banking, liquidity and bank runs in an in–nite …kiyotaki/papers/gk-bankrun...banking, liquidity...

53
Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an Innite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki NYU and Princeton University September 2014 (rst version May 2012) Abstract We develop an innite horizon macroeconomic model of banking that allows for liquidity mismatch and bank runs. Whether a bank run equilibrium exists depends on bank balance sheets and an endogenous liquidation price for bank assets. While in normal times a bank run equilibrium may not exist, the possibility can arise in a recession. A run leads to a signicant contraction in banking services and aggregate economic activity. Anticipatations of a run have harmful e/ects on the economy even if the run does not occur. We illustrate how the model can shed light on some key aspects of the recent nancial crisis. Thanks to Fernando Alvarez, David Andolfatto, Marios Angeletos, Anton Braun, Markus Brunnermeier, Wouter den Haan, Doug Diamond, Jordi Gali, Matthias Kehrig, John Moore, Hyun Shin, Aleh Tsyvinski, Stephen Williamson, the editor and four anony- mous referees for helpful comments and to Francesco Ferrante and Andrea Prespitino for outstanding research assistance, well above the call of duty. 1

Upload: builiem

Post on 16-May-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runsin an

In�nite Horizon Economy

Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki�

NYU and Princeton University

September 2014 (�rst version May 2012)

Abstract

We develop an in�nite horizon macroeconomic model of bankingthat allows for liquidity mismatch and bank runs. Whether a bank runequilibrium exists depends on bank balance sheets and an endogenousliquidation price for bank assets. While in normal times a bank runequilibrium may not exist, the possibility can arise in a recession. Arun leads to a signi�cant contraction in banking services and aggregateeconomic activity. Anticipatations of a run have harmful e¤ects on theeconomy even if the run does not occur. We illustrate how the modelcan shed light on some key aspects of the recent �nancial crisis.

�Thanks to Fernando Alvarez, David Andolfatto, Marios Angeletos, Anton Braun,Markus Brunnermeier, Wouter den Haan, Doug Diamond, Jordi Gali, Matthias Kehrig,John Moore, Hyun Shin, Aleh Tsyvinski, Stephen Williamson, the editor and four anony-mous referees for helpful comments and to Francesco Ferrante and Andrea Prespitino foroutstanding research assistance, well above the call of duty.

1

Page 2: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

1 Introduction

There are two complementary approaches in the literature to capturing theinteraction between banking distress and the real economy. The �rst, summa-rized recently in Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011), emphasizes how the depletionof bank capital in an economic downturn hinders banks ability to intermedi-ate funds. Due to agency problems (and possibly also regulatory constraints)a bank�s ability to raise funds depends on its capital. Portfolio losses expe-rienced in a downturn accordingly lead to losses of bank capital that areincreasing in the degree of leverage. In equilibrium, a contraction of bankcapital and bank assets raises the cost of bank credit, slows the economy anddepresses asset prices and bank capital further. The second approach, pio-neered by Diamond and Dybvig (1983), focuses on how liquidity mismatchin banking, i.e. the combination of short term liabilities and partially illiq-uid long term assets, opens up the possibility of bank runs. If they occur,runs lead to ine¢ cient asset liquidation along with a general loss of bankingservices.In the recent crisis, both phenomena were at work. Depletion of capital

from losses on subprime loans and related assets forced many �nancial insti-tutions to contract lending and raised the cost of credit they did o¤er. (SeeAdrian, Colla and Shin, 2012 for example.) Eventually, as both Bernanke(2010) and Gorton (2010) have emphasized, weakening �nancial positionsled to classic runs on a variety of �nancial institutions. These runs occurredmainly in the lightly regulated shadow banking sector and in two phases:From the onset of the subprime crisis in August of 2007 through the nearfailure of Bear Stearns in March 2008, up until early September 2008 werea series of "slow runs" where creditors became increasingly reluctant to rollover short term loans to shadow banks. The crisis then culminated in Octo-ber 2008 with series of "fast runs", beginning with the collapse of LehmannBrothers and then followed by collapse of the entire shadow banking system.Importantly, as Bernanke argues, the asset �resales induced by the runs am-pli�ed the overall distress in �nancial markets, raising credit costs which inturn helped trigger the sharp contraction in economic activity.To date, most macroeconomic models which have tried to capture the

e¤ects of banking distress have emphasized �nancial accelerator e¤ects, buthave not adequately captured bank runs. Most models of bank runs, however,are typically quite stylized and not suitable for quantitative analysis. Further,often the runs are not connected to fundamentals. That is, they may be

2

Page 3: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

equally likely to occur in good times as well as bad.Our goal is to develop a simple macroeconomic model of banking insta-

bility that features both �nancial accelerator e¤ects and bank runs. Ourapproach emphasizes the complementary nature of these mechanisms. Bal-ance sheet conditions not only a¤ect the cost of bank credit, they also a¤ectwhether runs are possible. In this respect one can relate the possibility ofruns to macroeconomic conditions and in turn characterize how runs feedback into the macroeconomy.For simplicity, we consider an in�nite horizon economy with a �xed sup-

ply of capital, along with households and bankers. It is not di¢ cult to mapthe framework into a more conventional macroeconomic model with capitalaccumulation and employment �uctuations. The economy with a �xed en-dowment and a �xed supply of capital, however, allows us to characterize ina fairly tractable way how banking distress and bank runs a¤ect the behaviorof asset prices and credit costs. It is then straightforward to infer the impli-cations of the resulting �nancial distress for aggregate economic activity ina setting with variable investment and employment.As in Gertler and Karadi (2011) and Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011), endoge-

nous procyclical movements in bank balance sheets lead to countercyclicalmovements in the cost of bank credit. At the same time, due to liquidity mis-match, bank runs may be possible. Whether or not a bank run equilibriumexists will depend on two key factors: the condition of bank balance sheetsand an endogenously determined asset liquidation price. Thus, a situationcan arise where a bank run cannot occur in normal times, but where a severerecession can open up the possibility.Though our modeling of runs as products of liquidity mismatch in bank

portfolios is in the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig, our technical approachfollows more closely Cole and Kehoe�s (2000) model of self-ful�lling debtcrises. As with Cole and Kehoe, runs re�ect a panic failure to roll over shortterm loans (as opposed to early withdrawal) and whether these kinds of runequilibria exist depends on macroeconomic fundamentals.1

Some other recent examples of macroeconomic models that consider bankruns include Ennis and Keister (2003), Martin, Skeie, and Von Thadden(2012) and Angeloni and Faia (2013).2 These papers typically incorporate

1Our framework thus falls within a general class of macroeconomic models that featuresunspot equilbria to characterize �uctuations. See for example Farmer (1999).

2See Boissay, Collard, and Smets (2013) for an alternative way to model banking crises

3

Page 4: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

banks with short horizons (e.g. two or three periods)3. We di¤er by mod-eling banks that optimize over an in�nite horizon. In addition, bank assetliquidation prices are endogenous and a¤ect whether a sunspot bank runequilibrium exists.Section 2 presents the model and characterizes the equilibria without

and with bank runs. For pedagogical purposes, we start with a baselinewhere bank runs are unanticipated. Section 3 presents a number of numericalexperiments to illustrate how the model can capture both standard �nancialaccelerator e¤ects and bank runs, as well as the interaction between thetwo. In Section 4, we describe the extension to the case of anticipated bankruns. Here we present some numerical exercises to illustrate how the mereanticipation of runs can lead to harmful e¤ects on the economy, even if therun does not actually occur. In addition, we show how if we allow for a periodof anticipation prior to an actual run, the model can produce something likethe "slow run culminating in a fast run" phenomenon described by Bernanke.We discuss policies that can reduce the likelihood of bank runs in Section 5and directions for further research in the conclusion.

2 Basic Model

2.1 Key Features

The framework is a variation of the in�nite horizon macroeconomic modelwith a banking sector and liquidity risks developed in Gertler and Karadi(2011) and Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011).4 There are two classes of agents -households and bankers - with a continuum of measure unity of each type.Bankers are specialists in making loans and thus intermediate funds betweenhouseholds and productive assets. Households may also make these loansdirectly, but are less e¢ cient in doing so than banks.There are two goods, a nondurable good and a durable asset, "capital."

Capital does not depreciate and is �xed in total supply which we normalize

that does not involve runs per se. For other related literature see Allen and Gale (2007),Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2012), Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011) and Holmstrom and Ti-role (2011) and the reference within.

3A very recent exception is Robatto (2013) who adopts an approach with some simi-larities to ours, but with an emphasis instead on money and nominal contracts.

4See also He and Krishnamurthy (2013) and Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2014) fordynamic general equilbirum models with capital constrained banks.

4

Page 5: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

to be unity. Capital is held by banks as well as households. Their totalholdings of capital is equal to the total supply,

Kbt +Kh

t = 1; (1)

where Kbt is the total capital held by banks and K

ht be the amount held by

households.When a banker intermediates Kb

t units of capital in period t; there is apayo¤ of Zt+1Kb

t units of goods in period t+ 1 plus the leftover capital:

date t

Kbt capital

!

date t+1�Zt+1K

bt output

Kbt capital

(2)

where Zt+1 is a multiplicative aggregate shock to productivity.By contrast, we suppose that households that directly hold capital at t

for a payo¤ at t+1 must pay a management cost of f(Kht ) units of goods at

t; as follows:date t

Kht capital

f(Kht ) goods

�!

date t+1�Zt+1K

ht output

Kht capital

(3)

The management cost is meant to re�ect the household�s lack of expertiserelative to banks in screening and monitoring investment projects. We sup-pose further that for each household the management cost is increasing andconvex in the quantity of capital held:

f(Kht ) =

2(Kh

t )2; (4)

with � > 0: The convex cost implies that it is increasingly costly at themargin for households to absorb capital directly.In the absence of �nancial frictions, bankers will intermediate the entire

capital stock. In this instance, households save entirely in the form of bankdeposits. If the banks are constrained in their ability to obtain funds, house-holds will directly hold some of the capital. Further, to the extent that theconstraints on banks tighten in a recession, as will be the case in our model,the share of capital held by households will expand.

5

Page 6: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

As with virtually all models of banking instability beginning with Di-amond and Dybvig (1983), a key to opening up the possibility of a bankrun is liquidity mismatch. Banks issue non-contingent short term liabilitiesand hold imperfectly liquid long term assets. Within our framework, thecombination of �nancing constraints on banks and ine¢ ciencies in householdmanagement of capital will give rise to imperfect liquidity in the market forcapital. To keep the model simple, we have assumed that households arethe only type of non-specialists to which banks can sell assets. It would bestraightforward to enrich the model to allow for other kinds of non-specialists,including alternative �nancial institutions. What is key is that these alter-native institutions are in some way less e¢ cient at holding the assets thanare the banks.5

For expositional simplicity, we simply assume in our baseline analysis thatbanks issue short term debt. In the Appendix we then generalize the modelto allow for household liquidity risks in the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig inorder to provide some motivation why banks issue short term non-contingentdebt in the absence of a run.

2.2 Households

Each household consumes and saves. Households save by either by lendingfunds to competitive �nancial intermediaries (banks) or by holding capitaldirectly. In addition to the returns on portfolio investments, each householdreceives an endowment of nondurable goods, ZtW h, every period that variesproportionately with the aggregate productivity shock Zt:6

Intermediary deposits held from t to t + 1 are one period bonds thatpromise to pay the non-contingent gross rate of return Rt+1 in the absenceof a bank run. In the event of a run depositors only receive a fraction xt+1 ofthe promised return, where xt+1 is the total liquidation value of bank assetsper unit of promised deposit obligations. Accordingly, we can express thehousehold�s return on deposits, Rt+1, as follows:

5For example, during the crisis, shadow banks sold some of their assets to commer-cial banks who were are a disadvantage in holding these assets due to regulatory capitalconstraints. In this vein, one can interpret banks in our model as shadow banks andhouseholds as an aggregation of individuals and commercial banks.

6We introduce the household endowment because it helps improve the quantitativeperformance of the model by helping smooth household consumption, thus smoothing theriskelss interest rate.

6

Page 7: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Rt+1 =

�Rt+1 if no bank runxt+1Rt+1 if run occurs

(5)

where 0 � xt < 1:7 Note in the event of a run all depositors receive the same

pro rata share of liquidated assets. As we discuss later, we do not imposea sequential service constraint on deposit contracts that relates payo¤s in arun to a depositor�s place in line, which was a central feature of the Diamondand Dybvig model.For pedagogical purposes, we begin with a baseline model where bank

runs are completely unanticipated events. Accordingly, in this instance thehousehold chooses consumption and saving with the expectation that the re-alized return on depositsRt+1 equals the promised returnRt+1 with certainty:In a subsequent section, we characterize the case where households anticipatethat a bank run may occur with some likelihood.Household utility Ut is given by

Ut = Et

1Xi=0

�i lnCht+i

!where Cht is household consumption and 0 < � < 1. Let Qt be the marketprice of capital. The household chooses consumption, bank deposits Dt anddirect capital holdingsKh

t to maximize expected utility subject to the budgetconstraint

Cht +Dt +QtKht + f(Kh

t ) = ZtWh +RtDt�1 + (Zt +Qt)K

ht�1: (6)

Here, consumption, saving and management cost are �nanced by the endow-ment and the returns on the saving from the previous period.Given that the household assigns a zero probability of a bank run, the

�rst order conditions for deposits is given by

Et(�t;t+1)Rt+1 = 1 (7)

where the stochastic discount factor �t;t+i satis�es

�t;t+i = �iChtCht+i

: (8)

7As show later that, a bank run equilbrium can exist if and ony if xt < 1 with positiveprobability:

7

Page 8: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

In turn, the �rst order condition for direct capital holdings is given by

Et(�t;t+1Rht+1) = 1 (9)

with

Rht+1 =Zt+1 +Qt+1Qt + f 0(Kh

t )(10)

where f 0(Kht ) = �Kh

t and Rht+1 is the household�s gross marginal rate ofreturn from direct capital holdings.Observe that so long as the household has at least some direct capital

holdings, the �rst order condition (9) will help determine the market priceof capital. Further, the market price of capital tends to be decreasing in theshare of capital held by households as the marginal management cost f 0(Kh

t )is increasing. As will become clear, a banking crisis will induce banks to selltheir assets to households, leading a drop in asset prices. The severity of thedrop will depend on the quantity of sales and the convexity of the manage-ment cost function. In the limiting case of a bank run, households absorb allthe capital from banks and assets prices drop sharply to a minimum.

2.3 Banks

The banking sector we characterize corresponds best to the shadow bankingsystem which was at the epicenter of the �nancial instability during the GreatRecession. In particular, banks in the model are completely unregulated,holding long-term security and short-term debt, and are potentially subjectto runs.Each banker manages a �nancial intermediary. Bankers fund capital in-

vestments by issuing deposits to households as well as by using their ownequity, or net worth, nt. Due to �nancial market frictions, bankers may beconstrained in their ability to obtain deposits from households.To the extent bankers may face �nancial market frictions, they will at-

tempt to save their way out of the �nancing constraint by accumulatingretained earnings in order to move toward one hundred percent equity �nanc-ing. To limit this possibility, we assume that bankers have a �nite expectedlifetime: Speci�cally, each banker has an i.i.d. probability � of surviving untilthe next period and a probability 1� � of exiting. The expected lifetime ofa banker is then 1

1�� :

8

Page 9: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Every period new bankers enter with an endowment wb that is receivedonly in the �rst period of life. The number of entering bankers equals thenumber who exit, keeping the total constant. As will become clear, this setupprovides a simple way to motivate "dividend payouts" from the bankingsystem in order to ensure that banks use leverage in equilibrium.In particular, we assume that bankers are risk neutral and enjoy util-

ity from consumption in the period they exit.8 The expected utility of acontinuing banker at the end of period t is given by

Vt = Et

" 1Xi=1

�i(1� �)�i�1cbt+i

#;

where (1� �)�i�1 is probability of exiting at date t+ i; and cbt+i is terminalconsumption if the banker exits at t+ i:Figure 1 shows the timing of events. The aggregate shock Zt is realized

at the start of t. Conditional on this shock, the net worth of "surviving"bankers is the gross return on assets net the cost of deposits, as follows:9

nt = (Zt +Qt)kbt�1 �Rtdt�1: (11)

For new bankers at t, net worth simply equals the initial endowment:

nt = wb: (12)

Meanwhile, exiting bankers no longer operate banks and simply use their networth to consume:

cbt = nt: (13)

Observe that the equity withdrawals by the exiting bankers correspond todividend payouts.During each period t; a continuing bank (either new or surviving) �nances

asset holdings Qtkbt with newly issued deposits and net worth:

Qtkbt = dt + nt: (14)

8We could generalize to allow active bankers to receive utility that is linear in con-sumption each period. So long as the banker is constrained, it will be optimal to defer allconsumption until the exit period.

9In data, net worth here corresponds to the mark-to-market di¤erence between assetsand liabilities of the bank balance sheet. It is di¤erent from the book value often used inthe o¢ cial report, which is slow in reacting to market conditions.

9

Page 10: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

We assume that banks can only accumulate net worth via retained earnings.While this assumption is a reasonable approximation of reality, we do notexplicitly model the agency frictions that underpin it.To motivate a limit on the bank�s ability to issue deposits, we introduce

the following moral hazard problem: After accepting deposits and buyingassets at the beginning of t, but still during the period, the banker decideswhether to operate "honestly" or to divert assets for personal use. To operatehonestly means holding assets until the payo¤s are realized in period t + 1and then meeting deposit obligations. To divert means selling the fraction �of assets secretly on a secondary market in order to obtain funds for personaluse. We assume that the process of diverting assets takes time: The bankercannot quickly liquidate a large amount assets without the transaction beingnoticed. To remain undetected, he can only sell up to the fraction � of theassets and he can only sell these assets slowly. For this reason the bankermust decide whether to divert at t; prior to the realization of uncertainty att+1: The cost to the banker of the diversion is that the depositors can forcethe intermediary into bankruptcy at the beginning of the next period.The banker�s decision at t boils down to comparing the franchise value of

the bank Vt; which measures the present discounted value of future payoutsfrom operating honestly, with the gain from diverting funds, �Qtkbt . In thisregard, rational depositors will not lend funds to the banker if he has anincentive to cheat. Accordingly, any �nancial arrangement between the bankand its depositors must satisfy the following incentive constraint:

�Qtkbt � Vt: (15)

Note that the incentive constraint embeds the constraint that the net worthnt must be positive for the bank to operate since the franchise value Vt willturn out to be proportional to nt: We will choose parameters and shockvariances that keep nt non-negative in a "no-bank run" equilibrium.10

Given that bankers simply consume their net worth when they exit, wecan restate the bank�s franchise value recursively as the expected discountedvalue of the sum of net worth conditional on exiting and the value conditionalon continuing as:

Vt = Et[�(1� �)nt+1 + ��Vt+1]: (16)

10Following Diamond and Dybvig (1983), we are assuming that the payo¤ on depositsis riskless absent a bank run, which requires that bank net worth be positive without run.A bank run, however, will force nt to zero, as we show later.

10

Page 11: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

The banker�s optimization problem then is to choose�kbt ; dt

�each period to

maximize the franchise value (16) subject to the incentive constraint (15)and the balance sheet constraints (11) and (14).From the balance sheet constraints, we can express the growth rate of net

worth as

nt+1nt

=Zt+1 +Qt+1

Qt

Qtkbt

nt�Rt+1

dtnt

= (Rbt+1 �Rt+1)�t +Rt+1; (17)

where

Rbt+1 =Zt+1 +Qt+1

Qt;

�t � Qtkbt

nt:

The variable Rbt+1 is the realized rate of return on bank asset from date tto t+1. �t is the ratio of assets to net worth, which for convenience we willrefer to as the "leverage multiple". The growth rate of bank net worth is anincreasing function of the leverage multiple when the realized rate of returnon bank asset exceeds the deposit rate, i.e., Rbt+1 > Rt+1:Because both the objective and constraints of the bank are constant re-

turns to scale, the bank�s optimization is reduced to choosing the leveragemultiple to maximizing its "Tobin�s Q ratio", given by the franchise valueper unit of net worth, Vt

nt. Let Vt

nt� t: Then given equations (16) and (17),

we can express the bank�s problem as

t = Max�t

Et��(1� � + � t+1)

�(Rbt+1 �Rt+1)�t +Rt+1;

�(18)

= Max�t

f�t�t + �tg;

subject to the incentive constraint

��t � t = �t�t + �t; (19)

where�t = Et[�t+1(R

bt+1 �Rt+1)]; (20)

�t = Et (�t+1)Rt+1; (21)

11

Page 12: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

witht+1 � 1� � + � t+1:

We can think of �t as the excess marginal value of assets over deposits,and �t is the marginal cost of deposits.11 Observe also that the discountfactor the bank uses to evaluate payo¤s in t+1 is weighted by the multipliert+1; which is a probability weighted average of the marginal values of networth to exiting and to continuing bankers at t+1. For an exiting bankerat t + 1 (which occurs with probability 1 � �), the marginal value of anadditional unit of net worth is simply unity, since he or she just consumesit. For a continuing banker (which occurs with probability �), the marginalvalue is t+1. As will become clear, Tobin�s Q, t, may exceed unity due tothe bank�s �nancing constraint.The bank�s value maximization implies that the incentive constraint (19)

is binding if and only if the excess marginal value from honestly managingassets �t is positive but less than the marginal gain from diverting � units ofassets; i.e.12

0 < �t < �:

Assuming this condition is satis�ed, the incentive constraint leads to thefollowing limit on the leverage multiple:

�t = t�

=�t

� � �t: (22)

The constraint (22) limits the portfolio size to the point where the bank�sgain from diverting funds (per unit of net worth) ��t is exactly balanced bythe cost of losing the franchise value, measured by t = �t�t + �t . In thisrespect the agency problem leads to an endogenous capital constraint on thesize of the bank�s portfolio.In the absence of the incentive constraint, unlimited arbitrage by banks

will push discounted excess returns to zero, implying �t = 0: In this instance

11�t is the shadow value of a unit of bank assets holding �nanced by deposits since itis the shadow value of assets holding net worth constant. Conversely, because �t is theshadow value of net worth holding assets constant, it equals shadow cost of deposits.12In the numerical analysis in Section 3, we choose parameters to ensure that the con-

dition 0 < �t < � is always satis�ed in the no bank-run equilibrium.

12

Page 13: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

banks will intermediate all the capital and the economy will resemble onewith frictionless �nancial markets, where �nancial structure in banking isirrelevant to real activity and bank runs are not possible.With a binding incentive constraint, however, limits to arbitrage emerge

that lead to positive expected excess returns in equilibrium, i.e., �t > 0; andto the shadow value of bank net worth exceeding unity, (i.e., t > 1).

13 In thisinstance the bank�s portfolio is constrained by its net worth. Fluctuationsin net worth accordingly will induce �uctuations in bank lending, leadingto conventional �nancial accelerator e¤ects. But that is not all: Because abank cannot operate with negative net worth, a bank run equilibrium maybe possible. As we will make clear shortly, in terms of Figure 1, a run mayoccur if after the realization of Zt at the beginning of period t, depositorschoose en masse not to roll over their deposits.

2.4 Aggregation and Equilibrium without Bank Runs

Given that the leverage multiple �t is independent of individual bank-speci�cfactors and given a parametrization where the incentive constraint is bindingin equilibrium, we can aggregate across banks to obtain the relation betweentotal assets held by the banking system QtK

bt and total net worth Nt :

QtKbt = �tNt: (23)

Summing across both surviving and entering bankers yields the followingexpression for the evolution of Nt :

Nt = �[(Zt +Qt)Kbt�1 �RtDt�1] +W b (24)

where W b = (1� �)wb is the total endowment of entering bankers. The �rstterm is the accumulated net worth of bankers that operated at t � 1 andsurvived to t, which is equal to the product of the survival rate � and the netearnings on bank assets (Zt+Qt)Kb

t�1�RtDt�1: Conversely, exiting bankersconsume the fraction 1� � of net earnings on assets:

Cbt = (1� �)[(Zt +Qt)Kbt�1 �RtDt�1]: (25)

13The latter follows because in the neighborhood of the steady state, �Rt+1 is approxi-mately equal to unity by the household�s choice. Thus as long as �t > 0; we have �t > 1and t > 1 in the neighborhood of the steady state.

13

Page 14: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Total output Yt is the sum of output from capital, household endowmentZtW

h and bank endowment W b :

Yt = Zt + ZtWh +W b: (26)

Finally, output is either used for management costs, or consumed by house-holds and bankers:

Yt = f(Kht ) + Cht + Cbt : (27)

2.5 Unanticipated Bank Runs

We now consider the possibility of an unexpected bank run. (We defer ananalysis of anticipated bank runs to Section 4.) In particular, we maintainthe assumption that when households acquire deposits at t�1 that mature int; they attach zero probability to a possibility of a run at t: However, we nowallow for the chance of a run ex post as deposits mature at t and householdsmust decide whether to roll them over for another period.14

As we showed in the previous section, for a bank to continue to oper-ate it must have positive net worth (i.e., nt > 0). Otherwise, the incentiveconstraint that ensures the bankers will not divert assets is violated. Accord-ingly, it is individually rational for a household not to roll over its deposits, if(i) it perceives that other households will do the same, forcing banks to liqui-dation and (ii) this forced liquidation makes the banks insolvent (i.e., nt = 0).In this situation two equilibria exist: a "normal" one where households rollover their deposits in banks, and a "run" equilibrium where households stoprolling over their deposits, banks are liquidated, and households use theirresidual funds to acquire capital directly.Our modeling of runs as sunspot phenomena is similar to Diamond and

Dybvig (1983). But it is not the same. A key requirement for the runequilibrium in Diamond and Dybvig are deposit contracts which feature asequential service constraint where in the event of a run a depositor receiveseither the full non-contingent return Rt+1 or zero, depending on the place

14Note that the liabilities in our model correspond best to asset-back commercial paper,i.e., uninsured short term funding back by a generic pool of assets, which Krishnamurthy,Nagel and Orlov (forthcoming) argue was the primary source of funding by the shadowbanking sector. Further, this kind of funding of was subject to the kind of roll-over riskwe are modeling.

14

Page 15: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

in line. It is the possibility of zero payo¤ for arriving late to the bank thatmakes the run equilibrium exist. In contrast, what is necessary in our case isthat an individual depositor perceives that a run by other depositors leavesthe bank with zero net worth. Thus a run equilibrium may exist even if alldepositors receive an equal haircut in the event of a run. In this regard, ourformulation of the sunspot run equilibrium is technically closer to Cole andKehoe�s (2000) model of self-ful�lling sovereign debt crises than Diamondand Dybvig (1983).

2.5.1 Conditions for a Bank Run Equilibrium

The runs we consider are runs on the entire banking system, not on individualbanks. Given the homogeneity of banks in our model, the conditions for a runon the banking system will be the same for the depositors at each individualbank.In particular, at the beginning of period t; after the realization of Zt,

depositors decide whether to roll over their deposits with the bank. If theychoose to "run", the bank liquidates its capital and turns the proceeds overto households who then acquire capital directly with their less e¢ cient tech-nology. Let Q�t be the price of capital in the event of a forced liquidation ofthe banking system. Then a run on the system is possible if the liquidationvalue of bank assets (Zt+Q�t )K

bt�1 is smaller than its outstanding liability to

the depositors, RtDt�1; in which case the bank�s net worth would be wipedout. De�ne the recovery rate in the event of a bank run xt as the ratio of(Zt +Q

�t )K

bt�1 to RtDt�1 Then the condition for a bank run equilibrium to

exist is that the recovery is less than unity as,

xt =(Q�t + Zt)K

bt�1

RtDt�1< 1: (28)

The condition determining the possibility of a bank run depends on twokey endogenous factors, the liquidation price of capital Q�t and the conditionof bank balance sheets. From (17) ; we can obtain a simple condition for abank run equilibrium in terms of just three variables:

xt =Rb�tRt

� �t�1�t�1 � 1

< 1 (29)

with

15

Page 16: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Rb�t �Zt +Q�tQt�1

;

where Rb�t is the return on bank assets conditional on a run at t, and �t�1is the bank leverage multiple at t � 1: A bank run equilibrium exists if therealized rate of return on bank assets conditional on liquidation of assets Rb�tis su¢ ciently low relative to the gross interest rate on deposits Rt and theleverage multiple is su¢ ciently high to satisfy condition (29). Note that theexpression �t�1

�t�1�1is the ratio of bank assets Qt�1Kb

t�1 to depositsDt�1, whichis decreasing in the leverage multiple. Also note that the condition for a rundoes not depend on individual bank-speci�c factors since (Rb�t =Rt, �t�1) arethe same for all in equilibrium.Since Rb�t ; Rt and �t are all endogenous variables, the possibility of a bank

run may vary with macroeconomic conditions. The equilibrium absent bankruns (that we described earlier) determines the behavior of Rt and �t: Thebehavior of Rb�t is increasing in the liquidation price Q�t ; which depends onthe behavior of the economy, as we show in the next sub-section.Figure 2 illustrates how the possibility of a run may depend on macro-

economic a conditions. The vertical axis measures the ratio of bank assetreturns conditional on a run to the deposit rate, Rb�t =Rt and the horizontalaxis measures the leverage multiple �t�1: The curve which is increasing andconcave in (Rb�t =Rt, �t�1) space represents combinations of points for whichthe recovery rate xt equals unity. To the left of this curve, depositors alwaysreceive the promised returns on their deposits and a bank run equilibriumdoes not exist. To the right, xt < 1 and a bank run is possible. In thesimulations that follow we start the economy at a point like A in the �gurewhere a run is not feasible. A negative shock then raises leverage and reducesliquidation prices (as we show below), moving the economy to a point like Bwhere a bank run is possible.

2.5.2 The Liquidation Price

To determineQ�t we proceed as follows. A depositor run at t induces all banksthat carried assets from t � 1 to fully liquidate their asset positions and goout of business.15 Accordingly they sell all their assets to households, whohold them at t: The banking system then re-builds itself over time as new

15See Uhlig (2010) for an alternative bank run model with endogenous liquidation prices.

16

Page 17: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

banks enter. For the asset �resale during the panic run to be quantitativelysigni�cant, we need there is at least a modest delay in the ability of new banksto begin operating. Accordingly, we suppose that new banks cannot beginoperating until the period after the panic run. Suppose for example thatduring the run it is not possible for households to identify new banks thatare �nancially independent of the banks being run on: New banks accordinglywait for the dust to settle and then begin issuing deposits in the subsequentperiod. The results are robust to alternative timing assumptions about theentry of new banks, with the proviso that every thing else equal, the severityof the crisis is increasing in the time it takes for new banks to begin operating.Accordingly, when banks liquidate, they sell all their assets to households

in the wake of the run at date t, implying

1 = Kht ; (30)

where, again, unity is the total supply of capital. The banking system thenrebuilds its equity and assets as new banks enter at t+1 onwards. Accord-ingly, given our timing assumptions and (24) bank net worth evolves in theperiods after the run according to

Nt+1 = W b + �W b;

Nt+i = �[(Zt+i +Qt+i)Kbt+i�1 �Rt+iDt+i�1] +W b; for all i � 2:

Here only at the date after the run, the aggregate net worth of bankersconsists of endowment of new bankers and that of bankers who enter withdelay, (assuming that the endowment is storable one-for-one between theperiods).Rearranging the Euler equation for the household�s capital holding (9)

yields the following expression for the liquidation price in terms of discounteddividends Zt+i net the marginal management cost �Kh

t+i.

Q�t = Et

" 1Xi=1

�t;t+i(Zt+i � �Kht+i)

#� �: (31)

Everything else equal, the longer it takes for the banking sector to recapitalize(measured by the time it takesKh

t+i to fall back to steady state), the lower willbe the liquidation price. Note also that Q�t will vary with cyclical conditions.In particular, a negative shock to Zt will reduce Q�t ; possibly moving the

17

Page 18: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

economy into a regime where bank runs are possible, consistent with theexample in Figure 2.16

Finally, we observe that within our framework the distinction between aliquidity shortage and insolvency is more subtle than is often portrayed inpopular literature. If a bank run equilibrium exists, banks become insolvent,i.e. their liabilities exceed their assets if assets are valued at the �re-sale priceQ�t . But if assets are valued at the price in the no-run equilibrium Qt; thebanks are all solvent. Thus whether banks are insolvent or not depends uponequilibrium asset prices which in turn depend on the liquidity in the bankingsystem; and this liquidity can change abruptly in the event of a run. As areal world example of this phenomenon consider the collapse of the bankingsystem during the Great Depression. As Friedman and Schwartz (1963) pointout, what was initially a liquidity problem in the banking system (due in partby inaction of the Fed), turned into a solvency problem as runs on banks ledto a collapse in long-term security prices and in the banking system alongwith it.

3 Numerical Examples

Our goal here is to provide some suggestive numerical examples to illustratethe workings of the model. Speci�cally we construct an example where abank run is not possible in steady state, but where a recession opens up arun possibility. We then simulate a recession that leads to an unanticipatedrun and trace out the e¤ects on �nancial and real variables. Given thesimplicity of our model, these numerical exercises are not precise estimates.

3.1 Parameter Choices and Computation

Table 1 lists the choice of parameter values for our baseline model, whileTable 2 gives the steady state values of the endogenous variables. We takethe period length to be one quarter. Overall there are eight key parame-ters in the baseline model. Two parameters in the baseline are conventional:

16Our notion of the liquidation price is related to Brunnermeier and Pedersens�s (2009)concept of market liquidity, while our notion of bank leverage constraints is related totheir concept of funding liquidity. For us as well as for them, the two concepts of liquidityoperate jointly in an asset �resale crisis.

18

Page 19: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

the quarterly discount factor � which we set at 0:99 and the serial correla-tion � of the productivity shock Zt which we set at 0:95. Six parameters(�;W b; �; �;W h; Z) are speci�c to our model.We choose values for the fraction of assets the bank can divert � and

the banker�s initial endowment W b to hit the following targets in the steadystate absent bank runs: a bank leverage multiple � of ten and an annualspread between the the expected return on bank assets and the riskless rateof one hundred basis points. As we noted earlier, the banks in our modelcorrespond best to shadow banks, which tended to operate with higher lever-age multiples and lower interest margins than do commercial banks. It isdi¢ cult to obtain precise balance sheet and income statements for the entireshadow banking sector. Thus, the numbers we use are meant to be reason-able benchmarks that capture the relative weakness of the �nancial positionsof the shadow banks.17 The results are robust to plausible variations aroundthese benchmarks.We set the banker�s survival probability � equal to 0:95 which implies

an expected horizon of �ve years. We set the parameter that re�ects "man-agerial cost" � at 0:008, a value low enough to ensure that households �ndit pro�table to directly hold capital in the bank run equilibrium, but highenough to produce an increase in the credit spread in the wake of the runthat is consistent with the evidence. We set the household steady state en-dowment ZW h (which roughly corresponds to labor income) to three timessteady state capital income Z: Finally, we also normalize the steady stateprice of a unit of capital Qt at unity, which restricts the steady value of Zt(which determined output stream from capital).We defer to the Appendix a detailed description of our numerical proce-

dures. Roughly speaking, we illustrate the behavior of our model economy bycomputing impulse responses to shocks to Zt: In each case we construct theimpulse response of a variable to the shock as the nonlinear perfect foresightsolution, assuming that Zt follows a deterministic process after the shock.Once multiple equilibria emerge (i.e., a bank run equilibrium coexists witha no run equilibrium), we allow for a sunspot which can shift the economy

17On the eve of the Great Recession commerical banks operated with leverage ratiosin the vicinity of eight and interest margins of roughly two hundred basis points (e.g.Phillipon 2013). In shadow banking system leverage multiples ranged from very modestlevels (two or below) for hedge funds to extremely high levels for investment banks (twentyto thirty). Interest margins ranged from twenty-�ve basis points for ABX securities to onehundred or more for agency mortgage-backed securities and BAA corporate bonds.

19

Page 20: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

from the no bank run to the bank run equilibrium. To calculate the leadupto the bank run we compute the perfect foresight path up to the point wherethe run occurs. After the run we then compute a new perfect foresight pathback to the steady state, given the values of the state variables in the wakeof the run. In the exercises here, we assume that individuals perceive zeroprobability of a run. Later, we assume they perceive a positive probabilityof runs.

3.2 Recessions, Banking Distress and Bank Runs: SomeSimulations

Figure 3 shows the response of the baseline model to an unanticipated neg-ative �ve percent shock to productivity Zt, assuming the economy stays inthe "no bank run" equilibrium. This leads to a drop in output (total outputminus household capital management costs) of roughly six percent, a mag-nitude which is characteristic of a major recession. Though a bank run doesnot arise in this case, the recession induces �nancial distress that ampli�esthe fall in assets prices and raises the cost of bank credit. The unanticipateddrop in Zt reduces net worth Nt by about �fty percent, which tightens bankbalance sheets, leading to a contraction of bank deposits and a �resale ofbank assets, which in turn magni�es the asset price decline. Households ab-sorb some of the asset, but because this is costly for them, the amount theyacquire is limited. The net e¤ect is a substantial increase in the cost of bankcredit: the spread between the expected return to bank assets and the risk-less rate increases by seventy basis points. Overall, the recession induces thekind of �nancial accelerator mechanism prevalent in Bernanke and Gertler(1989) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) and other macroeconomic models of�nancial distress.Figure 4 revisits the recession experiment for the baseline model, this

time allowing for a bank run ex post. As we noted in section 2.5.1, a run

equilibrium exists when the depositor recovery rate xt =(Q�t+Zt)K

bt�1

RtDt�1is less

than unity. Accordingly, de�ne the variable runt as the shortfall of therecovery rate below unity, as follows:

runt = 1� xt: (32)

A bank run equilibrium exists i¤ runt > 0: The �rst panel of the middlerow shows that the run variable becomes positive upon impact and remains

20

Page 21: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

positive for a while. An unanticipated bank run is thus possible at anypoint in this interval. The reason the bank run equilibrium exists is thatthe negative productivity shock reduces the liquidation price Q�t and leadsto an increase in the bank�s leverage multiple �t (as bank net worth declinesrelative to assets). Both these factors work to make the banking systemvulnerable to a run, as equations (29) and (32) indicate. In the steady ofour model run < 0, implying a bank run equilibrium does not exist in theneighborhood of the steady state.In Figure 4 we suppose an unanticipated run occurs in the second pe-

riod after the shock. The solid line portrays the bank run while the dottedline tracks the no-bank run equilibrium for reference. The run produces acomplete liquidation of bank assets as Kb

t drops to zero at date 3. The as-set price falls to its liquidation price which is roughly �fteen percent belowthe steady state. Output net of household capital management costs dropsroughly twelve percent. The high management costs arise due the damagedbanking system, which induces households to hold the capital stock eventhough they are not e¢ cient at doing so. The reduction of net output im-plies that household consumption drops roughly seven percent on impact.Bankers consumption - which is equal to the net worth of retiring bankers -drops nearly to zero as existing bankers are completely wiped out and newbankers take time to accumulate their net worth.After date 4 onward, as new banks enter and the banking system re-

capitalizes. Because asset prices are low initially, banks are able to earn highpro�ts and operate with high degrees of leverage. Eventually, bank equityreturns to its steady state levels, along with bank asset holdings and capitalasset values. How long this process takes depends on how quickly banks areable to build up their equity capital bases.18

18One subtle question is whether during a systematic run the depositors of an individualinsolvent bank might want to roll over their deposits until the bank regains solvency,assuming they can collectively agree to do so. We can show numerically the answer isno. What causes this strategy to unravel is that the banker will be tempted to divertassets: The bank franchise value from operating for a period with negative net worth isnot su¢ ciently high to prevent the incentive constraint from being violated. Given thedepositors of an individual bank cannot a¤ect aggregate conditions, they will be better o¤shutting down the insolvent bank and receiving the reduced payout instead of collectivelyrolling over their deposits. We would like to thank John Moore for raising this question.

21

Page 22: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

4 Anticipated Bank Runs

So far, we have analyzed the existence and properties of an equilibrium witha bank run when the run is not anticipated. We now consider what happens ifdepositors expect a bank run will occur with a positive probability in future.Appendix A provides a detailed analysis of this case. Here we highlight thedi¤erences from our baseline analysis.Suppose that pt is the probability households assign at t to a bank

run happening in t+1. (Shortly we will discuss how pt is determined.)When households anticipate bank run occurs with a positive probability,the promised rate of return on deposits Rt+1 of each bank from date t to t+1has to satisfy the household�s �rst order condition for deposits as:

1 = Rt+1Et�(1� pt)�t;t+1 + pt�

�t;t+1xt+1

�(33)

where ��t;t+1 = �Cht =Ch�t+1 is the household�s intertemporal marginal rate of

substitution conditional on a bank run at t+ 1. The depositor recovery ratext+1 in the event of a run now depends, on Rt+1 (as opposed to the risklessrate) as follows:

xt+1 = Min

�1;(Q�t+1 + Zt+1)k

bt

Rt+1dt

�= Min

�1;Rb�t+1Rt+1

�t�t � 1

�: (34)

Observe from equation (33) that Rt+1 is an increasing function of the like-lihood of run so long as Et

���t;t+1xt+1

�< Et(�t;t+1): When a run is more

likely, the bank must compensate its creditors with an increased promiseddeposit rate.The bank�s decision problem for the case of anticipated runs closely re-

sembles the baseline we studied earlier but with one key di¤erence. Thechoice of its leverage multiple �t(= Qkbt=nt) in�uences the deposit rate Rt+1the individual bank pays, whereas earlier it simply paid the riskless rate.From (33) and (34) ; we get

Rt+1 =1� ptEt

���t;t+1R

b�t+1

� �t�t�1

(1� pt)Et(�t;t+1): (35)

Observe that Rt+1 is a decreasing function of the leverage multiple since therecovery rate xt+1 is decreasing in �t: The bank must now factor in how it�s

22

Page 23: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

leverage decision a¤ects deposits costs, which in turn a¤ects accumulatedearnings nt (in the absence of a run):

nt = RbtQtkbt�1 �Rtdt�1: (36)

As before, the bank chooses its balance sheet�kbt ; dt

�to maximize the

objective Vt given by equation (16). The maximization is subject to theexisting constraints (14) and (15) ; the modi�ed expression for nt; (36) andthe constraint on Rt+1; (35) : Overall, the solution is very similar to thebaseline case except that now the likelihood of a run in�uences the bank�sbehavior.In particular, the leverage multiple remains the same increasing function

of the excess value of assets �t and the marginal cost of deposits �t; i.e.,�t = �t=(���t) (see equation (22)). However, unlike before, �t now dependson pt :

�t = �Etft+1[Rbt+1 �Rot+1 � pt(Rbt+1 �Rot+1Et(�

�t;t+1R

b�

t+1))]g; (37)

where Rot+1 � 1Et(�t;t+1)

is the riskless rate conditional on no bank run. Theexcess return �t is decreasing in pt. As a consequence, an increase in thebank run probability reduces the leverage multiple, e¤ectively tightening theleverage constraint. Intuitively, an increase in pt reduces the franchise valueof the bank (Vt = (�t�t+�t)nt), which tightens the incentive constraint givenby equations (19). (See the Appendix A for details).As earlier, if the leverage constraint is binding, total bank asset holdings

equal the product of the maximum leverage multiple and aggregate bank networth; i.e., QtKb

t = �tNt (see equation (23)). Aggregate bank net worthsimilarly depends on Rt+1 :

Nt+1 =

��[(Rbt+1 �Rt+1)�t +Rt+1]Nt +W b; if no bank run,

0; if run occurs.(38)

An increase in pt can reduce Nt+1 even if a run does not occur at t + 1: Itcan does so in two ways: �rst by raising the cost of funds Rt+1, and secondby reducing the leverage multiple �t.In sum, an increase in the perceived likelihood of a bank run has harmful

e¤ects on the economy even if a bank run does not materialize. It does so bycausing bank credit to contract, partly by reducing the maximum leverageratio and partly by causing aggregate net worth to shrink due to an increaseddeposit rate.

23

Page 24: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

We next turn to the issue of how the probability depositors assign to abank run is determined. In principle, a way to determine to pin down theprobability of a run is to use the global games approach developed by Morrisand Shin (1998) and applied to bank runs by Goldstein and Pauzner (2005).Under this approach, the run probabilities are tied to the fundamentals ofthe economy and bank run equilibria are unique outcomes as opposed tosunspots. Given the complexities involved, however, this approach has beenlimited largely to very simple two period models as opposed to an in�nitehorizon general equilibrium framework like ours. Instead we follow the spiritof the global games approach by postulating a reduced form that relates ptto the aggregate recovery rate xt, which is the key fundamental determiningwhether a bank run equilibrium exists.19 In particular we assume that theprobability depositors assign to a bank run happening in the subsequentperiod is a decreasing function of the expected recovery rate, as follows

pt =

�g(Et(xt+1)) with g0(�) < 0

0; if Et(xt+1) = 1:. (Assumption 1)

To be clear, under this formulation a bank run remains a sunspot outcome.However the probability pt of the "sunspot" depends in a natural way on thefundamental xt+1: In the numerical simulations that follow, we assume thatg takes the following simple linear form:

g(�) = 1� Et(xt+1): (39)

The dependency of the bank run probability on the recovery rate worksto amplify the e¤ects of aggregate disturbances to the economy, even beyondthe ampli�cation that comes from the conventional �nancial accelerator. Weillustrate this point with numerical simulations. We stick with the same cali-bration as in our baseline case (see Table 1). But we now allow for individualsto anticipate a run with probability pt, as determined by equations (Assump-tion 1) and (39). In addition, we suppose that if a run does occur, individualsstill use the same relations to determine the likelihood of a subsequent runas the banking system recovers after the run.Figure 5 reports the impulse responses to a negative shock to Zt for the

case where pt responds endogenously, given by the solid line in each panel.To isolate the e¤ect of the anticipation of the run, we suppose in this case

19We thank both Hyun Shin and an anonymous referee for suggesting this approach.

24

Page 25: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

that the run never actually occurs ex post. For comparison, the dotted linesreports the responses of the economy in the case where individuals attachzero probability of a bank run (as portrayed in Figure 3).In the wake of the negative Zt shock the run probability increases to two

percent. It does so because the associated weakening of banks balance sheetsand drop in liquidation prices induces a decline in the recovery rate. In turn,the increase in pt further weakens the economy. Unlike the baseline casewith a zero run probability, the deposit rate increases relative to the riskfreerate to compensate depositors for the run possibility. The increase in bankfunding costs then works to magnify the increase in bank lending rates (givenby the required return on bank assets), leading to an enhanced contractionof bank assets and deposits. For example, banks assets fall by more than�fty percent, as compared to twenty-�ve percent for the case where runs arenot anticipated. This additional decline is due to households shifting theirdeposits out of the banking system as a result of an increased run probability.In this way the model captures the "slow runs" on the shadow banking systemprior to the Lehmann collapse. Finally, the enhanced contraction of thebanking system due to the anticipated run magni�es the drop in net outputdue to the reduced intermediation e¢ ciency. Overall, even if a run does notoccur, the mere anticipation of a run induces harmful e¤ects to the economy.In Figure 6 we repeat the experiment, but this time we allow for a run to

occur in period 4. The purpose is to illustrate how the model can capture thepattern of a period of slow runs leading to a fast run that was a central featureof the recent �nancial crisis, as we discussed in the Introduction. Relative tothe case of Figure 4 where the ex post run is completely unanticipated, thereis an enhanced deterioration of �nancial conditions before the run. The risein pt following the shocks elevates spreads and enhances the out�ow bankassets prior to the run, as in the �rst few periods of the experiment in Figure5. The ex post run still produces a sharp rise in spreads and contraction inbank intermediation. But the signs of stress leading up to the collapse areclearer than in the case of unanticipated runs, in way that is consistent withthe data.In particular, in Figure 7 we show that the simple experiment of Fig-

ure 6 can capture some of the key features of �nancial stress leading up toand through the Lehmann collapse. The top panel plots a representativecredit spread, speci�cally the excess bond premium by Gilchrist and Zakres-jek (2012) over the period 2007Q2 to 2010Q2 versus the value implied bythe model experiment, while the bottom panel does the same for the market

25

Page 26: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

value of bank equity, measure by the S&P �nancial index. This measure ofbank equity corresponds to the franchise value Vt in our model: We do nottry to capture the entire run-up to the Lehmann collapse. Instead, the modeleconomy starts in 2007Q4 and the �rst shock hits in 2008Q1, the time of theBear Stearns fallout. The ex post run then occurs in 2008Q4, the time of theLehmann collapse and the collapse of the shadow banking system along withit. Overall, the model reasonably captures the temporal pattern of creditspreads and bank equity over the crisis. Following the peak of the crisis,credit spreads in the data decline faster than in the model, likely re�ectingthe variety of interventions by the Federal Reserve and Treasury to rescuethe banking system that are not present in the model.

5 Policies to Contain Financial Fragility

We turn next to government �nancial policy. Because our framework incor-porates both conventional �nancial accelerator e¤ects and the possibility ofsunspot runs, our analysis has several new insights to o¤er. Given spaceconsiderations, we restrict attention to qualitative insights here and deferquantitative policy analysis to future research. We discuss both ex ante reg-ulatory policies designed to reduce the likelihood of a �nancial crisis and expost policies a central bank might take during a crisis.We start on the "ex ante" side, beginning with deposit insurance. A

role for deposit insurance is perhaps the central policy insight that emergesfrom Diamond and Dybvig (1983). The deposit insurance eliminates anyindividual depositor�s incentive to run, thus eliminating the sunspot bankrun equilibrium. If all goes well, further, the deposit insurer never has to payin equilibrium. In our framework, however, deposit insurance does not workdue to moral hazard, an ingredient that is missing from Diamond and Dybvig.In particular, the incentive problem that induces an endogenous balance sheetconstraint on banks implies that if the government were to protect deposits,banks would simply increase their leverage and divert funds.A complementary consideration is that deposit insurance is usually con-

sidered for commercial banks which are heavily regulated in part to o¤setthe moral hazard from government protection. However, as we saw duringthe recent crisis and as is true in our model, vulnerability to runs and relateddistress pertain to any �nancial institutions that rely heavily on short term

26

Page 27: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

liabilities to hold partially illiquid assets, including investment banks andmoney market mutual funds. Extending deposit insurance to these institu-tions would be highly problematic for incentive reasons.An alternative ex ante policy is to impose capital requirements. In the

context of our model, this boils down to setting a regulatory maximum forthe leverage multiple �t that is below the laissez-faire value. A number ofpapers have analyzed capital requirements, though usually in the context of�nancial accelerator models (e.g. Lorenzoni (2008), Bianchi (2011), Chariand Kehoe (2014), and Gertler, Kiyotaki and Queralto (2012)). In theseframeworks, individual borrowers do not take into account the impact oftheir own leverage decisions on the vulnerability of the system as a whole.Thus the free market leverage multiple is larger than the social optimum.Capital requirements can o¤set such distortion.A similar rationale for capital requirements presents in our model: Indi-

vidual banks do not take into an account the e¤ect of their leverage decisionson the extent of asset �resales in distress states, leading to excessive leveragein the competitive equilibrium. In our model, however, there is an addi-tional consideration due to link between leverage and the possibility of runs.In particular, let xt+1 be the aggregate depositor recovery rate given thegovernment imposes a regulatory leverage multiple �t below the laissez-fairevalue �t:

xt+1 =Min

�1;Rb�t+1Rt+1

�t�t � 1

�(40)

Given the inverse link between the recovery rate and the likelihood of a run,reducing the leverage multiple by regulation can lower the possibility of run.In principle, this policy can eliminate the possibility of runs altogether bypushing the recovery rate to unity.There is of course a tradeo¤: While tightening the capital requirement

may reduce vulnerability to runs, it does so by reducing bank intermediation.This contracts economic activity by raising the overall cost of capital, sincehouseholds now directly hold a greater share of capital. Complicating mattersis that the optimal capital requirement is likely to depend on the state ofthe economy. For example the laissez-faire leverage multiple increases inrecessions since �t is increasing in excess returns (since Figure 3 and equation(22)). While the socially optimal �t may lie below its laissez-faire value,it is likely to be countercyclical.20 Accordingly, a �xed regulatory capital

20Gertler, Kiyotaki and Queralto (2012) show that the socially optimal leverage multiple

27

Page 28: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

requirement may lead to an excessive contraction in bank lending during arecession.In addition to the ex ante policies, our model suggests a role for ex post

lender of the last resort policies in reducing vulnerability to runs. As dis-cussed in Gertler and Karadi (2011) and Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011), insituations where private intermediaries are �nancing constrained, there isscope for interventions in credit markets, even if the central bank is less e¢ -cient at intermediating credit than private banks. The advantage the centralbank has is that it is not balance-sheet constrained: it can issue interest-bearing reserves or sell other short term government debt to provide credit.It can do so either directly by purchasing assets (e.g. the Federal Reserve�spurchases of agency mortgage-backed securities beginning in early 2009) orindirectly by lending funds to banks and taking loans made by these banksas collateral (e.g. the commercial paper funding facility the Fed set up inthe wake of the collapse of this market in October 2008). These central bankinterventions in a �nancial crises can support asset prices and reduce creditspreads, thereby stimulating the economy.A new insight from the current framework is that lender of the last resort

policies can have "ex ante" bene�ts by improving the liquidity of secondarymarkets. To the extent market participants understand ahead of time thatthese policies are available for use in a crisis, these polices can reduce the like-lihood of damaging runs, even without having to be put to use. In particular,lender of the last resort policies push up the liquidation price in the event ofrun Q�t+1, which raises the return on bank assets conditional on a run R

b�t+1.

The perceived recovery rate increases (as equation (40) indicates), reducingthe likelihood of a run. Intuitively, by making secondary markets more liq-uid in the event of run, the central bank reduces the chances depositors willperceive they might lose in the event of a run. One possible side-e¤ect of thispolicy is that a reduction in the run probability will increase bank leverage inequilibrium, possibly making the system more vulnerable to conventional �-nancial accelerator e¤ects, everything else equal. Quantitative investigationsare needed to design optimal mix of these ex ante and ex post policies.

is indeed countercyclical in a model with similar features to the current one, thoughwithout the possibility of runs.

28

Page 29: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

6 Conclusion

We have developed a macroeconomic model to integrate the "macroeco-nomic" approach which stresses �nancial accelerator e¤ects with the "mi-croeconomic" one which stresses bank liquidity mismatch and runs. Weillustrated how combining the two approaches is useful for characterizingbanking instability. For example, a recession that constrains bank lendingdue to conventional �nancial accelerator e¤ects also opens up the possibilityof runs due to the associated weakening of balances sheets and reduced liq-uidity of secondary markets for bank assets. In addition, anticipated bankruns can be harmful even if the runs do not actually occur ex post. Indeed,we argue that allowing for a period of anticipation of a runs prior to an actualrun is useful to characterize how the banking distress played out in the GreatRecession up to and through the collapse of the shadow banking system.In addition to pursuing a quantitative policy analysis, there are two other

areas that warrant further investigation. The �rst involves modeling beliefsof bank run probabilities. Due to the complexity of our model, we haveused a simple reduced form approach that relates the probability of runto the fundamentals that determine the existence of a run equilibrium. Itwould be useful to explore an alternative approach that tightly ties downbeliefs. Secondly, the banks we have modeled correspond best to the lightlyregulated shadow banking sector which was at the center of the instabilityof the recent �nancial crisis. In doing so we abstracted from the rest of the�nancial intermediary system. For example, we did not include commercialbanks which were tightly regulated and did not experience the same kinds ofruns as did the shadow banks. A complete description of the banking criseswill require allowing for a richer description of the �nancial system.

29

Page 30: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

7 Appendix

7.1 Appendix A: Details of Anticipated Bank Run Case

This appendix describes the global condition for the bank�s optimizationproblem under anticipated bank runs, as laid out in Section 4. We showin particular that the local solution described in the text is in fact a globalsolution. We show that the bank always has the incentive to raise its leverageto the point where the incentive constraint is binding (equation 22 in thetext.) It has no incentive restrict leverage in order to be able to operative inthe event of bank run when all other banks have failed.First some preliminaries before turning to the optimization problem:

When an individual bank chooses its leverage multiple �t, the payo¤ to de-positors per unit in the next period equals

Rt+1 =Min

�Rt+1;

(Zt+1 +Qt+1)kbt

dt

�=Min

�Rt+1; R

bt+1

�t�t � 1

�:

The �rst order conditions of the household for this bank implies

1 = Et

�(1� �t+1)�t;t+1Rt+1 + �t+1�

�t;t+1Min

�Rt+1; R

b�t+1

�t�t � 1

��(41)

where Rt+1 is the promised rate of return on deposit of this bank, and �t+1is the indicator function which is equal to 1 if the run occurs and equal to 0otherwise.The bank chooses its balance sheet

�kbt ; dt

�to maximize the objective

Vt subject to the existing constraints (14; 15; 16; 36) and the constraint onthe promised rate of return on deposits (41) : Because the objective andconstraints of the bank are constant returns to scale, we can rewrite thebank�s problem as choosing the leverage multiple �t to maximize the valueper unit of net worth as follows

t =Vtnt= max

�t�Et

�(1� � + � t+1)

nt+1nt

�= max

�t�Etf(1� �t+1)t+1[(R

bt+1 �Rt+1)�t +Rt+1]

+�t+1�t+1Max[0; (Rb�t+1 �Rt+1)�t +Rt+1]g

subject to the incentive constraint t � ��t; where �t+1 and t+1 are the

marginal value of net worth 1� � + � t+1 with and without a bank run.

30

Page 31: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

In order to analyze further the individual bank�s choice under the antici-pated run, we consider an economy in which uncertainty about the aggregateproductivity is negligible compared to the uncertainty about a bank run infuture. In particular, we assume the deviation of log of aggregate produc-tivity from the steady state level follows a deterministic AR(1) process fromdate t onward without any further shock:

lnZt+i � lnZ = �(lnZt+i�1 � lnZ); for all i = 1; 2; ::: (42)

Under the local optimum, the bank chooses its leverage multiple to satisfythe incentive constraint (22). We now consider whether an individual bankmight have an incentive to deviate by choosing a di¤erent value of �t: UnderAssumption 1, with a deterministic process of aggregate productivity, wehave perfect foresight about aggregate variables contingent on whether bankrun occurs or not at each date. Then, using the expression for the depositorrecovery rate xt+1 (equation (29)), we can �nd a threshold value for leveragemultiple b�t below which the individual bank does not default during a bankrun at date t+1

Rft+1 = Rb�t+1b�tb�t � 1 :b�t is the value of �t at which the recovery rate is one, where Rft+1 is the

riskfree rate which satis�es

1 = Rft+1�(1� pt)Et(�t;t+1) + ptEt(�

�t;t+1)

�:

Now consider the bank�s choice when the leverage multiplier is below andabove b�t.When this bank has a leverage multiple smaller than b�t; it does not default

during a systemic bank run and its Tobin�s Q is

t = �(1� pt)Et

nt+1

h(Rbt+1 �Rft+1)�t +Rft+1

io+�ptEt

n�t+1

h(Rb�t+1 �Rft+1)�t +Rft+1

io: (43)

Thus Tobin�s Q increases with the leverage multiple if and only if

�t = (1� pt)Et[�t+1(Rbt+1 �Rft+1)] + ptEt[�

�t+1(R

b�t+1 �Rft+1)] > 0: (44)

Thus, if the global condition (44) is satis�ed (i.e. �t > 0 in this case), thenbank has no incentive to cut back leverage to survive a bank run. Whenever

31

Page 32: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

�t < b�t, the bank has an incentive to raise leverage to the point in whicheither the incentive constraint is binding or � = b�t.When the leverage is above this critical level b�t; this bank will default

during a bank run and the promised rate of return satis�es

1 = (1� pt)Et(�t;t+1)Rt+1 + ptEt

���t;t+1R

b�t+1

�t�t � 1

�;

or

Rt+1 =1� ptEt

���t;t+1R

b�t+1

� �t�t�1

(1� pt)Et(�t;t+1);

as (35) in the text. Tobin�s Q for the bank is

t = �(1� pt)Et

(t+1

Rbt+1�t �

�t � 1� �tptEt���t;t+1R

b�t+1

�(1� pt)Et(�t;t+1)

!);

Thus Tobin�s Q increases with the leverage multiple if and only if

�t = �Etft+1[Rbt+1 �Rot+1 � pt(Rbt+1 �Rot+1Et(�

�t;t+1R

b�

t+1))]g > 0; (45)

where, as in equation (37) in the text Rot+1 =1

Et(�t;t+1). If equation (45) is

satis�ed, then whenever �t � b�t, the bank will raise the leverage multiple tothe point where the incentive constraint is binding.We verify numerically that the two global conditions (44; 45) are satis�ed

in our equilibrium, which implies that the local optimum we described in thetext is in fact a global optimum. Thus banks always choose the maximumleverage multiple in equilibrium. Intuitively, although the bank can earn highreturns in the wake of the bank run, the low probability of a bank run makesit not worthwhile to reduce earnings in the no run case. The result is robustto allowing the bank to hold deposits in other banks as opposed to the riskycapital.

7.2 Appendix B: Household liquidity risks

Up to this point we have simply assumed that banks engage in maturitymismatch by issuing non-contingent one period deposits despite holding riskylong maturity assets. We now motivate why banks might issue liquid shortterm deposits. In the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig (1983), we do so by

32

Page 33: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

introducing idiosyncratic household liquidity risks, which creates a desire byhouseholds for demandable debt. We do not derive these types of depositsfrom an explicit contracting exercise. However, we think that a scenariowith liquidity risks moves us one step closer to understanding why banksissue liquid deposits despite having partially illiquid assets.As before, we assume that there is a continuum of measure unity of house-

holds. To keep the heterogeneity introduced by having independent liquidityrisks manageable, we further assume that each household consists of a con-tinuum of unit measure individual members.Each member of the representative household has a need for emergency

expenditures within the period with probability �. At the same time, be-cause the household has a continuum of members, exactly the fraction � hasa need for emergency consumption. An individual family member can onlyacquire emergency consumption from another family, not from his or her ownfamily. Conversely, drawing from its endowment, the family sells emergencyconsumption to individuals from other families.In particular, let cmt be emergency consumption by an individual member,

with �cmt = Cmt being the total emergency consumption by the family. Foran individual with emergency consumption needs, period utility is given by

logCht + � log cmt ;

where Cht is regular consumption. For family members that do not need tomake emergency expenditures, period utility is given simply by

logCht :

Because they are sudden, we assume that demand deposits at banks arenecessary to make emergency expenditures above a certain threshold.The timing of events is as follows: At the beginning of period t; before

the realization of the liquidity risk during period t, the household choosesCht and the allocation of its portfolio between bank deposits Dt and directlyheld capital Kh

t: subject to the �ow-of fund constraint:

Cht +Dt +QtKht + f(Kh

t ) = RtDt�1 + (Zt +Qt)Kht�1 + ZtW

h � Cm

t ;

where the last term Cm

t is the sales of household endowment to the otherfamilies needing emergency consumption (which is not realized yet at thebeginning of period). The household plans the date-t regular consumption

33

Page 34: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

�Cht�to be the same for every member since all members of the household

are identical ex ante and utility is separable in Cht and cmt . After choosing

the total level of deposits, the household divides them evenly amongst itsmembers. During period t, an individual member has access only to his orher own deposits at the time the liquidity risk is realized. Those having tomake emergency expenditures above some threshold cm must �nance themfrom their deposits accounts at the beginning of t;21

cmt � cm � Dt: (46)

Think of cm as the amount of emergency expenditure that can be arrangedthrough credit as opposed to deposits.22 After the realization of the liquidityshock, individuals with excess deposits simply return them to the house-hold. Under the symmetric equilibrium, the expected sales of householdendowment to meet the emergency expenditure of the other households C

m

t

is equal to the emergency expenditure of the representative household �cmt ;and deposits at the end of period D0

t are

D0t = �(Dt � cmt ) + (1� �)Dt + C

m

t = Dt;

and equal to the deposit at the beginning of period. Thus the budget con-straint of the household is given simply by

Cht + �cmt +Dt +QtKht + f(Kh

t ) = RtDt�1 + (Zt +Qt)Kht�1 + ZtW

h: (47)

The next sequence of optimization then begins at the beginning of periodt+ 1.We can express the formal decision problem of the household with liquid-

ity risks as follows:

Ut(Dt�1; Kht�1) = max

Cht ;cmt ;Dt;K

ht

f(logCht + �� log cmt + �Et[Ut+1(Dt; Kht )]g

subject to the budget constraint (47) and the liquidity constraint (46).

21One can think each member carrying a deposit certi�cate of the amount Dt. Eachfurther is unable to make use of the deposit certi�cates of the other members of the familyfor his or her emergency consumption because they are spacially separated.22We allow for cm so that households can make some emergency expenditures in a bank

run equilibrium, which prevents the marginal utility of cm from going to in�nity.

34

Page 35: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Let �t be the Lagrangian multiplier on the liquidity constraint. Then the�rst order conditions for deposits Dt and emergency expenditures are givenby:

Etf�t;t+1Rt+1g+ ��t1=Cht

= 1; (48)

cmt� 1

Cht= �t: (49)

The multiplier on the liquidity constraint �t is equal to the gap between themarginal utility of emergency consumption and regular consumption for ahousehold member who experiences a liquidity shock. Observe that if theliquidity constraint binds, there is a relative shortage of the liquid asset,which pushes down the deposit rate, everything else equal, as equation (48)suggests.The �rst order condition for the households choice of direct capital hold-

ing is the same as in the case without liquidity risks (see equation (9)). Thedecision problem for banks is also the same, as are the conditions for aggre-gate bank behavior.In the aggregate (and after using the bank funding condition to eliminate

deposits), the liquidity constraint becomes:

Cmt � �cm � �(QtKbt �Nt):

Given that households are now making emergency expenditures, the relationfor uses of output becomes

Yt = Cht + Cmt + Cbt + f(Kht ): (50)

Otherwise, the remaining equations that determine the equilibrium withoutliquidity risks (absent bank runs) also applies in this case.Importantly the condition for a bank run (equation (28)) also remains

unchanged. The calculation of the liquidation asset price Q�t is only slightlydi¤erent from (31), since households are now making emergency expenditurescmt ; in addition to consuming C

ht :

7.3 Appendix C: Computation

Here we describe how we compute impulse responses to shocks to Zt; wherebank runs can occur. We assume the shock comes in the �rst period and

35

Page 36: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

then Zt obeys a deterministic path back to steady state, following the �rstorder process (42). Accordingly, our computational procedures boils down tocomputing nonlinear perfect foresight paths that allow for sunspot equilibriato arise.We describe our procedure for the case where a single bank run occurs

before the economy returns to steady state, though it is straightforward togeneralize to the case of multiple bank runs. In particular, suppose theeconomy starts in a no-bank run equilibrium in the steady state and thenis hit with a negative shock to Zt at t = 1: It stays in the no-bank runequilibrium until t� when a bank run occurs, assuming the condition (28) fora bank run equilibrium is met. After the bank run it then returns to theno-bank run equilibrium until it converges back to the steady state. Supposefurther that after T periods from the initial shock (either productivity shockor sunspot shock) the economy is back to steady state. Let fZtgTt=1 be theexogenous path of Zt over this period and let fXtgt

�+Tt=1 be the path of the

vector of endogenous variables Xt.Then there are three steps to computing the response of the economy

to the run experiment, which involve working backwards: First, one needsto calculate the saddle path of the economy from the period after the runhappens back to its steady state, i.e. fXtgt

�+Tt=t�+1. Second, given fXtgt

�+Tt=t�+1,

and given that a run occurs at t�, one can then computeXt� ; the values of theendogenous variables at the time of the run. Third, one needs to compute thesaddle path of the economy starting from the initial shock in t = 1 back tothe steady state and then select the �rst t� � 1 elements to obtain fXtgt

��1t=1 .

(The elements of this saddle path from from t� to T can be ignored since therun happens at t�:)What aids in the computation of the three pieces of the impulse is that

we know the initial value of the endogenous state. For the initial piece, theendogenous state begins at its steady state value. For the second piece, thebank run at date t, Nt = 0: For the �nal piece, which begins the period afterthe run, Nt depends on the endowment of entering bankers and Kh

t�1 = 1and Dt�1 = 0.The details of the algorithm will be di¤erent depending on whether the

run is anticipated or not. Below we brie�y explain the implementation of thealgorithm in these two cases.

36

Page 37: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

7.3.1 Unanticipated Run

1. Compute fXtgt�+Tt=t�+1

Let T be a time after which the system is assumed to be back in steadystate. Let fXtgt

�+T+1t=t�+1 be the solution of the system given by the equi-

librium equations at each t = t� + 1; ::::; t� + T

Cht +(1� �)

�(Nt �W ) +

2

�Kht

�2= Zt + ZtW

h +W

Qt + �Kht = �

�ChtCht+1

(Zt+1 +Qt+1)

�1 = �

�ChtCht+1

Rt+1

�Qt�1�Kh

t

�= �tNt

��t = ��1� � + ���t+1

� ��t

�(Zt+1 +Qt+1)

Qt�Rt+1

�+Rt+1

�Qt�1�Kh

t

�= Nt +Dt

Nt = ��(Zt +Qt)

�1�Kh

t�1��Dt�1Rt

�+W + "t

where "t = 0 for t 6= t� and "t�+1 = �W (which ensures that at Nt�+1 =(1 + �)W ):

In addition we have the terminal condition Xt�+T+1 = XSS as well asthe initial conditions for the state given by Kh

t� = 1 and Dt� = 0.

2. Compute Xt� fromCht� +

2= Zt� + Zt�W

h

Qt� + � = �

�Cht�

Cht�+1(Zt�+1 +Qt�+1)

�1 = �

�Cht�

Cht�+1Rt�+1

�Kht� = 1

Nt� = 0

Dt� = 0:

37

Page 38: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

3. Compute fXtgt��1t=1

Let fX 0tgT+1t=1 be the solution of

Cht +(1� �)

�(Nt �W ) +

2

�Kht

�2= Zt + ZtW

h +W

Qt + �Kht = �

�ChtCht+1

(Zt+1 +Qt+1)

�1 = �

�ChtCht+1

Rt+1

�Qt�1�Kh

t

�= �tNt

��t = ��1� � + ���t+1

� ��t

�(Zt+1 +Qt+1)

Qt�Rt+1

�+Rt+1

�Qt�1�Kh

t

�= Nt +Dt

Nt = ��(Zt +Qt)

�1�Kh

t�1��Dt�1Rt

�+W

X 0T+1 = XSS

given initial conditions for the state given by Kh0 = Kh;SS, D0 = DSS

and R1 = RSS. Then fXtgt��1t=1 = fX 0

tgt��1t=1 . Note that the run never

occurs in the neighborhood of the steady state and the run occurs atmost once in our example. Thus we restrict the attention to t�+T � 2T:

7.3.2 Anticipated Run

We now allow for an endogenously determined probability of a run pt, asdescribed in the text. This means allowing for an additional equation forpt: In addition, in order to perform steps 1 and 3 in this case, we need tocompute the values households� consumption and asset prices that wouldmaterialize if the run happened at each time t:This is because when thereis a probability of a run, consumption and asset prices depend on what isexpected to happen if a run actually occurs in the subsequent period.First note that the endogenous state variables at t+1 are reset fresh when

a run occurs at date t as

Kht = 1; Dt = 0; and Nt+1 = (1 + �)W b:

38

Page 39: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

The only other state variable is the exogenous aggregate productivity Zt+1:(Our economy has endogenous "amnesia" after the run.) Hence, we canalways compute the saddle path of the economy back to steady state aftera run occurs at t by initializing the endogenous state as above and pickingthe appropriate path for the exogenous state, i.e. (Zs)

t+Ts=t+1 : We denote the

endogenous variable vector at date s when a run occurs at t along such pathas ftX��

s gt+Ts=t+1 :

Secondly, given the saddle path after the date-t bank run, we can computeasset price and household consumption when a run occurs at date t as afunction of Zt as

Q�t = Q�(Zt) and Ch�t = Ch�(Zt):

Let the endogenous variable vector that includes that at the time of run asftX��

s gt+Ts=t . Note that all the subsequent endogenous variable vector is only

a function of Zs; the date of the last run t and the present date s:Basic Step We assume that at T + 1 the productivity is back in steady

state and Zt = ZSS for t � T + 1: Then we learn that the asset price andhousehold consumption when the run occurs at date t � T + 1 are numbersas

Q�t = Q�(ZSS); Ch�t = Ch��ZSS

�, for all t � T + 1:

We also learn all the subsequent endogenous variable vector only dependsupon the time since the last run as

fJX��t g

J+Tt=J = fJ+1X��

t gJ+1+Tt=J+1 � f���(t� J)gTt�J=0

for J � T + 1:We can now compute Q�

�ZSS

�, Ch�

�ZSS

�and fJX��

t gJ+Tt=J = f���(t �

J)gTt�J=0 for J � T +1:We focus on parametrizations such that a run is notpossible in steady state, although the technique, with minor modi�cations,is easily applicable to cases in which a run can occur also in steady state.

Q��ZSS

�, C�h

�ZSS

�and fJX��

t gJ+Tt=J+1 are the solution of the following

system of equations at each t = J + 1; :::; J + T:

pt = 1�min(�

ZSS +Q��ZSS

�� �1�Kh

t

��Rt+1Dt

; 1

)

Cht +(1� �)

�(Nt �W ) +

2

�Kht

�2= ZSS + ZSSW h +W

39

Page 40: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Qt+�Kht = �

�(1� pt)

ChtCht+1

�ZSS +Qt+1

�+ pt

ChtCh� (ZSS)

�ZSS +Q�

�ZSS

���

1 = � �Rt+1

"(1� pt)

ChtCht+1

+ ptCht

Ch� (ZSS)min

(�Zt+1 +Q�

�ZSS

�� �1�Kh

t

��Rt+1Dt

; 1

)#Qt�1�Kh

t

�= �tNt

��t = (1� pt)��1� � + ���t+1

� ��t

�(Zt+1 +Qt+1)

Qt� �Rt+1

�+ �Rt+1

�Qt�1�Kh

t

�= Nt +Dt

Nt = ��(Zt +Qt)

�1�Kh

t

��Dt�1 �Rt

�+W + "t

Ch��ZSS

�+�

2= ZSS + ZSSW h

Q��ZSS

�+ � = �

"Ch�

�ZSS

�ChJ+1(Z

SS)

�ZSS +QJ+1(Z

SS)�#;

and the terminal condition

JX��J+T+1 = XSS;

given initial conditions for the state given by KhJ = 1 and DJ = 0. The

variable "t = 0 for t 6= J + 1 and "J+1 = �W:Inductive Step: From the Basic Step, we have Q�

�ZSS

�, Ch�

�ZSS

�and

fJX��t g

J+Tt=J for J � T + 1: We �nd the endogenous variables after a bank

run by solving inductively for J = T; T � 1; :::; 1: Given fQ� (Zt)gJ+T+1t=J+1 ,�Ch� (Zt)

J+T+1t=J+1

and fJ+1X��t g

J+Tt=J+1 ; we �nd fQ� (Zt)g

J+Tt=J ,

�Ch� (Zt)

J+Tt=J

and fJX��t g

J+T�1t=J ; for J = 1; 2; :::; T:

Let fJX��t g

J+T+1t=J+1 be the solution of the system given by the equilibrium

equations at each t = J + 1; :::; J + T + 1

pt = 1�min((Zt+1 +Q� (Zt+1))

�1�Kh

t

��Rt+1Dt

; 1

)

Cht +(1� �)

�(Nt �W ) +

2

�Kht

�2= Zt + ZtW

h +W

Qt+�Kht = �

�(1� pt)

ChtCht+1

(Zt+1 +Qt+1) + ptCht

C� (Zt+1)(Zt+1 +Q� (Zt+1))

�40

Page 41: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

1 = � �Rt+1

"(1� pt)

ChtCht+1

+ ptCht

C�h (Zt+1)min

((Zt+1 +Q� (Zt+1))

�1�Kh

t

��Rt+1Dt

; 1

)#Qt�1�Kh

t

�= �tNt

��t = (1� pt)��1� � + ���t+1

� ��t

�(Zt+1 +Qt+1)

Qt� �Rt+1

�+ �Rt+1

�Qt�1�Kh

t

�= Nt +Dt

Nt = ��(Zt +Qt)

�1�Kh

t

��Dt�1 �Rt

�+W + "t

and the terminal condition

JXJ+T+1 = XSS

given initial conditions for the state given by KhJ = 1 and DJ = 0. The

variable "t = 0 for t 6= J + 1 and "J+1 = �W: Here Ch� (Zt+1) and Q� (Zt+1)are the elements of J+1X��

J+1 in the previous iteration.Find Q� (ZJ) and Ch� (ZJ) from

Ch� (ZJ) +�

2= ZJ + ZJW

h

Q� (ZJ) + � = �

�Ch� (ZJ)

Ch�� (ZJ+1)(ZJ+1 +Q�� (ZJ+1))

�where Ch�� (ZJ+1) and Q�� (ZJ+1) are elements of JX��

J+1: Use Q� (ZJ) and

Ch� (ZJ) and the other obvious values to form JX��J :

This procedure yields fQ� (Zt)gTt=1�Ch� (Zt)

Tt=1

andnfJX��

t gJ+Tt=J

oTJ=1

:

Given these we have fXtgTt=t� = ft�X��t g

Tt=t� when a run actually occurs at

t�; and step 3; appropriately modi�ed in order to account for the endogenousprobability of a run, yields fXtgt

t=1.

41

Page 42: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

References

[1] Adrian, T., Colla, P., and Shin, H., 2012. Which Financial Frictions?Paring the Evidence from Financial Crisis of 2007-9. Forthcoming inNBER Macroeconomic Annual.

[2] Allen, F., and Gale, D., 2007. Understanding Financial Crises. OxfordUniversity Press.

[3] Angeloni, I., and E. Faia, 2013, Capital Regulation and Monetary Policywith Fragile Banks, Journal of Monetary Policy 60, 3111-382.

[4] Bernanke, B., 2010. Causes of the Recent Financial and Economic Crisis.Statement before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, Washington,September 2.

[5] Bernanke, B., and Gertler, M., 1989. Agency Costs, Net Worth andBusiness Fluctuations. American Economic Review 79, 14-31.

[6] Bianchi, J., 2011. Overborrowing and Systemic Externalities in the Busi-ness Cycle. American Economic Review 101, 3400-3426.

[7] Boissay F., F. Collard, and F. Smets, 2013, Booms and Systemic Bank-ing Crises, mimeo.

[8] Brunnermeier, M. K., and Pedersen, L., 2009. Market Liquidity andFunding Liquidity. Review of Financial Studies 22, 2201-2238.

[9] Brunnermeier, M. K., and Sannikov, Y., 2014. A Macroeconomic Modelwith a Financial Sector. American Economic Review 104, 379-421.

[10] Cole, H. and T. Kehoe, 2000, Self-ful�lling Debt Crises, Review of Eco-nomic Studies 67, 91-161/

[11] Cooper, R. and T. Ross, 1998, Bank Runs: Liquidity Costs and Invest-ment Distortions, Journal of Monetary Economics 41, 27-38.

[12] Diamond, D., and Dybvig, P., 1983. Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, andLiquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91, 401-419.

[13] Ennis, H. and T. Keister, 2003, Economic Growth, Liquidity and BankRuns, Journal of Economic Theory 109, 220-245.

42

Page 43: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

[14] Farmer, R., 1999. The Macroeconomics of Self-Ful�lling Prophecies.MIT Press.

[15] Friedman, M., and Schwartz, A., 1963. A Monetary History of theUnited States, 1867-1960. Princeton University Press.

[16] Gertler, M., and Karadi, P., 2011. A Model of Unconventional MonetaryPolicy, Journal of Monetary Economics, January.

[17] Gertler, M., and Kiyotaki, N., 2010. Financial Intermediation and CreditPolicy in Business Cycle Analysis. In Friedman, B., and Woodford,M. (Eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam,Netherlands.

[18] Gertler, M., Kiyotaki, N., and Queralto, A., 2012. Financial Crises, BankRisk Exposure and Government Financial Policy, Journal of MonetaryEconomics 59, S17-S34.

[19] Gilchrist, S., and E. Zakresjek. 2012. Credit Spread and Business CycleFluctuations, American Economic Review.

[20] Goldstein, I., and A. Pauzner. 2005. Demand-Deposit Contracts and theProbability of Bank Runs. Journal of Finance 60, 1293-1327.

[21] Gorton, G., 2010. Slapped by the Invisible Hand: The Panic of 2007.Oxford University Press.

[22] He, Z. and A. Krishnamurthy, 2013, Intermediary Asset Pricing, Amer-ican Economic Review.

[23] Holmstrom, B. and J. Tirole, 2011. Inside and Outside Liquidity. MITPress.

[24] Kiyotaki, N., and Moore, J., 1997. Credit Cycles. Journal of PoliticalEconomy 105, 211-248.

[25] Krishnamurthy, A., S. Nagel and D. Orlov. 2014. Seizing Up Repo. Jour-nal of Finance. Forthcoming.

[26] Lorenzoni, G., 2008. Ine¢ cient Credit Boom. Review of Economic Stud-ies 75, 809-833.

43

Page 44: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

[27] Martin, A., D. Skeie and E.L. Von Thadden. Repo Runs. Mimeo, FederalReserve Bank of New York.

[28] Morris, Stephen and Hyun Shin. 1998. Unique Equilibrium in a Model ofSelf-Ful�lling Currency Attacks. American Economic Review 88, 587-97.

[29] Phillipon, T. 2013. Has the U.S. Finance Industry Become Less E¢ cient?

[30] Robatto, R. 2013, Financial Crises and Systematic Bank Runs in a Dy-namic Model of Banking, mimeo, University of Chicago.

[31] Uhlig, H., 2010, A Model of a Systemic Bank Run, Journal of MonetaryEconomics 57, 78-96.

44

Page 45: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Table 1: ParametersBaseline Model

� 0.99 Discount rate� 0.95 Bankers survival probability� 0.19 Seizure rate� 0.008 Household managerial cost� 0.95 Serial correlation of productivity shockZ 0.0126 Steady state productivity!b 0.0011 Bankers endowment!h 0.045 Household endowment

1

Page 46: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

Table 2: Steady State ValuesSteady State Values

BaselineK 1Q 1ch 0.055cb 0.0036Kh 0.31Kb 0.69� 10Rk 1.0504Rh 1.0404R 1.0404

2

Page 47: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

1

Figure 1: Timing

Page 48: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2Figure 2: Run Threshold

¡1

¤

B

Negative Z-shock

ANo Run-EquilibriumPossible

Run-EquilibriumPossible

Page 49: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

0 20 40-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0z

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0y

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0kb

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0Q

%

from

ss

0 20 400

2

4

6

8x 10-3 ERb-R

Ann.

fr

om s

s

0 20 40-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0n

%

from

ss

0 20 400

2

4

6

8x 10-3 R

Quarters

Ann.

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.03

-0.02

-0.01

0ch

Quarters

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0cb

Quarters

%

from

ss

FIGURE 3: A Recession in the Baseline Model; No Bank Run Case

Page 50: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

0 20 40-0.2

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0y

%

from

ss

0 20 40-1

-0.5

0kb

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.2

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0Q

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.01

0

0.01

0.02RUN

0 20 40-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0Q*

%

from

ss

0 20 40-2

0

2

4

6*

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1ch

Quarters

%

from

ss

0 20 40-1

-0.5

0cb

Quarters

%

from

ss

No Run Recession unanticipated run

0 20 400

0.01

0.02

0.03ERb-R

Quarters

Ann.

fr

om s

s

Figure 4: Ex-Post Bank Run in the Baseline Model

Page 51: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

0 20 400

0.01

0.02

0.03p

fro

m s

s

0 20 40-0.08

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0y

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0kb

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.1

-0.05

0Q

%

from

ss

0 20 400

0.5

1

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0n

%

from

ss

0 20 400

0.005

0.01

0.015ERb-Rd

Quarters

Ann.

fr

om s

s

0 20 400

1

2x 10-3 Rd-Rfree

Quarters

Ann.

fr

om s

s

Recession with positive probability of run No Run Recession

0 20 400

2

4

6

8x 10-3 Rfree

Quarters

Ann.

%

from

ss

Figure 5: Recession with positive probability of a run

Page 52: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

0 20 400

0.01

0.02

0.03p

fro

m s

s

0 20 40-0.2

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0y

%

from

ss

0 20 40-1

-0.5

0kb

%

from

ss

0 20 40-0.2

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0Q

%

from

ss

0 20 40-5

0

5

10

%

from

ss

0 20 40-1.5

-1

-0.5

0n

%

from

ss

0 20 400

0.01

0.02

0.03ERb-Rd

Quarters

Ann.

fr

om s

s

0 20 400

0.5

1

1.5

2x 10-3 Rd-Rfree

Quarters

Ann.

fr

om s

s

0 20 40-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3Rfree

Quarters

Ann.

%

from

ss

anticipated Run No Run Recession

Figure 6: Recession with positive Run Probability and Ex-Post Run

Page 53: Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite …kiyotaki/papers/GK-BankRun...Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In–nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

2007 Q2 2008 Q2 2009 Q2 2010 Q20

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

Bank

Equ

ity

DATA MODEL

2007 Q2 2008 Q2 2009 Q2 2010 Q2-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

Cre

dit S

prea

ds

Lehman BrothersBear Sterns

Figure 7: Credit Spreads and Bank Equity: Model VS Data

Description: The data series for Credit spreads is the Excess Bond Premium as computed by Gilchrist and Zakrasjek (2012); Bank Equity is the S&P500 Financial Index. The model counterparts are the paths of E(Rb-Rd) and V as depicted in Figure 6 normalized so that their steady-state values match the actual values in 2007 Q2.