brandeis university heller graduate school sustainable

47
Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable International Development Effect of the remittances received at municipal level on the population living in poverty in Mexico for the years 2000 and 2005 Master Paper Presented by: J. Eloy Palacios-Sanchez A paper submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Master of Arts Degree in Sustainable International Development Academic Advisor _________________________________Date ___________________ Director, Program in _______________________________Date ___________________ Sustainable International Development

Upload: others

Post on 03-Feb-2022

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

Brandeis University

Heller Graduate School Sustainable International Development

Effect of the remittances received at municipal level on the population living in

poverty in Mexico for the years 2000 and 2005

Master Paper Presented by:

J. Eloy Palacios-Sanchez

A paper submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the

Master of Arts Degree in

Sustainable International Development

Academic Advisor _________________________________Date ___________________

Director, Program in _______________________________Date ___________________

Sustainable International Development

Page 2: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

1

Table of Contents

Abstract…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………2

Executive Summary…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..….3

Acknowledgements………………………………………………………………………………………………..…………………………….6

Abbreviations………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….......6

I. Introduction……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….7

II. Background and Problem Statement…………………………………………………………………………………………..…10

III. Methods………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..14

IV. Literature Review………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..…19

V. Findings and Substantive Discussion………………………………………………………………………………………………29

VI. Conclusions and Implications……………………………………………………………………………………………………..…36

VII. Tables……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………38

VIII. List of References…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………42

Page 3: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

2

Abstract

How effectively do remittances sent by Mexican immigrants in U.S. contribute to reduce municipal

poverty in Mexico?

This master paper endeavors to answer this question estimating the effects of the amount of

remittances received at municipal level in Mexico on the percentage of the population living in

poverty.

The present study comprises the totality of municipalities in Mexico for the years 2000 and 2005.

Although the phenomenon of migration from Mexico to the United States is strongly concentrated just

in some states and municipalities of Mexico the present study attempts to find disparities among the

municipalities receiving remittances and those without them; for this purpose an econometric model is

included in the study using the percentage of people living in poverty as the dependent variable and

the amount of remittances received at municipal level as the main independent variable.

In 2000 the states having their municipal poverty levels reduced are: Guerrero, Oaxaca, Chiapas,

Veracruz and Tabasco for the three income-poverty categories and Querétaro, Estado de México,

Distrito Federal, Morelos, Hidalgo, Tlaxcala and Puebla in the case of assets-poverty.

In 2005 the reduction in poverty accounts for all the municipalities except for those in the states of

Campeche, Yucatán and Quintana Roo. Additionally the capabilities-poverty and assets poverty is

reduced in the municipalities of the states of Baja California, Baja California Sur, Sonora, Sinaloa and

Nayarit. The States of Guerrero, Oaxaca and Chiapas reduced their assets-poverty as well.

Page 4: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

3

Executive Summary

Income remittances by migrants contribute to incomes of households in migrant-source

municipalities; if remittances are substantial and well oriented to poor households then may reduce

poverty.

The present study comprises the totality of municipalities in Mexico for the years 2000 and 2005.

Although the phenomenon of migration from Mexico to the United States is strongly concentrated just

in some states and municipalities of Mexico the present study attempts to find disparities among the

municipalities receiving remittances and those without them; for this purpose, an econometric model

is included in the study using the percentage of people living in poverty as the dependent variable and

the amount of remittances received at municipal level as the main independent variable.

The literature concerning the effects of remittance on poverty provided split conclusions. On one hand

some studies supported the negative correlation between remittances and poverty differentiating its

effects by regions inside a country, whereas others found no correlation when there was no distinction

by region and the country was taken as a whole entity.

In this paper I provided the results of two econometrics models, one including region-remittance

interactions and the other without the interactions with the purpose to provide additional evidence

supporting or rejecting what prior studies have contributed.

The main findings of the study allow us to observe different correlations between remittances and

poverty across 8 regions obeying to different patterns of migration from Mexico to US. At national

level the total amount of remittances received grew from 6,572 million dollars in 2000 to 21,688

million dollars in 2005, a percentage increase equivalent to 230% in 5 years or 46% average increase

annually.

When including the “region” as a control variable in the econometric model the effect of remittances

on poverty is better disentangled and then is possible to observe to those municipalities getting the

best from remittances.

Page 5: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

4

In 2000 the states having their municipal poverty levels reduced are: Guerrero, Oaxaca, Chiapas,

Veracruz and Tabasco for the three income-poverty categories and Querétaro, Estado de México,

Distrito Federal, Morelos, Hidalgo, Tlaxcala and Puebla in the case of assets-poverty.

In 2005 the reduction in poverty accounts for all the municipalities except for those in the states of

Campeche, Yucatán and Quintana Roo. Additionally the capabilities-poverty and assets poverty is

reduced in the municipalities of the states of Baja California, Baja California Sur, Sonora, Sinaloa and

Nayarit. The States of Guerrero, Oaxaca and Chiapas reduced their assets-poverty as well.

The net-largest recipients of remittances are not the only states reducing their municipal

poverty rates.

Not all the municipalities receiving high-per capita remittances reduced their poverty rates, in

some cases municipalities with high level of remittances per capita reduced poverty in 2000 but

not in 2005 and others performed the other way around.

In 2005 almost all the municipalities reduced alimentary-poverty and this reduction is

coincident with the large net-increase of remittances from 2000 to 2005.

As a general conclusion the amount of remittances received by municipalities reduces the percentage

of people living in poverty but selectively by regions, not everywhere and not uniformly.

Page 6: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

5

Acknowledgements

This Masters paper is dedicated to Nancy for being such supportive, patient and loving wife throughout

this amazing two-year master’s program.

I express my sincere thanks to Professor Barry Friedman for his willingness, support and guidance

throughout this project.

I am eternally grateful for the Heller School for Social Policy and Management’s Professors and Staff for

giving me this great opportunity in life to pursue a master’s program, it is been such a wonderful

experience.

Page 7: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

6

Abbreviations

1. BANXICO: Central Bank of Mexico (Banco Nacional de México)

2. CONAPO: National Population Council (Consejo Nacional de Población)

3. CONEVAL: National Council for the Evaluation of Social Development Policy (Consejo Nacional

de Evaluación de la Política de Desarrollo Social)

4. ENIGH: Household Income and Expenditure National Survey (Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y

Gastos de los Hogares)

5. INEGI: National Institute of Statistics and Geography (Instituto Nacional de Estadística Geografía

e Informática)

6. SEDESOL: Ministry for Social Development (Secretaría de Desarrollo Social)

7. UNDP: United Nations Development Program

8. U.S.: United States of America

Page 8: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

7

I. Introduction

1.1 The Development Question

How effectively do remittances sent by Mexican immigrants in U.S. contribute to reduce municipal

poverty in Mexico?

This master paper endeavors to answer this question estimating the effects of the amount of

remittances received at municipal level in Mexico on the percentage of the population living in

poverty.

According to Esquivel et. al. (2005. pp. 8) the percentage of the population living in extreme poverty in

Mexico is 20.3%, to say they cannot afford a minimum basket of food, 26% of the population lives in

poverty, to say they cannot afford food, health and education and 51.7% of the population cannot

afford food, health, education, dressing, home and public transportation.

Income remittances by migrants contribute to incomes of households in migrant-source municipalities.

If remittances are substantial and well oriented to poor households then may reduce poverty (Taylor et

al. 2005. pp.3). Furthermore an increase in the amount of remittances received would have a larger

effect in a region where a large share of households have migrants in U.S. than in a region in which

households with international migrants are rare (Taylor et al. 2005. pp.4).

1.2 The Case Study

This study includes the totality of municipalities in Mexico for the years 2000 and 2005 (2452 and 2454

municipalities respectively). Although the phenomenon of migration from Mexico to the United States

is strongly concentrated just in some states and municipalities of Mexico the present study attempts to

find disparities among the municipalities receiving remittances and those without them. Historically

the States with highest levels of migration to USA are: Durango, Guanajuato, Michoacán, Nayarit,

Zacatecas, Aguascalientes, Colima, Jalisco y San Luis Potosí (CONAPO, 2002).

Relying on the information available and making some estimations for missing data, the study will

include information for the years 2000 and 2005 given that in the decade between 1990 and 2002 both

Page 9: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

8

urban and rural Mexico has experienced a massive outflow of labor to the United States where the

share of the working population rose from 7% to 14% (Taylor et al. 2005. pp.6).

1.3 Contribution of the study to development

Most of the literature reviewed concerning migration and remittances supports that family

remittances by migrants contribute to incomes of households in migrant-source areas. However what

is not clear is whether remittances indeed can reduce the percentage of people living in poverty at

municipal level.

Since the existent literature about the effects of remittances on poverty is insufficient to

unquestionably support a positive or negative statement the present master paper contributes to

sustain or refute the findings obtained by prior authors with the case study of the Mexican

municipalities. However the undeniable fact is the massive impact that remittances from US have in

the Mexican municipalities, which in any case remittances may not embody a change in the poverty

rates but represent a great dependency of the Mexican municipalities on foreign remittances.

The main purpose of this paper is to arouse concern regarding in-progress Mexican and US social

policies and programs directed to provide support to poor municipalities of Mexico. If remittances can

effectively reduce poverty in the Mexican municipalities, then new social policies may be created in

order to funnel and harness enhanced government expenditure combined with remittances received

by municipalities, promoting consequently the sustained development of poor regions. Nonetheless

this master paper will be limited to obtain a generalized statement regarding the net effect of

remittances on poverty and will not embrace the social implication of its effects but rather may

reinforce the platform for further studies emphasizing its social policy implications.

1.4 Context of the Study

The information used to address the development question is obtained from official government

institutions as secondary sources of information.

The dataset analyzed contain information at the municipal level for the years 2000 and 2005 including

2452 and 2454 municipalities respectively. Although most of the information is obtained from official

Page 10: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

9

government institutions some data set estimations were done based on the official sources of

information.

1.5 Professional Background

The author of the present paper has a bachelor degree in economics and his experience has been

acquired working during 8 years in the Ministry for Social and Economic Development of the state of

Puebla, Mexico. His development work consisted in the implementation of projects in the poorest

municipalities of Puebla intended to improve their socio-economic conditions, dealing especially with

those municipalities ranked among the highest-migration areas from Mexico to US.

The second-year in Heller, besides to be an amazing experience in life, mainly focused the courses

work on the Analysis of the Causes and Consequences of the International Migration and the

acquisition of statistical tools to measure the effect of remittances on poverty with courses as

Household Economics and Measurement of Inequality.

Additionally, another courses complemented the holistic vision of development with courses as

Integrated Conservation and Development, Food and Security Nutrition, Sustainable Use of Renewable

Energy Sources, to mention just the most relevant.

Page 11: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

10

II. Background and Problem Statement

2.1 Background

The importance of migration is evident in the continued and increasing movement of people from

south to north and east to west (Castles and Miller, 2003; Massey et al., 1998). Whether we study

Mexicans migrating to the United States or Pakistanis moving to England, there is little doubt that

migration brings opportunities and challenges (Cohen, 2005. pp. 89).

To understand remittances, it is important to differentiate between voluntary and forced migration

given that voluntary migration is motivated by economics and is typically tied to local and international

issues in economic growth; forced migration is tied to neither growth nor development (Cohen, 2005.

pp. 89). At times, these moves become so regular as to create a “transnational community” that

transcending geographic limits and comes to exist among various locations (Cohen, 2005. pp. 90).

Research on international migration tends to support the hypothesis that migration can lead to long-

term remittance practices, rather than the traditional expectation that remittances will decline or as

migration flows mature (Stark 1978). This process, whereby remittances continue over the long-term,

is evident among Mexicans moving between migrant-sending regions in the central states of the

country to the United States (dela Garza and Szekely, 1997; Massey et al., 1994).

Most studies of voluntary migration, whether national, international, or transnational, argue that the

high wages motivates most decisions to move. For example Gonzalez and Escobar (2001), working in

Jalisco, Mexico, they note that 93% of all remittances went to household expenses. In Cohen and

Rodriguez (2004) they found that in rural communities of Oaxaca, Mexico 92% of remittances went to

daily and household expenses, with only about 8% of remittances going to business start-ups or

investments.

Proponents of dependency theory argue that the seductive pull of wages and the rise of receiving-

household incomes that remittances bring addicts rural Mexicans to migration and leads to what

Reichert coined the “migrant syndrome” (1981). This syndrome ensnares rural migrants in a vicious

cycle of repeat migrations, because they face few opportunities for work in home communities.

Page 12: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

11

The history of migration between Mexico and United States is strongly enrooted in a private-public

collaboration between U.S. farmers and the U.S. and Mexican governments: the Bracero Program of

imported Mexican agricultural workers, which lasted from 1942 to 1964 (Rodriguez, 2004. pp. 457).

The Bracero Program was originally organized as a wartime measure to replenish the agricultural

workforce that had lost workers to the armed forces and to wartime industries in the cities (Calavita,

1992; Craig, 1971). In response to requests from large farmers in California, Texas, and Arizona and a

few railroad companies, the U.S. government obtained a labor import agreement with the Mexican

government in 1942 (Rodriguez, 2004. pp. 457).

In 1942, the program started when 4,203 braceros arrived to work in U.S. and by the end of the

program in 1964, 4.9 million braceros had gone through the program (Barrera, 1979).

For the agricultural employers, a much-desired economic advantage was to have a large supply of

workers to keep wages down. Bracero labor allowed agricultural employers to reduce operating costs

by about 50% (Rodriguez, 2004. pp. 458). This advantage increased for employers when U.S.

government agents arrested thousands of undocumented workers for illegal entry into the United

States and then converted them into bracero workers for U.S. farmers.

The Bracero Program had become a preferred labor supply of agricultural employers and some railroad

corporations. One large agricultural employer described the attitude toward bracero labor as follows:

“We used to own our slaves, now we rent them from the U.S. government” (Moquin & Van Doren,

1971, p. 344).

When World War II ended in 1945, a total of 168,000 braceros had been imported from Mexico to U.S.

for temporary work, but 4.7 million more would be imported by the end of the program in 1964. The

braceros program peak in the period from 1956 to 1960, when more than 400,000 workers were

imported annually (Barrera, 1979).

Page 13: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

12

2.2 Problem Statement

In the past decade rural Mexico has experienced a massive outflow of rural labor to Mexican urban

centers and to the United States. Between 1990 and 2002, the share of Mexico’s rural population

working in the United States rose from 7% to 14%, and the share at internal-migrant destinations rose

from 11% to 15%; however, the share varies widely across regions (Mora and Taylor, 2005).

Mexico is the second-largest recipient of remittances in the world. Its Diaspora is unusual in that,

compared to other countries it is so heavily concentrated in the United States (Newland, 2004. pp. 12).

The interactions between migration and poverty are among the least researched and understood

topics in economics (Taylor et al; 2005. pp. 3).

The possible impacts of migration on poverty are presented under to “optimistic” and “pessimistic”

scenarios. The optimistic scenario is that migration reduces poverty in source areas by shifting

population from the low-income rural sector to the relatively high-income urban (or foreign) economy

and then reducing poverty through the availability of remittances (Taylor et al; 2005. pp. 3).

The pessimistic view is that poor households face liquidity, and risk that limit their access to migrant

labor markets which is the case of international migration entailing high transportation costs and other

fees like bribes, payment to smugglers etc. (Taylor et al; 2005. pp. 4).

However, beneficiaries of migration may not include the rural poor when is costly and risky and initially

may come from middle or upper segments of the source-area income distribution and not from the

poorest locations (Taylor et al; 2005. pp. 4).

Initially, when few households have access to migrant labor markets abroad, international-migrant

remittances are likely to flow primarily to middle and upper-income families. If this is the case, then

changes in remittances will have little effect on poverty.

Page 14: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

13

However with an equal opportunity to reach international labor markets, international migration

eventually becomes diffused downward through the income distribution and poverty may become

increasingly sensitive to changes in remittances benefiting to everyone (Taylor et al; 2005. pp. 4).

2.3 Hypothesis

The implication of international migration of Mexicans and specially to the U.S. raise the interest of the

present paper in the migration effects on poverty through the increasing and sustained patterns of

remittances received in Mexican home communities from immigrants in US and then the main interest

of this paper is to analyze the effect of the amount of remittances received at municipal level on the

percentage of the population living in poverty for the years 2000 and 2005. Then we can state the

hypothesis:

Hypothesis: On average and holding everything else constant, the amount of remittances received by

municipalities reduces the percentage of people living in poverty at its three different categories: food,

capabilities and assets-poverty.

Page 15: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

14

III. Methodology

3.1 Data

The dataset analyzed in the present paper contain information at the municipal level for the years

2000 and 2005 including 2452 and 2454 municipalities respectively. Most of the information included

is obtained from official government institutions; nonetheless some data estimations were done given

the need to include additional information, but even so the estimated variables were based on the

official information available.

3.2 Variables in the Model

3.2.1 The Econometric model

One econometric model is proposed for each year using the same variables; the regressions are run

separate and then there is no need to correct for inflation in every period.

Y^Poverty2000= α - β1 lnMun_Remittim2000 - β2 lnMun_Expim2000 + β3 lnMun_popim2000 - β4 lnMun_Icomeim2000 +

β5Margim2000 + β6Mun_unem2000 - β7REG1 - β8REG2 -β9REG3 - β10REG4- β11REG5 - β12REG5 - β13REG5 -

β14(REG1*lnMun_Remitt2000) -β15 (REG2*lnMun_Remitt2000) -β16 (REG3*lnMun_Remitt2000) - β17

(REG4*lnMun_Remitt2000)- β18 (REG5*lnMun_Remitt2000) - β19 (REG6*lnMun_Remitt2000) - β20

(REG7*lnMun_Remitt2000) - µ

Y^Poverty2005= α - β1 lnMun_Remittim2005 - β2 lnMun_Expim2005+ β3 lnMun_popim2005 - β4 lnMun_Icomeim2005+

β5Margim2005 + β6Mun_unem2005 - β7REG1 - β8REG2 -β9REG3 - β10REG4- β11REG5 - β12REG5 - β13REG5 -

β14(REG1*lnMun_Remitt2005) -β15 (REG2*lnMun_Remitt2005) -β16 (REG3*lnMun_Remitt2005) - β17

(REG4*lnMun_Remitt2005)- β18 (REG5*lnMun_Remitt2005) - β19 (REG6*lnMun_Remitt2005) - β20

(REG7*lnMun_Remitt2005) - µ

3.2.2 Dependent Variable: Poverty in three different categories

Poverty Categories are defined as an Index (CONEVAL, 2000 and 2005):

Food-Based Poverty: Percentage of the total population whose income is insufficient to cover

the basic needs of food

Capabilities-Based Poverty: Percentage of the total population whose income is insufficient to

cover the basic needs of education and health

Page 16: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

15

Assets-Based Poverty: Percentage of the total population whose income is insufficient to cover

the basic needs of housing, transportation, clothes, shoes and other.

3.2.3 Independent Variable

lnMun_Remittim: Total amount of remittances received at the municipal level for the years 2000 and

2005.

The total amount of remittances received in Mexico is available from official sources at national and at

state level; nonetheless the amount received by every municipality is not available from any official

sources in Mexico and then the first step for the inclusion of this variable of the study is the estimation

of the amount of remittances received at the municipal level.

For the calculation of the amount of remittances received at the municipal level I followed the

methodology proposed by Barcelata (2010) for the estimation of municipal level of remittances;

however Barcelata’s estimated the municipal amount of remittances of the state of Veracruz (210

municipalities) and just for the year 2007; on the other hand the present paper estimates the amount

of remittances received by every Mexican municipality in 2000 and 2005.

First, the official amount of remittances received by every state of the Mexican Republic (31 states and

1 federal district) is obtained from BANXICO (2000 and 2005) for the years of the study.

Second, the total number of rural and urban households in every municipality is obtained from the

INEGI (2000 and 2005).

Third, through the CONAPO (2000 and 2005) and the ENIGH (2000 and 2005) is obtained the average

percentage of rural and urban households who received remittances and then we obtain the number

of households receiving remittances in every municipality.

Fifth, we have the total number of households receiving remittances by every municipality and state,

and also we have the total amount of remittances received by state, then is possible to estimate the

amount of remittances received by municipality as a percentage of its total number of households.

Sixth, by adding up the amount of remittances received in urban and rural households we obtain the

total amount of remittances received in every municipality.

Page 17: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

16

Finally, the core independent variable is converted to Mexican pesos (exchange rate, 2000: 9.4556

pesos/dollar, 2005: 10.8959 pesos/dollar: BANXICO) and expressed in log natural in order to read any

increase or decrease of the amount of remittances as a percentage.

The expected sign of this variable is negative since a 1% increase in the amount of remittances received

at the municipal level is likely to reduce the percentage of people living in poverty in its three different

categories.

3.2.4 Control Variables

1.- lnMun_Expim: Total Government Expenditure at the municipal level for the years 2000 and 2005.

The municipal total expenditure is obtained from the INEGI. This variable includes the total amount of

money invested by the government in every municipality in social programs, infrastructure, roads,

provision of basic services, etc.

This variable is expressed in natural log in order to read any increase or decrease of the government

expenditure as a percentage.

The expected sign of this variable is negative since a 1% increase in the amount of municipal

expenditure received is likely to reduce the percentage of people living in poverty in its three different

categories.

2.- lnMun_popim: Total population in the municipality.

This variable is obtained for every municipality from the INEGI and is expressed in log natural in order

to read any increase or decrease of the municipal population as a percentage.

The expected sign for this variable is positive since a 1% increase in the municipal population may

increase the percentage of people living in poverty.

3.- lnMun_Icomeim: Total Municipal Income.

This variable is obtained for every municipality from the PNUD (2000 and 2005) and converted to

Mexican pesos (BANXICO 2000 and 2005) and expressed in log natural in order to read any increase or

decrease in the municipal income as a percentage.

Page 18: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

17

The expected sign for this variable is negative since a 1% increase in the municipal income is associated

with a decrease in the percentage of poor people.

4.- Margim: Marginality Index at municipal level (CONAPO, 2000 and 2005).

Index compounded by 4 core social-exclusion indicators:

a) percentage of Illiterate population and percentage of the population without primary schooling,

b) percentage of the population without provision of basic services in the household (potable water,

sewer, electricity), percentage of the population with ground floor in household and household

overcrowding,

c) percentage of the population earning less than twice minimum wage and

d) percentage of the population living in communities with less than 5000 inhabitants.

Since the provision of basic services and education in rural communities (less than 5000 inhabitants) is

the responsibility of the Mexican government at its three levels (federal, state and municipal) this

variable is included in the model as a determinant of the percentage of the population living in

poverty, assuming that income poverty (food-based, capabilities-based and assets-based) per se can

not influence directly the provision of services by government and then attenuating the problem of

edogeneity between these variables without getting rid of it though.

The expected sign of this variable is positive since an increase in the Marginality Index is assumed to

increase the income poverty rate at municipality level.

5.- Mun_unem: Municipal Unemployment Rate

This variable provides the percentage of the population unemployed for the years of the study (INEGI,

2000 and 2005). Since the information for the rate of municipal unemployment was unavailable the

unemployment rate by state is included instead as a proxy variable in every municipality.

The expected sign for this variable is positive since a larger unemployment rate is associated with an

increase in the percentage of population living in poverty at municipal level.

3.2.5 Dummy Variables

The last part of the econometric model includes 7 dummy variables equivalent to 8 geographical

regions of Mexico including 32 states. The regionalization has been done arbitrarily but the states in

Page 19: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

18

each region are clustered according with their geographical location, vicinity and socio-economic

status: North, north-east, north-west, center-west, center-east, east, south and Yucatán Peninsula.

To generate the dummy variables is necessary to exclude one region. The omitted region (the richest)

will be the North-East Region comprised of the states of Nuevo León y Tamaulipas. Hence the dummy

variables are:

1.- REG1: Taking the value of 1 if it’s REG1 and 0 if other region. (Baja California, Baja California Sur,

Sonora, Sinaloa and Nayarit).

2.- REG2: Taking the value of 1 if it’s REG2 and 0 if other region. (Chihuahua, Coahuila, Durango,

Zacatecas and San Luis Potosí).

3.- REG3: Taking the value of 1 if it’s REG3 and 0 if other region. (Jalisco, Aguascalientes, Colima,

Michoacán, Guanajuato).

4.- REG4: Taking the value of 1 if it’s REG4 and 0 if other region. (Querétaro, Estado de México, Distrito

Federal, Morelos, Hidalgo, Tlaxcala and Puebla).

5.- REG5: Taking the value of 1 if it’s REG5 and 0 if other region. (Guerrero, Oaxaca and Chiapas).

6.- REG6: Taking the value of 1 if it’s REG6 and 0 if other region. (Veracruz and Tabasco).

7.- REG7: Taking the value of 1 if it’s REG7 and 0 if other region. (Campeche, Yucatán and Quintana

Roo).

3.2.6 Interactive Dummy Variables

Remi*REGi (i= 1, 2…7). In order to obtain a better defined explanatory variable, every Dummy variable

“Region” is multiplied by the “amount of remittances received” by every municipality obtaining a

combined variable that allows effect of remittances to vary by region.

The expected sign in every combined dummy variable is a priori expected to be negative since poverty

in every region is assumed to be reduced as the amount of remittances increases.

Page 20: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

19

IV. Literature Review

5.1 Remittances: Definition

The definition of remittances has been stretched by social science analysts to include elements that are

not strictly economic (Vertovec, 2000). Peggy Levitt (1998) used the term social remittances to

describe various types of social practices, ideas and values, mainly to migrant-sending areas, which

accompany the migration process. Nichols (2002) emphasized the importance of knowledge, skills and

technology brought back by returning migrants, being called technical or technological remittances.

Others have focused on changes in political identities, demands and practices associated with

migration (Fitzgerald, 2000; Goldring, 1992b, 1998a, 2002; Moctezuma, 2000; Rivera-Salgado, 2000;

Smith, 1998, 1999) which one could refer to as political remittances. Identifying various kinds of non-

economic remittances would be consistent with approaches that analyze migration as a complex and

multi-dimensional process (Massey et al., 1993).

On his work, Jorge Durand (1988) identify three types of remittances: (1) traditional individual or family

cash remittances which might be transferred through a courier, via money orders, or some other

method; (2) savings invested in houses or businesses; and (3) durable goods or products that migrants

brought back upon their return (trucks, televisions, and so forth).

Goldring (2004) argues that family remittances can be understood as having a social meaning that

involves expressions or claims of membership in a family or social network, nonetheless the fact that

family remittances are embedded in social relations of kinship means that as long as people have

relatives overseas they will remit money but migrants tend to remit less over time, and much less once

their immediate family members have joined them, or relatives living abroad have migrated or died.

Durand (1994) identified three types of remittances based on their use or function. The first was

remittances as wages or salary sent by circular migrants sent to support close relatives. These migrants

tended to be from areas characterized by limited investment opportunities because of monopoly or

else low-yield agriculture. The second type was remittances as investment: these remittances could be

Page 21: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

20

sent during a trip, or brought back upon return. Third were remittances as capital: this was money

saved specifically to invest in a productive venture.

Goldring (2004) identify three peculiarities between households receiving remittances. First, both

households receiving remittances and those that do not, use almost the same proportion of their

income (about 80 per cent) to cover recurrent expenses, leaving less than 20 per cent for other uses.;

second, remittance receiving households are not homogeneous, and include groups with an absent

family member who sends money and those where a relative who is no longer a central member of the

household sends the money. Corona (2001) concludes that in these two types of households there will

be little opportunity to use remittances for productive investments. Third, there are remittance-

receiving households without migrants and households with migrants that do not receive remittances

(Lozano, 2001). The former receive relatively small amounts of remittance money, while the latter

receive none.

Goldring’s study (2004) concludes that in Mexico, remittances are largely used as income, most income

is used to cover recurrent expenses and education, and only a small share goes to savings and

investments. There is now a consensus that the highest share of remittances is spent supporting

households’ recurrent costs, including education and health (Delgado and Rodríguez, 2001; Suro, 2003;

Waller, 2000).

Durand (1994) identified and defined the key differences between family, collective and

entrepreneurial remittances. Family remittances tend to be used to cover basic needs as they act as a

source of income; entrepreneurial remittances represent savings with the potential to become

investment and finally collective remittances are associated with organizations with considerable social

and political leverage in recent years.

The positive reading would argue that remittances do contribute to development through multiplier

effects, and investment in human capital and health, while the negative position would stress the

regional and macro-economic constraints that limit the possibility of using remittances as anything else

besides income (Goldring, 2004).

Page 22: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

21

5.2 Remittances and Poverty

Remittances to developing countries have been growing relatively fast in recent years. In many

countries they are now the most important source of external financing. Furthermore, remittances

from abroad seem to be more stable than other types of external inflows and they even seem to be

countercyclical. Notwithstanding the growing importance of remittances for the developing world,

their effects on the recipient economies are relatively unknown. Indeed, there are relatively few

studies that investigate the effects of remittances on these economies (Esquivel et al; 2006. pp. 1).

One of the areas that have received less attention in the research agenda is the relationship that may

exist between remittances and poverty (Esquivel et al; 2006. pp. 1). For some authors, the existence of

a positive relation between these two variables is somehow obvious and may not deserve further

discussion meanwhile other authors assert the relationship between remittances and poverty is

affected by certain characteristics of the migration process. Some authors express the fact that since

migration is costly should not belong to the poorest people in the sending economies. For that reason,

remittances might not have an immediate and direct effect on poverty (Esquivel et al; 2006. pp. 1).

This position is well represented by Kapur (2004): “The fact that migrants are not drawn from the

poorest households in their country of origin means that while remittances are poor-friendly, their

direct effects on the poorest groups may be limited. Instead, the effects on structural poverty are likely

to occur through substantial indirect effects … ” Similarly, Adams and Page (2003) conclude that

“because of the considerable travel costs associated with international migration, international

migrants come from those income groups which are just above the poverty line in middle-income

developing countries”.

Other authors have also suggested that the poorest people may lack the appropriate skills to benefit

from international migration, and therefore they tend to have lower emigration rates. This argument

also implies that remittances may not have a direct impact on poverty (Esquivel et al; 2006).

In the most extensive literature on this topic, Adams and Page (2003) analyze the relationship between

poverty and remittances in a sample of seventy-four developing countries. They find that international

Page 23: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

22

remittances have a strongly statistical negative impact on poverty. Specifically, they find that a 10

percent increase in the share of remittances in a country’s GDP, leads to a reduction of 1.6 percent in

the share of people living in poverty. On the other hand, Adams (1991), Adams (2004) and López-

Cordova (2005) analyze the relation between remittances and poverty indicators at a country level, in

Egypt, Guatemala, and Mexico, respectively. Adams (1991) finds that in Egypt the number of rural

households in poverty drops in 9.8 percent when household’s income includes international

remittances. In Guatemala, poverty gap measure declines by 19.8 percent when international

remittances are included as part of total household income. This occurs, according to the author,

because the income status of households at the lowest decile changes considerably when they receive

remittances.

López-Cordova (2005) finds that remittances have a statistically and economically significant impact in

reducing poverty in Mexico at the municipal level. He estimates that a one percentage point increase in

the fraction of remittance-receiving households in a municipality significantly reduces the fraction of

the population earning relatively low income.

International remittances have traditionally been an important source of foreign exchange resources

for the Mexican economy. In recent years, however, remittances have become a growing source of

external funds. The amount of remittances flowing into Mexico has increased monotonically since

1991 and they are now more than twice the inflows from tourism-related activities. In recent years,

remittances have even been as large as foreign direct investment inflows to Mexico. In terms of the

importance of remittances relative to the size of the economy, remittances in Mexico are now close to

3 percent of GDP and they have become particularly important since 2000.

Mexico is already the country that receives the second largest amount of remittances around the

world (India is the first) (Esquivel et al; 2006. pp. 5).

In terms of their regional distribution, remittances-receiving households in Mexico are not uniformly

distributed across the country. Remittance-receiving households are concentrated in a few Mexican

states and that they tend to be located in the center-north part of the country. Indeed, more than one

third of all remittances-receiving households in Mexico are concentrated in only four states

(Michoacán, Durango, Guanajuato and Zacatecas. Similarly, in seven Mexican states 10 percent or

Page 24: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

23

more of their total households receive remittances from abroad (Michoacan, Durango, Guanajuato,

Zacatecas, San Luis Potosí, Jalisco and Aguascalientes). It is interesting to note that the poorest

Mexican states, such as Chiapas, Guerrero, Oaxaca, Puebla or Veracruz, do not belong to this list,

although the recent pattern of migration may change this distribution in the future (Esquivel et al;

2006. pp. 9-10).

Esquivel et al (2006) estimated in his paper through the construction of a propensity score the

probability of Mexican households of being in poverty situation in 2002 where the dependent variable

is 1 if the household receives international remittances and 0 otherwise.

The effect of receiving remittances on the probability of being in a poverty situation using three

alternative, officially-defined, measures of poverty (food-based, capabilities-based and assets-based).

The empirical results show that receiving remittances from abroad reduces the probability of being in

food-based and capabilities-based poverty in 8 and 6 percentage points, respectively. Given the

observed poverty rates at the household level using nationally representative data (15.8% and 21.1%,

respectively), this effect, depending on who actually migrates, could be equivalent to a reduction of

around 50 and 30% in the corresponding poverty rates for remittance receiving households vis á vis

non remittance receiving households. However, receiving remittances does not seem to affect a

household’s probability of being in assets-based poverty. In that sense, we may conclude that

remittances contribute to the reduction in the level and depth of poverty, but only up to a certain

point.

On the other hand a study carry out by Lopez-Córdova (2005) looks at a cross-section of Mexican

municipalities and analyzes whether development indicators improve as the fraction of remittance

receiving households in a municipality rises. He pays particular attention to schooling and health

status, with a secondary focus on poverty and a marginalization index that summarizes several welfare

measures.

The results suggest that an increase in the fraction of households receiving remittances reduces infant

mortality and illiteracy among children aged six to fourteen years, while at the same time alleviating

some dimensions of poverty and improving living conditions. Remittances seem to improve school

attendance among young children, although the opposite seems to be the case among teenagers.

Page 25: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

24

To assess whether remittances reduce poverty, he uses use as dependent variables the fraction of the

population whose income is equivalent to the minimum wage or less, which he label extreme poverty,

and the fraction whose income is at most two minimum wages, which he label poverty. He shows that

remittances do not seem to dent the incidence of extreme poverty in a statistically significant way. This

might reflect the fact that migration is a costly endeavor, and households at very low income levels

might not be able to defray the costs. In other words, only households with income above some given

level are able to emigrate and remit.

Although most studies recognize that the impact of remittances is a question that must be analyzed in

each case, multi-government institutions and initiatives such as the Berne initiative, the World Bank

and the Inter-American Development Bank, the GCIM, the Puebla process and others, state clearly that

most remittances are directed at poor households (Escobar, 2009. pp. 77).

Since remittances are treated as net income, analyses conclude that remittances tend to increase the

income of the poor, and to consider this a developmental impact of migration. According to this

argument, remittances must be protected because they are private transactions, the poor depend on

them to survive, and they reduce poverty (Escobar, 2009. pp. 77).

The OECD (2008) published a position paper that summarizes a situation may exist today. In their view,

lowest-income countries export mostly high-skilled labour, while middle–income labour exporters tend

to export mostly low–skill workers. High-skill workers tend to migrate legally, which entitles them to

take their family along and significantly reduces remittances. Lower-skilled workers, on the contrary,

tend to migrate illegally, and this increases remittances. As a result, very low-income countries would

seem to be investing large portions of their GDP in the training of high-skill individuals, and then lose

these workers with very modest remittances in exchange (Escobar, 2009. PP. 78). On the contrary,

medium– income countries export persons in which the country has invested little in the way of private

or public funds, and they tend to remit larger relative amounts, which would produce a significant net

income for their families, thus reducing poverty and possibly furthering development (Escobar, 2009.

pp. 77).

Because of its proximity to the United States, which lessens the cost of migration, and the cumulative,

social-networking effect of a century of low-skill migration, Mexico would be among those most

Page 26: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

25

favored by this situation. It is a medium–income country exporting low-skill workers who migrate

illegally and therefore tend to remit more often than other migrants. As a result, poverty should

diminish markedly in Mexico due to migration, and this is considered a developmental effect (Escobar,

2009. pp. 77-78).

Other analyses point at improvements resulting from migration. Unger (2005) showed that poor

municipalities with significant emigration converge upwards in terms of their per capita income over

time. Adelman and Taylor (1990) find that the largest multiplier impact of remittances is obtained in

very poor isolated communities. Cruz (2008) finds that incomes have risen dramatically (and poverty

fallen) as a result of recent international migration in the Chatino community (south-eastern Oaxaca

indigenous group) he studies, although he sees dependence on remittances, and rapidly decreasing

agricultural self-sufficiency, as negative consequences of emigration (Escobar, 2009. pp. 79).

Rural emigration and the dependence of rural households on remittances are clear. But other facts

seem harder to reconcile. The propensity of the poor to migrate is lower than that of other groups,

although almost one-half of the rural young of 1995 have already left rural areas. Remittances to the

poor are growing (400% from 1992 to 2006, and by a smaller but significant 40% between 2000 and

2002), but Mexico does not benefit from remittances as much as other Latin American countries

(Escobar, 2009. pp. 79).

The finding of a close connection between rural poverty and migration is in agreement with studies by

Tuirán (2002), which stress that a majority of the municipalities receiving highest per-capita

remittances are high–marginality (and high poverty) municipalities. Remittances are most significant

for the rural poor, but they still are not a major source of income to them, although some families

depend on them. Wage income and government transfers are more important. Therefore, migration is

not a significant factor lowering rural poverty or explaining rural economic growth (Escobar, 2009. pp.

89).

In a recently published study, Escobar (2008) has argued that the rural poor migrate in specific ways

due to three factors: their financial constraints, the recent nature of their migration, which means they

have little access to legal migration and their networks are only beginning to consolidate, and the

specific nature of the social capital used to migrate.

Page 27: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

26

In this context, Escobar (2008) emphasize that successful migrants have significant incentives to flee, or

to break-up from their families and communities of origin, further lowering the social capital of their

relatives. Continuity of membership involves investing large resources and helping poor relatives and

community members. Communities slow this process through identity-reinforcing mechanisms, lists of

members in the United States, extending debt to family members remaining in the community, and

control of the marriage market: in many indigenous communities, participation (and sponsorship) in

the local festivities is a necessity, if a migrant member wishes to marry someone from the same

community.

The impact of remittances on poverty and inequality can be summarized thus:

1) Remittances make a significant contribution to GDP.

2) Remittances, however, do not compensate the labour force lost to migration

3) A preliminary approximation to the impact of remittances on poverty is provided by census evidence

of low migration rates in poor areas, and among poor households, but this analysis could

underestimate the emigration rates of poor households in particular.

4) The proportion of households receiving remittances is higher among low-income strata (which

qualifies the evidence from 3).

5) Non-poor households receive larger absolute remittances than poor households, but poor

households receive a larger share of their total income from remittances.

6) Remittances reduce income inequality, but poverty and inequality are lower in a no-migration

counterfactual scenario.

7) The above could be related to the specific social process of migration among the poor, which does

yield remittances, but does so in more difficult conditions than those obtaining for non-poor migrants.

Escobar (2008) concludes saying that the conclusions are mixed is not useful. From a development

perspective, however, it is possible to state that, in the current context, migration may represent a net

loss for Mexico. It seems to have a positive impact on poor, high-emigration areas, but the potential

impact of this labour force in Mexico is greater.

Page 28: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

27

Adams et al (2005) calculates the effect of Migrant Remittances on Poverty in rural communities. A

modification of the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke (1984) poverty index was used to analyze the poverty

implications of remittances.

According with his work a poverty line, z, is required in order to estimate the effects of changes in

migrant remittances on poverty. The poverty line used is the per-capita income required to purchase a

basic basket of food and nonfood items in rural areas estimated by SEDESOL (2000).

The incidence of poverty ranges from 35 percent in the Northwest region to 81 percent in the South-

Southwest. His results showed that overall, poverty decreases when migrant remittances go up.

Nationally, the rural poverty effect is substantially greater for international remittances than for

remittances from internal migrants.

Another interesting finding in Adams et al (2005) is that poverty elasticity of remittances from migrants

abroad vary sharply across regions. The sensitivity of poverty to international remittances is greatest in

the high migration, West-Center region, and it is smallest in the low migration, South-Southwest

region. Other things being equal, a 10-percent increase in international remittances reduces poverty by

1.64 percent in the West-Center compared with only 0.11 percent in the South-Southwest; poverty

decreases by 1.68 percent in the West-Center, but there is no change in poverty in the South-

Southwest.

These findings suggest that the ameliorative effect of international remittances on rural poverty

increases with the prevalence of migration and that the distributional effects of migration become

more equal as increasing numbers of households gain access to foreign labor markets.

Finally on the revisión of Barcelata (2010. pp. 110) is observed that for the period between 2003-2008

the states with larger remittances reception and migration are the states with low state GDP growth

(LSGDP) compared with the rest of the states in the Mexican Republic. For the case of Guanajuato,

Oaxaca, Hidalgo, Guerrero, Michoacán y Distrito Federal presented a growth rate between 12 and 16%

compared with the 10 states with larger growth of 26%.

There is another group of states with strong remittances reception, showing higher GDP growth rates

but still lower than the highest GDP states: Jalisco, Veracruz y Puebla (19.8; 19.5, y 18.5%); just the

state of Mexico presented an income-growth rate of 26%.

Page 29: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

28

In the same way Barcelata (2010. pp. 110) estimates the per capita GDP for every state. The states

with strong migration patterns are ranked as those with less per capita GDP growth.

The states of Guerrero, Oaxaca, Veracruz, Distrito Federal, Hidalgo, México y Michoacán presented per

capita GDP growth rates of 11, 13 y 16% for the firsts in the period of 1995-2005; and 23; 24.5; 24.7 y

26% for the four latter while the states with highest growth reached a 38% per captia GDP growth for

the same period. Nonetheless the states of Guanajuato and Puebla with strong remittances reception

grew in 36% and 37% respectively.

According with Barcelata (2005), we can not establish for sure a strong correlation between low GDP

growth / low-GDP per capita growth and migration.

Concluding with Barcelata study, he did not find any relationship between poverty reduction and the

magnitude of remittances received at municipal level, for the state of Veracruz. He found that for the

period 2004-2005 the municipalities with larger poverty reduction were those with a moderate

remittances reception. On the other hand the municipalities concentrating just 23% of the remittances

reduced their poverty on 9.8% average whereas the reduction in poverty was of 3.9% for the

municipalities getting the 38% of the total amount of remittances of the state of Veracruz.

Page 30: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

29

V. Results

As anticipated in the methodology chapter, I obtain two OLS multiple regressions for the years 2000

and 2005 in a model which includes region-remittance interactions. The rationale to run this model is

to find, based on some literature, substantive differences in effects of remittances by region.

On the other hand some literature did not find an effect of remittances, but these studies tended to

look at the country as a whole, hence to try to reproduce these results I obtain the regressions of a

model without region-remittance interactions.

Comparing these models is possible to see that selectively remittances had an effect, but not

everywhere and not uniformly.

The table 1 summarizes the results obtained for the years of the study for the 2452 and 2454

municipalities of Mexico respectively. It’s important to mention that missing data (in both years 2000

and 2005) for the variable “municipal expenditure” in more than 200 municipalities caused a marginal

decrease in the total number of observations relative to the total number of municipalities (10%

decrease).

5.1 Main Findings

5.1.1 Regionalization of states

On the table 1 is possible to appreciate the interactive effect of the variable “region” and remittances

on the percentage of people living in poverty.

In every case on the table 1, the coefficient of ln_remitt now should be read as the coefficient of the

omitted region (the richest region) when the dummy variables are equal to zero (region 1 to 7).

As observed on this table, the coefficient of the omitted variable is positive and statistically significant

at a 99% of confidence level for the year of 2000, pointing out a positive correlation between

remittances and poverty. Nonetheless for the year 2005 the poverty categories “capabilities and

assets” are statistically non significant and the alimentary poverty though statistically significant

changes its sign indicating a negative correlation between remittances and the percentage of people

living in alimentary poverty.

Page 31: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

30

Then for the omitted variable (the richest region of Mexico) ceteris paribus every 1% increase in the

amount of remittances received at municipal level increases in 1.7% the alimentary-poverty, increases

in 2.5% the capabilities-poverty and increases in 4.8% the assets-poverty in2000. In 2005 the omitted

region indicates that ceteris paribus every 1% increase in the amount of remittances at municipal level

indeed reduces in 1.9% the alimentary-poverty, hence supporting the hypothesis stated on this

paper.

Now, let’s analyze the coefficients obtained in the seven regions left.

Given that the omitted region is the “base category” the interpretation of the coefficient obtained in

every region should be read as a comparison to this base category.

For the interactive variable lnRem_REG1 (Region 1) in the year 2000 the coefficient of the three

poverty categories is negative as expected in the hypothesis nonetheless is non statistically significant

meaning that the coefficient obtained in Region 1 is not statistically different to the coefficient

obtained in the omitted category and then in average for Region is 1 is obtained the same

interpretation than the omitted category regarding the sign and effect of remittances on poverty at its

three categories.

In the year 2005 the effect of remittances for the Region 1 seems to have a negative larger effect on

the percentage of people in poverty.

The coefficient of the three poverty categories in Region 1 ceteris paribus, point out that every 1%

increase in the amount of remittances received at municipal level may reduce the percentage of

people living in alimentary-poverty in 3.27% (coefficient of the base category + coefficient of Region 1=

(-1.96) + (-1.32)=-3.27%), may reduce in 1.38% the percentage of people living in capabilities poverty

and may reduce in 2% the amount of people living in assets-poverty.

For the interactive variable lnRem_REG2 in the year 2000 the three categories of poverty showed a

positive correlation again between remittances and poverty, but especially a larger effect that the base

category in the case of alimentary, and capabilities. Ceteris paribus for the Region 2 a 1% increase in

the amount of remittances received by the municipality increased the percentage of people living in

alimentary-poverty in 3.47% (coefficient of the base category + coefficient in REG1), capabilities-

poverty in 4.45% and assets-poverty in 4.84% (the same as the base category given that coefficient was

Page 32: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

31

not statistically significant). However for 2005 the alimentary-poverty is diminished in 1.9% (as well as

the base category).

The interactive variable lnRem_REG3 indicates a positive correlation in alimentary-poverty and

capabilities increasing the level of poverty in 3.5% and 4.58% respectively for 2000. For 2005 the

variable indicates a negative correlation just for the alimentary-poverty reducing it in 1.96% as the

base category.

The interactive variable lnRem_REG4 present the same positive correlation and coefficient that the

base category for alimentary and capabilities poverty in 2000. For 2005 the coefficient are the same as

the base category.

For the variable lnRem_REG5 is observed a strong negative correlation between remittances and

poverty rates. For 2000 the poverty rates show a decrease in the three categories of poverty of 3.2%,

3% and 3.1% respectively and in 2005 the alimentary-poverty and assets poverty are reduced by 1.96%

and 2.1 respectively.

The coefficients of the variable lnRem_REG6 suggest that municipal poverty is reduced at every

category in 2.3%, 2.1% and 2.2% respectively in 2000. In 2005 the reduction of poverty is just observed

for the alimentary-poverty category.

Finally in the Region 7 we can see that in 2000 is observed an increase in poverty as the remittances

received increased at municipal level in 1.7%, 2.54% and 4.84% respectively (same as the base

category) and in 2005 and increase in poverty for every 1% increase in remittances of 3%, and 2.89%

for alimentary and capabilities poverty respectively.

The interpretation of the coefficients in the control variables changed slightly after including the

regionalization and hence they will be explained following the information obtained from the table 2.

The control variable ln_totEx (log natural of municipal expenditure) presents the opposite expected

sign in 2000 and is significant just for the alimentary-poverty, which means that ceteris paribus, a 1%

increase in the amount of expenditure received at municipal level increase the percentage of people in

alimentary poverty in 0.82%; for 2005 a negative pattern is observed, reducing capabilities-poverty in

1.07% and assets-poverty in 2.26%.

Page 33: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

32

The control variable ln_totInc (municipal income) is significant for every category of poverty for both

years and presents the expected negative sign which indicates that ceteris paribus every 1% increase in

the municipal income reduces in 9.6% the percentage of people living in alimentary poverty, in 9.3%

the capabilities-poverty and in 7.9% the assets-poverty at municipal level for the year 2000. In 2005

the same patter is observed but with a larger effect, reducing the percentage of people living in

alimentary poverty in 29.6%, capabilities-poverty in 34% and assets-poverty in 37%.

The other control variable ln_totPop shows the expected positive sign and its coefficient is statistically

significant for every poverty category in both years. Then ceteris paribus every 1% increase in the total

population increases the percentage of people living in alimentary-poverty in 9.2%, capabilities poverty

in 8.6% and assets-poverty in 6.2% at municipal level. For 2005 the effect is similar but of larger impact

increasing in 39% the alimentary-poverty, in 44% the capabilities poverty and in 46% the assets-

poverty.

The control variable margin (marginality index) also shows the expected positive sign and its coefficient

is statistically significant for every of the two years for every poverty category, indicative of a positive

correlation between marginality and poverty; hence ceteris paribus every 1% increase in marginality

index results in an increase of 15% the percentage of people in alimentary-poverty, 14.9% for

capabilities-poverty and 12.2% for assets-poverty. For 2005 the same pattern is observed with a 12.7%

increase in the alimentary-poverty, 12.5% in capabilities poverty and 46% increase of assets-poverty.

The last control variable mun_Unem (municipal unemployment) is statistically significant for all the

categories in 2000 but just presents the positive expected sign in 2005 in the assets-poverty category;

the other categories show the opposite sign and hence ceteris paribus every 1% increase in the

municipal unemployment is associated with a 3.9% decrease of alimentary poverty, 3.8 decrease in

capabilities-poverty, and 11.6% decrease in assets-poverty in 2000. For 2005 the correlation becomes

positive for the assets-poverty with a 1.9% increase in poverty for every 1% increase of unemployment.

5.1.2 Without Regionalization of states

The table 2 explains the effect of remittances on poverty without region-remittance interactions.

The core explanatory variable ln_remitt (log natural of remittances received at municipal level)

presents a positive signs and its coefficient is significant at 99% confidence level. The same situation

Page 34: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

33

can be observed for the three different categories of poverty for 2000 and 2005. Nonetheless the sign

observed is the opposite of that expected and rejects the hypothesis stating that ceteris paribus (in

average and holding everything else constant) a 1% increase in the amount of remittances reduces the

percentage of people living in poverty.

Further more the coefficient showed in the table 2 suggest a positive correlation between the amount

of remittances and the percentage of people living in poverty, which means that ceteris paribus, a 1%

increase in the amount of remittances received at municipal level indeed increases the percentage of

people in alimentary-poverty in 1.1%, capabilities-poverty in 1.5% and poverty assets in 2 % at

municipal level for the year 2000; in the year 2005 the situation is not far different showing an increase

in alimentary-poverty of 1.2%, capabilities poverty of 1.2% and 0.88% for assets-poverty in every

municipality.

The control variable ln_totEx (log natural of municipal expenditure) presents the expected sign and is

significant for every category of poverty (except for alimentary-poverty in 2000), which means that

ceteris paribus, a 1% increase in the amount of expenditure received at municipal level reduces the

percentage of people in capabilities poverty in 1.1% and in 1.7% for assets-poverty; for 2005 the same

pattern is observed, but reducing alimentary-poverty in 1.1%, capabilities poverty in 2% and assets-

poverty in 3.7%.

The control variable ln_totInc (municipal income) is significant for every category of poverty for both

years and presents the expected negative sign which indicates that ceteris paribus every 1% increase in

the municipal income reduces in 12% the percentage of people living in alimentary poverty, in 11.8%

the capabilities-poverty and in 10% the assets-poverty at municipal level for the year 2000. In 2005 the

same patter is observed but with a larger effect, reducing the percentage of people living in alimentary

poverty in 29.7%, capabilities-poverty in 35% and assets-poverty in 39%.

The other control variable ln_totPop shows the expected positive sign and its coefficient is statistically

significant for every poverty category in both years. Then ceteris paribus every 1% increase in the total

population increases the percentage of people living in alimentary-poverty in 12.5%, capabilities

poverty in 12.4% and assets-poverty in 11.5% at municipal level. For 2005 the effect is similar but of

larger impact increasing in 34% the alimentary-poverty, in 44.5% the capabilities poverty and in 49.3%

the assets-poverty.

Page 35: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

34

The control variable margin (marginality index) also shows the expected positive sign and its coefficient

is statistically significant for the two years for every poverty category, indicative of a positive

correlation between marginality and poverty; hence ceteris paribus every 1% decrease in the

marginality index results in an decrease of 14% the percentage of people in alimentary-poverty, 14%

for capabilities-poverty and 12% for assets-poverty. For 2005 the same pattern is observed with a 12%

decrease in the alimentary-poverty, 12.5% in capabilities poverty and 9% decrease of assets-poverty.

The last control variable mun_Unem (municipal unemployment) is statistically significant for almost all

the categories (except for assets-poverty in 2005) but just presents the positive expected sign in 2000

for the assets-poverty category; the other categories show the opposite negative sign and hence

ceteris paribus every 1% increase in the municipal unemployment is associated with a 3.9% decrease of

alimentary poverty, 3.8 decrease in capabilities-poverty, and 11.6% increase in assets-poverty in 2000.

For 2005 the negative correlation is consistent for the alimentary-poverty with a 0.63% decrease and

0.5% decrease in capabilities poverty.

5.2 Discussion

The different correlations observed between remittances and poverty across the 8 regions seem to

obey to different patterns of migration from Mexico to US given that the net amount of remittances

received increased in the spam of 5 years. At national level the total amount of remittances received

grew from 6,572 million dollars in 2000 to 21,688 million dollars in 2005 a percentage increase

equivalent to 230% in 5 years or 46% average increase annually.

When including region-remittance interactions in the econometric model the effect of remittances on

poverty is disentangled and then the correlation is neater identifying the states most benefited from

migration and remittances of US.

This is not clear the reason why some regions present a positive correlation between remittances and

poverty and may exist additional “omitted factors” having an influence on the net effect of poverty.

Nonetheless the focus on the present paper is focused on testing the hypothesis stating a negative

correlation between remittances and poverty and then is just emphasized its negative and significant

correlation. However in the chapter of conclusion some reasons of this observed phenomenon are

going to be exposed.

Page 36: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

35

In summary the Mexican Regions supporting the hypothesis that an increase in the amount of

remittances received at municipal level indeed reduces the percentage of people in poverty are:

For 2000

Alimentary-poverty: Region 5 and 6

Patrimonial-poverty: Region 5 and 6

Assets-poverty: Region 4, 5 and 6.

For 2005

Alimentary-poverty: the omitted Region, Region 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6 (except for Region 7)

Capabilities-poverty: just Region 1

Assets-poverty: Region 1 and 5

Page 37: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

36

VI. Conclusions

The literature concerning the effects of remittance on poverty provided split conclusions. On one hand

some studies supported the negative correlation between remittances and poverty differentiating its

effects by regions inside a country, whereas others found no correlation when there was no distinction

by region and the country was taken as a whole entity.

In this paper I provided the results of two econometrics models, one including region-remittance

interactions and the other without the interactions with the purpose to provide additional evidence

supporting or rejecting what prior studies have contributed.

The model with region-remittance interactions provided far different results to those provided with

the model without region-remittance interactions. The prior presented a negative correlation between

remittances and poverty while the latter tended to sub-estimate the regional negative correlation that

remittances have on poverty and in some cases even to show a positive correlation.

Comparing these models is possible to see that selectively remittances reduce poverty, but not

everywhere and not uniformly.

The tables 3 and 6 show the states with the largest reception of remittances for the years 2000 and

2005.

The states of Michoacán, Guanajuato, Jalisco, México, Veracruz, Puebla, Guerrero and Oaxaca

concentrate the 59% of the amount of remittances received at national level in 2000.

For 2005 the same states with the exception of Oaxaca concentrated exactly the same percentage. In

this year the Distrito Federal surpassed the amount of remittances received by Oaxaca State becoming

one with the largest number of remittances received.

In the same tables we can observe that the amount of remittances received by states changes when

divided by the total population. Nonetheless by far three states seem to keep taking the first ranking in

both years 2000 and 2005: Michoacán, Guanajuato and Guerrero; further more these states

concentrate 26% and 25% of the total amount of remittances in 2000 and 2005.

Page 38: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

37

Comparing these data with the results obtained in the econometric regressions a priori one should

expect a reduction in poverty in the municipalities of the states receiving more remittances or at least

the largest effect. However my results show for the 2000 the states having their poverty levels

reduced are: Guerrero, Oaxaca, Chiapas, Veracruz and Tabasco for alimentary, capabilities and

assets-poverty and Querétaro, Estado de México, Distrito Federal, Morelos, Hidalgo, Tlaxcala and

Puebla in the case of assets-poverty.

For the year 2005 the reduction in poverty accounts for all the municipalities except for the

municipalities of Campeche, Yucatán and Quintana Roo. Additionally the capabilities-poverty and

assets poverty is reduced for the municipalities of Baja California, Baja California Sur, Sonora, Sinaloa

and Nayarit. The States of Guerrero, Oaxaca and Chiapas reduced as well their assets-poverty.

Whit these results as a general conclusion the hypothesis stated at the beginning of the document is

supported: on average and holding everything else constant, the amount of remittances received by

municipalities reduces the percentage of people living in poverty at its three different categories: food-

poverty, capabilities-poverty and assets-poverty, nonetheless selectively remittances reduce poverty,

but not everywhere and not uniformly.

The table 7 summarizes additional information to state that:

The net-largest recipients of remittances are not the only states reducing their municipal

poverty rates.

Not all the municipalities receiving high-per capita remittances reduced their poverty rates, in

some cases municipalities with high level of remittances per capita reduced poverty in 2000 but

not in 2005 and others performed the other way around (table 7).

In 2005 almost all the municipalities reduced alimentary-poverty and this reduction is

coincident with the large net-increase of remittances from 2000 to 2005 (table 4 and 6).

Remittances reduce poverty rates certainly but given the complexity of the migratory phenomenon

and its factors involved it is difficult to disentangle the process by which remittances and migration

may effectively reduce poverty in every municipality and state.

Page 39: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

38

VII. Tables.

Table 1. Effect of the amount of remittances received at municipal level, municipal expenditure, municipal income, total population, marginality, municipal unemployment AND the interactive effect of the remittances and geographical region on the percentage of people living in poverty: Results of OLS multiple regressions

Variables

Year 2000 Year 2005

Alimentary Poverty

Capabilities Poverty

Assets Poverty

Alimentary Poverty

Capabilities Poverty

Assets Poverty

ln_remitt 1.783* (1.96)

2.542* (2.75)

4.846*** (5.40)

-1.965** (-2.89)

-1.278 (-1.75)

1.165 (1.47)

lnRem_REG1 -1.130 (-1.34)

-1.112 (-1.30)

-1.463 (-1.76)

-1.327** (-2.03 )

-1.382** (-1.97 )

-2.003*** (-2.63)

lnRem_REG2 1.692* (1.95)

1.913** (2.18)

1.474 (1.72)

0.857 (-1.28)

1.170 (1.63)

1.230 (1.58)

lnRem_REG3 1.805** (2.03)

2.045** (2.26)

1.685 (1.92)

-0.085 (-0.13)

0.137 (0.19)

0.452 (0.58)

lnRem_REG4 -1.074 (-1.35)

-1.382 (-1.70)

-2.448*** (-3.11)

0.377 (-0.63)

0.077 (0.12)

-1.264 (-1.80)

lnRem_REG5 -3.264***

(-4.23) -3.076***

(-3.93) -3.181***

(-4.18) 0.128 (-0.22)

-0.394 (-0.63)

-2.151*** (-3.19)

lnRem_REG6 -2.325**

(-2.4) -2.155**

(-2.19) -2.226**

(-2.33) -0.244 (-0.33)

-0.344 (-0.43)

-1.217 (-1.41)

lnRem_REG7 1.065 (1.09) .730

(t=0.74 ) -1.174 (-1.22)

3.095*** (-4.23)

2.898*** (3.69 )

0.790 (0.93)

ln_totExp 0.822** (2.19)

.532 (1.39)

.055 (0.15)

-0.422 (-1.05)

-1.074** (-2.48)

-2.266*** (-4.83)

ln_totInc -9.629***

(-11.9) -9.364***

(-11.40) -7.941***

(-9.94) -29.638***

(-17.83) -34.291*** (-19.20)

-37.331*** (-19.29)

ln_totPop 9.236***

(9.15) 8.602***

(8.40) 6.236***

(6.26) 39.103***

(19.68 ) 44.105***

(20.65) 46.076***

(19.91)

margin 15.082***

(35.4) 14.976***

(34.64) 12.215***

(29.05) 12.751***

(36.54) 12.513***

(33.37) 46.076***

(23.17)

mun_Unem -3.950***

(-7.05) -3.794***

(-6.67 ) -2.453***

(-4.43) 0.185 (0.59)

.628 (1.85)

1.912*** (5.21)

N 2228 2228 2228 2182 2182 2182

Adjusted R-squared

0.85 0.85 0.81 0.84 0.84 0.78

* Significant at <0.10 ** Significant at <0.05 *** Significant at <.01

t ratios in parentheses

Page 40: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

39

Table 2. Effect of the amount of remittances received at municipal level, municipal expenditure, municipal income, total population, marginality and municipal unemployment on the percentage of people living in poverty: Results of OLS multiple regressions

Variables

Year 2000 Year 2005

Alimentary Poverty

Capabilities Poverty

Assets Poverty

Alimentary Poverty

Capabilities Poverty

Assets Poverty

ln_remitt 1.170***

(3.34 ) 1.502***

(4.19) 2.038***

(5.74) 1.268***

(4.69) 1.280***

(-4.45) 0.887** (2.86)

ln_totExp -0.634* (-1.77)

-1.126** (-3.06)

-1.735*** (-4.75)

-1.137** (-2.88)

-2.057** * (-4.89)

-3.733*** (-8.22)

ln_totInc -12.192 ***

(-15.33) - 11.849***

(-14.56) -10.455***

(-12.95) -29.709***

(-17.44) -35.051***

(-19.32) -39.196***

(-20.03)

ln_totPop 12.491***

(13.98) 12.438***

(13.60) 11.534 ***

(12.71) 34.335***

(18.16) 44.558***

(20.64) 49.303***

(22.71)

margin 14.141***

(33.06 ) 14.195***

(32.42 ) 12.215***

(29.05) 12.316***

(34.98) 12.513***

(33.37) 9.361*** (23.15)

mun_Unem -3.919***

(-10.26) -3.819***

(-9.76) 11.689***

(26.91 ) -0.634** (-3.01)

-0.528** (-2.35)

0.048 (0.20)

N 2228 2228 2228 2182 2182 2182

Adjusted R-squared

0.83 0.82 0.77 0.82 0.82 0.75

* Significant at <0.10

** Significant at <0.05

*** Significant at <.01

t ratios in parentheses

Table 3. States of Mexico with the largest reception of remittances in 2000

Absolute (million dollars) Relative (percentage) Per captia (dollars)

Michoacán 694 11 195

Guanajuato 603 9 131

Jalisco 524 8 92

México 524 8 37

Veracruz 420 6 63

Puebla 393 6 73

Guerrero 371 6 124

Oaxaca 368 6 100

Total 3,897 59 -

6,573

Amount Received

State

Total amount of remittances received in Mexico (million)

Page 41: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

40

TOTAL 1,194,317.84 TOTAL 6,572.74 TOTAL 100

MEAN 489.27 MEAN 2.69 MEAN 1.31

MAX 16,899.40 MAX 116.03 MAX 60.69

MIN 3.27 MIN 0.02 MIN 0.01

ST. DEV 1,182.09 ST. DEV 6.53 ST. DEV 3.6

VARIANCE 1,397,332.24 VARIANCE 42.70 VARIANCE 12.97

NUMBER OB 2,441 NUMBER OB 2,441.00 OBS 2,441

Households receiving remittances (percentage)

Remittances per municipality/state

(percentage)

Number of Households:

Number of households receiving remittances per

municipality

Amount of remittances received per state

(million dollars)

Table 4. Number of households receiving remittances; amount and percentage of remittances received per state and municipality

in 2000

22,268,126

5.4

Absolute (million dollars) Relative (percentage) Per captia (dollars)

Michoacán 2,462 11 621

Guanajuato 1,905 9 389

Mexico 1,792 8 128

Jalisco 1,723 8 255

Veracruz 1,364 6 192

Distrito Federal 1,334 6 153

Puebla 1,133 5 211

Guerrero 1,117 5 359

Total 12,830 59 -

21,689

Table 5. States of Mexico with the largest reception of remittances in 2005

Total amount of remittances received in Mexico (million)

State

Amount Received

TOTAL 1,480,865 TOTAL 21,688.80 TOTAL 100

MEAN 603.45 MEAN 8.84 MEAN 1.3

MAX 17,151.41 MAX 315.99 MAX 55.7

MIN 4.49 MIN 0.07 MIN 0.01

ST. DEV 1,288.12 ST. DEV 20.14 ST. DEV 3.41

VARIANCE 1,659,249.33 VARIANCE 405.72 VARIANCE 11.65

NUMBER OB 2,454 NUMBER OB 2,454 OBS 2,454

Households receiving remittances (percentage)

Number of Households: 24,803,625

6.0

Number of households receiving remittances per

municipality

Amount of remittances received per state

(million dollars)

Remittances per municipality/state

(percentage)

Table 6. Number of households receiving remittances; amount and percentage of remittances received per state and municipality

in 2005

Page 42: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

41

Alimentary-

poverty

Capabilities-

povertyAssets-poverty

Remittances per

capita (dollars)

Alimentary-

poverty

Capabilities-

povertyAssets-poverty

Remittances per

capita (dollars)

Guerrero Guerrero Guerrero 124

All except

Campeche,

Yucatán and

Quintan Roo

Baja California Baja California 93

Oaxaca Oaxaca Oaxaca 100Baja California

Sur

Baja California

Sur49

Chiapas Chiapas Chiapas 48 Sonora Sonora 126

Veracruz Veracruz Veracruz 63 Sinaloa Sinaloa 175

Tabasco Tabasco Tabasco 20 Nayarit Nayarit 325

Querétaro 88 Guerrero 359

Estado de México 37 Oaxaca 300

Distrito Federal 41 Chiapas 180

Morelos 104

Hidalgo 118

Tlaxcala 67

Puebla 73

Tabla 7. States with municipal poverty reduction through remittances

Year 2000 Year 2005

Page 43: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

42

VIII. References

1. Adams, Jr., Richard H. and John Page. (2003). “International Migration, Remittances and

Poverty in Developing Countries”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3179, December.

2. Adams, Jr., Richard. (1991). “The Effects of International Remittances on Poverty, Inequality and

Development in Rural Egypt”, Research report 86, IFPRI.

3. Adams, Jr., Richard. (2004). “Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala”, World Bank Policy

Research Working Paper 3418, September.

4. Adelman, I., and J.E. Taylor. (1990). ‘‘Is structural adjustment with a human face possible? the

case of Mexico’’, Journal of Development Studies, 26(3): 387–407.

5. Barcelata, H. (2010). Veracruz, Pobreza y Crecimiento Económico. Ensayos sobre la economía

Veracruzana. E. Universidad de Málaga. Málaga, España, Grupo Eumed.net: 143.

6. Barrera, M. (1979). Race and class in the southwest: A theory of racial inequality. Notre Dame,

IN: University of Notre Dame Press.

7. Calavita, K. (1992). Inside the state: The Bracero Program, immigration, and the I.N.S. New York:

Routledge.

8. Castles, S., Miller, M., & Ammendola, G. (2005). The Age of Migration: International Population

Movements in the Modern World. American Foreign Policy Interests, 27(6), 537-542. Retrieved

from EBSCOhost.

9. Cohen, Jeffrey H. (2001). “Transnational Migration in Rural Oaxaca, Mexico: Dependency,

Development and the Household.” American Anthropologist 103(4): 954–967.

10. Cohen, Jeffrey H., and Leila Rodriguez. (2005). “Remittance Outcomes in Rural Oaxaca, Mexico:

Challenges, Options and Opportunities for Migrant Households.” Population, Space and Place

(forthcoming 2005).

11. Cohen, J. H. (2005). Remittance Outcomes and Migration: Theoretical Contests, Real

Opportunities. Studies in Comparative International Development, 40(1), 88-112. Retrieved

from EBSCOhost.

12. Conway, Dennis. (2000). “Notions Unbound: A Critical (Re)reading of Transnationalism Suggests

that U.S.-Caribbean Circuits Tell the Story Better.” In Theoretical and Methodological Issues in

Migration Research: Interdisciplinary, Intergenerational and International Perspectives. B.

Agozino, ed. Pp. 203–226. Aldershot: Ashgate Publishers.

Page 44: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

43

13. Corona, Rodolfo. (2001). “Monto y Usos de las remesas en México”, Mercado de Valores 8:27–

46.

14. Craig, R. B. (1971). The Bracero Program: Interest groups and foreign policy. Austin: University

of Texas Press.

15. Cruz, T. (2008). ‘‘Pueden las remesas abatir la pobreza? efecto económico y modelos

distributivos de las remesas en una comunidad de la región Chatina’’, in A. Escobar (Ed),

Pobreza y Migración Internacional, CIESAS, Mexico City: 321–343.

16. Durand, Jorge. (1994). Más allá de la línea: Patrones migratorios entre México y Estados Unidos.

México, DF: Consejo Nacional para la Cultura y las Artes.

17. Durand, Jorge. (1988). “Los migradolares: Cien Años de inversión en el medio rural”,

Argumentos: Estudios Críticos de la Sociedad 5: 7–21.

18. Delgado Wise, Raúl and Héctor Rodríguez. (2001). “The Emergence of Collective Migrants and

their Role in Mexico’s Local and Regional Development”, Canadian Journal of Development

Studies 22(3): 747–64.

19. de la Garza, Rodolfo O., and Gabriel Szekely. (1997). “Policy, Politics, and Emigration:

Reexamining the Mexican Experience.” In At the Crossroads: Mexican Migration and U.S. Policy.

F.D. Bean, R.O. de la Garza, B.R. Roberts, and S. Weintraub, eds. Pp. 201–226. Lanham, MD:

Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc.

20. Escobar, A. (2008). Pobreza y Migración Internacional, CIESAS, Mexico City.

21. Escobar, A. (2009). Can Migration Foster Development in Mexico? The Case of Poverty and

Inequality. International Migration, 47(5), 75-113. doi:10.1111/j.1468-2435.2009.00583.x

22. Esquivel, G., & Huerta-Pineda, A. (2006). Remittances and Poverty in Mexico: A Propensity

Score Matching Approach. Integration and Trade, 11(27), 45-71. Retrieved from EBSCOhost.

23. Foster, J., J. Greer and E. Thorbecke, “A Class of Decomposable Poverty Measures,”

Econometrica, Vol. 52, No. 3 (1984), pp. 761-766.

24. Goldring, L. (2002). The Mexican State and Transmigrant Organizations. Latin American

Research Review, 37(3), 55-99. Retrieved from EBSCOhost.

25. Goldring, L. (2004). Family and Collective Remittances to Mexico: A Multi-dimensional

Typology.Development and Change, 35(4), 799-840. Retrieved from EBSCOhost.

26. González de la Rocha, Mercedes, and Augustín Escobar Latapí. (1991). “The Impact of IRCA on

the Migration Patterns of a Community in Los Altos, Jalisco, Mexico.” In The Effect of Receiving

Page 45: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

44

Country Policies on Migration Flows. S. Diáz-Briquet and S. Weintraub, eds. Pp. 205–231.

Boulder: Westview Press, Inc.

27. Hendricks, Glenn. (1974). The Dominican Diaspora: From the Dominican Republic to New York

City—Villagers in Transition. New York: Teachers College Press.

28. Taylor, Eduard J. M. a. R. A. (2005). Remittances, Inequality and Poverty: Evidence from Rural

Mexico. American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting. Providence, Rhode

Island: 40.

29. Kapur, Devesh. (2004). “Remittances: The New Development Mantra?”, G-24 Discussion Paper

no. 29, August.

30. Levitt, Peggy. (1998). “Social Remittances: Migration Driven Local-Level Forms of Cultural

Diffusion”, International Migration Review 32: 926–48.

31. Levitt, Peggy. (2000). “Migrant Participation Across Borders: Towards an Understanding of

Forms and Consequences.”In Immigration Research for a New Century: Multidisciplinary

Perspectives. N. Foner, R.G. Rumbaut, and S.J. Gold, eds. Pp. 459–479. New York: Russell Sage

Foundation.

32. López-Córdova, E. (2005). Globalization, Migration, and Development: The Role of Mexican

Migrant Remittances. Economia, 6(1), 217-256. Retrieved from EBSCOhost.

33. Lozano, Fernando. (2001). “Hogares, Migración y Remesas en México: Los Casos de Morelos y

Zacatecas’, Segundo Seminario Internacional Sobre Migración, Remesas y Desarrollo Regional,

Zacatecas (21–22 September).

34. Massey, Douglas S., et al. (1998). Worlds in Motion: Understanding International Migration at

the End of the Millennium. New York: Oxford University Press.

35. Massey, Douglas S., Luin Goldring, and Jorge Durand. (1994). “Continuities in Transnational

Migration: An Analysis of Nineteen Mexican Communities.” American Journal of Sociology

99(6): 1492–1533.

36. Moquin,W.,&Van Doren, C. (Eds.). (1971). A documentary history of the Mexican Americans.

New York: Praeger.

37. OECD. (2008). Policy Coherence for Development: Migration and Developing Countries, The

Development Center, OECD, Paris.

Page 46: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

45

38. Newland, K. (2004). "Beyond Remittances: The Role of Diaspora in Poverty Reduction in their

Countries of Origin." A Scoping Study by the Migration Policy Institute for the Department of

International Development. 59.

39. Reichert, Joshua. (1981). “The Migrant Syndrome: Seasonal U.S. Wage Labor and Rural

Development in Central Mexico.” Human Organization 40(1): 56–66.

40. Rodriguez, N. (2004). "Workers Wanted": Employer Recruitment of Immigrant Labor. Work &

Occupations, 31(4), 453-473. doi:10.1177/0730888404268870

41. Suro, Roberto. (2003). “Remittance Senders and Receivers: Tracking the Transnational

Channels”. Washington, DC: Multilateral Investment Fund, Inter-American Development Bank,

Pew Hispanic Center and Bendixen & Associates (November).

42. Tuirán, R. (2002). ‘‘Migración, remesas y desarrollo’’ in La situación demográfica de México

2002, CONAPO, Mexico City: 77–88.

43. Unger, K. (2005). ‘‘Regional economic development and Mexican out-migration,’’ NBER

Working Paper no. 11432, http://www.nber.org/papers/w11432.

44. Vertovec, Steven.(2000). “Rethinking Remittances”. Paper presented at the 5th International

Metropolis Conference, Vancouver, British Columbia. Working Paper, ESRC Transnational

Communities Programme, WPTC-2K-15. Available online: http://www.transcomm.

ox.ac.uk/working_papers.htm

Websites:

1. BANXICO Banco Nacional de México Website. (2011, January). Estadísticas de remesas

familiares 2000 and 2005. Retrieved from:

http://www.banxico.org.mx/SieInternet/consultarDirectorioInternetAction.do?accion=consulta

rCuadro&idCuadro=CE99&sector=1&locale=es

2. CONAPO Consejo Nacional de Población Website. (2011, January). Migración Internacional.

Retrieved from:

http://www.conapo.gob.mx/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=328&Itemid=25

1

3. CONAPO Consejo Nacional de Población Website. (2011, January). Índice de Marginación 2000

and 2005. Retrieved from:

http://conapo.gob.mx/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=78&Itemid=194

Page 47: Brandeis University Heller Graduate School Sustainable

46

4. CONEVAL Consejo Nacional de Evaluación de la Política de Desarrollo Social Website. (2011,

January). Medición de la Pobreza 2000. Retrieved from:

http://www.coneval.gob.mx/cmsconeval/rw/pages/medicion/mapas/mapas2000.es.do

5. CONEVAL Consejo Nacional de Evaluación de la Política de Desarrollo Social Website. (2011,

January). Medición de la Pobreza 2005. Retrieved from:

http://www.coneval.gob.mx/cmsconeval/rw/pages/medicion/mapas/mapas2005.es.do

6. INEGI Instituto Nacional de Estadística Geografía e Infromática Website. (2011, January). Censo

General de Población y Vivienda 2000. Retrieved from:

http://www.inegi.org.mx/sistemas/olap/Proyectos/bd/censos/cpv2000/Pobladores.asp?s=est&

c=10260&proy=cpv00_phv

7. INEGI Instituto Nacional de Estadística Geografía e Infromática Website. (2011, January). Censo

General de Población y Vivienda 2005. Retrieved from:

http://www.inegi.org.mx/sistemas/olap/Proyectos/bd/conteos/conteo2005/PHV.asp?s=est&c=

17355&proy=cpv05_phv

8. INEGI Instituto Nacional de Estadística Geografía e Infromática Website. (2011, January).

Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos de los Hogares ENIGH 2000 and 2005. Retrieved from:

http://www.inegi.org.mx/est/contenidos/Proyectos/Encuestas/Hogares/regulares/Enigh/defau

lt.aspx

9. INEGI Instituto Nacional de Estadística Geografía e Infromática Website. (2011, January).

Finanzas Públicas Estatales y Municipales 2000 and 2005. Retrieved from:

http://www.inegi.org.mx/prod_serv/contenidos/espanol/biblioteca/Default.asp?accion=1&upc=702825

169947

10. INEGI Instituto Nacional de Estadística Geografía e Infromática Website. (2011, January).

Ocupación y Empleo 2000 and 2005. Retrieved from:

http://www.inegi.org.mx/Sistemas/temasV2/Default.aspx?s=est&c=25433&t=1

11. United Nations Development Program UNDP Website. (2011, January) Human Development

Index 2000 and 2005. Retrieved from: http://hdrstats.undp.org/en/tables/default.html