9); factional competition and ethnic

    identity

    (Pollard, Chapter 7; Brumfiel Chapter 8); and

    factional competition and imperial expansin(Hicks,

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    6/31

    6 ElizabethM Brumfiel

    Chapter 10). The apparent absenceof corporate groups

    and factional competition is analyzed for theValleyof

    Oaxaca (Kowaiewski, Chapter 12), cycles of factional

    competition

    and

    political change

    are defined for the

    southeastern

    UnitedStates,

    the Maya lowlands and the

    Postclassic

    highlands (Anderson, Chapter 6; Pohl and

    Pohl,

    Chapter 13; Fox, Chapter 14), and the

    shifting

    composition

    of factions and factional

    conflict

    in pre-

    imperial, imperial,

    and

    colonial

    societies is examined for

    the central Andes( D A l t r o y ,Chapter 15).

    Al l theessaysin this volume are concerned

    wi th

    the

    relationships of

    factional

    competition to ecological con-

    ditionsand

    classconflict.

    The next two sections of this

    introduction

    exploretheserelationships.

    actionalcompetition andculturalecology

    A t firstglance, the study of factional competition and

    culturalecology

    would

    seemtohave littletooffereach

    other. Factional competitionfocusesattention upon the

    inner

    dynamics of

    socialsystemswhile

    ecosystem theory

    derives the dynamics of social

    change from

    the inter

    action

    of human populations

    wi th

    their environments

    (HiU

    1977:88;

    Binford

    1983:221). The study of factional

    competition

    invoives consideration of strategic

    de isin

    making

    by self-promoting

    leaderswhile,

    in the

    view

    of

    cultural

    ecologists, social

    change

    is unrelated to the

    perceptions and motives of

    social

    actors

    (Hil l

    1977:66-7;

    Price 1982:720). Despite these differences, cultural

    ecology can

    only

    benefit

    from

    a more

    explicit

    consider

    ation

    of

    factional polities.

    Such studies

    would

    reveal the

    internal needsand resource requirements of complex

    political

    institutions that affect their

    distribution

    in time

    and

    space.

    And studies of

    factional

    polities

    would

    reveal

    the importance of the traits that accompany complex

    political

    institutions but

    appear

    toserveno

    critical

    eco

    logical function. Forthese

    reasons,

    perhaps,a concern

    withfactional polities is alreadypresentin theworkof

    several ecosystems theorists (Flannery 1972; Webster

    1975, 1976; Yoffee 1979;Spencer1982).

    Cultural

    ecologists generallyassertthat

    socio-political

    hierarchies evolvebecausechiefly and

    state

    hierarchies

    provide

    for a more effective relationship

    o f

    a population

    to

    its environment; under certain demographic and

    environmental

    conditions,

    political

    hierarchies are

    adaptive.

    Ecosystem theorists often assume that incipiently

    complex political

    institutions are at leastsporadically

    present in simpler societies, ready to be pressed into

    service when they are favored by demographic and

    environmental conditions. The

    timing

    and location of

    incipiently complex institutions is said to be random;

    they do not in themselves constitute a problem suitable

    for

    research. Variation,

    as Price (1982:716)

    observes,

    arises

    constantly in all

    l iving systems

    and

    does

    not, in

    terms of an evolutionary paradigm, require expla

    naron. But this is not entirely true.

    Just

    as

    sociopoliti-

    cal

    complexity might be precluded by environmental

    problems that

    have

    no managerial solution, complex

    political

    institutions might be precluded by ecological

    conditions

    that do not meet their own institutional

    requirements.

    A n excellent example of this principie is supplied by

    Clark

    and Blake (Chapter 2 , summarizing Hayden 1990;

    Hayden and Gargett 1990).A l lbut the most ephemeral

    formso f

    political

    leadership require a disposable surplus,

    a fund of power (Sahhns 1968:89). But so long as

    humans relied upon limitedand fluctuatingresources,

    the competitive accumulation of surplus depleted com-

    munal

    resources

    and was not tolerated. Henee, despite

    the managerial benefits that more powerful specialized

    leadership mighthaveconferred upon the population,

    such leadership did not emerge

    until

    after subsistence

    carne

    to be

    based

    upon

    r ich

    and reliable

    foodresources.

    Asecond and even more interesting example concerns

    long-distance trade. Long-distance trade has a tendency

    to increase

    as

    political

    institutions become more

    complex.Cultural

    ecologists,

    wi th

    their attention peren-

    nially fixed on population-environment interaction,

    havesupplied three accounts of long-distance trade. One

    regardsit as a

    means

    ofprocuring

    criticalresources

    that

    are not

    locally

    available (Rathje 1971; Johnson and

    Earle 1987:245). A second regards it as a

    means

    of

    gaining alliances and valuables (storable wealth) that

    enhance

    subsistence security (Flannery 1968; Halstead

    and

    O'Shea

    1982). The thirdregardslong-distance trade

    as unimportantbecauseit is most often concerned wi th

    sumptuary, as opposed to subsistence, goods (Price

    1977;Binford 1983:227-31;

    Sanders

    1984).

    However,a llthese

    accounts draw attention away

    from

    the fact that valuables acquired

    from

    distant

    sources

    supply

    considerable

    political

    control

    because

    of their

    ability

    to attract

    followers,

    allies and patrons and to

    maintain

    hierarchies of control (Schneider 1977; Earle

    1978; Friedman and Rowlands, 1978; Helms 1979;Kris-

    tiansen 1981:257;

    Brumfiel

    and Earle 1987; Gosden

    1989).Coalition

    buildingis an essential

    activity

    in creat-

    ing

    andmaintaining

    political

    power. But we cannot

    fully

    appreciate the importance of

    thisaspect

    of long-distance

    trade in valuables untilwe stop looking for a directly

    adaptive function for thisinstitutionor, unable to find

    one,assesssuch trade as epiphenomenal.

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    7/31

    ntroduction 7

    Although

    factional competition must be

    eonsidered

    in

    ecological

    analyses

    of

    political

    complexity, ecological

    variables areessential for understanding factional com

    petition.

    As Hayden and Gargett (1990) suggest, fac

    tional

    competition

    w i l l

    not exist so long as

    subsistence

    is

    based

    upon

    l imited

    and fluctuating

    resources associated

    w i t h

    generalized foraging. When factional competition is

    present,

    the

    success

    of faction

    leaders

    is partly

    deter-

    mined

    by local

    resource

    productivity and

    trade

    route

    accessibility. Faction

    leaders w i l l

    be most successful in

    reas

    that are most productive, giving the prevailing

    methods

    of

    resource

    exploitation. For example,

    under

    conditions of low agricultural

    in tensicat ion,

    faction

    leadersw i l l

    dobest in

    reas l ike

    the American Bottoms

    regin

    of the middle Mississippi River) where a large

    fo l lowing

    can

    gather

    to enjoy the benefits of factional

    membership without incurring the costs of intensified

    subsistence

    effort. Butunderconditions of higher agri

    cultural intensification,

    leaders w i l l

    dobest in

    reas w i t h

    the

    greatest

    quantity of intensifiable

    resources

    (irrigable

    land,

    etc.).

    Pohl and Pohl (Chapter 13)

    suggest

    that ecological

    variables affecting agricultural production also shape

    the

    onset

    and intensity

    of factional

    competition. Rainfall

    agriculture permits a more mobile commoner popu

    lation,easily

    able

    to shift allegiance

    from

    one leader to

    another. Leaders

    then

    compete

    to control

    segments

    of

    this mobile population. More intensive agricultural

    regimes tie farmers to the land, lessening competition

    between

    political

    lites

    and permitting

    greater

    political

    stability.

    Price (1984) has

    also

    noted this difference,

    adding that

    leaders

    in rainfall agricultural regimes are

    more

    l ikely

    to

    engage

    in conspicuous generosity in order

    to attract followers.

    Anderson (Chapter 6)

    suggests

    that extreme com

    petition and violence are common during periods of

    environmental instability or change. He believes that

    European contact intensified factional competition

    among native

    peoples

    in the

    southeastern

    UnitedStates,

    first

    through the introduction of European diseasesthat

    ki l led

    individuis

    who occupied strategic positions

    in

    the

    regional alliance network, and

    second

    through the

    intro

    ductionof European trade goodsthat

    opened

    new possi-

    bilities

    for acquiring wealth items.

    Spencer

    (Chapter 3)

    cites a

    case

    where

    disease

    in a

    Shavante

    village led to a

    realignment of factions.

    Geography, by affecting theshape of interaction

    net

    works, also shapes

    factional competition. Clark and

    Blake (Chapter 2)

    arge

    that more open settlement

    systemsw i th

    greaterpossibilities for regional interaction

    have greater

    potential for being dominated by a single.

    advantageously

    situated authority. Conversely, both

    Anderson (Chapter 6) and Byland and Pohl (Chapter 12)

    suggest

    that, in patchy environments, the

    dif i icul ty

    of

    maintaining

    Communications

    between

    scattered

    commu

    nities

    prevents

    any one

    from

    dominating the others.

    Under

    these

    conditions, factional competition

    tends

    to

    persist in a more or

    less stable equilibrium.

    The recognition that factional competition is

    shaped

    by

    ecological variables does not

    imply

    that factional

    competition

    is always, at the base,

    caused

    by

    subsistence

    shortages.

    Cultural ecologists

    have

    frequently argued

    that intercommunity warfare is the result of growing

    populations competing for

    scarce subsistence

    resources

    (Sanders

    and Price 1968; Carneiro 1970; Webster 1975;

    Ferguson 1984; Johnson and Earle 1987). Alternative

    views on the

    motivation

    and

    character of

    warfare

    appear

    in

    this volume. For example, Redmond (Chapter

    4)

    finds

    that, in northern South America,

    tribal

    warfare is

    m o t i -

    vated by the

    desire

    for

    revenge

    rather than the

    desire

    for

    resources.

    A careful consideration of

    Panamanian

    chiefs

    leads

    Helms (Chapter 5) to conclude that their

    leader

    ship of warfare was motivated by theirdesire forper

    sonal gain without the

    added spur

    of population

    pressure. Spencer

    (Chapter 3)

    suggests

    that the elitist

    character of warfare in ranked

    societies

    is revealed

    archaeologically in the fact that

    litecenters

    are

    fortified

    while

    smaller communities are not.

    But i f

    warfare

    arises

    from

    the

    desire

    for

    revenge,

    why

    does

    it occur in

    some

    societies

    but not

    others

    (Johnson

    and Earle 1987:124, 134)? And

    i f

    warfarearises

    from

    the

    selfishmotives of chiefs, why do followers

    particpate

    A s

    Redmond (Chapter 4)

    makes

    clear,

    individuis

    are

    very

    reluctant to

    fight;

    in fact, an

    ambitousleader

    may

    earn

    the

    indebtedness

    of

    individuis

    who must seek

    revenge

    by organizing a

    raiding

    party on their

    behalf

    (see

    also Spencer,Chapter

    3). Presumably,

    leaders

    organize

    these

    rads

    on thesame basis as other activities that they

    carry out, by

    calling

    to action

    thosendebted

    to them for

    previous favors. Thus, warfare

    becomes

    possible

    once

    individual

    jealousies

    and thedesire forrevenge become

    linked

    to the

    politicalgoals

    of self-aggrandizing

    leaders

    whohave established followings that they can

    cali

    upon

    to implement theirplans (seealso Sillitoe 1978).

    I n

    more stratified societies, the participation ofsub

    ordnate

    groups in warfare is

    less

    problematic. Rulers

    compel participation through

    coer c in,

    and they reward

    participation by conferring promotions of status upon

    those

    whose

    performance is outstanding. The

    l ink

    between warfare and population pressure in stratified

    societies

    is weak. This is clearly indicated by Pohl and

    Pohl s

    (Chapter 13) observation that the population of

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    8/31

    8

    Elizabeth

    M Brumfiel

    Caracol grew by 325 percent in the 130

    years

    after it

    defeated

    T ika l . f

    Caracol was making war

    wi th

    a popu

    lation

    oflessthan one-third ofitscapacity, it is

    difficult

    to

    believe that the war was aconsequenceofpopulation

    pressure.

    actional

    competition and class conflict

    I f, because

    of earlier

    research

    agendas, factions

    have

    frequently

    beencontrasted

    with

    corporate groups, our

    own

    interest in social transformation

    leads

    us to contrast

    factions

    withclasses.

    Under conditions ofclassstruggle,

    ociety is divided by horizontal

    cleavages

    that

    seprate

    nternally

    solidary and externally competing

    strata.

    This

    wi th

    a situation of factional competition in

    society is divided by vertical

    cleavages

    that unite

    of differentstrata and foster conflict between

    of the

    samestrata.

    Intra-class competition is a common theme in Marx's

    on capitalist society. Marx (1977:266-7)

    erved that capitalist society contained two market-

    intra-class struggles: on the one hand, the

    waro fcapitalists among themselves to main

    profits, on the other hand, the competition among

    competition is only

    overeme

    byclassconscious-

    brought about by class struggle: The

    seprate

    form a classonlyin so far as theyhaveto carry

    a common battie against another

    class;

    otherwise they

    wi th each

    other as competitors

    and Engels 1947:48-9). Thus, factional compe

    and

    classconflict

    are

    presented

    as inversely related,

    intensies.

    Andclass

    greaterexplanatory weight: The

    of all hitherto existing society is the history of

    struggles

    (Marx

    1977:222).

    AsBloch(1983:18) points out, Marx'semphasisupon

    struggle has not

    been

    very

    helpful

    for anthropolo

    causesof

    change

    inclasslesssoci

    absenceo fclassstruggle, Marxist anthropo

    have

    variously attributed social

    change

    in

    societies to technological development and

    change

    (see Levine and

    Wright

    1980); to

    structural incompatabilities ( contradictions )

    tween the forces of production, the relations of pro

    and the social and ideological superstructure

    r 1977; Friedman 1975; Friedman and Rowlands

    conflict

    of interests between

    individuis

    occupy

    subordnate

    statuses

    wi thin

    society (women,

    those who domnate them

    1983:160). The dynamics of

    conflict

    among

    those

    similar social positions has received

    little

    attention.

    On the other hand, several anthropologists, working

    from

    a variety of positions sympathetic to Marxism,

    have suggested

    that factional conflict

    wi thin

    the

    lite

    stratum explains the intensification, modification and

    decline of

    lite

    power in chiefdoms and agrarianstates

    (Webster 1975; Earle 1978, 1987;

    Cowgill

    1979;

    Kristian-

    sen 1981;

    Brumfiel

    1983; Gailey and Patterson 1987;

    Patterson 1991). This volume

    extends

    their arguments to

    suggest

    that conflicts

    wi thin

    (both commoner and

    lite

    stratainteract

    with

    conflicts betweenstratato determine

    the

    course

    of

    political

    development.

    First of all , competition between non-elites provides

    frequent opportunities for

    leaders

    to expand their influ

    enceand power. As

    Spencer

    (Chapter 3) and Redmond

    (Chapter 4)ind cate ,leadersin lowland South America

    increased their influence by assisting

    individuis

    embroiled

    in personaldisputesor blood feuds.

    Brumfiel

    (Chapter 8)

    suggests

    that mediating competition

    between calpulliand teccalli groups for houses, land,

    titles,and other

    resources

    was an important service per-

    formed by city-state rulers in central

    Mxico

    prior to

    Aztec rule. Pohl and Pohl (Chapter 13)

    indcate

    that the

    Postclassic

    Maya

    lites,

    as patrons to their subjects,

    resolved property disputes and defended community

    resources

    against outside attack. And the

    military

    com-

    manders

    of the pre-Inka Wanka prosecuted wars that at

    least

    ostensbly

    defended community

    resources from

    radsby neighboring groups (D Al t r o y , Chapter 15). In

    each

    of

    thesecases,

    competition among non-elites

    mot i

    vated commoners to

    subordnate

    themselves

    to a

    po l i

    ticalleader.The resultingalgnmentswere factions.

    A t the

    same

    time, competition among political

    ehtes

    frequently

    moderates the intensity

    with

    which com

    moners are exploited. In the

    tribal

    societies described

    by Clark and Blake (Chapter 2),

    Spencer

    (Chapter 3),

    and Redmond (Chapter 4)

    leaders

    compete

    wi th

    each

    other to supply benefits to followers, although the

    suc

    cessful

    leader wil lalso havecultvated

    his

    ability

    tocali

    in

    his

    debts

    at critical junctures. In chiefdoms and

    cty-states, rulers seek to finance their competition

    against

    rival lites

    by enlarging the

    size

    of their tribute-

    paying

    populations. Although this is sometimes accom

    plished

    through conquest, it can also be achieved by

    offerng

    commoners prime

    agricultural

    land (Earle 1978)

    or a low per

    capta

    tribute burden (Pohl and Pohl,

    Chapter 13) as inducements to settle. In pre-Aztec

    Mxico , intense

    competition

    wi thin

    the

    rulng class

    enabled commoners to move

    from

    one city-state to

    another,thus

    avoidng

    conditionso fintenseexploitation

    (Hicks 1982;

    Brumfiel,

    Chapter 8).

    The suppression of commoner residential

    mobility

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    9/31

    Introduction

    may be a

    necessary

    condition for the existence of

    class

    stratification in agrarian states.This could be accom

    plished

    through social circumscription (Carneiro

    1970),

    as Pohl and Pohl (Chapter 13)suggest for the

    t nMaya. Or, it might be accomplished by the

    po l i

    tical unification

    of a

    regin,

    resulting in

    uniform

    con

    ditionsofexploitation for the commoner class.Seeing

    the

    advantages

    of

    unification,

    ruling

    lites

    might

    volun-

    tarily

    surrender their sovereignty to an expanding

    regional

    state(Smith 1986;Hicks,Chapter 10).

    Commoners can sometimes exploit intra-elite com

    petition

    to their ownadvantageeven without leaving

    home. When plagued by oppressiverule,commoners can

    support the efforts of

    some

    ambitious prince to over-

    throwthe incumbentruler.Classwarfare canassumethe

    guise of c iv il war between noble factions (Fallers

    1956:247; Sahlins 1968:92-3). Thus, the suppression of

    intra-elite

    competition is a second condition

    necessary

    fortheemergence

    of

    class

    stratification.

    Mechanisms for

    unifying the ruling class include fostering a homo-

    geneous

    lite

    culture (Pollard, Chapter 7;

    Brumfiel,

    Chapter 8),liteintermarriage (vanZantwijk, Chapter

    9) ,

    the rotation of status-conferring ritual and political

    activities (van Zantwijk, Chapter 9; Pohl and Pohl,

    Chapter 13; Fox, Chapter 14), and the forging of

    patron-client relationships between the

    state

    and

    indi

    vidual

    members of the regional

    nobili ty

    (Pollard,

    Chapter 7; Hicks, Chapter 10; Fox, Chapter 14;

    D A l t r o y ,

    Chapter 15). Interestingly enough, a homo-

    geneous

    lite

    culture,

    lite

    intermarriage, and possibly

    the rotationo fritualresponsibilities werepresentamong

    the Classic Maya, who never achieved regional

    unifi

    cation

    (Pohl and Pohl, Chapter 13). Thus, intra-elite

    patron-client relationships, backed by coercive forc,

    emergeas the most important mechanism for securing a

    unified

    rulingclassamong therelatively non-bureaucra-

    ticAztecs and Inkas.

    While

    factional competition affects the dimensions of

    socialinequality,classstructureshapescompetitionand

    alliance building

    (L loyd

    1965). In the tribal systems

    described by Clark and Blake (Chapter 2),

    Spencer

    (Chapter 3), and Redmond (Chapter 4),

    classes

    are

    absent,and followersalign themselves w i th the leader

    who

    supplies them

    w i th

    the

    greatest

    immediate benefits.

    These

    verticalalliances are shallow, extending

    only from

    followersto thelocalleader. On the regionallevel, l ink-

    ages

    are supplied by alliances between village leaders,

    and theselinkages are the most critical

    advantage

    that

    incumbentleadersenjoy over aspiringrivals.Alliances

    between

    leaders

    give incumbents greater

    access

    to exotic

    goods and

    mili tary

    assistancethan is available to their

    rivals. Spencer

    (Chapter 3) suggests that efforts by

    incumbent

    leaders

    to regularize relationships

    w i thin

    their alliance network might lead them to deal prefer-

    entially

    with

    the heir of a

    deceased

    leader, initiatinga

    form

    of ascriptive leadership that could develop into a

    permanent chieftainship.

    Institutionalized tribute extraction in chiefdoms and

    city-states makesavailable greater quantities of wealth

    for lite competition and alliance building.Anderson

    (Chapter 6)suggeststhat competition is most intense

    when the material rewardsassociated

    w i th

    leadership are

    greatest, and this is borne out by the high level of

    factional competition

    w i thin

    the

    lite

    stratum of the

    chiefdoms and city-states described in this volume.

    Internally, cisekinsmen struggle to control leadership

    offices;externally,

    leaders

    struggle to gain higher posi

    tions in the regionalpolitical hierarchy. Their allies in

    this

    quest

    are an unstable

    coalition

    o f

    consanguineal and

    affinal kin and commoners raised to noble rank as a

    reward for valorous

    mili tary

    service.

    These

    coalitions are

    heldtogether by the redistribution of tribute wealth to

    noble followers and the allotment of

    segments

    of the

    tribute-paying

    population to the

    leader's

    strongest

    rivals.

    But

    the intra-elite competition, as discussed above,

    limitsexploitation, creating a chronically underfunded

    ruling

    class.

    To augment their incomes,

    leaders

    make

    war upon their neighbors, and, as Redmond (Chapter 4)

    documents so convincingly, warfare in chiefdoms

    reaches

    an intensity that is clearly greater than that

    found among tribal peoples. To survive both internal

    and external competition, leaders place themselves

    under the patronage of strong regional leaders.

    These

    verticalallianceshavegreater depth (three or four

    levis

    andterritorialrangethan the vertical alliances found in

    tribal big-man

    systems.

    Anderson (Chapter 6) sug

    gests

    that such

    systems

    are marked by a secular trend

    away from intra-elite and inter-class relations

    based

    upon

    display and redistribution toward the greater use

    o f forc.

    The

    unification

    of

    lites

    in a regionalstate permits

    very

    high

    levis

    of tribute extraction. This surplus

    flows

    to the paramount ruler who

    establisheshimself

    as the

    primarysuppliero fsumptuary goods and

    mili tary

    assist

    ancetosubordnateleaders. Thus, vertical alliance net

    works

    all converge on thestaterulerswhilehorizontal

    alliances between

    local

    rulers wither away.Statepatron

    age permits

    subordnate

    rulers to enjoy a definite

    in-group

    advantageover theirlocal rivals.As in modern

    systems

    of centralized patronage, the

    level

    of overt fac

    tional

    competition

    tends

    to be quite low.

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    10/31

    ElizabethM Brumfiel

    Thepositionof local litesis further weakened when

    the

    state creates

    newterritorialunits and administrative

    offices filled by members of the state s ruling group

    instead of by local rulers. Such policies result in the

    severing of ties between rulers and

    ruled

    and strengthen

    class

    stratification

    ( D A l t r o y ,

    Chapter 15). Sub-

    sequently, these policies may give rise to disputes

    between those who have

    traditional

    claims on resources

    and

    those who derive claims from the new system, both

    of

    whommustturn to thestatefor recognition of their

    claims.

    The absence of local

    solidarity

    and the com

    petition

    between localfactions for favorable treatment

    by the state weakens the

    local

    capacity for resistance

    (D Al t roy , Chapter 15; see also Dennis 1987). The

    greatest threat tothese

    states

    is

    factional competition

    at

    the very highest level,

    wi th in

    the

    royal family

    (van

    Zantwijk,Chapter 9;D A l t ro y , Chapter 15).

    As

    states

    disintegrate, considerable wealth and power

    maybecomelodgedoutside therealmo f politicalcontrol.

    Blanton (1983) points out that associations organizing

    craft productionor exchange tend to arise

    during

    periods

    of

    weakened

    statecontrol.Religious

    power may also be

    lodged

    in more orlessautonomous institutionssuch as

    the priesthood

    during

    Postclassic times in Oaxaca and

    possibly

    also the

    Mayalowlands(Pohl

    and

    Pohl,

    Chapter

    13;

    see also Patterson 1985). To deal

    wi th

    thesegroups,

    political

    lites are sometimes forced to admit their

    members

    topolitical

    officeso that the interests

    o f

    outside

    groups coincide

    wi th

    the interest of the political

    lite

    (Lloyd

    1965:98). At other times, such groups promote

    factional

    competitionamong

    political

    litesto maintain

    their

    own

    autonomy.Aligning themselves

    wi th

    different

    litefactions, outside groups may succeed in transform-

    ing

    a

    tributarystateinto

    a broker state, in which

    factional

    competition

    is overshadowed by competition between

    functionallydifferentiated interest groups.

    actional

    competitionandthe archaeological record

    Factionalcompetition invoives twocomplementary pro

    cesses: the construction of coalitions of support and

    participationin

    political

    contests. Inbuilding

    coalitions

    of

    support, leaders forge ties between themselves and

    their clients, allies, and patrons. Inpolitical contests,

    leaders exchange Information on the strength of their

    coalitions

    and determine who wi l l

    control

    contested

    resources (seeBailey 1969).Coalition buildingand con

    testsmay occursimultaneously,as

    when

    leaders compete

    o

    offer potential supporters the most attractive

    gifts.

    oth alliancebuilding and political contests leave dis-

    inctiveimprintson the archaeological record.

    Alliance building is frequently achieved through

    exchange.

    Locally,

    the liberal

    distribution

    of gifts and

    preferred foods is used to attract followerswho are then

    tied to the leader by their indebtedness for unrecipro-

    cated favors (Sahlins 1968:88-90).Regionally,balanced

    gift

    exchange establishes a pattern

    o f

    mutual

    aid between

    allied leaders whileasymmetrical exchange

    (involving

    the movement of staple crops upward and the flow of

    valuables downward) characterizes relations between

    locallitesand regional paramounts. The valuables used

    in theseexchanges are

    scarce

    andhighlyvalued, usually

    owing to their

    foreign

    origin or the quantity of labor

    involved in their production (Drennan 1976:357). The

    valuables are endowedwi th

    symbolic

    meanings that val-

    date the alliances under

    construction;

    furthermore, the

    valuables are distributed inritualcontexts that further

    vahdate the relations of

    alliance.

    The

    intensity

    andorganization

    o f

    alliance

    building

    are

    visible in the frequency and distribution of exotic or

    highly crafted wealth items, preferred foods, and

    feasting

    paraphernalia in prehistoric sites.

    Clark

    and

    Blake

    (Chapter 2) cite the presence of

    finely

    finished,

    elaborately decorated ceramies and maize to rge for

    competitive

    coalition building on coastal Chiapas by

    1600 BC.

    D A l t r o y

    (Chapter 15)

    suggests

    that thehigh

    concentrationof butchered camelidbones and certain

    jar and basin types inlite households are evidence of

    lite sponsorship of

    feasts

    at Tunanmarca, Per. Since

    there appear to have been few dietary differences

    between

    lites

    and commoners, commoners were prob

    ablythe

    guests

    at elite-sponsored

    feasts

    (see also Costin

    and Earie 1989).

    A more exclusive

    sphere

    oflitealliancebuilding at

    Tunanmarca is suggested by the

    restriction

    to lite

    housesofmetalworkingand metal artifacts.Metalwas

    probably

    used in gift exchanges that created

    coalitionso f

    support among

    political lites.

    In Barinas, Venezuela, a

    similar restrictionof polished stonejewelry(much of it

    from extra-local serpentine) to lite contexts also sug

    geststhe existence of a sepr te

    sphere

    oflitealliance

    building

    (Spencer, Chapter 3).

    The

    presence

    of

    non-local

    goods in non-elite contexts

    mightreveal another

    dimensin

    o f alliancebuilding.For

    example, in Early to Middle Formative Oaxaca, the

    uniformity

    among households of the

    sources

    of

    obsidian

    usedsuggeststhat obsidian wasdistributed to a ll house

    holds from a single point

    (Winter

    and Pires-Ferreira

    1976).

    This

    could

    be interpreted as evidence that obsi

    dian

    procurement and

    distribution

    was used by a

    faction

    leader tobui ld a popularfol lowing (seeClark 1987 for a

    discussion of how the procurement and processing of

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    11/31

    Introduction

    obsidian provided opportunities for political entre-

    preneurship inMiddleFormative Mesoamerica).

    Shifts in the frequency and distribution of prestige

    goods, preferred foods, and feasting paraphernalia

    provide

    Information

    on changes in the structure and

    intensity

    of alliance

    building

    over time. Anderson

    (Chapter 6)argesthat thedecliningfrequency of pres

    tige goods in Mississippian chiefdoms marks the tran-

    sition from

    leadership

    based

    on

    persuasin

    (which

    required chiefs to build amass following among com

    moners) to leadershipbasedoncoercin(whichpermit-

    ted chiefs to l imittheir attentions to a smaller group of

    strong-arm men).I ntheValleyo f

    Mxico

    and the central

    Andes, a decline in the frequency ofvessels used in

    feasting in the capitals of

    previously

    autonomousstates

    reflects the suppression ofpoliticalcompetition among

    local polities by a powerful regional state

    (Brumfiel

    1987a, Costin and Earle 1989).

    Marriages also play an important role in alliance

    building.Unfortunately, the archaeological recordonly

    rarely

    preserves

    evidence of marriage alliance. Stone

    inscriptions

    from

    the Classic Maya constitute one of the

    very few instances where such records are preserved

    (Marcus 1976). Pohl and Pohl (Chapter 13)

    suggest

    that

    the Late toTerminalClassic

    shift in

    stelaesubject matter

    frommarriage to warfarereectsa secular trendinMaya

    political

    factionalism from an earlier

    dependence

    upon

    alliances among regional

    lites

    to a later pattern of

    violent competition.

    The construction

    o f

    coalitionsrequires the production

    of surplus wealth

    which

    can underwrite

    gift exchange

    and feasting (Sahlins 1968, D A l t roy and Earie 1985).

    Because the vast majority of production in agrarian

    societies is household

    based,

    changesin the intensity of

    factionalcompetition should be marked bychangesin

    household size and composition. The ini tia l stagesof

    coalition building ought to be marked by high bir th

    rates,

    polygamy, and/or the inception of

    dependent

    labor

    wi thin

    the households of faction

    leaders

    (Sahlins

    1968:89, Coontz and Henderson 1986).

    Increases

    in

    leaders' influence and power should be reflected in the

    size and structure of

    a

    growing

    number of households as

    the leader extracts increasing amounts of goods and

    labor

    from

    a widercircleof clients and subjects.

    Successful

    coalition building

    might leave its imprint

    onsettlement patterns. The sizeo ftheleader'ssettlement

    may suddenlyincreaseas it did during theemergenceof

    chiefdoms on the south Chiapas

    coast

    (Clark and Blake,

    Chapter 2) .The early

    expansin

    of San

    os

    Mogote in

    theValley of Oaxaca might also be an example of an

    unusually large settlement created by successful

    coali

    t ion building (Flannery and Marcus 1983b). Thesuc

    cessful control of

    local

    rivals should be reflected in the

    distribution of

    literesidenceswi thin

    a

    regin,

    as in de

    MontmolHn's (1989:191-6) Ehte Forced Settlement

    measure- the proportion of

    lite residences

    found at

    political

    centers

    compared to the total number of

    ehte

    residences

    in the political catchment controUed from

    thesecenters. Alternatively,paramounts might favor a

    policy

    of dispersing their rivals to a

    mximum

    extent

    (Anderson, Chapter 6). A lack of control over rivals

    might

    be indicated by evenly dispersed, tightclusters of

    lite

    and commoner housing indicative of leader-

    followergroupings

    well

    suited to factional competition.

    Successful coalition building may also be evident in

    constructions that by their size or complexity

    suggest

    communal labor: raised fields and

    causeways

    in Venez

    uela (Spencer, Chapter 3), agricultural terraces and

    defensive works in

    Per (D Al t roy ,

    Chapter 15), and

    fortifications

    and monumental architecture among the

    Mayas (Pohl and Pohl, Chapter 13; Fox, Chapter 14).

    The particular type of labor investment reflects different

    strategies

    for competitive

    success.

    Agricultural intensifi

    cationmay improve the

    leader'sabil i ty

    to attract

    follow

    ers by sponsoring largerfeastsor bysupplyingthemwi th

    improvedlands (Earle 1978). Fortifications

    suggest

    that

    warfare provided wealth that a leader could redistribute

    to

    followers (Webster 1975). Monumental architecture

    might

    involve

    manipulation of the symbols of group

    unity:the ancestral or

    patrn

    deity.Such symbolswould

    be most prominent under conditions of

    competition

    at

    the regional

    level

    as part of an

    effort

    to

    crate

    bonds

    between

    leaders

    and followers that could not be easily

    transferred to competing leaders. Ethnic symbols may be

    manipulated

    wi th

    similar goals

    (Brumfiel,

    Chapter 8;

    Pohl

    and Pohl, Chapter 13). Public architecture also

    suggests efforts to impress a regional audience of

    potentialallies andrivalswho use the size

    o f

    thebuilding

    projects to judge the size and commitment of one's

    following.

    Competitionon the regional

    level

    often

    takes

    the

    form

    of

    warfare. Warfare is archaeologically visible in a

    number of ways: physical evidence ofviolentdeath and

    the taking of war trophies, defensive works, large settle

    ment size, ephemeral site occupation, defacejnent of

    public

    buildings and prestige goods, and depictions of

    warfare

    in

    art andinscriptions. Drawingupondata

    from

    Oaxaca, Kowaiewski (Chapter 12)suggests that terri-

    torial ly based

    competing polities on the regional

    level

    might also be indicated by the occurrence of shrines,

    boundary markers, and bufferzonesbetween localities,

    by roughly equivalent amounts of civic-ceremonial

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    12/31

    12

    Elizabeth

    M

    Brumfiel

    architectureacrosssubregions, by theabsenceoforganic

    sohdarity between subregions, by the existence of subre-

    gional differences in settlement patterns and ceramic

    styles, and by a settlement plan in regional capitals that

    provides representation of geographically

    affiliated

    sub

    regions. Many of the archaeological manifestations of

    sociopolitical

    and spatial segmentation in theValleyof

    Oaxaca are also to be found in the Classic Maya

    polity

    analyzed by de Montmol l in(1989).

    onclusin implic tions for theory

    This

    overview of factional competition and political

    development has eonsidered a wide variety of ecological

    and social variables. Resource productivity, geo-

    graphical

    boundedness,

    long-distance exchange,

    warfare, kinship and marriagesystems,rules ofsucces

    sion,

    class,

    corporate group structure, and ethnicity all

    impinge

    upon the patterning and intensity of factional

    competitionand are, in

    turn,

    affected by

    it .

    The number

    of

    variables discussed reflects the fact that competitive

    advantageis pursued through the strategicmanipulation

    o fmany material and social variables;

    winningstrategies

    must be fabricated according to the

    resources

    available.

    The relativeadvantagesof extensive or intensive agri

    culture,

    attached craft production or long-distance

    exchange, marriage alliance or warfare, ethnic assimila-

    tionor ethnicpersistencevary according tolocal

    circum-

    stances.In addition, the efficacy of different

    strategies

    v res

    over time, depending upon the development of

    resources,alliancesystems,and competitivestrategiesas

    consequencesof earlier rounds of

    competition.

    Given the great variation of competitivestrategies

    over time andspace,no twocasesare identical.While

    the logic of factional competition provides an essential

    principiefor understanding thecourseof

    local

    history,

    the study of factional competition isunlikelyto reveal

    any universal laws of cultural development. The vari-

    ablesinvolved

    are too numerous; the

    strategies

    for

    mobi-

    lizing

    resources

    are too diverse.Althoughfactional com

    petition

    provides a common

    mpetus

    to political

    development, any particular

    sequence

    of development is

    uniquelycomplex and contingent.

    Inthe face of suchcomplexity,it isnecessarytoaltr

    nate

    between a subject-centered and a system-centered

    analysis. A subject-centered analysis organizes ecological

    and social variables byweighingthem according to their

    importance in

    specic

    competitive strategies. A system-

    centered analysis

    reveis

    how the implementation of

    strategiesalters thequalityanddistribution o fecological

    and socialresourcesfor the next round ofcompetition.

    Asubject-centered analysis is also required in order to

    account for the dynamics ofpoliticaldevelopment.

    Poli-

    ticaldevelopment should be attributed to the efforts of

    individuis

    toadvancetheir goals of

    material

    advantage

    and socialesteemby

    joining

    factions or

    class

    alliances

    that prosecute their interests in competition

    with

    oppos-

    ing factions or classes. Competition occurs

    within

    a

    structure or matrix of ecologicalresources,social rela

    tions,

    and cultural rules and

    vales which

    constrain

    behavior but which also provide opportunities for

    innovation.The growth ofpoliticalcomplexity,marked

    by

    the

    emergence

    of larger, more centralized polities

    with

    greaterdegreeso fverticaland horizontaldifferenti-

    ation,is an epiphenomenalconsequenceof thestrategies

    and counter-strategies employed by

    leaders

    and

    fol low-

    ersengagedin factionalcompetitionand

    lites

    and com

    moners locked inclassstruggle (see Clark and Blake,

    Chapter 2).

    The methodological

    individualism

    at thebasisof this

    formulation

    might be criticized as a projection of the

    competitive,self-seeking, pragmatic ideology

    o f

    Western

    capitalist society. This is

    partially

    true, although the

    problemis ameliorated by situating self-interested com

    petition

    in specific ecological, social,cultural,and his-

    torical

    contexts. Even so, such a

    formulation

    might be

    inappropriate for analyzing the more expressive and

    solidary

    aspectsof social

    life.

    However, an assumption

    o fcompetitive, self-seeking, pragmatic social actors is

    eminently suited to the analysis offactional competition,

    for,

    as Earle (1987:294)

    observes,

    factional competition,

    which

    is inherently a competitive, pragmatic

    process,

    requires

    a maximizing strategy (see also Bailey

    1969:36-7).

    The subject-centered/system-centered approach to

    factional competition and political development

    adopted in this volume contrasts sharply

    with

    the

    exclusively system-centered focus of both cultural

    ecology and structural

    Marxism,

    currently the two most

    popular theories for explaining political

    change

    in

    ancient societies. Bothcultural ecology and structural

    Marxism focus upon strictly bounded, culturally dis-

    tinct

    social groups. In

    cultural

    ecology, the social

    unit

    is

    defined

    by external boundaries, created by geographic

    isolation and by the competitive relationships that

    develop between populations under conditions of

    resource scarcity

    (Sanders

    and Price 1968; Carneiro

    1970; Ferguson 1984). In structuralMarxism,the social

    unit

    is defined by its internal organization of social

    production and reproduction under a guiding set of

    social

    rules and practices ( structures ) (Friedman 1975;

    Godelier 1977:63).

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    13/31

    Introduction 3

    Both

    cultural ecology and structural

    Marxism post-

    late the narrow constraint of human behavior and deci

    sinmaking

    with in

    thesesystems:by stringent consider-

    ations of energetic efliciency in cultural ecology Price

    1982:719) and by the Hmits of structurally determined

    consciousness

    in structural

    Marxism

    Godelier

    1978:768).

    Thesesame

    constraints

    opr te

    equally for

    all

    members of society,

    implying

    a condition of cultural

    homogeneity for human groups.

    Based upon such assumptions, cultural ecology and

    structural

    Marxism

    supply accountsofthegrowthof

    poli-

    ticalcomplexitythat are quite different

    from

    the one pro-

    posed in this volume. Cultural ecologists believe that

    incipientpolitical

    complexityoccurs as a normal part of

    the array of random,

    low-level

    cultural variation

    present

    in all populations Price 1982:724). However,political

    complexitybegins togrowonlyafterpopulation

    pressure

    has created the need to intensify production

    within

    groups and to compete for

    resources

    belonging to others

    Sandersand Price 1968; Carneiro 1970; Webster 1975;

    Ferguson 1984; Johnson and Earle 1987:16-18). Through

    either

    exp nsin

    or emulation, the beliefs and practices

    that resultinlarger groupswithgreaterabilityto organize

    production

    and warfare

    prev lwithin

    a

    regin.

    The con

    centration ofwealth,coercive power, and prestige in the

    hands of political leaders contributes to managerial

    capacityby

    giving

    leaderstheabilitytocoordn telarger,

    more complex populations Webster 1975, 1976).

    This formulation can becriticized on two grounds.

    First,

    it

    proposes

    that populationpressureand

    resource

    shortages

    arenecessarytoinitiatetheprocessofpolitical

    development and to maintain its progress. There is,

    however, empirical evidence to the contrary, presented

    in

    this volume and elsewhere. Second, in analyzing the

    concept of power, cultural ecologists focus attention on

    the energy used to maintain competing populations and

    the

    Information flows

    used to organize them e.g., White

    1959; Price 1982;Wright 1969; Flannery 1972; Johnson

    1978).

    But they tend to ignore the relations of alliance

    and dominance that brings organizational structures

    into existence and maintain them. The manipulation of

    social

    relations is as important as the manipulation of

    natural

    resources

    i n

    theprocessofpoliticaldevelopment,

    a pointwhichculturalecologists tend to ignore but not

    always, see Webster 1975, 1976;Spencer1982).

    Structural Marxists

    present

    an epigenetic model of

    political development Friedman and Rowlands 1978).

    Politicalchangeis not due to the goal-directedstrategies

    ofpolitical

    leaders

    but, rather, is a

    consequence

    of struc

    tural contradiction that is, the

    incompatibility

    of the

    interlinked

    forces of production, relations of pro

    duction, and social and ideological superstructure)

    resulting in structural reorganization Friedman 1975;

    Godelier

    1977:63, Bloch 1983:154). Power is not con

    structed by

    individuis,

    but rather

    falls

    to certain people

    as a

    consequence

    of the prevailing cultural rules,

    especially

    those

    allocating

    resources,

    labor, and product

    Godelier 1978; Bender 1985). In the

    init ial

    phasesof

    politicalcomplexityand socialinequality,the conferring

    of

    superordinate statusoccurs with the consent of sub

    ordn te

    groups,

    with

    superordinate status

    falling

    to

    those

    who

    med te

    between humans and deities, i.e.

    thosewho control the imaginarymeansof social repro

    duction through religious

    ritual

    Friedman and Row

    lands 1978; Godelier 1986:156-64; Bender 1985).

    Likecultural ecology, this account ofpoliticaldevel

    opment is deficient. Its principal difiiculty is that it

    postl les

    consensus

    with in

    the bodypolitic

    prior

    to the

    emergence

    of

    class

    and

    class

    struggle.

    While

    the consent

    of

    followers

    is

    certainlyneededbyleadersinthe veryfirst

    stagesofpoliticalcomplexity Clark and Blake, Chapter

    2;

    Spencer,

    Chapter

    3;

    Redmond, Chapter

    4 ,

    evidence

    in

    this volume

    and elsewheresuggeststhatcoercinand not

    consensus

    is a dominant

    mo t i f in

    complex chiefdoms and

    is absolutely pervasive in agrarianstates.

    Culturalecology and structural

    Marxism

    difier

    from

    the approach taken in this volume in yet another way.

    They bothpostl testrict behavioral determinismwhile

    this volume

    takes

    seriously the impactofhuman purpose,

    creativity, and choice. This difference derives

    from

    the

    number of variables employed by

    each

    of the

    analyses.

    Both cultural ecology and structural Marxismemploy

    models constructed of relatively few variables,

    which

    necessarilylimitshuman choice and agency toafewhighly

    redundant options. As aconsequence,human behavior

    emergesas

    highly

    determined. In contrast, the studies in

    this volume consider the

    rich

    complexity of

    competitive

    strategizing,

    which invoives the manipulation of every

    conceivable ecological and social variable

    in

    complex and

    contingent ways. In doing so, they broaden the dimen

    sions

    of

    human choice and leave room for the exercise of

    human agency. Thus, the

    willingness

    to consider the

    full

    complexity

    of specific historical situations

    restores

    the

    concept of agency to the study of

    social

    change.

    Acknowledgments

    Earlierdrafts of

    this

    chapter were patiently read by John

    Clark,

    Timothy

    Earle, John Fox, Roberto Korzenie-

    wicz, Hattula Moholy-Nagy,Mary Pohl, and Glenn

    Perusek. Their criticisms, comments, and lineediting

    shaped

    the chapter in many important ways. I am grate-

    fu l for their help.

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    14/31

    Ethnicity

    and political

    control in a complex

    society:

    theTarascan

    state

    of

    prehispanic

    xico

    H E L E N P E R L S T E I N P O L L R D

    The interrelationship between ethnic units and a central

    political authority is known historically to have been

    crucial to the operation of complex societies. In the

    process of this interaction central authorities,

    par

    ticularly ruling lites havecreated new ethnic groups,

    havealtered the attributeswhichdefine ethnic identity,

    and

    have

    restructured relationships between ethnic

    groups (Enloe 1980:17ff.).

    Political

    authoritieshavetwo

    fundamental goals for the survival of their centralized

    power: (1) the economic

    exploitation o f

    populations and

    resources,

    and (2) the protection of the integrity of the

    state

    frontiers. In achieving both

    these

    goals ethnic

    diversity

    can either

    faciltate

    or hinder

    lite

    action.

    Centralized authorities canassuremaximalaccessto

    populations and

    resources

    when

    decisin

    making

    flows

    from the top downward, according to principiesestab

    lished

    by dominant

    lites.

    Ethnicdiversityoften disrupts

    this

    f low

    by interposing local or regionalleaders,who

    acquire power not through their allegiance to central

    hierarchies, but through positions of ethnic

    status.Deci

    sin

    making may be undertaken to reflect the needsof

    local

    populations or local

    lites

    at theexpense of the

    state.

    On the other hand, under conditions of rapid

    territorial

    expansin

    when large populations and/or

    resources

    are being incorporated into a single political

    unit,

    the existing lines of authority, legitimacy, and

    social

    cohesinpresent

    n ethnically

    distnct

    populations

    may provide central authorities

    wi th

    an infrastructure

    o f political

    and economic networks that can be tapped

    to

    the benefit of the

    state.

    In a similar manner, the main-

    tenance

    of the state's territorial integrity

    demands

    populations w ing to defend that territory, and not

    themselves

    act to foster rebellion against central auth

    or i ty . That can be achieved in at least two ways: the

    acceptance of

    state

    ideology and legitimacy, usually

    through the

    identification

    of

    individuis

    and groups as a

    single social group, i.e.,

    coirmion

    ethnicity;or theaccept

    anceof common self-interest among ethnically diverse

    populations who see their itmninent survival as depend

    ent on subordination to a central authority. The second

    is often found on active mil i tary frontiers or among

    refugee populations fleeing

    conquest.

    To the

    state

    such

    peoples

    can provide valuable service as warriors,mess-

    engers, spies, and long-distance traders, services that

    may outweigh the hazard of desertion.

    T o

    a great extent our understanding of the evolution

    o f complex societies is

    based

    on societies known pri-

    marily or exclusively through archaeology. One

    approach to studying the archaeology of

    ethnicity,

    that

    o f ethnoarchaeology, has primarily concentrated on

    acephalous

    societies, attempting to

    test

    the regularities

    in

    relationships between isolable cultures and artifact

    distributions

    (e.g. Hodder 1979). A second major

    approach, modeling the spatial and functional

    distri-

    bution

    of prehistoric ethnic groups on the

    basis

    of

    ethnohistoric evidence, has the

    advantage

    of dealing

    directly

    wi th

    complex, ethnically plural societies. The

    primarydisadvantageis its l imitat ion tothose societies

    knowable through both ethnohistoric and

    archaeo

    logical

    Information.

    These

    societies,

    while

    representing

    only a small sample of complex societies which have

    ever evolved,

    nevertheless

    provide a

    basic resource

    for

    the identification of

    those

    ethnic

    processes

    of sig-

    nificance in societal evolution and their detection

    archaeologically. In the New

    Wo r id

    such an approach

    has

    been used

    in the Andes to

    evalate

    the

    patterns

    of

    Inka

    expansin

    (Morris 1982; Rowe 1982; Wachtel

    1982, among others) and to

    genrate

    models of ethnic/

    state

    interaction

    which

    can be applied to earlier periods

    (Schaedel 1978).

    The central defining feature of an ethnic group, self-

    identification,

    and categorization by the governinglite

    is cleariy beyond the

    resources

    of archaeologically

    derived

    research.

    Nevertheless,

    because

    ethnicity is gen

    erally

    associated

    wi th

    high

    rates

    of endogamy, the

    sharing of clusters of beliefs and vales marked by the

    use of a common language, and is often

    territorially

    isolable, the discemment of ethnic variation is not

    impossible. As

    wi th

    allaspectsof archaeological analy

    sis, the introduction of ethnicity into the variables

    studied must bedone

    wi th

    care.Ethnic boundaries are

    fluid contracting or expanding

    wi th

    majorpoliticaland

    economic shifts in the society at large. Ethnic identifica-

    tions coexist

    w i th

    other social

    identi f cat ions

    meaning

    79

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    15/31

    80 HelenPerislein Pollard

    that occupational and class boundaries, for example,

    may cross-cut ethnic groups. Different artifact

    classes,

    or

    properties of artifacts may signal thesedifferent social

    boundaries. Moreover,

    wi th in

    a single multi-ethnic,

    complex society the intensity of ethnic

    affiliation

    may

    differ,

    and along

    wi th

    this the number and kinds of

    markers usedby a group to signal ethnicity may vary.

    Finally,

    the archaeologist

    deals with

    units of time that

    often

    compress

    ethnic maps andobscurethe

    processes

    ofethnicemergenceandchange.

    Justas complex societies vary in theirbasicstructures

    and developmental trajectories, one must expect similar

    variation in the structure and significance of ethnicity.

    Aspart of the larger processof developing theories of

    the nature of complex societies, one goal should there

    fore

    be the development o fmodels ofethnicity,

    based

    on

    various ethnohistorically knowable societies, and their

    application to earlier

    polities.

    Wi th

    this goal in

    mind,

    a model of the structure o f

    ethnicity

    in the proto-

    historic

    Tarascan state of central

    Mxico

    (AD 1450-

    1520) is hereinpresented Fig.7.1).

    TheTarascanterritorialstatein its sixteenth-century

    orm is renowned for its high degree of political

    and relatively unchallenged control of its

    p AZTEC

    H TARASCAN

    y

    QUICHE

    M

    7 1

    Protohistoric

    Mesoamerica

    territory

    (Gorenstein and Pollard 1983, Pollard 1993).

    When viewed

    from

    the perspective of the geopolitical

    core, the Lake

    Ptzcuaro

    Basin,thesecharacteristics can

    be related to theemergence,by the protohistoric period,

    of a social system

    with

    a fully

    Tarascan

    identity, pro-

    duced by the conscious subordination and replacement

    of

    localethnic/linguisticstatusas thebasisfor social or

    political power. Despite clear indications of earlier

    ethnic heterogeneity in central

    Michoacn

    Relacinde

    Michoacn [1541] 1956), by the sixteenth century the

    population

    was self-identifying and being identified by

    othersas solelyTarascan RelacindeMichoacn[1541]

    1956;Suma deVisitasdePueblos[1547-50] 1905;Rela-

    ciones

    Geogrficas[1579-81] 1987; Warren 1968, 1985,

    among others).

    Such subordination and replacement of ethnic

    vari

    ationdistinguishes this system

    from

    the mainstream of

    protohistoric Mesoamerica,

    which

    was characterized by

    ethnic economic and political specialization and

    mult i -

    ethnic social classes (Carrasco 1971; Zantwijk 1973).

    Along the Tarascan mil i tary frontier, however, the

    Tarascan poli ty

    was multi-ethnic,

    plural,

    and demo-

    graphically largely non-Tarascan (Mendieta y

    Nez

    1940; Brand 1943; Gorenstein 1974, 1985; Herrejn

    Peredo

    1978;

    onzlez

    Brespo 1979; Contreras

    Ramrez

    1987). Taken together,

    these

    policies, the one emphasiz-

    ingsocial homogeneity of the

    lite

    and a new common

    Tarascan

    identity, and the other emphasizing

    plurality

    and heterogeneity, appearto be in

    conflict.

    However,

    these

    two distinct policies of ethnic assimi-

    lation and ethnic segregation, dominated community

    interaction

    in geographically

    seprate

    zones of the

    Tarascan

    poli ty.

    By 1520 they had resulted in the ethnic

    boundaries recorded inthe early documents and mapped

    by

    Brand (1943; Fig. 7.2). Combining our knowledge of

    the ecological, economic,

    poli t ical ,

    and artifactual

    vari

    ation

    wi th in

    this territory we canproposethe following

    model of the

    Tarascan state.

    one

    ofassimilation

    This

    is the territory

    wi th in which

    Tarascan was the

    dominant

    language

    and cultural identity was ethnic Tar

    ascan.

    It included at

    least

    two distinct regions.

    Ethnicheartland

    This

    is the

    zonewi th inwhich

    the

    Tarascan

    politicalcore

    existed,

    wi th in

    whichTarascan

    vales

    and norms were

    held by the bulk of the population, and

    wi th in

    which

    there

    was a similar economic and settlement adaptation

    to the

    regin

    (Stanislawski 1947). Thus, thiszonedefines

    the regional marketing network of the core Fig.7.3) and

  • 8/9/2019 Brumfield y Fox 1994. Factional competition (1).pdf

    16/31

    Ethnicityin theTarascanstate 81

    ig

    7.2 Sixteenth century

    ethnicllinguisticboundaries.

    Based on

    Brand

    1943.

    the primary extent of

    Tarascan religin

    and ideology.

    The population

    wi th in

    this

    zone,

    especially the

    lite,

    participated in a unitary social system dating to the

    political

    incorporation of central

    Michoacn

    (1350-

    1440) and the

    emergence

    of

    Tarascan

    identity (Goren

    stein and Pollary 1983). The geographical extent of this

    zone is largely co-terminous

    wi th

    the

    regin wi th in