auditors and principal-principal agency conflicts in

34
1 Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in Family-controlled Firms Chiraz Ben Ali 1 IPAG Lab, France [email protected] Sabri Boubaker IRG, Université Paris Est, France Champagne School of Management, Groupe ESC Troyes, France [email protected] Michel Magnan Concordia university [email protected] Abstract This study examines whether control competition between the largest controlling shareholders (LCS) and multiple large shareholders (MLS) has an impact on audit fees. Auditors’ effort (measured by audit fees) decrease in firms where auditors perceived lower audit risk. MLS are likely to play a corporate governance role to mitigate LCS control power reducing agency conflicts and auditors’ effort. Using a hand-collected sample of 1,483 firm-year observations representing French family controlled firms over the period 2003-2010, our results show (1) a positive relationship between excess control of LCS and audit fees suggesting that auditors ask for a fee premium for higher principal-principal conflict (2) audit fees decrease with the presence, number and voting power of MLS evidencing that multiple large shareholders play an important monitoring role. Keywords: agency problems, audit fees, corporate governance 1 Chiraz Ben Ali, Associate Professor of Accounting IPAG Business School 184 Boulevard Saint-Germain 75006 Paris, France Tel (Office) : +33 (1) 55 04 11 45 Tél : +33 (0)1 55041145 [email protected] Preliminary draft. No citation permitted. Comments welcome. This draft 27th, February, 2014

Upload: others

Post on 20-May-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

1

Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

Family-controlled Firms

Chiraz Ben Ali1

IPAG Lab, France

[email protected]

Sabri Boubaker

IRG, Université Paris Est, France

Champagne School of Management, Groupe ESC Troyes, France

[email protected]

Michel Magnan

Concordia university

[email protected]

Abstract

This study examines whether control competition between the largest controlling shareholders

(LCS) and multiple large shareholders (MLS) has an impact on audit fees. Auditors’ effort

(measured by audit fees) decrease in firms where auditors perceived lower audit risk. MLS are

likely to play a corporate governance role to mitigate LCS control power reducing agency

conflicts and auditors’ effort. Using a hand-collected sample of 1,483 firm-year observations

representing French family controlled firms over the period 2003-2010, our results show (1) a

positive relationship between excess control of LCS and audit fees suggesting that auditors

ask for a fee premium for higher principal-principal conflict (2) audit fees decrease with the

presence, number and voting power of MLS evidencing that multiple large shareholders play

an important monitoring role.

Keywords: agency problems, audit fees, corporate governance

1 Chiraz Ben Ali, Associate Professor of Accounting IPAG Business School 184 Boulevard Saint-Germain 75006 Paris, France Tel (Office) : +33 (1) 55 04 11 45 Tél : +33 (0)1 55041145 [email protected]

Preliminary draft. No citation permitted. Comments welcome. This draft –27th, February, 2014

Page 2: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

2

Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

Family-controlled Firms

1. Introduction

Previous corporate governance literature evidenced that ownership concentration is

predominant in listed firms suggesting the prevalence of the principal-principal conflict

(Holderness, 2009). However, these studies focuses on the largest controlling shareholder

(LCS) or consider all controlling shareholders together to study his/their opportunity to

extract private benefits at the expense of minority shareholders. Conversely, the presence of

other blockholders, called multiple large shareholders (MLS) besides the largest controlling

shareholder (LCS) (Laeven and Levine, 2008) could bring new insight in this corporate

governance framework. Indeed, MLS are likely to monitor the largest LCS (Bolton and Von

Thadden, 1998; Laeven and Levine, 2008; Mishra, 2011) and compete for control (Attig et

al., 2008) which alleviate information asymmetry and agency conflicts. As auditors consider

agency conflicts in their audit risk assessment (Khalil et al., 2008) to determine audit effort,

firms facing opportunistic behavior from managers or largest controlling shareholder present

higher audit fees. At the opposte firms with low agency conflicts face lower audit fees.

We believe the distinction between MLS and LCS is important in explaining why previous

research has provided mixed evidence of the relation between blockholders ownership and

audit fees (Hay et al., 2006). Our paper examine whether control contestability between LCS

and MLS has an impact on audit pricing in a concentrated ownership context. We focus on

family controlled firms because families have stronger incentives to expropriate wealth from

minority shareholders compared to widely-held corporations because private benefits of

control are not diluted among several independent owners (Villalonga and Amit, 2006)2.

We conduct our research in the context of French firms because France presents an interesting

setting. First, it is a country which has been used as a typical representative of a weak investor

protection country family (La Porta et al., 2000). Second, listed French firms present high

ownership concentration (Faccio and Lang, 2002; Ben Ali, 2013) and are mostly controlled by

families that participate to the management (Boubaker et al., 2014).

2 For information, we also have data for non-family controlled firms see Table 9: Robustness tests Set 2:

Alternative sample compositions

Page 3: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

3

We use regression analyses on non-financial French listed companies and focus on family

controlled firms. Our final sample comprises a panel of 1,483 firm-year observations over the

period 2003-2010. Our results are consistent with our hypotheses evidencing a negative

relationship between audit fees and multiple large shareholders (MLS) power which supports

that MLS play an important role in monitoring LCS. First, we find that audit fees are

positively associated to LCS excess of control, measured by the difference between his voting

rights and his cash flow rights. Consistent to prior studies, we evidence that auditors are more

likely to supply greater effort to prevent misstatement associated with moral hazard and

adverse selection problems resulting from principal-principal conflict (Khalil et al., 2008;

Hope et al., 2012). Second, we show a negative relationship between audit fees and the

presence, number and voting power of MLS consistent with MLS corporate governance role.

These results are robust to alternative measures of contestability (Shapley value, PCA index),

endogeneity propensity score matching consideration and alternatives sample compositions

(adding non-controlled family firms, excluding cross listed firms or pyramid firms). Because

auditing is an agency costs that should increase when agency conflicts are high, when auditors

perceive high risk of minority expropriation by LCS, they incorporate such risk in their audit

pricing. MLS play an important role in a firm’s governance by monitoring the LCS. The

presence, number and voting power of MLS alleviate the power of the LCS and weaken his

opportunity to extract private benefits reducing therefore information asymmetry and agency

conflict which result in lower audit fees

Our results highlight that auditors adjust their level of effort depending on expected agency

conflicts level when auditing financial accounting information. Our theoretical developments

and empirical results present new explanations for previous scant and ambiguous results (Hay

et al., 2006) regarding the relationship between audit fees and blockholders ownership. Prior

research (1) do not isolate MLS and LCS (Fan and Wong, 2005; Niemi, 2005) or focus only

on LCS ownership and control (Khalil et al., 2008).

Our examinations draw on very detailed data on ultimate ownership that has been hand

collected on all listed french firms on 2003-2010 period while most of prior research consider

ownership stable in a short period (less than four year) or examine direct ownership. Our data

consider the ultimate 1st, 2

nd, 3

rd and 4

th shareholder in seven years and to the best of our

knowledge, no prior study has been able to test the effects of ownership on audit fees using

such detailed data. We also contribute to the existing audit literature in several ways. First,

very scarce studies examine the relation between principal-principal conflict and audit fees

Page 4: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

4

(Fan and Wong, 2005; Khalil et al., 2008; Hope et al., 2012) and to the best of our

knowledge, this is the first study that examines a sample of family controlled firms while

family have many particularities affecting many accounting dimensions including information

asymmetry, earnings quality, corporate governance (Lennox, 2005; Dechun, 2006; Ali et al.,

2007; Chau and Gray, 2010; Anderson et al., 2012). Finally, there is a debate on the role of

MLS in corporate governance. While some of the research evidences that MLS play a

monitoring role to enable minority expropriation by the LCS (Mishra, 2011), other research

finds that MLS may conspire with LCS to extract divisible private benefits of control

(Zwiebel, 1995; Bennedsen and Wolfenzon, 2000).We contribute to this debate by

empirically examining the effect of MLS on audit fees and answer previous call for research

to examine the special corporate governance features of publicly traded firms with multiple

large owners (Laeven and Levine, 2008).

The paper is organized as follows. The next section (section 2) provides the theoretical

framework and develops our hypotheses. Section 3 presents the research design, and section 4

provides the sample selection procedures and descriptive statistics. Regression results are

disclosed in section 5, with robustness analyses reported in section 6. We summarize the main

findings and limitations of our study in section 8.

2. Audit fees in ownership concentrated firms

The ownership concentration is considered as an institutional arrangement that facilitates

transactions in a weak investor protection environment, for instance France (La Porta et al.,

1999). Indeed, shareholders need to hold large percentage of capital to monitor the manager

and avoid expropriation since the legal system could not efficiently protect then. However, in

a context of high ownership concentration, shareholders who obtain dominant control of a

firm are able to determine the profit distribution and are likely to deprive minority

shareholders of their rights which raise the prinicpal-principal agency conflict (Fan and

Wong, 2005). Controlling shareholders have the incentive and/or opportunity to divert firm

resources at the expense of outside shareholders (Gul et al., 2010). This expropriation can take

various forms, for instance: higher compensation, misappropriation of assets, and dilution of

minority shareholders’ interests through the issuance of stocks or dividends (Hope et al.,

2012). One stream of research considers that controlling shareholders collude together to

perceive substantial private benefits at the expenses of minority shareholders (Zwiebel, 1995;

Bennedsen and Wolfenzon, 2000) while recent studies evidence that MLS play an important

role in a firm’s governance by monitoring the LCS (Maury and Pajuste, 2005; Laeven and

Page 5: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

5

Levine, 2008; Mishra, 2011). ISAs (International Standars on Auditing §5) “require the

auditor to obtain reasonable assurance about whether the financial statements as a whole are

free from material misstatement, whether due to fraud or error”. Agency conflicts increase

audit risk, consequently auditors effort is high in firms suffering from more severe agency

conflicts (Khalil et al., 2008; Hope et al., 2012).

2.1. Audit fees and private benefits by the LCS

Delgado-Garcia et al. (2010) show that ownership concentration in the hands of the LCS

harms corporate reputation. Most of LCSs participate to the top management as managers,

president or vice-president of the board (La Porta et al., 1999), they can therefore manipulate

accounting information and dismiss information to continue to expropriate minority

shareholders. Also, the non-respect of the “one share one vote” rule in France confirms the

idea of weak investor protection suggested by La Porta, et al. (2000). Prior studies suggest

that firms with deviations between ultimate control and ownership have lower firm value,

poorer information disclosure and more severe information asymmetry and illiquidity (Chau

and Gray, 2002; Claessens et al., 2002; Fan and Wong, 2002; Attig et al., 2006). Attig, et al.

(2006) explain that a larger deviation between voting rights and cash flow rights is associated

to more selfish behavior by the ultimate shareholder. We suggest that when the legal

environment is not able to protect efficiently investors, investors have more incentives to pay

for monitoring costs, for instance external audit, to protect their wealth.

The role of auditing is to provide assurance of the quality of accounting information via the

enforcement of the application of proper accounting policies (Francis and Wang, 2008).

Auditing is considered therefore as one of the key component of the corporate governance

system (Francis et al., 2003) and assumed to be a monitoring cost (Jensen and Meckling,

1976) that will limit the LCS ability to manipulate accounting numbers and hence his ability

to extract private benefits of control.

Since the largest controlling shareholder (LCS) is likely to hold voting rights in excess of his

cash flow rights (La Porta et al., 1999; Faccio and Lang, 2002), he can easily expropriate

minority interests and benefit financially from related party transactions in which profits are

transferred to other companies he controls (Doidge et al., 2009). That excess control built

through dual-class shares, pyramidal structures or cross-holding among firms exacerbate the

agency conflict between the LCS and minority shareholders because it enables him to accrue

private benefits (Claessens et al., 2000; Fan and Wong, 2005). Indeed, the higher the

deviation between voting rights and cash flow rights of the LCS, the more entrenched is his

Page 6: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

6

position, and therefore the more able he is to expropriate wealth from minority shareholders

(Fan and Wong, 2005). Fan and Wong (2002) and Chau and Gray (2002) posit that the

ultimate owner could minimize and delay the disclosure of information to increase the chance

of executing his plans and avoid the intervention of other shareholders or to base their

decisions on inadequate information. Outside investors are likely to perceive the possible

manipulation of earnings for outright expropriation by LCS (Fan and Wong, 2002) and will

ask for high audit quality. To form an opinion on the truth and the fairness of financial

statements of these firms, auditors charge higher audit fee to bear the additional effort

engaged because of additional firm risk (Choi et al., 2008). For instance, when examining the

canadian market, Khalil et al. (2008) find a positive relation between audit fees and the wedge

between cash flow rights and control rights. They assume that higher audit fees result from an

increase in audit cost as auditors conduct wider scope audits as dual-class shares increase

audit risk and/or auditor business risk.

We therefore state the following hypothesis consistently with previous development.

Hypothesis 1: Greater divergence between the control and cash flow rights of the ultimate

LCS is associated with higher audit fees.

2.2. Audit fees in firms with multiple large shareholders

Although many studies examine the impact of excess control by the LCS scant attention has

been given to the governance role of MLS, despite their pervasiveness around the world

(Attig et al., 2009). Indeed, recent studies show the prevalence of firms with multiple large

shareholders (MLS) besides the large controlling shareholder (LCS) (Mishra, 2011). For

instance, Laeven and Levine (2008) use a sample of 1,657 European firms and find that one-

third of publicly listed firms in Europe have MLS. Boubaker (2012) finds that MLS are

present in 38% of French publicly listed firms. our study aims to respond to this call for

research on this governance issue (Laeven and Levine, 2008).

The MLS shareholding structure differs significantly from the one with only one dominant

shareholder in term of corporate governance. Consistent with recent research about MLS

(Attig et al., 2008; Mishra, 2011; Boubaker et al., 2012), the presence of MLS can shape

agency problems (Laeven and Levine, 2008; Mishra, 2011). Pagano and Röell (1998) model

that firms with multiple large shareholders enjoy stronger internal monitoring that prevents

opportunistic behavior by the controlling shareholder

Page 7: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

7

Attig et al. (2008) argue that MLS can achieve valuable internal monitoring, either by forming

coalitions with large equity stakes (Bennedsen and Wolfenzon, 2000) or by competing for

corporate control (Bloch and Hege, 2003). The authors examine the impact of MLS on cost

of equity and find a negative relation between the cost of equity and both the size of the

second largest shareholders and the voting power of the four controlling shareholders beyond

the largest one. They conclude that investors associate the presence of MLS to an efficient

monitoring of the firm. These results are also consistent with Maury and Pajuste (2005)’s

finding who find that a more equal distribution of votes among large blockholder improves

corporate governance.

Moreover, in a sample of 1,686 firms drawn from nine Eastern Asian countries, Mishra

(2011) finds that the power and presence of MLS improve internal governance by mitigating

agency problems between the dominant shareholder and minority shareholders and help

promote a more optimal non-conservative investment policy while in the absence of MLS, the

LCS have the power and incentives to extract private benefits of control by undertaking a

conservative investment policy. Mishra (2011)’s results support that in firms with a dominant

shareholder, the presence of MLS reduces agency problems and thus aligns the managerial

interests with those of other minority shareholders.

Consistent with the substitution hypothesis between internal and external corporate

governance mechanisms (ownership as internal governance and auditing as external

governance), auditor will engage less effort in firms with MLS because of corporate

governance improvement since the MLS play an efficient monitoring role of the LCS. For

instance, El Ghoul, et al. (2013) find that firms with MLS are less likely to hire Big Four

auditors because MLS presence strengthens internal monitoring. We suggest that MLS power

decrease accounting manipulation risk, thus, auditors will charge less audit fees.

We therefore state the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 2: The presence, number and voting power of MLS are associated with lower

audit fees.

3. Empirical design

We use the following regression model to test our hypotheses:

Page 8: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

8

Dependent variable: Following prior research (Hay et al., 2006),we use LNFEE: the natural

logarithm of audit fees to proxy for audit effort.

Corporate governance variables: VARMLS is composed of all MLS and LCS variables.

VARMLS equal: EXCESS CONTROL, MLSD, MLSN, VR234, VRRATIO and HERF. We

Consider La Porta’s (1999) definition to identify large shareholders. Hence, a large

shareholder is a legal entity that controls, directly or indirectly, at least 10% of the firm’s

voting rights. To capture the entrenchment effect of the LCS, we use EXCESS CONTROL,

which equals the largest ultimate shareholder’s control rights (UCO) in excess of his of

cashflow rights (UCF) all divided by his control rights (UCO). For each firm in our sample,

we compute UCF and UCO of the LCSs as follows: First, we determine the shareholder that

controls the largest block of direct voting rights. Second, we identify the latter’s direct largest

shareholder, and we repeat this procedure until reaching the ultimate LCS of each sampled

firm. Following Claessens et al.(2002), we calculate UCO by summing the weakest links

along the different control chains and using a 10% threshold. UCF are obtained by summing

the products of direct cash flow rights along the different ownership chains.

Consistent with Attig et al. (2009), we employ variables reflecting various attributes of MLS.

First, we identify whether the firm has more than one large shareholder by constructing a

dummy variable (MLSD) equal 1 if at least one large shareholder other than LCS controls

more than 10% of the firm, and 0 otherwise. Second, we use MLSN to measure the number of

MLS other than the LCS, up to the fourth. Third, we refine our analysis by including VR234

and VRRATIO to study the impact of control contestability on audit fees. VR234 is the sum

of voting rights of the second, third and fourth largest blockholders; and VRRATIO calculate

the ratio of this sum to the voting rights of the LCS measuring contestability of the LCS’s

voting power by MLS. Greater contestability of LCS power by MLS is associated with higher

dilution of minority shareholders’ interests, lower agency costs and lower audit fees therefore.

Hence, we expect a negative effect of variables measuring contestability (i.e., VR234,

VRRATIO) on audit fees.

Finally, we investigate the importance of control dispersion in shaping the governance role of

MLS by examining HERF, the Herfindahl index of the differences between the voting rights

Page 9: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

9

(VR) of the four largest shareholders : HERF = (VR1 − VR2) 2

+ (VR2 − VR3) 2

+ (VR3 −

VR4)2. All else equal, higher HERF implies lower contestability of the control of the LCS by

the coalition of multiple large shareholders. Consistent with the MLS efficient-monitoring

hypothesis, we expect a positive effect of the variable HERF measuring the dispersion of

voting rights on audit fees.

Control Variables: Our audit fees model includes two types of firm specific control variables,

which control for: (1) audit costs (size and complexity); (2) the risk of loss that an audit could

face in the future (Simunic, 1980; Francis, 1984; Hay et al., 2006). Size is coded by

LNASSET (natural logarithm of total assets expressed in k€). We then add two variables

which proxy for client complexity: INVREC (sum of the inventories and receivable, scaled by

total sales), INT (percentage of international sales) and NBS (natural log of business segments

+ 1). Similar to Simunic (1980) and Choi et al. (2009), we include LOSS (dummy that equal 1

if net income is negative) and LEVERAGE (total debt divided by total assets) to measure the

client-specific litigation risk potentially borne by the auditors, and we add ROA (Return on

Assets), LQD (the ratio of current assets to current liabilities), and CROSSLIST to code for

being cross-listed in a higher litigation risk market (US or UK) (Choi et al., 2009). We also

include the audit firm size (BIG_4) to capture the Big 4 premium (Francis, 1984). We also

add the year-end peak (FISYEND) to capture the busy season effect (Hay et al., 2006) related

to the auditor’s peak of activity of the 31st of December. Finally we include an audit demand

effect with a Book-to-market ratio (BTM). Finally, model (2) includes also fixed year and

industry effects and an error term (). Expected signs for the variables are reported in the

regression tables.

4. Sample and descriptive statistics

The initial sample consists of all French listed firms appearing in the Worldscope database

over the 2003-2010 period. We exclude from the sample: (1) financial firm having a two-digit

SIC code between 6000 and 6999 (2) firms with less than two usable observations during the

sample period, (3) widely held firms where there is no ultimate shareholder who owns more

than 10% of the voting rights, (4) firm with missing or incomplete ownership, return or

financial data. We focus only on family controlled firms. Our final sample comprises a panel

of 1,483 firm-year observations. Ownership and voting data are hand-collected from the

firm’s annual reports. Financial data are from Worldscope database.

Table 1 summarizes the definitions and data sources for all variables and Table 2 describes

the distribution of sample firms across industries and years. On one hand, the services and

Page 10: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

10

consumer durables industries dominate our sample, firms in these two sectors represent

respectively 24.34% and 18.00% of the total number of firm-year observations. On the other

hand, petroleum and transportation sectors make up the smallest share of the sample with only

0.20% et 2.43%. Table 2 shows also that the firms are evenly distributed across the studied

period.

Table 3 presents descriptive values concerning the dependent and independent variables. To

limit the influence of outliers, all continuous variables are winsorized at 1%. Panel A

(Governance variables) shows a high separation between cash flow rights and voting rights of

the LCS. The ratio of difference between control and ownership rights of the LCS divided by

his control rights has an average value of 24.5%. This finding indicates that our sampled firms

are, in general, subject to agency costs between LCSs and minority shareholders. We also find

that MLS are present in almost 35.9% of the sampled firms. This finding is consistent with

Faccio and Lang (2002) who find that 39% of Western European firms have more than one

large shareholder (at the 10% threshold). This percentage is also similar to Attig et al. (2009)

who document that one-third of the firms in East Asian listed firms have MLS. Our

subsample of firms with MLS (533 firm-year observations) shows that the average (median)

total voting rights held by the three largest shareholders, beyond the LCS, is 26.8% (25.3%).

When considering the whole sample, we find that the average power of the second, third and

fourth largest shareholders is 39.8% higher to the LCS voting rights. Panel B presents

summary statistics concerning firm characteristics representing audit fees and control

variables. Table 3 shows an important variance of control variables, which illustrates the

diversity of the firms included in our sample.

5. Empirical evidence

5.1. Univariate Tests

We present initial insights on the relation between audit fees and MLS from univariate tests.

Table 4 reports mean and median difference tests of the governance variables used in our

analysis. We find that the mean (median) value of audit fees are significantly higher for firms

with higher excess control of LCS. This result suggest apriori that auditors ask for a fee

premimum for firms with higher risk of corporate wealth extraction by the LCS which is

consistent with hypothesis 1. Table 4 shows also that firms with MLS have significantly

lower audit fees compared to firms with firms without MLS. We further evidence that the

mean audit fees is significantly lower at 1% for firms with higher MLSN (number of MLS),

VR234 (MLS voting rights) and VRRATIO (MLS voting power compared to LCS). These

Page 11: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

11

last results suggest that MLS play a corporate governance role reducing engagement risk. This

is appreciated by auditors who consequently charge lower audit fees.

Table 4 presents a significant negative difference in the mean (median) audit fees between

firms with low HERF values and firms with high HERF values. When control dispersion

(HERF) is high, the LCS is more entrenched and control contestability is low. Consequently,

to cover the increased audit risk, auditors expend more effort and ask therefore for higher

audit fees.

5.2. Regression results for audit fees

Table 5 reports the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates for the model discussed above. The

p-values are computed using robust standard errors, adjusted for heteroscedasticity and

clustered at the firm level. We include year and, industry effects in all regressions.

**** Insert Table 5 about here****

All model specifications control for the determinants of the audit fess reported in the previous

studies and discussed above. In interpreting the results, we primarily focus on the effects of

MLS and LCS related variables. In Model 1, our basic regression indicates a positive and

statistically significant coefficient for Excess control (at the 1% level), suggesting that the

separation between ownership and control rights of the ultimate controlling shareholder

increases the audit fees. We therefore validate H1: Greater divergence between the control

and cash flow rights of the ultimate LCS is associated with higher audit fees. This also lends

support to recent evidence that firms with cash flow and voting rights divergence incur higher

audit fees to compensate for higher audit risk and/or higher auditor business risk (Khalil et al.,

2008). In Models 1 through 5, we separately include MLS variables to avoid multicolinearity.

In Model 1, we start by examining the impact on audit fees of a binary variable: the presence

of MLS beyond the ultimate owner. Column 1 reports a negative and statistically significant

at the 1% level coefficient of MLSD ( coeff. = -0.170, p < 0.01). In otherwords, this relation

implies lower audit fees for firms with MLS compared to firms with a unique controlling

shareholder. This result is consistent with MLS efficient-monitoring hypothesis. Additionally,

we evidence in Model 2 a negative and statistically significant coefficient for the number of

MLS (coeff. =-0.121, p < 0.01), suggesting that increasing number of controlling shareholders

is statistically significant to reduce auditor’s efforts. This result, in line with our predictions,

is also consistent to prior studies evidincing a corporate governance role of MLS (Bennedsen

and Wolfenzon, 2000; Attig et al., 2008; Boubaker and Sami, 2011; Mishra, 2011; Attig et

al., 2013). Conversly to prior studies that consider all controlling shareholders as a block

Page 12: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

12

harm shareholder rights (Fan and Wong, 2005; Ben Ali and Lesage, 2013), the presence of

MLS is likely to mitigate firm's agency costs and therefore benefit minority interests.

In the rest of Table 5, we report the results for more stringent MLS variables measuring the

contestability of the controlling shareholder's power. For instance, model 3 reports a

significant negative relation between audit fees and the total voting rights of the three

controlling shareholders beyond the largest (VR234: -0.438; p < 0.05). This finding is further

confirmed in Model 4, which includes the voting rights power of the these three controlling

shareholders compared to the largest one (VRRATIO: -0.133; p < 0.01). These findings

indicate that not only the presence of MLS or number of MLS, but also the size of the voting

rights and its weight to LCS’s voting rights, is economically significant in reducing firm's

agency costs.

We further test the influence of control dispersion between blockholders on firms' audit fees

by examining the Herfindahl index of the differences between the voting rights of the four

largest shareholders. Results are reported in column 5 and show that the coefficient of

HERFINDAHL is negative and statistically significant at the 1% level. This evidence is

consistent with Boubaker et al. (2012) and Attig et al.(2008) results evidencing that greater

parity in voting rights among the blockholders improves corporate governance, priorly

suggested by Bloch and Hege (2003). These results indicate that a high risk of control

contestability of the LCS is associated with a firm's enhanced information quality and thus

lower misreproting, lower audit risk and consequently lower auditor’s effrots (as measured by

audit fees). Finally, similarly to Attig et al. (2008), we argue that MLS play a valuable

information role by lowering the cost of audit engagement for firms with severe information

problems embedded in their ownership structures.

When considering the control variables,we observe several significant variable coefficients

consistent with previous audit fees litterature. With respect to our predicted signs on control

variables, we find a positive and significant relation at the 1% level between audit fees and (1)

size, (2) the proportion of international sales and (3) the number of business segments. The

results evidence also a negative and significant at the 5% level of performance measured with

ROA. Finally, table 5 reports that the coefficients of the BTM is negative and significant at

the 1% level variable consistent to the audit demand effect.

Page 13: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

13

6. Robustness analyses

In this section we check the reliability of our results by performing several sensitivity tests.

The relationship between audit fees and MLS is robust with respect to a number of alternative

tests that we report in Tables 6 to 10.

***Insert table 6***

***Insert table 7***

First, we run our regression using a PSM ( propensity score matching) sample to control for

endogeneity issue. Following Chaney et al. (2004), we believe that client firms are not

randomly assigned to auditors. Ho and Fei (2013) argue that “it is likely that firms self-select

audit firms based on firm characteristics, private information, or other unobservable

characteristics” affecting audit fees. Therefore, we adopt the propensity scoring matching

(PSM) to address potential endogeneity in the standard ordinary least squares (OLS)

regressions. The results remain qualitatively similar (see table 6). Table 7 presents a

comparison of variables considered to determine the presence of MLS in original and matched

samples.

***Insert table 8***

Second, we replicate in table 8 our tests after changing the proxies for certain independent

variables. For instance, we change the measure of LCS excess control ( EXCESS CONTROL)

by 1) UCO-UCF measured by the difference between voting rights and cash flow rights and

2) EXCESS DUMMY which is dummy variable that takes one if the voting rights of LCS is

higher than his cashflow rights. Results in table 7 are similar to our predictions on a positive

relation between audit fees and the excess of voting rights to cash flow rights of the LCS (see

table 8).

When considering hypothesis 2, our results hold if we change the measure of the MLS

variables. Indeed, we introduce various control contestability variables that have been used in

previous literature. For instance, we introduce SHAPLEY1 measured by the Shapley value

solution for the largest controlling shareholder in a four shareholder voting game. Our model

include a contestability index defined as the common factor extracted from a principal

component analysis to resume our previous MLS variable: MLSD, MLSN, VR234,

VRRATIO and HERFINDAHL (see table 8). In table 8, column 5 replicates our tests after

changing the proxies for certain control variables (e.g., size proxied by log sales and number

Page 14: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

14

of employees instead of log assets). Results are similar to those presented in the main

analysis.

***Insert table 9 ***

Third, we perform alternative sample compositions to assuage the concern that our results are

unduly influenced by sample selection bias. Our main analysis focus only on family

controlled firms; when, enlarging our sample to all controlled firms (Table 9, column 1) and

to closely and widely held firms (Table 9, column 2), the conclusions remains unaffected and

our two hypothesis are validated. We also replicates our regression after eliminating firms

controlled through a pyramid. Column 3 reports these last results. Holding a firm through

sucessive tiers dramatically exacerbates the seperation of control and cashflow rights of the

ultimate owner, giving him higher incentives to extrac private benefits (Boubaker et al.,

2013). Also, as pyramids suffer from more information asymetry, it should increase audit

efforts and therefore audit fees since auditors garantie that financial reporting is free from

mistakes. For instance, Jensen and Meckling (1976) suggest auditing is one of the main

external monitoring costs to reduce information asymmetry. In table 9, model 3 shows that the

inferences remain unchanged showing that our results are not driving by pyramid-affliation

effect. Choi et al. (2009) argue that legal environments play a crucial role in determining the

auditor's legal liability and that firm cross listed in law enforced countries are subject to

higher audit fees. To acertain that our results are not influenced by this cross-listed fees

premium, we exclude cross-listed firms from our intial sample and run our regressions. Our

results remain unchaged evidencing that they are not driven by cross-listed effect. Finally,

Table 9, Eq . (5) reports results using balanced panel data and confirm our prior results.

***Insert table 10 ***

Finally, to check the robustness of our main results, we include additional control variables:

discretionnary accruals, new stock issuance and IFRS adoption. Large controlling

shareholders participate often in the management or serve as directors on the board (Chen et

al., 2008) and could therefore manipulate financial reporting and induce higher earnings

management (Mei-Ling, 2010). However, auditors are likely to anticipate this effect and ask

for higher fees to compensate increased audit effort (Bedard and Johnstone, 2004). Also,

when performing their monitoring role, multiple large shareholders increase auditor’s efforts

because they have enough power to accuse auditors for audit default, consequently audit fees

are higher. These prior development suggests to consider earnings management in our model.

Hence, we include 3 measures of discretionnary accruals to control for earnings management

Page 15: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

15

in table 10, Eq . (1), Eq . (2) and Eq . (3). Our results remain qualitatively similar. Our results

are also robust after controlling firm complexity, specifically after IFRS adoption and new

stock issuance. Table 10 also presents others control variables that could increase audit

engagement complexity for instance: number of analysts following the firm, asset tangibility,

sales growth and free cash flow.

***Insert table 10 ***

7. Conclusion

Although the literature on audit fees is well developed, the relations between principal-

principal conflicts and audit fees are less established. Also previous studies focus either on

widely held firms or firms with a single controlling owner. However this conventional

dichotomy of corporate governance is controversial since recent studies evidence a strong

presence of multiple controlling shareholders in most firms (Attig et al., 2008; Laeven and

Levine, 2008; Mishra, 2011). However, these growing body of research do not provide

unequivocal evidence of the governance role of MLS (Attig et al., 2008).

Our research use very detailed data on ultimate ownership in French listed firms and spans

2003–2010. Consistent with agency theory framework, we suggest that shows that audit fees,

as an agency cost, depend on the level of agency conflicts (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Our

results evidence that auditors adjust their efforts (i.e. audit fees) when auditing firms with

high agency conflicts. Similarly to prior research, we find that audit fees is higher in firms

where the largest controlling shareholders hods voting rights in excess of his cashflow rights

(Khalil et al., 2008) because of increased risk due to high minority expropriation threat.

Conversly, the presence, number and voting power of MLS decrease audit fees. This result

evidences that that multiple large shareholders play an important monitoring role. Our results

are robust to alternative measures of MLS-LCS contestability (Shapley value, PCA index),

endogeneity propensity score matching consideration and alternatives sample compositions

(adding non-controlled family firms, excluding cross listed firms or pyramid firms).

Similarly to (Ho and Fei, 2013), we believe our findings on the empirical link between auditor

choice and audit fees enhance our understanding of the effect of ownership structure in

financial reporting and the audit planning process. The paper contributes to the audit pricing

literature in the following ways. First, it fills a gap in the literature by investigating how

multiple large shareholdings affect audit fees. It suplements the prior empirical evidence in

prior studies (Fan and Wong, 2005; Khalil et al., 2008; Hope et al., 2012) by investigating

Page 16: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

16

ultimate ownership of the second, third and fourth controlling shareholders and the power

contest between blockholders and examine a different institutional context: France that has

been pointed as typical of the least investor protection family (La Porta et al., 1999). Finally,

it also control for a wide array of audit fees determinant variables that has not been examined

priorly.

Page 17: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

17

8. Tables

Table 1: Variables definitions and sources

Variable Definition Source

Dependent variable

LNFEE Natural logarithm of audit fees in thousands of euros. Worldscope

Test variables

EXCESS CONTROL

The difference between the ultimate owner’s control rights

and cash-flow rights (at the 10% threshold) all divided by her

control rights.

Annual reports and authors’

calculations

MLSD Dummy variable that equals one if the firm has at least two

large shareholders (at the 10% threshold) and zero otherwise.

Annual reports and authors’

calculations

MLSN The number of large shareholders other than the largest

shareholder up to the fourth

Annual reports and authors’

calculations

VR234 The sum of voting rights of the second third and fourth largest

shareholders.

Annual reports and authors’

calculations

VRRATIO

The sum of voting rights of the second third and fourth

largest blockholders divided by the voting rights of the largest

shareholder.

Annual reports and authors’

calculations

HERFINDAHL

The sum of squared differences between the voting rights of

the four largest shareholders that is (VR1 − VR2)² +

(VR2−VR3)² + (VR3−VR4)²; where VR1 VR2 VR3 and

VR4 equal the voting rights of the first second third and

fourth largest shareholders.

Annual reports and authors’

calculations

Other variables

SIZE Natural logarithm of total assets in thousands of euros.

Worldscope Worldscope

INTSALES International sales divided by total sales. Worldscope

INVREC The sum of inventories and accounts receivables scaled by

total sales. Worldscope

LEVERAGE LEVERAGE Total debt divided by total assets, Worldscope

BIG_4 Dummy variable that equals one if the firm uses one of the

Big 4 auditing firms or their forerunners and zero otherwise. Worldscope

ROA Earnings before interest and taxes divided by the book value

of assets at the beginning of the fiscal year. Worldscope

BTM The book-to-market ratio. Worldscope

NBS The natural logarithm of the firm’s number of business

segments + 1. Worldscope

LOSS

Dummy variable that equals one if the firm reports a net loss

in year t (that is its net income after taxes before

extraordinary item and taxes on extraordinary item < 0) AND

zero otherwise.

Worldscope

CURRATIO Current ratio which equals to the ratio of current assets to

current liabilities at the end of the fiscal year. Worldscope

FISYREND Dummy variable that equals one if the fiscal year-end is

December 31 and zero otherwise. Worldscope

CROSSLIST Dummy variable that equals one if the firm is cross-listed in

foreign capital markets in year t and zero otherwise Bank of New York

Page 18: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

18

Table 2: Distribution of sample firms across industries and years

Total

Industry

(SIC codes) 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Number per

industry

Percentage

of total

Petroleum

(13, 29) 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 3 0.20

Consumer durables

(25, 30, 36, 37, 50, 55, 57) 16 22 34 41 42 39 38 35 267 18.00

Basic industry

(10, 12, 14, 24, 26, 28, 33) 14 17 24 27 24 22 21 17 166 11.19

Food and tobacco

(1, 2, 9, 20, 21, 54) 5 7 12 14 14 12 13 12 89 6.00

Construction

(15, 16, 17, 32, 52) 6 7 10 11 9 8 10 9 70 4.72

Capital goods

(34, 35, 38) 13 15 20 23 24 25 26 26 172 11.60

Transportation

(40, 41, 42, 44, 45, 47) 3 4 4 4 4 5 6 6 36 2.43

Utilities

(46, 48, 49) 2 4 9 12 10 10 11 11 69 4.65

Textiles and trade

(22, 23, 31, 51, 53, 56, 59) 14 16 22 24 22 21 22 19 160 10.79

Services

(72, 73, 75, 76, 80, 82, 87,

89)

41 47 54 52 49 41 39 38 361 24.34

Leisure

(27, 58, 70, 78 , 79) 9 14 13 10 12 11 12 9 90 6.07

Total number per year 123 153 202 218 210 195 199 183 1,483 100.00

Percentage of total 8.29 10.32 13.62 14.70 14.10 13.15 13.42 12.34 100

This table shows the distribution of the sample firm-year observations across industries and years. Our sample comprises a

panel of 1,483 firm-year observations over the period 2003-2010. We use Campbell (1996) to classify firms into 11

industries. The industries are petroleum (SIC 13, 29), consumer durables (SIC 25, 30, 36, 37, 50, 55, 57), basic industry (SIC

10, 12, 14, 24, 26, 28, 33), food and tobacco (SIC 1, 2, 9, 20, 21, 54), construction (SIC 15, 16, 17, 32, 52), capital goods

(SIC 34, 35, 38), transportation (SIC 40, 41, 42, 44, 45, 47), utilities (SIC 46, 48, 49), textiles and trade (SIC 22, 23, 31, 51,

53, 56, 59), services (SIC 72, 73, 75, 76, 80, 82, 87, 89) and leisure (SIC 27, 58, 70, 78, 79).

Page 19: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

19

Table 3: Summary statistics for ownership structure variables and firm

characteristics

Variable N Mean S.D. Min. 25th percentile Median 75th percentile Max.

Panel A: Governance variables

EXCESS CONTROL 1,483 0.245 0.208 -0.024 0.077 0.219 0.360 0.858

MLSD (N(MLSD=1) = 533) 1,483 0.359 0.480 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000

MLSN 1,483 0.440 0.650 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000 3.000

VR234 533 0.268 0.097 0.101 0.200 0.253 0.340 0.478

VRRATIO 1,483 0.398 0.497 0.000 0.000 0.194 0.597 2.012

HERFINDAHL 1,483 0.264 0.241 0.000 0.051 0.195 0.431 0.886

Panel B: Firm characteristics

LNFEE 1,483 5.755 1.524 1.977 4.787 5.631 6.668 9.717

SIZE 1,483 12.560 2.041 8.454 11.114 12.307 13.801 17.516

INTSALES 1,483 0.379 0.266 0.000 0.167 0.386 0.583 0.999

INVREC 1,483 0.455 0.280 0.103 0.315 0.402 0.506 2.031

LEVERAGE 1,483 0.230 0.167 0.000 0.092 0.214 0.338 0.752

BIG_4 1,483 0.488 0.500 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000

ROA 1,483 3.689 7.868 -26.351 1.607 4.462 7.423 23.933

BTM 1,483 0.816 0.269 0.222 0.620 0.816 0.994 1.551

NBS 1,483 1.569 0.384 0.693 1.386 1.609 1.946 2.197

LOSS 1,483 0.196 0.397 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000

CURRATIO 1,483 1.540 0.795 0.394 1.034 1.347 1.803 5.749

FISYREND 1,483 0.786 0.410 0.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000

CROSSLIST 1,483 0.038 0.191 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000

This table shows descriptive statistics for the ownership structure variables (Panel A) and firm characteristics (Panel B).

EXCESS CONTROL is the difference between the ultimate owner’s control rights and cash-flow rights (at the 10%

threshold), all divided by her control rights. MLSD is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm has at least two large

shareholders (at the 10% threshold), and zero otherwise. MLSN is the number of large shareholders, other than the largest

shareholder, up to the fourth. VR234 is the sum of voting rights of the second, third and fourth largest shareholders.

VRRATIO is the sum of voting rights of the second, third and fourth largest blockholders divided by the voting rights of the

largest shareholder. HERFINDAHL is the sum of squared differences between the voting rights of the four largest

shareholders, that is, (VR1 − VR2)² + (VR2−VR3)² + (VR3−VR4)²; where VR1, VR2, VR3 and VR4 equal the voting rights of

the first, second, third and fourth largest shareholders. LNFEE is the natural logarithm of audit fees in thousands of euros.

SIZE is the natural logarithm of total assets in thousands of euros. INTSALES equals to the international sales divided by total

sales. INVREC is computed as the sum of inventories and accounts receivables scaled by total sales. LEVERAGE equals to

total debt divided by total assets. BIG_4 is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm uses one of the Big 4 auditing firms

or their forerunners, and zero otherwise. ROA is the firm’s return on assets defined as earnings before interest and taxes

divided by the book value of assets at the beginning of the fiscal year. BTM is the book-to-market ratio. NBS equals to the

natural logarithm of the firm’s number of business segments + 1. LOSS is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm

reports a net loss in year t (that is, its net income after taxes before extraordinary item and taxes on extraordinary item < 0),

and zero otherwise. CURRATIO is the firms’ current ratio, which equals to the ratio of current assets to current liabilities at

the end of the fiscal year. FISYREND is a dummy variable that equals one if the fiscal year-end is December 31, and zero

otherwise. CROSSLIST is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm is cross-listed in foreign capital markets in year t, and

zero otherwise.

Page 20: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

20

Table 4: Univariate Tests: governance variables

Mean Median

Low High t-statistic Low High z-statistic

EXCESS CONTROL 5.514 6.069 -7.055*** 5.594 5.733 -2.954***

MLSD 5.936 5.431 6.200*** 5.795 5.241 6.413***

MLSN 5.935 5.436 6.133*** 5.795 5.241 6.342***

VR234 5.956 5.488 5.931*** 5.844 5.393 5.386***

VRRATIO 5.858 5.567 3.530*** 5.783 5.497 3.158***

HERFINDAHL 5.696 5.840 -1.791* 5.669 5.838 -2.146**

UCF 5.876 5.622 3.211*** 5.615 5.645 2.286**

This table presents mean and median difference tests of the governance variables used in our analysis for 1,483 nonfinancial

French firms over the period 2003-2010. LNFEE is the natural logarithm of audit fees in thousands of euros. EXCESS

CONTROL is the difference between the ultimate owner’s control rights and cash-flow rights (at the 10% threshold), all

divided by her control rights. MLSD is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm has at least two large shareholders (at the

10% threshold), and zero otherwise. MLSN is the number of large shareholders, other than the largest shareholder, up to the

fourth. VR234 is the sum of voting rights of the second, third and fourth largest shareholders. VRRATIO is the sum of voting

rights of the second, third and fourth largest blockholders divided by the voting rights of the largest shareholder.

HERFINDAHL is the sum of squared differences between the voting rights of the four largest shareholders, that is, (VR1 −

VR2)² + (VR2−VR3)² + (VR3−VR4)²; where VR1, VR2, VR3 and VR4 equal the voting rights of the first, second, third and

fourth largest shareholders, UCF equals to the cash-flow rights of the ultimate owner (at the 10% threshold) measured by the

sum of the products of ownership stakes along the different control chains. The superscript asterisks ***, **, and * denote

statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively

Page 21: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

21

Table 5: Influence of control contestability on audit fees

Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

EXCESS CONTROL 0.40989*** (2.64)

0.41397*** (2.63)

0.38551** (2.44)

0.42034*** (2.60)

0.35401** (2.25)

MLSD -0.17056*** (-2.87)

MLSN -0.12142*** (-2.94)

VR234

-0.43856** (-2.11)

VRRATIO -0.13348*** (-2.60)

HERFINDAHL 0.04798** (2.45)

SIZE 0.49269*** (24.88)

0.49119*** (24.65)

0.49513*** (25.12)

0.49674*** (25.33)

0.49837*** (25.52)

INTSALES 0.61776*** (5.73)

0.61707*** (5.71)

0.61649*** (5.70)

0.61790*** (5.72)

0.61720*** (5.71)

INVREC -0.02544 (-1.45)

-0.02538 (-1.45)

-0.02435 (-1.39)

-0.02406 (-1.38)

-0.02419 (-1.41)

LEVERAGE -0.22317 (-1.12)

-0.19364 (-0.98)

-0.20046 (-1.01)

-0.19075 (-0.96)

-0.19436 (-0.98)

BIG_4 0.06698 (1.31)

0.06361 (1.24)

0.06702 (1.30)

0.07009 (1.36)

0.06343 (1.23)

ROA -0.00843** (-2.03)

-0.00819** (-1.97)

-0.00892** (-2.14)

-0.00923** (-2.22)

-0.00925** (-2.22)

BTM -0.47568*** (-4.51)

-0.46450*** (-4.41)

-0.46908*** (-4.46)

-0.46202*** (-4.40)

-0.44973*** (-4.30)

NBS 0.18883*** (2.68)

0.19406*** (2.78)

0.19031*** (2.69)

0.18776*** (2.68)

0.20680*** (2.98)

LOSS -0.10049 (-1.18)

-0.10460 (-1.24)

-0.11630 (-1.38)

-0.11304 (-1.34)

-0.12929 (-1.54)

CURRATIO -0.03729 (-0.92)

-0.03775 (-0.93)

-0.04085 (-0.99)

-0.03666 (-0.90)

-0.03575 (-0.87)

FISYREND -0.05536 (-0.78)

-0.05774 (-0.82)

-0.05585 (-0.79)

-0.06084 (-0.86)

-0.05612 (-0.80)

CROSSLIST -0.30789 (-1.43)

-0.30612 (-1.42)

-0.30615 (-1.42)

-0.30080 (-1.39)

-0.28978

(-1.34)

Intercept

-1.88113*** (-5.43)

-1.94899*** (-5.79)

-1.98238*** (-5.75)

-2.00970*** (-6.03)

-2.18620*** (-6.87)

Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Sample size 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483

Adjusted R² 0.582 0.582 0.581 0.581 0.580

This table presents regression results for the impact of multiple large shareholders on audit fees. The dependent variable

is LNFEE, defined as the natural logarithm of audit fees in thousands of euros. Eight specifications are considered.

Specification 1 is our basic regression specification. In specifications 2 and 3, we include the variables EXCESS

CONTROL and MLSD, respectively. EXCESS CONTROL is the difference between the ultimate owner’s control rights

and cash-flow rights (at the 10% threshold), all divided by her control rights. MLSD is a dummy variable that equals one

if the firm has at least two large shareholders (at the 10% threshold), and zero otherwise. In specifications 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8

we include the variables MLSD, MLSN, VR234, VRRATIO and HERFINDHAL, respectively, to proxy for the presence,

number and voting power of MLS. MLSN is the number of large shareholders, other than the largest shareholder, up to

the fourth. VR234 is the sum of voting rights of the second, third and fourth largest shareholders. VRRATIO is the sum of

voting rights of the second, third and fourth largest blockholders divided by the voting rights of the largest shareholder.

Page 22: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

22

HERFINDAHL is the sum of squared differences between the voting rights of the four largest shareholders, that is, (VR1

− VR2)² + (VR2−VR3)² + (VR3−VR4)²; where VR1, VR2, VR3 and VR4 equal the voting rights of the first, second, third

and fourth largest shareholders. SIZE is the natural logarithm of total assets in thousands of euros. INTSALES equals to

the international sales divided by total sales. INVREC is computed as the sum of inventories and accounts receivables

scaled by total sales. LEVERAGE equals to total debt divided by total assets. BIG_4 is a dummy variable that equals one

if the firm uses one of the Big 4 auditing firms or their forerunners, and zero otherwise. ROA is the firm’s return on assets

defined as earnings before interest and taxes divided by the book value of assets at the beginning of the fiscal year. BTM

is the book-to-market ratio. NBS equals to the natural logarithm of the firm’s number of business segments + 1. LOSS is a

dummy variable that equals one if the firm reports a net loss in year t (that is, its net income after taxes before

extraordinary item and taxes on extraordinary item < 0), and zero otherwise. CURRATIO is the firms’ current ratio, which

equals to the ratio of current assets to current liabilities at the end of the fiscal year. FISYREND is a dummy variable that

equals one if the fiscal year-end is December 31, and zero otherwise. CROSSLIST is a dummy variable that equals one if

the firm is cross-listed in foreign capital markets in year t, and zero otherwise. All continuous variables are winsorized at

the 1st and 99th percentiles. t-values based on White (1980) heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors are in

parentheses beneath coefficient estimates. The superscript asterisks ***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the

1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Page 23: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

23

Table 6: Influence of control contestability on audit fees: PSM sample

Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

EXCESS CONTROL 0.44972** (2.32)

0.46073** (2.35)

0.42321** (2.15)

0.44128** (2.19)

0.37654* (1.93)

MLSD -0.17099*** (-2.75)

MLSN -0.12929*** (-3.08)

VR234

-0.50878** (-2.24)

VRRATIO -0.11016** (-1.99)

HERFINDAHL 0.03286** (2.16)

SIZE 0.47765*** (19.45)

0.47435*** (19.23)

0.47817*** (19.50)

0.48037*** (19.63)

0.47907*** (19.53)

INTSALES 0.56613*** (4.47)

0.56255*** (4.44)

0.56383*** (4.44)

0.56260*** (4.44)

0.55914*** (4.41)

INVREC -0.02122 (-1.29)

-0.02137 (-1.30)

-0.02014 (-1.21)

-0.01990 (-1.22)

-0.02006 (-1.24)

LEVERAGE -0.32509 (-1.45)

-0.28848 (-1.30)

-0.31062 (-1.38)

-0.29308 (-1.32)

-0.29809 (-1.34)

BIG_4 0.01678 (0.28)

0.01330 (0.22)

0.01913 (0.32)

0.02070 (0.34)

0.01584 (0.26)

ROA -0.00852* (-1.80)

-0.00817* (-1.73)

-0.00917* (-1.92)

-0.00956** (-2.00)

-0.00960** (-2.00)

BTM -0.36972*** (-3.01)

-0.35764*** (-2.92)

-0.37563*** (-3.07)

-0.36048*** (-2.95)

-0.35835*** (-2.94)

NBS 0.18515** (2.24)

0.19139** (2.34)

0.18346** (2.20)

0.18638** (2.27)

0.20999*** (2.60)

LOSS -0.09690 (-1.01)

-0.09933 (-1.04)

-0.11580 (-1.20)

-0.11874 (-1.22)

-0.13543 (-1.40)

CURRATIO -0.03074 (-0.65)

-0.03067 (-0.64)

-0.03652 (-0.75)

-0.02963 (-0.62)

-0.02761 (-0.58)

FISYREND -0.07775 (-0.88)

-0.08020 (-0.91)

-0.08154 (-0.93)

-0.08447 (-0.96)

-0.08353 (-0.95)

CROSSLIST -0.34707 (-1.07)

-0.34352 (-1.06)

-0.35782 (-1.11)

-0.34364 (-1.07)

-0.33013

(-1.02)

Intercept

-1.35923*** (-3.35)

-1.41001*** (-3.57)

-1.39541*** (-3.44)

-1.48696*** (-3.76)

-1.59858*** (-4.17)

Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Sample size 1,066 1,066 1,066 1,066 1,066

Adjusted R² 0.536 0.537 0.535 0.534 0.533

This table presents regression results for the impact of multiple large shareholders on audit fees using a propensity score

matched sample that consists of 1,066 firm–year observations. The dependent variable is LNFEE, defined as the natural

logarithm of audit fees in thousands of euros. Eight specifications are considered. Specification 1 is our basic regression

specification. In specifications 2 and 3, we include the variables EXCESS CONTROL and MLSD, respectively. EXCESS

CONTROL is the difference between the ultimate owner’s control rights and cash-flow rights (at the 10% threshold), all

divided by her control rights. MLSD is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm has at least two large shareholders (at the

10% threshold), and zero otherwise. In specifications 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8 we include the variables MLSD, MLSN, VR234,

VRRATIO and HERFINDHAL, respectively, to proxy for the presence, number and voting power of MLS. MLSN is the

number of large shareholders, other than the largest shareholder, up to the fourth. VR234 is the sum of voting rights of the

second, third and fourth largest shareholders. VRRATIO is the sum of voting rights of the second, third and fourth largest

Page 24: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

24

blockholders divided by the voting rights of the largest shareholder. HERFINDAHL is the sum of squared differences

between the voting rights of the four largest shareholders, that is, (VR1 − VR2)² + (VR2−VR3)² + (VR3−VR4)²; where VR1,

VR2, VR3 and VR4 equal the voting rights of the first, second, third and fourth largest shareholders. SIZE is the natural

logarithm of total assets in thousands of euros. INTSALES equals to the international sales divided by total sales. INVREC is

computed as the sum of inventories and accounts receivables scaled by total sales. LEVERAGE equals to total debt divided by

total assets. BIG_4 is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm uses one of the Big 4 auditing firms or their forerunners,

and zero otherwise. ROA is the firm’s return on assets defined as earnings before interest and taxes divided by the book value

of assets at the beginning of the fiscal year. BTM is the book-to-market ratio. NBS equals to the natural logarithm of the

firm’s number of business segments + 1. LOSS is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm reports a net loss in year t (that

is, its net income after taxes before extraordinary item and taxes on extraordinary item < 0), and zero otherwise.

CURRATIO is the firms’ current ratio, which equals to the ratio of current assets to current liabilities at the end of the fiscal

year. FISYREND is a dummy variable that equals one if the fiscal year-end is December 31, and zero otherwise. CROSSLIST

is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm is cross-listed in foreign capital markets in year t, and zero otherwise. All

continuous variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles. t-values based on White (1980) heteroscedasticity-

consistent standard errors are in parentheses beneath coefficient estimates. The superscript asterisks ***, **, and * denote

statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Page 25: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

25

Table 7: Comparison of variables considered to determine the presence of

MLS in original and matched samples

This table shows the mean difference tests of the variables used to determine the presence of MLS using the original and the

propensity score matching samples. It also provides the standardized percentage biases for each variable and the percentage

reduction in standardized bias. SIZE is the natural logarithm of total assets in thousands of euros. AGE is the firm age.

LEVERAGE equals to total debt divided by total assets. FCF is computed as earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and

amortization less interest, taxes, and common dividends, all divided by total assets. Tangibility equals to the firm’s property,

plants and equipment, divided by total assets. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles. The

superscript asterisks ***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Variable

Original sample Propensity score matching sample

Reduction

in bias

(%)

Firms

with

MLS

Firms

without

MLS

Diff. in

means

(t-stat)

Standa

rdized

bias

(%)

Firms

with

MLS

Firms

without

MLS

Diff. in

means

(t-stat)

Standar

dized

bias (%)

SIZE 12.095 12.824 -0.729***

(-6.68)

-36.4 12.095 12.141 -0.051

(-0.39) -2.3 93.7

AGE 39.484 46.414 -6.930***

(-4.19)

-22.5 39.484 40.931 -1.447

(-0.77) -4.7 79.1

LEVERAGE 0.216 0.236 -0.020**

(-2.23)

-11.9 0.216 0.198 0.018*

(1.71) 10.5 12.1

FCF 0.016 0.006 0.010

(1.50)

7.8 0.016 0.000 0.016*

(1.85) 11.9 -52.7

TANGIBLIT

Y

0.162 0.180 -0.018**

(-2.28)

-12.1 0.162 0.172 -0.010**

(-1.08)

-6.9 43.3

Page 26: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

26

Table 8: Robustness tests Set 1: Alternative variables

Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

UCO − UCF 0.47017*** (3.15)

EXCESS DUMMY 0.13057** (-2.40)

EXCESS CONTROL 0.33738** (2.13)

0.46151*** (2.96)

0.51053*** (3.33)

0.48312*** (3.09)

MLSD -0.14354** (-2.36)

-0.15528*** (-2.58)

-0.16287*** (-2.82)

-0.20067*** (-3.26)

SHAPLEY1 -0.19715** (-2.35)

PCA_INDEX -0.04440*** (-3.02)

SIZE 0.49582*** (25.26)

0.49318*** (24.93)

0.49809*** (25.66)

0.49266*** (24.88)

LN(SALES) 0.51445*** (26.09)

LN(EMPLOYEES) 0.43522*** (22.12)

INTSALES 0.61410*** (5.73)

0.61227*** (5.70)

0.59085*** (5.38)

0.62071*** (5.75)

0.75845*** (7.16)

0.91872*** (7.99)

INVREC -0.02596 (-1.48)

-0.02614 (-1.50)

-0.02577 (-1.55)

-0.02453 (-1.40)

0.00390 (0.29)

-0.00071 (-0.05)

LEVERAGE -0.17560 (-0.88)

-0.19731 (-1.00)

-0.18734 (-0.95)

-0.20883 (-1.05)

0.29766 (1.50)

0.47766** (2.28)

BIG_4 0.07209 (1.41)

0.07700 (1.50)

0.04742 (0.91)

0.06921 (1.35)

0.08312* (1.65)

0.12468** (2.29)

ROA -0.00856** (-2.07)

-0.00843** (-2.04)

-0.00834** (-2.00)

-0.00869** (-2.09)

-0.00680* (-1.67)

-0.00155 (-0.34)

BTM -0.47343*** (-4.49)

-0.48144*** (-4.57)

-0.42309*** (-4.02)

-0.47279*** (-4.48)

-0.44430*** (-4.18)

-0.65313*** (-5.39)

NBS 0.18913*** (2.67)

0.18726*** (2.66)

0.20945** (3.03)

0.18827*** (2.67)

0.15284** (2.14)

0.14496* (1.89)

LOSS -0.09637 (-1.14)

-0.10841 (-1.27)

-0.14538* (-1.72)

-0.10403 (-1.23)

-0.08903 (-1.07)

-0.16100* (-1.77)

CURRATIO -0.03369 (-0.82)

-0.03595 (-0.89)

-0.03551 (-0.87)

-0.03876 (-0.95)

0.03474 (0.85)

0.00146 (0.03)

FISYREND -0.05107 (-0.73)

-0.05990 (-0.84)

-0.06022 (-0.86)

-0.05864 (-0.83)

-0.02997 (-0.43)

-0.08165 (-1.11)

CROSSLIST -0.30146 (-1.39)

-0.29510 (-1.36)

-0.33145 (-1.54)

-0.30836 (-1.43)

-0.32084 (-1.43)

-0.04638 (-0.22)

Intercept

-1.99030*** (-5.81)

-1.91798*** (-5.59)

-2.11616*** (-6.61)

-1.96821*** (-5.88)

-1.13168*** (-3.49)

0.27147 (0.85)

Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Sample size 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483

Adjusted R² 0.581 0.581 0.581 0.582 0.590 0.540

This table presents a set of sensitivity tests as a robustness check of our results. The dependent variable is LNFEE, defined as

the natural logarithm of audit fees in thousands of euros. UCO equals to the control rights of the ultimate owner (at the 10%

threshold) measured by the sum of weakest links along each control chain. UCF equals to the cash-flow rights of the ultimate

owner (at the 10% threshold) measured by the sum of the products of ownership stakes along the different control chains.

Page 27: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

27

EXCESS DUMMY is a dummy variable that equals one if the control rights of the ultimate owner are higher than her cash-

flow rights; and zero otherwise. EXCESS CONTROL is the difference between the ultimate owner’s control rights and cash-

flow rights (at the 10%threshold), all divided by her control rights. MLSD is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm has

at least two large shareholders (at the 10% threshold), and zero otherwise. SHAPLEY1 is the Shapley value solution for the

largest controlling shareholder in a four shareholder voting game. PCA_INDEX is a contestability index defined as the

common factor extracted from the variables MLSD, MLSN, VR234, VRRATIO and HERFINDAHL using principal component

analysis. MLSN is the number of large shareholders, other than the largest shareholder, up to the fourth. VR234 is the sum of

voting rights of the second, third and fourth largest shareholders. VRRATIO is the sum of voting rights of the second, third

and fourth largest blockholders divided by the voting rights of the largest shareholder. HERFINDAHL is the sum of squared

differences between the voting rights of the four largest shareholders, that is, (VR1 − VR2)² + (VR2−VR3)² + (VR3−VR4)²;

where VR1, VR2, VR3 and VR4 equal the voting rights of the first, second, third and fourth largest shareholders. SIZE is the

natural logarithm of total assets in thousands of euros. LN (SALES) is the natural logarithm of sales. LN(EMPLOYEES) is the

natural logarithm of the number of employees. INTSALES equals to the international sales divided by total sales. INVREC is

computed as the sum of inventories and accounts receivables scaled by total sales. LEVERAGE equals to total debt divided by

total assets. BIG_4 is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm uses one of the Big 4 auditing firms or their forerunners,

and zero otherwise. ROA is the firm’s return on assets defined as earnings before interest and taxes divided by the book value

of assets at the beginning of the fiscal year. BTM is the book-to-market ratio. NBS equals to the natural logarithm of the

firm’s number of business segments + 1. LOSS is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm reports a net loss in year t (that

is, its net income after taxes before extraordinary item and taxes on extraordinary item < 0), and zero otherwise. CURRATIO

is the firms’ current ratio, which equals to the ratio of current assets to current liabilities at the end of the fiscal year.

FISYREND is a dummy variable that equals one if the fiscal year-end is December 31, and zero otherwise. CROSSLIST is a

dummy variable that equals one if the firm is cross-listed in foreign capital markets in year t, and zero otherwise. All

continuous variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles. t-values based on White (1980) heteroscedasticity-

consistent standard errors are in parentheses beneath coefficient estimates. The superscript asterisks ***, **, and * denote

statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Page 28: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

28

Table 9: Robustness tests Set 2: Alternative sample compositions

Variable

CLOSELY HELD FIRMS

CLOSELY HELD AND WIDELY HELD FIRMS

EXCLUDING PYRAMID

FIRMS

EXCLUDING CROSS-LISTED

FIRMS

USING ONLY BALANCED

PANEL DATA

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

EXCESS CONTROL 0.45082*** (2.77)

0.36709** (2.30)

0.46580** (2.14)

0.44387*** (2.87)

0.49900** (2.09)

MLSD -0.14968*** (-2.68)

-0.18135*** (-3.18)

-0.22435*** (-2.82)

-0.16850*** (-2.91)

-0.15765** (-2.14)

SIZE 0.54490*** (28.56)

0.53845*** (28.09)

0.48482*** (17.96)

0.51006*** (25.55)

0.45864*** (17.64)

INTSALES 0.78334*** (7.84)

0.81927*** (7.45)

0.51610*** (3.32)

0.45740*** (4.48)

0.52375*** (3.59)

INVREC -0.02378 (-1.43)

-0.02411 (-1.45)

-0.00828 (-1.29)

-0.02386 (-1.42)

-0.12313 (-1.03)

LEVERAGE -0.27624 (-1.63)

-0.23688 (-1.46)

0.19758 (0.74)

-0.24003 (-1.22)

0.24509 (0.92)

BIG_4 -0.07486 (-1.47)

-0.00711 (-0.13)

-0.03652 (-0.58)

0.05513 (1.08)

0.02632 (0.41)

ROA -0.00979*** (-2.68)

-0.01162*** (-3.18)

-0.01065** (-2.23)

-0.00989** (-2.39)

-0.00788* (-1.68)

BTM -0.33245*** (-3.68)

-0.38375*** (-4.30)

-0.64195*** (-5.11)

-0.44144*** (-4.22)

-0.51055*** (-3.65)

NBS 0.28810*** (4.84)

0.33060*** (5.22)

0.24463*** (2.59)

0.24301*** (3.53)

0.36677*** (3.62)

LOSS 0.04981 (0.56)

0.05351 (0.61)

-0.16776 (-1.58)

-0.10277 (-1.22)

-0.19818* (-1.94)

CURRATIO -0.06347** (-2.10)

-0.05884* (-1.91)

0.00277 (0.06)

-0.04219 (-1.04)

0.04882 (0.94)

FISYREND -0.00086 (-0.01)

-0.00034 (-0.01)

0.14230 (1.87)

-0.05636 (-0.79)

-0.11526 (-1.24)

CROSSLIST 0.09355 (0.49)

0.43648*** (2.74)

-0.12053 (-0.41)

--- -0.30106 (-1.37)

Intercept

-1.47461*** (-5.37)

-1.49942*** (-5.20)

-2.13817*** (-4.80)

-1.91386*** (-5.83)

-1.14261** (-2.07)

Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Sample size 1,943 2,035 976 1,427 808

Adjusted R² 0.610 0.620 0.560 0.592 0.563

This table presents a set of sensitivity tests as a robustness check of our results. The dependent variable is LNFEE, defined as

the natural logarithm of audit fees in thousands of euros. Column 1 presents regression results for the impact of multiple large

shareholders on audit fees using 1,943 family and non-family closely held firms. Column 2 shows results after using 2,035

closely held and widely held French listed firms. In Columns 3 and 4, we repeat our analysis after excluding all firms which

are controlled through pyramiding and all cross-listed firms, respectively. EXCESS CONTROL is the difference between the

ultimate owner’s control rights and cash-flow rights (at the 10% threshold), all divided by her control rights. MLSD is a

dummy variable that equals one if the firm has at least two large shareholders (at the 10% threshold), and zero otherwise.

SIZE is the natural logarithm of total assets in thousands of euros. INTSALES equals to the international sales divided by total

sales. INVREC is computed as the sum of inventories and accounts receivables scaled by total sales. LEVERAGE equals to

total debt divided by total assets. BIG_4 is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm uses one of the Big 4 auditing firms

or their forerunners, and zero otherwise. ROA is the firm’s return on assets defined as earnings before interest and taxes

divided by the book value of assets at the beginning of the fiscal year. BTM is the book-to-market ratio. NBS equals to the

natural logarithm of the firm’s number of business segments + 1. LOSS is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm

reports a net loss in year t (that is, its net income after taxes before extraordinary item and taxes on extraordinary item < 0),

and zero otherwise. CURRATIO is the firms’ current ratio, which equals to the ratio of current assets to current liabilities at

the end of the fiscal year. FISYREND is a dummy variable that equals one if the fiscal year-end is December 31, and zero

Page 29: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

29

otherwise. CROSSLIST is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm is cross-listed in foreign capital markets in year t, and

zero otherwise. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles. t-values based on White (1980)

heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors are in parentheses beneath coefficient estimates. The superscript asterisks ***,

**, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Page 30: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

30

Table 10: Robustness tests Set 2: Alternative control variables

Variable ANALYST UCF TANGIBILITY SALES_GR FCF PYRAMID AQ1 AQ2 EM IFRS ISSUE

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (10)

EXCESS CONTROL 0.47176*** (3.03)

0.30241* (1.65)

0.43446*** (2.82)

0.44500*** (2.90)

0.43839*** (2.84)

0.32606** (1.93)

0.44926*** (2.93)

0.44758*** (2.92)

0.44600*** (2.90)

0.44788*** (2.91)

0.43502*** (2.82)

MLSD -0.18202*** (-3.05)

-0.19705*** (-3.29)

-0.17155*** (-2.90)

-0.17100*** (-2.87)

-0.17227*** (-2.91)

-0.16901*** (-2.86)

-0.17701*** (-2.98)

-0.17512*** (-2.95)

-0.17355*** (-2.93)

-0.17366*** (-2.93)

-0.17163*** (-2.91)

ADDITIONAL CONTROL VARIABLE

-0.00579 (-0.81)

-0.24932* (-1.67)

-0.56323*** (-2.61)

-0.09728 (-0.72)

0.22432** (1.97)

0.10950* (1.76)

0.34840 (1.55)

0.31729 (1.35)

0.00037* (1.77)

0.69363*** (6.32)

0.26014** (2.29)

SIZE 0.50799*** (20.88)

0.48974*** (24.76)

0.49463*** (24.92)

0.49190*** (24.83)

0.49231*** (24.87)

0.49251*** (25.05)

0.49435*** (24.96)

0.49341*** (24.92)

0.49327*** (24.85)

0.49237*** (24.88)

0.49020*** (24.60)

INTSALES 0.62550*** (5.83)

0.60537*** (5.59)

0.61595*** (5.74)

0.61980*** (5.75)

0.62130*** (5.78)

0.61479*** (5.65)

0.62415*** (5.78)

0.62570*** (5.79)

0.61876*** (5.75)

0.62023*** (5.76)

0.61319*** (5.72)

INVREC -0.02486 (-1.43)

-0.02705 (-1.55)

-0.02718 (-1.54)

-0.02557 (-1.47)

-0.02484 (-1.42)

-0.02634 (-1.44)

-0.02315 (-1.39)

-0.02322 (-1.39)

-0.02529 (-1.45)

-0.02524 (-1.44)

-0.02502 (-1.44)

LEVERAGE -0.24687 (-1.25)

-0.23714 (-1.20)

-0.11389 (-0.56)

-0.21836 (-1.10)

-0.21857 (-1.10)

-0.23781 (-1.20)

-0.25369 (-1.27)

-0.25131 (-1.26)

-0.23250 (-1.17)

-0.22816 (-1.15)

-0.24370 (-1.23)

BIG_4 0.06694 (1.31)

0.05913 (1.15)

0.07104 (1.39)

0.06619 (1.29)

0.06893 (1.34)

0.07875 (1.54)

0.06694 (1.31)

0.06699 (1.31)

0.06518 (1.27)

0.06644 (1.30)

0.06368 (1.24)

ROA -0.00853** (-2.05)

-0.00819** (-1.97)

-0.00714* (-1.68)

-0.00787* (-1.92)

-0.00916** (-2.16)

-0.00879** (-2.11)

-0.00967** (-2.28)

-0.00921** (-2.20)

-0.00849** (-2.04)

-0.00847** (-2.04)

-0.00823** (-1.98)

BTM -0.50914*** (-4.46)

-0.46711*** (-4.42)

-0.41610*** (-3.76)

-0.48706*** (-4.43)

-0.47443*** (-4.49)

-0.47007*** (-4.44)

-0.46845*** (-4.44)

-0.47296*** (-4.48)

-0.47389*** (-4.48)

-0.47394*** (-4.48)

-0.46772*** (-4.43)

NBS 0.18556*** (2.62)

0.19247*** (2.73)

0.20204*** (2.89)

0.18977*** (2.69)

0.19118*** (2.72)

0.19799*** (2.79)

0.18243*** (2.59)

0.18421*** (2.61)

0.18795*** (2.67)

0.18896*** (2.68)

0.18568*** (2.64)

LOSS -0.09742 (-1.15)

-0.10798 (-1.26)

-0.08128 (-0.94)

-0.10799 (-1.25)

-0.10205 (-1.20)

-0.10970 (-1.30)

-0.10230 (-1.20)

-0.10292 (-1.21)

-0.10083 (-1.18)

-0.10089 (-1.18)

-0.09267 (-1.08)

CURRATIO -0.03538(-0.87)

-0.03860 (-0.96)

-0.03631 (-0.89)

-0.03794 (-0.94)

-0.04173 (-1.03)

-0.03162 (-0.77)

-0.04738 (-1.17)

-0.04747 (-1.17)

-0.03671 (-0.91)

-0.03710 (-0.92)

-0.03805 (-0.94)

FISYREND -0.05818 (-0.82)

-0.06752 (-0.96)

-0.04973 (-0.70)

-0.05325 (-0.76)

-0.05746 (-0.81)

-0.06275 (-0.89)

-0.06070 (-0.86)

-0.05930 (-0.84)

-0.05790 (-0.82)

-0.05683 (-0.81)

-0.05899 (-0.84)

Page 31: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

31

CROSSLIST -0.25176 (-1.13)

-0.33276 (-1.55)

-0.30103 (-1.39)

-0.31331 (-1.45)

-0.30807 (-1.43)

-0.30815 (-1.42)

-0.31570 (-1.46)

-0.31253 (-1.45)

-0.30923 (-1.43)

-0.30932 (-1.43)

-0.30315 (-1.41)

Intercept

-1.96914*** (-5.57)

-1.69933*** (-4.81)

-1.75350*** (-5.09)

-1.78316*** (-4.85)

-1.88415*** (-5.44)

-1.89554*** (-5.50)

-1.84025*** (-5.30)

-1.84052*** (-5.31)

-1.93634*** (-5.58)

-1.61321*** (-4.80)

-1.83070*** (-5.26)

Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Sample size 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483 1,483

Adjusted R² 0.582 0.583 0.584 0.582 0.583 0.583 0.583 0.582 0.582 0.582 0.583

This table presents a set of sensitivity tests as a robustness check of our results. The dependent variable is LNFEE, defined as the natural logarithm of audit fees in thousands of euros. EXCESS CONTROL is the difference between the ultimate owner’s control rights and cash-flow rights (at the 10% threshold), all divided by her control rights. MLSD is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm has at least two large shareholders (at the 10% threshold), and zero otherwise. ANALYST equals to the number of analysts reported if in I/B/E/S. UCF equals to the cash-flow rights of the ultimate owner (at the 10% threshold) measured by the sum of the products of ownership stakes along the different control chains. TANGIBILITY equals to the firm’s property, plants and equipment, divided by total assets. SALES_GR proxies for the firm’s sales growth, and computed as (SALESt−SALESt−1)/ SALESt−1. FCF = (Earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization − interest, taxes, and common dividends) / total assets. PYRAMID is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm is controlled through pyramiding, and 0 otherwise. AQ1 and AQ2 are measures of accruals quality based on Dechow and Dichev’s (2002) model and on McNichols’s (2002) model, respectively. EM is Leus et al.’s (2003) earnings management measure, defined as the ratio of the absolute value of accruals and the absolute value of the cash flow from operations, where Accruals = (Δtotal current assets − Δcash) − ( Δtotal current liabilities − Δshort-term debt − Δtaxes payable) − depreciation expense. SIZE is the natural logarithm of total assets in thousands of euros. INTSALES equals to the international sales divided by total sales. INVREC is computed as the sum of inventories and accounts receivables scaled by total sales. LEVERAGE equals to total debt divided by total assets. BIG_4 is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm uses one of the Big 4 auditing firms or their forerunners, and zero otherwise. ROA is the firm’s return on assets defined as earnings before interest and taxes divided by the book value of assets at the beginning of the fiscal year. BTM is the book-to-market ratio. NBS equals to the natural logarithm of the firm’s number of business segments + 1. LOSS is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm reports a net loss in year t (that is, its net income after taxes before extraordinary item and taxes on extraordinary item < 0), and zero otherwise. CURRATIO is the firms’ current ratio, which equals to the ratio of current assets to current liabilities at the end of the fiscal year. FISYREND is a dummy variable that equals one if the fiscal year-end is December 31, and zero otherwise. CROSSLIST is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm is cross-listed in foreign capital markets in year t, and zero otherwise. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles. t-values based on White (1980) heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors are in parentheses beneath coefficient estimates. The superscript asterisks ***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Page 32: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

32

References

Ali, A., Chen, T.-Y. and Radhakrishnan, S. (2007) Corporate disclosures by family firms, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 44(1-2), pp. 238-286.

Anderson, R. C., Reeb, D. M. and Zhao, W. (2012) Family-controlled firms and informed trading: Evidence from short sales, Journal of Finance, 67(1), pp. 351-386.

Attig, N., El Ghoul, S. and Guedhami, O. (2009) Do multiple large shareholders play a corporate governance role? Evidence from East Asia, Journal of Financial Research, 32(4), pp. 395-422.

Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O. and Rizeanu, S. (2013) The governance role of multiple large shareholders: Evidence from the valuation of cash holdings, Journal of Management & Governance, 17(2), pp. 419-451.

Attig, N., Fong, W. F., Gadhoum, Y. and Lang, L. H. P. (2006) Effects of large shareholding on information asymmetry and stock liquidity, Journal of Banking and Finance, 30, pp. 2875-2892.

Attig, N., Guedhami, O. and Mishra, D. (2008) Multiple large shareholders, control contests, and implied cost of equity, Journal of Corporate Finance, 14(5), pp. 721-737.

Bedard, J. C. and Johnstone, K. M. (2004) Earnings manipulation risk, corporate governance risk, and auditors' planning and pricing decisions, Accounting Review, 79(2), pp. 277-304.

Ben Ali, C. (2013) Qualité de la publication financière et mécanismes de gouvernance en France, Management & Avenir, 61(3), pp. 109-128.

Ben Ali, C. and Lesage, C. (2013) Les auditeurs financiers face aux conflits d'agence : Une étude des déterminants des honoraires d'audit en France, Comptabilité - Contrôle - Audit, 19(1), pp. 59-89.

Bennedsen, M. and Wolfenzon, D. (2000) The balance of power in closely held corporations, Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1/2), pp. 113-139.

Bloch, F. and Hege, U. (2003) Multiple shareholders and control contests, working paper HEC, pp.

Bolton, P. and Von Thadden, E.-L. (1998) Blocks, liquidity, and corporate control, Journal of Finance, 53(1), pp. 1-25.

Boubaker, S., Mansali, H. and Rjiba, H. (2013) Large controlling shareholders and stock price synchronicity, journal of banking and finance, forthcoming pp.

Boubaker, S., Mansali, H. and Rjiba, H. (2014) Large controlling shareholders and stock price synchronicity, Journal of Banking & Finance, 40, pp. 80-96.

Boubaker, S., Rouatbi, W. and Nguyen, P. (2012) Multiple large shareholders and corporate risk-taking: Evidence from France, SSRN eLibrary, pp.

Boubaker, S. and Sami, H. (2011) Multiple large shareholders and earnings informativeness, Review of Accounting and Finance, 10(3), pp. 246-266.

Chaney, P. K., Jeter, D. and Shivakumar, L. (2004) Self-selection of auditors and audit pricing in private firms., Accounting Review, 79(1), pp. 51-72.

Chau, G. and Gray, S. J. (2010) Family ownership, board independence and voluntary disclosure: Evidence from Hong Kong, Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, 19(2), pp. 93-109.

Chau, G. K. and Gray, S. J. (2002) Ownership structure and corporate voluntary disclosure in Hong Kong and Singapore, The International Journal of Accounting, 37(2), pp. 247-265.

Page 33: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

33

Chen, S., Chen, X. I. A. and Cheng, Q. (2008) Do family firms provide more or less voluntary disclosure?, Journal of Accounting Research, 46(3), pp. 499-536.

Choi, J.-H., Kim, J.-B., Liu, X. and Simunic, D. A. (2008) Audit pricing, legal liability regimes, and big 4 premiums: Theory and cross-country evidence, Contemporary Accounting Research, 25(1), pp. 55-99.

Choi, J.-H., Kim, J.-B., Liu, X. and Simunic, D. A. (2009) Cross-listing audit fee premiums: Theory and evidence, Accounting Review, 84(5), pp. 1429-1463.

Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J. P. H. and Lang, L. H. P. (2002) Disentangling the incentive and entrenchment effects of large shareholdings, Journal of Finance, 57(6), pp. 2741-2771.

Claessens, S., Djankov, S. and Lang, L. H. P. (2000) The separation of ownership and control in East Asian corporations, Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2 ), pp. 81-112.

Dechun, W. (2006) Founding family ownership and earnings quality, Journal of Accounting Research, 44(3), pp. 619-656.

Delgado-Garcia, J. B., De Quevedo-Puente, E. and De La Fuente-Sabaté, J. M. (2010) The impact of ownership structure on corporate reputation: Evidence from Spain, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 18(6), pp. 540-556.

Doidge, C., Karolyi, G. A., Lins, K. V., Miller, D. P. and Stulz, R. M. (2009) Private benefits of control, ownership, and the cross-listing decision, Journal of Finance, 64(1), pp. 425-466.

El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O., Lennox, C. S. and Pittman, J. (2013) External versus internal monitoring: The importance of multiple large shareholders and families to auditor choice in Western European firms, SSRN eLibrary, December 20(Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1373808 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1373808), pp.

Faccio, M. and Lang, L. H. P. (2002) The ultimate ownership of Western European corporations, Journal of Financial Economics, 65(3), pp. 365-395.

Fan, J. P. H. and Wong, T. J. (2002) Corporate ownership structure and the informativeness of accounting earnings in East Asia, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33(3), pp. 401-425.

Fan, J. P. H. and Wong, T. J. (2005) Do external auditors perform a corporate governance role in emerging markets? Evidence from East Asia, Journal of Accounting Research, 43(1), pp. 35-72.

Francis, J. R. (1984) The effect of audit firm size on audit prices : A study of the Australian market, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 6(2), pp. 133-151.

Francis, J. R., Khurana, I. K. and Pereira, R. (2003) The role of accounting and auditing in corporate governance and the development of financial markets around the world, Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics, 10, pp. 1-30.

Francis, J. R. and Wang, D. (2008) The joint effect of investor protection and big 4 audits on earnings quality around the world, Contemporary Accounting Research, 25(1), pp. 157-191.

Gul, F. A., Kim, J.-B. and Qiu, A. A. (2010) Ownership concentration, foreign shareholding, audit quality, and stock price synchronicity: Evidence from china, Journal of Financial Economics, 95(3), pp. 425-442.

Hay, D. C., Knechel, W. R. and Wong, N. (2006) Audit fees: A meta-analysis of the effect of supply and demand attributes, Contemporary Accounting Research, 23(1), pp. 141-191.

Ho, J. L. and Fei, K. (2013) Auditor choice and audit fees in family firms: Evidence from the S&P 1500, Auditing, 32(4), pp. 71-93.

Page 34: Auditors and Principal-Principal Agency Conflicts in

34

Holderness, C. G. (2009) The myth of diffuse ownership in the United States, Review of Financial Studies, 22(4), pp. 1377-1408.

Hope, O.-K., Langli, J. C. and Thomas, W. B. (2012) Agency conflicts and auditing in private firms, Accounting, Organizations & Society, 37(7), pp. 500-517.

Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. (1976) Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), pp. 305-360.

Khalil, S., Magnan, M. L. and Cohen, J. R. (2008) Dual-class shares and audit pricing: Evidence from the Canadian markets, Auditing, 27(2), pp. 199-216.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. (1999) Corporate ownership around the world, Journal of Finance, 54(2), pp. 471-517.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (2000) Investor protection and corporate governance, Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), pp. 3-27.

Laeven, L. and Levine, R. (2008) Complex ownership structures and corporate valuations, Review of Financial Studies, 21(2), pp. 579-604.

Lennox, C. (2005) Management ownership and audit firm size, Contemporary Accounting Research, 22(1), pp. 205-227.

Maury, B. and Pajuste, A. (2005) Multiple large shareholders and firm value, Journal of Banking & Finance, 29(7), pp. 1813-1834.

Mei-Ling, Y. (2010) The impact of controlling families and family ceos on earnings management, Family Business Review, 23(3), pp. 266-279.

Mishra, D. R. (2011) Multiple large shareholders and corporate risk taking: Evidence from East Asia, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 19(6), pp. 507-528.

Niemi, L. (2005) Audit effort and fees under concentrated client ownership: Evidence from four international audit firms, The International Journal of Accounting, 40(4), pp. 303-323.

Pagano, M. and Roëll, A. (1998) The choice of stock ownership structure: Agency costs, monitoring, and the decision to go public., Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1), pp. 187.

Simunic, D. A. (1980) The pricing of audit services: Theory and evidence, Journal of Accounting Research, 18(1), pp. 161-190.

Villalonga, B. and Amit, R. (2006) How do family ownership, control and management affect firm value?, Journal of Financial Economics, 80(2), pp. 385-417.

Zwiebel, J. (1995) Block investment and partial benefits of corporate control, Review of Economic Studies, 62(211), pp. 161.