aspiration, attainment and successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfeducation, inequality,...

20
©Copyright JASSS James Millington, Tim Butler and Chris Hamnett (2014) Aspiration, Attainment and Success: An Agent-Based Model of Distance-Based School Allocation Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 17 (1) 10 <http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html> Received: 03-Nov-2012 Accepted: 17-Jun-2013 Published: 31-Jan-2014 Abstract In recent years, UK governments have implemented policies that emphasise the ability of parents to choose which school they wish their child to attend. Inherently spatial school-place allocation rules in many areas have produced a geography of inequality between parents that succeed and fail to get their child into preferred schools based upon where they live. We present an agent-based simulation model developed to investigate the implications of distance-based school-place allocation policies. We show how a simple, abstract model can generate patterns of school popularity, performance and spatial distribution of pupils which are similar to those observed in local education authorities in London, UK. The model represents 'school' and 'parent' agents. Parental 'aspiration' to send their child to the best performing school (as opposed to other criteria) is a primary parent agent attribute in the model. This aspiration attribute is used as a means to constrain the location and movement of parent agents within the modelled environment. Results indicate that these location and movement constraints are needed to generate empirical patterns, and that patterns are generated most closely and consistently when schools agents differ in their ability to increase pupil attainment. Analysis of model output for simulations using these mechanisms shows how parent agents with above-average – but not very high – aspiration fail to get their child a place at their preferred school more frequently than other parent agents. We highlight the kinds of alternative school-place allocation rules and education system policies the model can be used to investigate. Keywords: Education, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has long been recognised that space is an important constraint on access to high quality education and health care services (e.g., Bradley et al. 1978; McLafferty 1982). In the UK, provoked by demands to improve educational attainment and in light of the 'widening choice' agenda forwarded by both New Labour and Conservative-led Coalition governments, there has recently been much interest in the geography of inequality in education provision and attainment (e.g., Butler and Hamnett 2007; Burgess and Briggs 2010; Harris and Johnston 2008; Gudson 2011). In recent years, both New Labour and Conservatives have implemented policies that emphasise the ability of parents to choose which school to send their child to, in part with the intention of driving up educational standards (Hamnett and Butler 2011). Despite this, evidence suggests that there has been little change in school intake composition (Allen and Vignoles 2007; Gibbons and Telhaj 2007). 1.2 Although work continues to investigate the causes and consequences of educational policy using traditional quantitative (e.g., Allen at al. 2013) and qualitative (e.g., Butler and Hamnett 2012) methods, there is clear scope for applying new tools such as agent-based simulation to investigate these issues (Tang et al. 2007; Maroulis et al. 2010a; Harland and Heppenstall 2012). However, very little work in this subject area has been pursued using agent-based modelling (ABM). Maroulis et al. (2010b) examined the impacts of choice-based reforms in Chicago Public Schools using an agent-based framework to show how variation in individuals' emphases in achievement led to constraints on the number of new schools that could survive in a given district. Harland and Heppenstall (2012) showed how simple rules allowed an agent-based model to reproduce empirical school allocation data for a region of northern England. To our knowledge, these studies are the current extent of the literature using agent-based simulation to investigate education systems. http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 1 15/10/2015

Upload: others

Post on 09-Oct-2020

6 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

©CopyrightJASSS

JamesMillington,TimButlerandChrisHamnett(2014)

Aspiration,AttainmentandSuccess:AnAgent-BasedModelofDistance-BasedSchoolAllocation

JournalofArtificialSocietiesandSocialSimulation 17(1)10<http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html>

Received:03-Nov-2012Accepted:17-Jun-2013Published:31-Jan-2014

Abstract

Inrecentyears,UKgovernmentshaveimplementedpoliciesthatemphasisetheabilityofparentstochoosewhichschooltheywishtheirchildtoattend.Inherentlyspatialschool-placeallocationrulesinmanyareashaveproducedageographyofinequalitybetweenparentsthatsucceedandfailtogettheirchildintopreferredschoolsbaseduponwheretheylive.Wepresentanagent-basedsimulationmodeldevelopedtoinvestigatetheimplicationsofdistance-basedschool-placeallocationpolicies.Weshowhowasimple,abstractmodelcangeneratepatternsofschoolpopularity,performanceandspatialdistributionofpupilswhicharesimilartothoseobservedinlocaleducationauthoritiesinLondon,UK.Themodelrepresents'school'and'parent'agents.Parental'aspiration'tosendtheirchildtothebestperformingschool(asopposedtoothercriteria)isaprimaryparentagentattributeinthemodel.Thisaspirationattributeisusedasameanstoconstrainthelocationandmovementofparentagentswithinthemodelledenvironment.Resultsindicatethattheselocationandmovementconstraintsareneededtogenerateempiricalpatterns,andthatpatternsaregeneratedmostcloselyandconsistentlywhenschoolsagentsdifferintheirabilitytoincreasepupilattainment.Analysisofmodeloutputforsimulationsusingthesemechanismsshowshowparentagentswithabove-average–butnotveryhigh–aspirationfailtogettheirchildaplaceattheirpreferredschoolmorefrequentlythanotherparentagents.Wehighlightthekindsofalternativeschool-placeallocationrulesandeducationsystempoliciesthemodelcanbeusedtoinvestigate.

Keywords:Education,Inequality,Aspiration,Schools,School-PlaceAllocation,ParentalChoice

Introduction

1.1 Ithaslongbeenrecognisedthatspaceisanimportantconstraintonaccesstohighqualityeducationandhealthcareservices(e.g.,Bradleyetal.1978;McLafferty1982).IntheUK,provokedbydemandstoimproveeducationalattainmentandinlightofthe'wideningchoice'agendaforwardedbybothNewLabourandConservative-ledCoalitiongovernments,therehasrecentlybeenmuchinterestinthegeographyofinequalityineducationprovisionandattainment(e.g.,ButlerandHamnett2007;BurgessandBriggs2010;HarrisandJohnston2008;Gudson2011).Inrecentyears,bothNewLabourandConservativeshaveimplementedpoliciesthatemphasisetheabilityofparentstochoosewhichschooltosendtheirchildto,inpartwiththeintentionofdrivingupeducationalstandards(HamnettandButler2011).Despitethis,evidencesuggeststhattherehasbeenlittlechangeinschoolintakecomposition(AllenandVignoles2007;GibbonsandTelhaj2007).

1.2 Althoughworkcontinuestoinvestigatethecausesandconsequencesofeducationalpolicyusingtraditionalquantitative(e.g.,Allenatal.2013)andqualitative(e.g.,ButlerandHamnett2012)methods,thereisclearscopeforapplyingnewtoolssuchasagent-basedsimulationtoinvestigatetheseissues(Tangetal.2007;Maroulisetal.2010a;HarlandandHeppenstall2012).However,verylittleworkinthissubjectareahasbeenpursuedusingagent-basedmodelling(ABM).Maroulisetal.(2010b)examinedtheimpactsofchoice-basedreformsinChicagoPublicSchoolsusinganagent-basedframeworktoshowhowvariationinindividuals'emphasesinachievementledtoconstraintsonthenumberofnewschoolsthatcouldsurviveinagivendistrict.HarlandandHeppenstall(2012)showedhowsimplerulesallowedanagent-basedmodeltoreproduceempiricalschoolallocationdataforaregionofnorthernEngland.Toourknowledge,thesestudiesarethecurrentextentoftheliteratureusingagent-basedsimulationtoinvestigateeducationsystems.

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 1 15/10/2015

Page 2: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

1.3 Oneoftheprimaryadvantagesofanagent-basedapproachforexaminingspatialmovementsofindividuals,comparedtousinganalyticspatialmodelssuchasgravityorradiationmodels(e.g.,Siminietal.2012),isthedisaggregatedandheterogeneousrepresentationofsystemelementsitallows.Whereasanalyticmodelsassumethesystemelementsbeingrepresentedarehomogenous,agent-basedapproachescanrepresentheterogeneousindividualswhichallowsuserstoexaminetheimportanceofdifferencesbetweenindividualsforsystem-leveloutcomes,andalsotheconsequencesofsystem-levelpropertiesforparticularindividualsystemelements.Furthermore,agent-basedsimulationmodelsrepresentenvironmentally-situatedentitiesthatarecapableofflexibleautonomousactiontomeetdesiredobjectives(i.e.,agentsthatcanactindifferentwaysdependingontheirenvironmentalcontext;O'Sullivan2008).Thesesimulationframeworkscanrepresentspatially-explicitprocesseswhentheirmodelassumptionsmeanthattherelativespatiallocationofheterogeneousindividualsinfluencesthecircumstances,andthereforebehaviour,ofothersimulatedindividuals(e.g.,Millingtonetal.2012).Thedegreetowhichdatainformstherepresentationoftheworldinthesemodelscanrangefromsimple,abstractmodelsusedasthoughtexperiments,throughlocallyspecificmodelsthataimtounderstandhowgeneralsocio-economicprocessesplayoutinparticularsettings,tohighlydetailedsimulationsthatrepresentverylarge,multi-dimensionalsystems(O'Sullivan2008).Ourapproachhereisatthesimple,abstractendofthisspectrumandis'generative'(Epstein1999,2006)inthatweseektoexplorehowthelocalinteractionofsimulatedheterogeneous,autonomousagentscanresultintheemergenceofmacroscopic(societal)regularities.Subsequently,wecanexaminetheimplicationsoftheindividualinteractionsthatproducesocialregularitiesfordifferentgroupsofindividuals(e.g.,withsimilarattributes).

1.4 Herewepresenttheinitialdevelopmentofanagent-basedsimulationmodelforinvestigatingtheimplicationsofUKlocaleducationauthorityschool-placeallocationpolicy.Webeginwithabriefoverviewoftheempiricalmacroscopic(i.e.,school-level)relationshipsweaimtoreproduce,beforethenpresentingmodelstructureandthelocalinteractionsitrepresents(i.e.,individualparents'attributesanddecision-making).Weexploredifferentsetsofrulesforinteractionsbetweenagents(schoolsandparents)andexaminetheirimpactonthereproductionofschool-levelrelationshipsandtheconsequencesforgroupsofparentswithsimilarattributes.Finally,wediscussourresultsandhighlightpotentiallyusefulwaysforwardforusingthismodellingapproachtoexaminesocialandpolicy-relatedquestions.

ThegeographyofinequalityinUKstateschooling

2.1 ThestatesecondaryschoolallocationprocessinEnglandandWalesisoperatedbylocaleducationalauthorities(LEAs).WithinanLEA,parentscanchoosetoapplytoasetnumberofschoolsfortheirchildtoattend,whichtheyrankintermsofpreference.Usingtheseapplicationsandrankings,LEAsthenallocateplacestoschools.Withtheexceptionofselective(e.g.,faith)schools,theallocationprocessisinherentlyspatialasplacesatover-subscribed(popular)schoolsareallocatedaccordingtothedistance

afamilylivesfromtheschool(nearestbeingallocatedfirst)[1].Thecloserafamilylivestoapopularschool,thebetterchanceofsecuringaplaceattheschoolforthechild.Thisformof'choice',thatbothfostersandaimstoaccommodateaspirationsofparentsbutwhichrequiresarationingmechanismtobalancethesupplyanddemandofpopularschools,producesageographyofinequalitywithwinnersandlosersthatsucceedorfailtogettheirchildintopreferredschools.

2.2 Thepatternsproducedbythiseducationalgeographyofinequalitycanbeseeninempiricaldataonschoolperformance,popularityandtraveldistances(HamnettandButler2011).SchoolperformanceismeasuredbythepercentageofstudentsachievingfiveormoreGeneralCertificateofSecondaryEducation(GCSE)gradesofA*–C(whichwerefertoasGCSE-5+).Schoolpopularitycanbemeasuredusingtheratioofparentapplicationstoavailableplaces(A:P)andtraveldistancesbythemaximumdistancewhichchildrenattendingtheschoollivefromit(MaxDist).ForempiricaldataonschoolsinsevenEastLondonLEAsin2007/08,HamnettandButler(2011)showhowtheapplicationandallocationcriteriadescribedaboveresultinapositiverelationshipbetweenA:PandGSCE-5+(seeTableVinHamnettandButler2011),anegativerelationshipbetweenA:PandMaxDist(seeTableVIIinHamnettandButler2011),andsmallerMaxDistformorepopularschoolscomparedtolesspopularschools(seeFigure5inHamnettandButler2011).

2.3 Todefinethesepatternsmorequantitativelysothatmodeloutputcanbebettercomparedweusepubliclyavailabledata[2]fortheBarkingandDagenhamLEAaveragedacrossfiveyears(2007-2011).Wefitlinearregressionmodelsandcalculatethe

coefficientofdeterminationr2forrelationshipsbetweenGCSE-5+andA:P,betweenA:PandMaxDist,andbetweenGCSE-5+andMaxDist(Figure1).AsHamnettandButler(2011)foundformultipleEastLondonLEAs,theserelationshipsshowthatschoolswithhigherpercentagesofstudentsachievingfiveormoreGCSEsatgradesA*–Caremorepopular(i.e.,havegreaterapplicationstoplacesratios,Figure1a),thatstudentsatmorepopularschoolsonaverageliveclosertotheschoolcomparedtolesspopularschools(Figure1b),andinturn,thatstudentsatthepoorestperformingschoolstravelonaveragefarthertoschoolthanthoseatthebestperformingschools(Figure1c).

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 2 15/10/2015

Page 3: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 3 15/10/2015

Page 4: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

Figure1.Empiricalschool-levelrelationshipsforschoolsinBarkingandDagenham2007–2011.Foreachplotm=regressioncoefficient,p=p-valueofregression,r2=coefficientofdetermination.

2.4 Theseempiricalpatternshighlighttheimportanceofthelocationwhereparentsliveforthechancesofgettingtheirchildintopopular,generallyhigherperforming,schools.However,interviewswithparentsinEastLondonhaveshownarangeofattitudestowardstheimportanceofeducation,fromlargelyindifferenttobeingthehighestpriority(ButlerandHamnett2011).Forexample,contrastthefollowingtwostatementsfromtwoparentsinthesameareaofEastLondon:

"Ithink[educationis]reasonablyimportant.Iwouldn'tputitupthereasreallytoprankedjustbecause,youknow,Ithinkthere'smoreimportantthingsinachild'slife."(ButlerandHamnett2011,p.105)

"Oh,thesinglemostimportantthingthataparentcangivetotheirchildreninlifeisafirst-classeducation"(ButlerandHamnett2011,p.98).

2.5 Withtheintentionofproducingasimple,abstractagent-basedsimulationmodelthatcangeneratethegeneralempiricalpatternsdescribedabove,wefocusontheover-archingconceptofparental'aspiration'tosendachildtothebestperformingschool(measuredbyexamresults).Weusethemodeltorepresentarangeof'aspiration'regardingeducationalattainment,fromlargelyindifferenttohighpriority.Furthermore,weusethisnotionalmeasureofaspirationasameanstoconstrainthelocationandmovementofparentswithinamodelledenvironment.Weexaminedifferentmechanisms(i.e.,modelrulesets)toidentifyhowtheyinfluencegeneratedpatternsandexaminethesensitivityofseveralkeymodelvariables.Firstwedescribethegeneralmodelstructure,beforethenpresentingresultsandanalysisofthedifferentmodelrule-andparametersets.

ModelStructure

3.1 OurdescriptionofmodelstructureusesselectedpartsoftheOverview,Designconcepts,andDetails(ODD)protocol.Thefull

ODDdescriptioncanbefoundonlinewiththemodelcodeatopenABM.org[3].

Purpose

3.2 ThepurposeofthismodelistoinvestigatemechanismsunderlyingthegeographyofeducationalinequalityintheUKandtheconsequencesofthesemechanismsforindividualswithvaryingattributesandmobility.

Entities,statevariablesandscales

3.3 Twotypesofagentsarerepresented;parentsandschools.Oneiterationofthemodelisassumedtobeequivalenttoasingleyear.Althoughparentsandschoolshaveexplicitspatiallocations,nospacescalesareimpliedorassumedandthemodelenvironmentisatorus.Atorusisappropriateinoursimple,abstractmodeltosuppressboundaryeffectssothatobservedvariationinattainmentandaccesstoschoolscanreliablybeattributedtostraight-linedistancesbetweenschoolsandparents(similartoapproachesusedinurbansegregationmodels;e.g.,LaurieandJaggi2003,FossettandDietrich2009).Themostimportantparentattributeistheiraspirationtosendtheirchildtothebestperformingschool.Aspirationtakesavaluefrom1to100andvariesbetweenparents.Thisrangeofvaluesrepresentsvariationinparents'attitudestowardswhethereducationalattainment(intermsofGCSEs)istheprimarycriteriaforselectingaschool(highvalues)oralessimportantcriteriainselectingaschool(lowvalues).Itreflectshowsomeparentswillseektomaximisethepossibilityoftheirchildattaininghighgradeswhereasotherwillbesatisfiedwithless(inthelightofotherprioritiesnotrepresentedinthismodel).Parents'aspirationvaluesaresetwhentheparentiscreatedanddonotchangethroughtime.Parentsareassumedtohaveasinglechild(notrepresentedasanindividualagent,butimplicitlyasanattributeoftheparent).Eachparenthastwochildattributes;child-ageandchild-attainment.Child-ageismeasuredinyearsandchild-attainmenttakesavaluefrom1to100.Bothchild-ageandchild-attainmentchange

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 4 15/10/2015

Page 5: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

throughtime.Initially,parents'child-attainmentisequaltotheiraspirationandchild-agehasavalueof9.Parentshaveanexplicitanduniquelocation(i.e.,parentscannotsharealocationwithotherparentsoraschool).Parentscanpotentiallychangelocationoncethroughtime.

3.4 Schoolshaveafinitenumberofplacesavailableforallocationtoparentseachyear.Schoolshavefiveacademicyearcohorts(i.e.,grades)ofparents(pupils)andhaveaGCSE-scoreattributewhichiscalculatedasthemeanofchild-attainmentvaluesofparentswithchild-age=15allocatedtotheschool(i.e.,GCSE-receivingfinal-yearstudents[4]).GCSE-scorecantakeavaluefrom0to100.Asbothallocatedparentsandchild-attainmentcanchangethroughtime,soGCSE-scorecanvarybetweenschoolsandthroughtime.Schoolshaveavalue-addedattributewhichisassignedatmodelinitializationandcanvarybetweenschoolsbutdoesnotchangethroughtime.Value-addedcantakeavaluebetween0.0and1.0.Eachyearschoolsrecordtheparentsallocatedaplaceandtheparentswhichappliedtotheschool.Schoolshaveanexplicitanduniquelocationwhichcannotchangethroughtime.Schoollocationscanberandomacrossthemodelenvironment,orwithequaldistancebetweeneachschool(i.e.,onagrid).

ProcessOverviewandscheduling

3.5 Eachyearexistingparentsintheenvironmentincreasetheirchild-agebyavalueof1.Schoolacademicyearcohortsarealsoaged(e.g.,year8parentsbecomeyear9parents)andparentsallocatedaschoolplaceinthepreviousyear(whentheirchildwasage10,nowage11)becomeyear7.Afterthisincrease,parentswithchild-age=16areremovedfromthemodelenvironment,astheirchildrenareassumedtohavereceivedtheirGCSEsandleftschool.Thisassumptionrepresentsthefactthathouseholdsthatnolongerhavechildrenatschoolwillnotbecompetingforplacesatschools(andnotbeoccupyingplacesatthoseschools)andensuresspaceisavailableintheenvironmentforparentswithyoungerchildrenapplyingforschoolplaces.Creatingthisspaceisimportantsothatthereproductionofeducationalinequalitycanbeexaminedthroughtimeandsharessimilaritieswithsimilarlysimple,abstractmodelsofresidentialsegregationthatassumeafixedpercentageofagentsleavethemodelenvironmentinagiventimestep(e.g.,Portugali2000;O'Sullivan2009).

3.6 Newparentsarethenaddedtothemodelenvironment.ThenumberofnewparentsaddedisgivenbyFamilies*Number-of-Schools.Thevaluesofthesevariablesarespecifiedbytheuseratmodelinitializationanddonotchangethroughtime.Newparentsareassignedtounoccupiedlocationsinthemodelenvironment.Locationassignmentcanbespatiallyrandomorconstrainedbyaspiration.Ifconstrained,themeanaspirationofparentsintheMooreneighbourhood(i.e.,8surroundinglocations)ofeachunoccupiedlocationiscalculated(knownaslocation-value;ifagivenlocationhasnoparentsinitsMooreneighbourhooditslocation-valueissettothemeanaspirationofallparentsinthemodelenvironment).Newparentsareassignedtheunoccupiedlocationwithgreatestlocation-valuewhichisalsolessthanthatparent'saspiration.Ifnolocationmatchesthesecriteria(i.e.,allunoccupiedlocationshavelocation-value>newparentaspiration)thenewparentisassignedthelocationwiththesmallestlocation-value.

3.7 Parentswhichhavenotyetbeenallocatedaschool(i.e.,thosewithchild-age=9orchild-age=10)thenassessschools.Theseparentsassesswhethertheybelievetheyarewithinthe'catchment'ofeachschool.Eachyearthemeanspatialdistanceofallallocatedparentsataschooliscalculated.Parentsassumetheyareinaschoolcatchmentiftheirdistancetotheschoolislessthanthesmallestmeandistanceforthelastparent-memoryyears.Theparent-memoryparameterissetbytheuseratmodelinitialization,doesnotvaryintimeorbetweenparents,andcantakeavaluefrom1to5.Unallocatedparentsalsoassesswhichschooltheyconsidersatisfactorytosendtheirchildto.Satisfactoryschoolsarethosewith:

(1)

Finally,theseunallocatedparentsassesswhich'poor'schoolstheywanttoavoidsendingtheirchild.Theseschoolstobeavoidedarethosewith:

(2)

Theavoided-thresholdparameterisaglobalparameterwhichdoesnotvaryintimeorbetweenparentsandcantakeavaluefrom0to1.

3.8 Parentswithchild-age=9(i.e.,oneyearbeforetheywillbeallocatedtoaschool)thencheckiftheywanttomovefromtheircurrentlocationtotrytoincreasetheirchanceofhavingtheirchildallocatedtoasatisfactoryschool(inthenextyear)bylivingclosertothatschool.ParentsrankthetopNumber-of-Rankschoolsusingoneofeightstrategies,dependingontheircircumstances(seeTable1).Theythenchecklocationsincatchmentsoftheseschoolsinrankorder(startingwithtoprank)untilalocationisfoundorallschoolcatchmentshavebeenchecked.Parentswillnotbeabletomoveiftherearenounoccupiedlocationsinacatchmentorifavailabilityoflocationsisconstrainedbylocation-value(seeabove).Theyearinwhichachild-age=9istheonlyoneinwhichparentscanmove.Ultimately,thisisnotanaccuraterepresentationofrealityasparentscouldmovemultipletimesbeforeandafterschoolallocation.However,thissingle-moveassumptioniscrediblegiventhataspectsthatmayinfluencehousemovesotherthanschooling(e.g.,changesinfamilyincomeorsize)arenotrepresentedinthissimple,abstractmodel.

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 5 15/10/2015

Page 6: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

Table1:Idealisedparentrankingstrategiesformoving.SchoolsconsideredbyparentstobesatisfactoryortobeavoidedaredeterminedbyEq.1andEq.2,respectively.

Strategy Criteria Response1 Believedtobeinnoschool

catchmentNoschoolsconsideredsatisfactoryNoschoolsavoided

RankallschoolsbyGCSE-scoredescending

2 BelievedtobeinnoschoolcatchmentNoschoolsconsideredsatisfactoryAtleastoneschoolavoided

Rankallschools–exceptthoseavoided–byGCSE-scoredescending

3 BelievedtobeinnoschoolcatchmentAtleastoneschoolconsideredsatisfactoryNoschoolsavoided

RankschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybyGCSEscoredescending,thenallotherschoolsbyGCSEscoredescending

4 BelievedtobeinnoschoolcatchmentAtleastoneschoolconsideredsatisfactoryAtleastoneschoolavoided

RankschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybyGCSEscoredescending,thenallotherschools–exceptthoseavoided–byGCSEscoredescending

5 BelievedtobeinoneormoreschoolcatchmentNoschoolsconsideredsatisfactoryNoschoolsavoided

RankschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybyGCSEscoredescending,thenallotherschoolsbyGCSEscoredescending

6 BelievedtobeinatleastoneschoolcatchmentNoschoolsconsideredsatisfactoryAtleastoneschoolavoided

RankschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybyGCSEscoredescending,thenallotherschools–exceptthoseavoided–byGCSEscoredescending

7 BelievedtobeinatleastoneschoolcatchmentAtleastoneschoolconsideredsatisfactoryNoschoolsavoided

Donottrytomove

8 BelievedtobeinatleastoneschoolcatchmentAtleastoneschoolconsideredsatisfactoryAtleastoneschoolavoided

RankschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybyGCSEscoredescending,thenallotherschools–exceptthoseavoided–byGCSEscoredescending

3.9 Parentswithchild-age=10rankthetopNumber-of-Rankschoolsthattheywillapplytosendtheirchildtousingoneofeightstrategiesdependingontheircircumstances(seeTable2).Todeterminewhichstrategytouse,parentscheckwhichschool

catchment(s)theybelievetheyarelocatedwithinandwhetherthereareschoolstheydeemsatisfactorytosendtheirchild[5].

Table2:Idealisedparentrankingstrategiesforschoolapplication.SchoolsconsideredbyparentstobesatisfactoryortobeavoidedaredeterminedbyEq.1andEq.2,respectively.

Strategy Criteria Response1 Believedtobeinno

schoolcatchmentNoschoolsconsideredsatisfactoryNoschoolsavoided

Rankallschoolsbydistanceascending

2 BelievedtobeinnoschoolcatchmentNoschoolsconsideredsatisfactoryAtleastoneschoolavoided

Rankallschools–exceptthoseavoided–bydistanceascending

3 Believedtobeinnoschoolcatchment

Rankschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybydistanceascending,thenallotherschoolsbydistanceascending

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 6 15/10/2015

Page 7: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

AtleastoneschoolconsideredsatisfactoryNoschoolsavoided

4 BelievedtobeinnoschoolcatchmentAtleastoneschoolconsideredsatisfactoryAtleastoneschoolavoided

Rankschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybydistanceascending,thenallotherschools–exceptthoseavoided–bydistanceascending

5 BelievedtobeinoneormoreschoolcatchmentNoschoolsconsideredsatisfactoryNoschoolsavoided

RankthoseschoolsbelievedtobeinthecatchmentofbyGCSEscoredescending,thenallotherschoolsbydistanceascending

6 BelievedtobeinatleastoneschoolcatchmentNoschoolsconsideredsatisfactoryAtleastoneschoolavoided

Exceptforthoseschoolsavoided,rankschoolsbelievedtobeinthecatchmentofbyGCSEscoredescendingfollowedbyallotherschoolsbydistanceascending

7 BelievedtobeinatleastoneschoolcatchmentAtleastoneschoolconsideredsatisfactoryNoschoolsavoided

RankthoseschoolsbelievedtobeinthecatchmentofbyGCSEscoredescending,thenthoseschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybydistanceascending,thenallothersschoolsbydistanceascending

8 BelievedtobeinatleastoneschoolcatchmentAtleastoneschoolconsideredsatisfactoryAtleastoneschoolavoided

Exceptforthoseschoolsavoided,rankthoseschoolsbelievedtobeinthecatchmentofbyGCSEscoredescending,thenthoseschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybydistanceascending,thenallother(non-avoided)schoolsbydistanceascending

3.10 Schoolsthenallocateplaces[6]toparentswithchild-age=10readyfortheirchildtobecomeapupiloftheschoolthenextyear.Schoolsallocateapplicantsthatrankedthemhighestfirst(startingwiththeclosestparentandallocatinginascendingorderofdistance).Onceallschoolshaveallocatedthesetop-rankingparents,ifplacesremainunallocated(i.e.,iftherewerelessparentsrankingthemfirstthantotalplacesavailable)schoolsthenallocateapplicantsthatrankedthemsecond(again,allocatingbydistanceascending).Thisprocesscontinues(thirdranks,fourthranks,etc.)untilallparents'rankingshavebeenchecked.Schoolsthathaveremainingplacesafterallrankedpreferenceshavebeenallocated,thenallocateremainingplacestounallocatedparentsondistance(closestallocatedfirstthenbydistanceascending).Thisapproachtoschool-placeallocationimplementstheGale-Shapley(1962)method(withrankingdeterminedbydistancetoschool)asusedbyLEAsinEngland(Allenetal.2010).

3.11 Finally,alsoinpreparationforthefollowingyear,existingparentsalreadyallocatedaplaceataschoolupdatetheirchild-attainmentusingtheidealisedrelationship:

(3)

whereCAischild-attainment,SVAisthevalue-addedoftheschoolattended,SPEisSchool-Peer-Effect,PEisParent-Effect,SCAisthemeanchild-attainmentofallparentsallocatedaplaceattheschoolandtdenotesthetimestep.Multiplefactorsarebelievedtoinfluencechangesinpupilattainmentduringtheirtimeatsecondaryschool,attributabletoindividualpupils'backgrounds(e.g.,ethnicityandclass;Connolly2006;Hamnettetal.2007)andschool-levelfactors(e.g.,schoolcompositionandpeer-effects;Thruppetal.2002;Willms2010).ThestructureandcompositionofEq.3allowstherelativeimportanceofseveralfactorstobeexamined.Specifically,School-Peer-EffectandParent-Effectcantakevaluesfrom0(noeffectonpupilattainmentthroughtime)to0.5(largeeffectonpupilattainmentthroughtime)andreflecttheinfluenceoftheattainmentofpupils'peersandtheaspirationsoftheirpupils'parentsonattainment.Thepossibleinfluenceoffactorsbeyondpupilsandparentsthemselves(i.e.,facilities,teachersetcoftheschoolitself)isreflectedbyvalue-added.Wheneachofthesethreevariablesiszerothereisnochangeinpupilattainmentthroughtime.SchoolsthenupdatetheirGCSE-scoretobethemeanofchild-attainmentofallocatedparentswithchild-age=15(i.e.,year11pupils).

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 7 15/10/2015

Page 8: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

ModelTestingandEvaluation

StateVariables

4.1 Toevaluateandtestthemodelweconsiderstatevariablesatthreedifferentlevelsofaggregationandscale.TomeasurespatialautocorrelationofparentaspirationattheleveloftheentiresimulatedenvironmentweuseMoran'sI,calculatingthestatisticandtheprobabilitythatthestatisticisstatisticallysignificantlydifferentfromzero(p)foreachtimestep.WecannotestimateMoran'sIforempiricaldataandsodonotconsiderthisanempiricalpatternbywhichtoassessthegenerativepropertiesofthemodelrules.However,thismeasureisausefulmeanstoidentifyiflocalinteractionsrulesresultinsystem-levelspatialpatterns(i.e.,spatialautocorrelationofparentagentattributes).AttheschoollevelwemeasureGCSE-score(correspondingtoGCSE-5+),A:PandMaxDistandfitlinearregressionmodels(withcoefficientandsignificancevaluesmandp,respectively)andcalculatethecoefficientofdetermination(r2)foreachcombinationofpairsofthesevariablesineachtimestep(aswedidforempiricaldatain

Figure1).Forregressionmodelsfrommodeloutputwecalculatethemeanmodelcoefficient,meanr2andthemeannumberof

timestepsduringamodelruninwhichregressionp>0.05.Weusevaluesform,pandr2asindicatorstocomparehowresultsfordifferentmodelrulessetsreproducethegeneralpatternsoutlinedabove,usingthequantifiedvaluesforourempirical

regressionsasaguide.Thus,weassumethatmodelresultswithlargerabsolutevaluesofm,higherr2valuesandlowerpvaluesindicatestrongerreproductionofgeneralempiricalpatterns.Attheparentlevelweconsiderparentstrategyforschoolapplication(seeTable2),applicationsuccess,distancetoallocatedschool,aspiration,child-attainmentchange,andwhethertheparentmovedornotpriortoallocation.Parentapplicationsuccessisevaluatedbycomparingwhetherachildwasallocatedaplaceattheirtoprankedschool(successifso,otherwisenot).Changeinchild-attainmentisthedifferencebetweenchild-attainmentwhenchild-age=10(i.e.,priortoenteringschool)andwhenchild-age=15(i.e.,whenreceivingGCSEresultsandleavingschool).Wedonotcurrentlyhaveempiricalequivalentswithwhichtocomparethesemeasures.

Methods

4.2 Totestandevaluatethemodelweconsiderwhichmodelrulesand/orconditionsarenecessaryforthemodeltogeneratetheschool-levelempiricalpatternsdescribedabove(Section2).Hence,theapproachis'generative'(Epstein1999).Wealsoexaminehowdifferentrulesandmodelconditionsinfluencespatialautocorrelationofparentaspirationacrosstheentiremodelenvironment.Weevaluatetheimportanceofthespatialdistributionofschools,locationconstraints,andschoolvalue-added(Table3).Weevaluatetheimportanceofthreemodelruleoptions:i)thespatialdistributionofschools,byeitherlocatingthemrandomlyacrossthemodelenvironmentorregularlyspaced(onagrid);ii)theimportanceofparentallocationconstraints,byrunningthemodelwithandwithouttheconstraintoflocation-value;andiii)theimportanceofschoolvalue-added,byeithersettingallschools'value-addedtozeroorallowingvaluestovaryrandomly(between0and1).Foreachoftheeightrule-setsthecombinationsoftheseruleoptionsproduce(Table3),werunthemodel25timesfor100timesteps(withparametervaluesasshowninTable4).Foranalysisweuseonlythelast80timestepsofeachmodelrunasrandominitializationmeansthatittakesatleast10timestepsbeforeschoolshavehadasinglecohortofstudentspassthroughtheschoolwithchild-attainmentcorrectlycalculated(Eq.3,andseeinitialvariationinvariablesinFigure2).

Table3:Combinationsofrulesformodeltesting.

RuleSet RandomSchools LocationConstraints SchoolValue-Added1 No Yes Yes2 No No Yes3 Yes Yes Yes4 Yes No Yes5 No Yes No6 No No No7 Yes Yes No8 Yes No No

Table4:Defaultparametervaluesusedinmodelruns(unlessotherwisespecified).

Parameter ValueFamilies 100Parent-Memory 5Number-of-Schools 9Number-of-Ranks 4

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 8 15/10/2015

Page 9: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

Initial-School-GCSE-Distribution Uniform,1Parent-Aspiration-Distribution Gaussian,μ=50σ=20Aspiration-Mean 50School-Value-Added-Distribution Gaussian,μ=0σ=0.1Avoided-Threshold 0.5School-Peer-Effect 0.25Parent-Effect 0.25

4.3 Forthemodelthatbestgeneratesempiricalpatternswealsoperformsensitivityanalyses(forparametersandvaluesasshowninTable5).

Table5:Parametervaluesusedinsensitivityanalyses.

ParameterSet Parameter Value9 NumberofRanks 210 NumberofRanks 611 AvoidedThreshold 0.0512 AvoidedThreshold 0.2513 AvoidedThreshold 0.7514 AvoidedThreshold 0.9515 SchoolPeerEffect,ParentEffect 0.00,0.0016 SchoolPeerEffect,ParentEffect 0.25,0.0017 SchoolPeerEffect,ParentEffect 0.50,0.0018 SchoolPeerEffect,ParentEffect 0.00,0.2519 SchoolPeerEffect,ParentEffect 0.50,0.2520 SchoolPeerEffect,ParentEffect 0.00,0.5021 SchoolPeerEffect,ParentEffect 0.25,0.5022 SchoolPeerEffect,ParentEffect 0.50,0.50

Results:Rulesets

4.4 Relationshipsbetweenstatevariables(Table6)indicatethatthemodelproducesresultswhichgenerateempiricalpatternsmost

closelyandconsistently(i.e.,largem,highr2,lowp)whenparentsareconstrainedbywheretheycanlive,whenschoolsdifferentiallyaddvaluetopupils'attainmentandwhenschoolsarenotrandomlylocated(i.e.,RuleSet1,Table3).ResultsindicatethatatleastoneoftheLocationConstraintsorSchoolValue-Addedrulesisneededtogeneratetherelationshipbetweenschoolperformanceandpopularity(GCSE-5+vs.A:P).Ifneitherispresent(e.g.,RuleSets6and8),therangeofschoolperformanceisverylow(i.e.,littledifferencebetweenmaximumandminimumschoolGCSE-5+,Figure2),andthereforenoclearpreferencesbetweenschoolsarise.TogeneratestrongspatialautocorrelationinparentaspirationtheLocationConstraintsruleisneeded(RuleSets1,3,5,7)astheseconstraintsproduce'neighbourhoods'ofaspiration(e.g.,Figure3).Inturn,whencombinedwithnon-randomlocationofschools(i.e.,RuleSets1and5),constrainingthelocationofparentsgeneratesgoodrelationshipsatschoollevel.Thus,patterninbothlocationofparentsandschoolsisrequiredtogenerateempiricalrelationships,andthisisenhancedwhenschoolsdifferinthevaluetheyaddtopupils'attainment.

Table6:Measuresofrelationshipsbetweenkeyempiricalvariablesfordifferentmodelrulesets[7]

Rule GCSE-5+vsA:P GCSE-5+vsMaxDist A:PvsMaxDist Moran'sISet m r2 p m r2 p m r2 p Stat. p

1 7.89 0.96 0.00 -0.78 0.70 5.58 -0.09 0.65 10.00 0.92 0.002 6.88 0.85 0.68 -0.18 0.38 47.20 -0.02 0.36 50.92 0.01 32.503 8.53 0.94 0.12 -0.41 0.23 70.16 -0.04 0.20 71.16 0.91 0.004 6.51 0.76 4.84 -0.01 0.13 74.68 0.00 0.14 74.44 0.01 31.505 6.98 0.97 0.00 -0.67 0.68 8.60 -0.09 0.65 10.96 0.92 0.006 1.79 0.30 56.68 0.00 0.12 76.16 0.00 0.11 76.88 0.01 46.007 7.36 0.92 2.60 -0.26 0.18 71.92 -0.03 0.16 74.96 0.91 0.00

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 9 15/10/2015

Page 10: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

8 1.37 0.26 61.40 0.01 0.15 74.44 0.00 0.17 72.56 0.01 54.00

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 10 15/10/2015

Page 11: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

Figure2.TimeseriesofGCSEandrangeandA:Prange.Solidlinesarethemeanof25modelrunsforthegivenparameterset.Shadedareasarethe95%confidenceintervalaroundthecorrespondingmean,calculatedfromthestandarderrorof25model

runs.

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 11 15/10/2015

Page 12: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

Figure3.Examplefinalmodelstatemaps.Mapsareofparentaspiration(lightershadesarehigheraspiration).Schoolsareshownashouseicons(lightershadesindicatehigherGCSE-score).NumbersindicateRuleSets(assummarisedinTable3).

Results:Sensitivityanalysis

4.5 Whencomparedtoresultsforthebestmodelruleset(RuleSet1),sensitivityanalysisresultsindicatethatmodelledschool-levelrelationshipsarelargelyinsensitivetovariationinparametersinfluencingparents'schoolrankingandchild-attainmentchange(Table7).Theexceptionisforhighervaluesofavoided-threshold(Eq.2).Whenavoided-threshold=0.95(ParameterSet6)relationshipsbetweenGCSE-5+andMaxDistandbetweenA:PandMaxDistbreakdown(i.e.,thereisnorelationship)andforavoided-threshold=0.75(ParameterSet5)therelationshipsbecomeweaker(i.e.,norelationshipmorefrequently).

Table7:Measuresofrelationshipsbetweenkeyempiricalvariablesforsensitivityanalyses[8]

Parm GCSE-5+vsA:P GCSE-5+vsMaxDist A:PvsMaxDist Moran'sISet m r2 p m r2 p m r2 p Stat. p

1 11.21 0.93 0.00 -0.70 0.65 8.76 -0.06 0.61 12.16 0.93 0.002 7.66 0.90 0.00 -0.79 0.69 6.08 -0.09 0.60 12.68 0.91 0.003 8.35 0.96 0.00 -0.80 0.71 5.00 -0.09 0.67 8.04 0.92 0.004 8.09 0.96 0.00 -0.80 0.70 4.12 -0.09 0.66 7.08 0.92 0.005 5.39 0.93 0.04 -0.68 0.59 20.56 -0.11 0.53 25.80 0.92 0.006 6.12 0.88 0.40 -0.04 0.13 76.52 0.00 0.11 78.12 0.93 0.007 9.67 0.95 0.00 -1.06 0.69 7.60 -0.11 0.67 9.12 0.92 0.008 10.69 0.93 0.00 -1.18 0.71 5.64 -0.11 0.69 6.44 0.92 0.009 10.80 0.93 0.00 -1.13 0.68 9.60 -0.10 0.66 12.40 0.92 0.0010 8.11 0.95 0.00 -0.84 0.70 5.52 -0.10 0.65 10.28 0.92 0.0011 7.39 0.96 0.00 -0.71 0.68 7.76 -0.09 0.63 12.32 0.92 0.0012 7.37 0.96 0.00 -0.72 0.64 10.16 -0.09 0.60 17.76 0.91 0.0013 7.16 0.96 0.00 -0.68 0.67 8.28 -0.09 0.63 12.92 0.91 0.0014 7.04 0.97 0.00 -0.66 0.66 9.72 -0.09 0.62 13.12 0.92 0.00

Results:Parent-levelanalysis

4.6 Attheparentlevel,plotsofproportionsofparentsinclassesofonestatevariablesagainstclassesofotherstatevariablesareusefultoidentifyrelationshipsbetweenthosevariables(e.g.,Figure4).Someoftheserelationshipsareappropriateforverifyingmodelfunctiongivenmodelstructure,butothersareinterestingtounderstandwhatthemodelstructureimpliesforparentswithdifferentattributes.

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 12 15/10/2015

Page 13: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 13 15/10/2015

Page 14: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

Figure4.Relationshipsbetweenvariablesattheparent-levelofanalysis(forRuleSet1).

4.7 Asexpected,givendistance-basedschoolallocationrulesinthemodel,resultsshowthatparentslivingclosertotheirallocatedschoolaremorelikelytohaverankedthatschoolastheirtoppreference(Figure4a).Furthermore,ofparentsthatsuccessfullygettheirchildintotheirtoprankedschool,morehavepositivechild-attainmentchange(bluecoloursinFigure4a)thannegative(redcolours).However,itisnottheparentsintheclosestdistanceclass(distance<10)thathavegreatestpositivechild-attainmentchange.Rather,onaverageitisparentsintheseconddistanceclass(10–20)thatachievegreatestchild-attainmentincreases.Forexample,agreaterproportionofparentsintheseconddistanceclasshavepositivechild-attainmentthanthoseintheclosest(82%comparedwith56%)andoverallmeanchild-attainmentchangeisgreaterforthesecondclass(+6.36)thantheclosest(+1.76).Incontrast,thevastmajority(92%)ofparentsinthefourthdistanceclassandgreater(i.e.,allocateddistance≥30)havenegativechild-attainmentchange.Ofparentsinthesedistanceclasses,only1%weresuccessfulingettingtheirchildintotheirtop-rankedschool,againhighlightingtheimportanceofdistanceallocationrulesandtheirrelationshipwithschool(andpupil)performance.

4.8 Whenweconsiderrelationshipsbetweenparentaspiration,allocateddistanceandwhetherparentshavemovedornot(Figure4b)weobservethatasaspirationincreasesparentsaremorelikelytomove.Parentsthatmovearemorelikelytoliveintheclosestallocatedschooldistanceclass(distance<10).Noparentsinthefarthestallocatedschooldistanceclasses(i.e.,distance≥30)movedtobeinthatposition,andtheseparentsarenotthosewithlowestaspiration.Rather,parentswithhigherthanaverage,butnotveryhigh,aspiration(i.e.,thosewithaspiration60–70)aremostlikelytobeallocatedtoaschoolwithdistance≥30.

4.9 Parentsinthismedium-highaspirationclass(aspiration60–70)alsofailtogettheirchildintotheirpreferredschoolmoreoftenthanparentsinotheraspirationclasses(Figure4c).Parentswithaspiration≥70aremorelikelytobeinaschoolcatchmentwhenapplyingtoaschool(Figure4c,increasedproportionsofstrategies5–8intheseclasses).Furthermore,asaspirationincreases,thelikelihoodofsucceedingusingstrategy3torankschoolsforallocationdecreases(Figure4c;i.e.,thedangerofnotbeingintheschoolcatchmentofasatisfactoryschoolisgreaterforthosewithhigheraspiration).

Discussion

ModelStructure

5.1 Ourmodeltestingandevaluationshowshowdifferencesbetweenschools'performance(andthereforeparents'schoolpreferences)combinedwithdistance-basedschool-placeallocationrules,areneededtoreproduceempiricallyobservedschool-levelpatterns.Theapproachwehaveusedis'generative'(Epstein1999,2006),seekingtoexplaintheemergenceofmacroscopic(societal)regularitiesarisingfromthelocalinteractionofsimulatedheterogeneous,autonomousagents.Usinganagent-basedsimulationmodelwehavegeneratedobservedmacroscopicregularities(i.e.,relationshipsbetweenschoolperformance,popularityandallocation)fromthe'bottomup'bysimulatingindividualparents'aspirationsregardingeducationalattainmentandtheireffortstodosointhefaceofdistance-basedschoolallocationrules.

5.2 Startingwithrandomlocationsofparentsandschoolswithidenticalperformance(GCSE-5+),thisgenerativeapproachallowsustoshowthateitheri)differencesintheabilitiesofparentstomovetolocationsnearpreferredschools,orii)variationintheincreasesinattainmentschoolscanprovidetopupilsareneededtogeneratetheempiricalrelationshipbetweenschoolexam(GCSE)performanceandschoolpopularity.Ifneitheroftheserulesispresentinthemodel,variationinschoolperformanceisnotproduced(Figure2)meaningthatparents'schoolpreferencesareinconsistentacrossthemodelledenvironment(i.e.,itisnotclearwhichschoolsarebetterthanothers).Differencesintheabilitiesofparentstomoveareimportantforcreatingneighbourhoods(groupings)ofparentswithsimilaraspiration(Figure3;Moran'sIinTable6).Inturn,theseneighbourhoodsmeanthatchildrenwithsimilarinitialattainment(becauseinitialchild-attainmentisequaltoparentaspiration)aremorelikelytoattendthesameschool,reinforcingimprovementsinschoolperformance(viaSchool-Peer-Effect).Variationintheimprovementthatschoolscancontributetopupils'attainmentalsoproducesvariationinschoolperformance,buttoalesserdegreethantheneighbourhoodsofaspirationeffect.Wefoundthatincreasingtherangeofimprovementthatschoolscontributetopupilattainment(i.e.,fromσ=0.1forSchool-Value-Added-Distributiontoσ=0.5,Table4)doesincreasethiseffect,butstilldoesnotproduceasconsistentlysignificantrelationshipsasforparentlocationconstraints(e.g.,pforGCSE-5+vs.MaxDistof22.48comparedwith5.58and8.60forRuleSets1and5respectively,Table6).

5.3 Anothermodelrule-setweinvestigatedwastherandomlocationofschools(i.e.,RuleSet3,Table3).Whenschoolsarerandomlylocatedspatiallyacrossthemodelenvironment,theempirically-observeddistancerelationshipscollapse.Thisis

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 14 15/10/2015

Page 15: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

becauseoftheabilitiesofparentstomoveintodesiredschoolcatchmentsandbecauseoftheagentlogicusedinthemodel.Withrandomschoollocations,schoolsareoftenclosetogetherandsoparentscanbelocatedinmorethanasingleschoolcatchment(i.e.,schoolcatchmentsoverlap),asituationwhichdoesn'toccurwhenschoolsareregularlyspaced.Consequently,agreaternumberofparentsareinschoolcatchmentswhenitcomestoparentsrankingforallocationandschoolsallocating,asshownbygreaterproportionsofparentsindistanceclasses10–20and20–30usingrankingstrategy7than3(compareFigures5aand5b).Theoverlappingofschoolcatchmentsalsomeansthatparentsaremorelikelytosucceedingettingtheirchildrenintotheirdesiredschoolswhenfartherfromthem(compareFigures5aand5b)asparentsneartheschoolmayhavesenttheirchildtoadifferent,butnearby,school.Thissituationimpliesthemodelisnotusefulforconsideringsituationswhereschoolsarenotspacedequally.However,initscurrentformwewouldnotexpectthemodeltobeusefulinthissituationasparents'rankinglogicformovingonlyconsidersthesinglebestschool(anditscatchment)anddoesnottakeaccountofwhichlocationsintheenvironmentwouldallowthemtobeinmultiple(good)schoolcatchments.Consequently,asthemodellogiccurrentlystands,themodelisbestusedwithregularlyspacedschoolssothatparentsareveryunlikelytobeinmorethanoneschoolcatchment,astheagentlogicassumes.

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 15 15/10/2015

Page 16: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

Figure5.Relationshipbetweendistanceandstrategyatparent-levelforrandomlylocatedschoolsfora)RuleSet1andb)RuleSet3(specifiedinTable3).

5.4 Alsointhecurrentmodelstructure,threemechanismsexistwherebyfeedbacksbetweenaspirationandchild-attainmentcanoccur.Thesearetheassumptionsthat:

i. initialchild-attainmentisequaltotheaspirationoftheparents(Att=Asp);ii. throughtimeatschoolchild-attainmentisinfluencedbytheaspirationoftheparent(PEinEq3);andiii. throughtimeatschoolchild-attainmentisinfluencedbythemeanchild-attainmentofschoolpeers(SPEinEq3).

5.5 Tochecktheimportanceoftheseassumptionsforthegenerationoftheschool-levelempiricalrelationships(e.g.,Figure1),weranthemodelforthedifferentcombinationsoftheseassumptionsbeingpresentinthemodelornot(seeTable8,while

maintainingotherassumptionsofRuleSet1[9]).ThesetestsindicatethatiftheAtt=Aspassumptionisabsent,themodeldoesnotgeneratetheschool-levelempiricalrelationshipswhenPEisalsonotpresent(i.e.,RuleSets10and12),butperformsbetterwhenPEispresent(i.e.,RuleSets14and15).Furthermore,theSPEeffectseemstobetheleastimportantofthethreeassumptionshighlightedabove,aswhenthisassumptionsisabsentbuttheothertwoassumptionsarepresentschool-levelrelationshipsarenotaffected(i.e.,compareresultsforRuleSet13withRuleSet1).Neighbourhoodsofaspirationareproducedinallcombinationsofassumptions(indicatedbyhighMoran'sIvalues).Theseresultsmakesenseasalthoughparentsofsimilaraspirationstillclustertogether,ifthereisnolinkbetweenparentaspirationandchild-attainment(viaeitherAtt=AsporPE)littlevariationinschoolperformanceisproducedbyspatialvariationinparentaspiration.AlthoughtheAtt=Aspassumptionisuseful,theseresultsimplythataperfectcorrelationbetweenaspirationandinitialchild-attainmentisnotnecessaryforthemodeltogenerateempiricalrelationships.

Table8:Measuresofrelationshipsbetweenkeyempiricalvariablesforaspirationandchild-attainmentmechanisms.

RuleSet PE SPE Att=Asp GCSE-5+vsA:P GCSE-5+vsMaxDist A:PvsMaxDist Moran'sI

r2 p r2 p r2 p Stat. p

9 F F T 0.93 0.00 0.60 17.24 0.59 17.68 0.93 0.0010 F F F 0.90 0.00 0.42 39.52 0.41 43.80 0.92 0.0011 F T T 0.93 0.00 0.61 17.36 0.61 16.76 0.93 0.0012 F T F 0.88 0.00 0.44 38.12 0.46 37.36 0.93 0.0013 T F T 0.95 0.00 0.70 5.52 0.67 8.48 0.92 0.0014 T F F 0.94 0.00 0.67 11.48 0.64 14.60 0.92 0.0015 T T F 0.94 0.00 0.68 10.48 0.65 13.88 0.92 0.00

Parent-levelpatterns

5.6 Ourgenerativeapproachtomodellinghasshownthattheconsequencesofourassumptionsaboutthesystemattheindividual,parent,levelcangeneratetheempiricallyobservedrelationshipsandpatternsatthehigher,school,level.Althoughthismodelisahighlysimplifiedconceptualisation,itallowsustoexaminerelationshipsbetweenentitiesatthelowerlevelandbetweenupperandlowerlevelsthatwouldnotbepossible(orattheleast,verydifficult)intherealworld.Forexample,ourparent-levelresults(forRuleSet1,Table3)showthatingeneralthoseintheseconddistanceclass(distance10–20)achievegreatest child-attainmentincreases,andnotthoseintheclosestdistanceclass(distance<10,Figure4a).Thisisbecausethoseparentsthatliveintheclosestdistanceclasshaveonaveragegreateraspirationthanthoseintheseconddistanceclassandthereforehavegreatestchild-attainmentinitially.Consequently,thechild-attainmentoftheseclosestparentsisonaveragemorelikelytodecreasethanincrease.

5.7 Anotherinterestingfindingfromourparent-levelanalysisisthatthoseparentswithaspiration60–70failtogettheirchildintotheirpreferredschoolmoreoftenthanotherparents(closelyfollowedbythosewithaspiration50–60,Figure4c).Asnotedintheresults,thelikelihoodoffailingtogetintoapreferredschoolusingstrategy3(rankschoolsconsideredsatisfactorybydistanceascending,thenallotherschoolsbydistanceascending,Table2)increasesasaspirationincreases(Figure4c).Althoughagreaterproportionofparentswithaspiration70–80failwhenusingstrategy3comparedtoparentswithaspiration60–70,parentsinthisloweraspirationclasshaveagreaterproportionofparentsusingthisstrategyoverall(parentswithhigheraspirationaremorelikelytobeinaschoolcatchmentandthereforeusestrategies5–8).Parentswithaspiration60–70arenolesslikelytofindthemselvesoutsideaschoolcatchmentthanparentswithloweraspiration(Figure4c)butbecausetheiraspirationishighertheyconsideronlybetterschoolssatisfactoryfortheirchild.Thismeanstheyhavefewerschoolstorank(sodistancetothoseschoolsislikelytobegreater),andeachofthoseschoolsismorelikelytohavegreaternumbersofparentsdeemingthemsatisfactorytosendtheirchildto(andsotheseschoolshavemanyparentsrankingthemasmostpreferred).Incontrast,parentswithloweraspiration(e.g.,aspiration<50)aremorelikelytogetintotheirpreferredschooleventhoughnotinanyschool'scatchment,bothbecausethedistancetothenearestschoolislikelytobesmaller(becausetherearemoreschoolsdeemedsatisfactory)and

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 16 15/10/2015

Page 17: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

becausetherearefewerotherapplicantsrankingthatschoolasmostpreferred(becauseotherparentsaremorelikelytoavoidit).Thefailureofparentswithaspiration60–70togetintotheirpreferred(i.e.,topranked)schoolisreflectedintheirgreaterallocationdistancesthananyotheraspirationclass(Figure4b).Furthermore,onlyapproximately3%ofparentswithaspiration60–70move,andmanyremainstuckinthepositionofhavinghigherthanaverageaspirationbutnotbeing'intherightplace'(spatially)whentheyinitiallyarriveinthemodelenvironment(becauseoflocationconstraints).Theseparentshaveaspirations'toohigh'relativetotheirabilitytomoveintopreferredschoolcatchments.

5.8 Thequestionthenarises;howmightschoolallocationrulesorpoliciesbemodifiedtohelpthoseparentswithaboveaverage,butnotveryhigh,aspiration(andthereforemobility)getintobetterschools(oratleastschoolstheywant)?Onewaymightbetoincreasethestandardsofschoolssothatagreaternumbermeettheaspirationsofparents.Insodoing,thenumberofschoolsthatparentswithaboveaveragebutnotveryhighaspirationdeemsatisfactorytosendtheirchildtowillincreaseandthedangerofnotbeinginaschoolcatchmentshoulddecrease.ToinvestigatethisweexamineascenarioinwhichwerunthemodelasforRuleSet1(Table3)butwithagreatermeanschoolvalue-addedof0.2(althoughwiththesamestandarddeviationaspreviouslyof0.1).Resultsforthis'improvedschoolstandards'scenarioindicatethatincreasedabilityofschoolstoraisechild-attainmentproduceschangesinstrategiesforparentswithhigheraspirationanddecreasestheproportionofparentswithaspiration60–70thatfailtogettheirchildintotheirpreferredschool(Figure6,comparetoFigure4c).Furthermore,thisincreaseinmeanschoolvalue-addedincreasestheproportionsofparentsinotheraspirationclassesthatfailtogettheirchildintoapreferredschool,resultinginamoreevendistributionoffailureacrosstheaspirationclasses.

Figure6.Relationshipbetweenaspirationandstrategyatparent-levelfor'improvedschoolstandards'scenario.

Prospectsforfuturework

5.9 The'improvedschoolstandards'scenarioisjustoneexampleofthekindsofscenarioswecanexaminewiththemodel.Themodelcouldalsobeusedtoexplorealternativeschoolallocationrulesandpolicies,whichmightincluderandomlotteriesforschoolallocation(e.g.,Allenetal.2013),opening'free'schoolsthatmayuseaptitudeasaselectioncriterion(e.g.,Hatcher2011),ortheclosureofunder-performingschools.FuturechangestothemodelmightextendittoenablerepresentationofothercriteriausedinUKstateschoolallocation(e.g.,religiousfaith,attendanceofsiblings).

5.10 Themodelpresentedhereusesonlyasingleparentagentvariable(aspirationforhigheducationalattainment)tosimultaneouslyrepresentthegoalsofparentsandtheconstraintsontheirabilitytomeetthosegoals.However,therearemanyfactorsunderlyingwherefamilieswantand/orareabletoliveandwhichschoolstheyperceiveasdesirablefortheirchildtoattend.Forexample,educationalaspirationvariesbyclassandethnicity(ButlerandHamnett2011,2012)andtheabilitytomovehousetoachievetheseaspirationsisaneconomicquestioninfluencedbythehousingmarket.Therepresentationofagentsandtheirenvironmentwithmultipleattributesthatmoreaccuratelyreflectmotivationsandconstraintsisneeded.Thereisnoreasonwhyaspirationforeducationalattainmentandeconomicwealthshouldbecorrelatedandfuturemodellingmayexplorehowvariationsindistributionsofthesefactorsresultindifferentwinnersandlosersthroughtimeandacrossspace.Improvingthisrepresentation

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 17 15/10/2015

Page 18: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

willrequireindividual-leveldataonattributes,preferencesandallocations.Theseimprovementsinrepresentationanddatawouldalsoallowaninvestigationofmotivationsforschoolchoicebeyondexamresultsalone,allowingagentstoidentifypreferencesbaseduponschoolethnicandsocio-economiccompositionandtheattributesofotherparentsthatsendtheirchildtoaschool(althoughthatisinsomewaysrepresentedherethroughtheAtt=Aspassumption).

5.11 Whatwehavebeenabletoshowhereusingasimple,abstractagent-basedmodelthatrepresentsindividualparentsindisaggregatedmanner,andwhichwasnotimmediatelyapparentattheoutset,ishowconstraintsonindividuals'movements,whencombinedwithdistanceallocationrules,producewinnersandlosersthatarenotdirectlycorrelatedtotheindividuals'attributes.Thatis,itisnotagentswithlowestaspirationthatareleastsatisfiedwiththeirschoolallocationoutcomes,andinsteaditisparentagentswithaboveaverage,butnotveryhigh,aspirationthatfailtogettheirchildintotheirpreferredschoolmorefrequentlythanotherparents.Usingdisaggregated,agent-basedsimulationapproacheslikethisallowsinvestigationofindividual-leveloutcomesofsystemlevelpolicies.Wheninformedmoredirectlybyindividual-leveldata,andusedincombinationwithscenariosofdifferenteducationpolicies,thismodellingapproachwillallowustomorerigorouslyinvestigatetheconsequencesofthosepoliciesforeducationinequalitiesacrossspaceandthroughtime.

Acknowledgements

JMisgratefultotheLeverhulmeTrustforanEarlyCareerFellowshipheldduringthetimeoftheresearchpresentedhere.WearealsogratefulforthecommentsfromthreereviewerswhichhelpedtoimprovethemanuscriptandtoDavidDemerittwhoseideasinitiatedthiswork.TBandCHalsowishtoacknowledgethesupportoftheEconomicandSocialResearchCouncil(ESRC)whichfundedtheproject'Gentrification,ethnicityandeducationinEastLondon'(RES-000-23_0793)aswellasthecontributionofProfessorRichardWebberandDrMarkRamsdenandDrSadiqMirtotheoriginalprojectwhichgaverisetothefindingsthatinspiredthiscollaborationwithJM.

Notes

1Othercriteriasuchastheattendanceofsiblingsataschoolandspecialeducationalneedsarealsoconsideredbutinfluenceaveryminorproportionofallapplicants.

2Datafrom:DepartmentforEducation.SecondarySchoolGCSEPerformanceTables2010:BarkingandDagenham.HMSO.2011.URL:http://www.education.gov.uk/schools/performance/archive/schools_10/pdf_10/301.pdf.Accessed:2012-10-18.(ArchivedbyWebCite®athttp://www.webcitation.org/6BVNtJTe9);DepartmentforEducation.SecondarySchoolGCSEPerformanceTables2011:BarkingandDagenham.HMSO.2012.URL:http://www.education.gov.uk/schools/performance/2011/download/pdf/301_ks4.pdf.Accessed:2012-10-18.(ArchivedbyWebCite®athttp://www.webcitation.org/6BVNziv1Z);LondonBoroughofBarkingandDagenham.TheRightSecondarySchool:Informationforparentsaboutmovingtosecondaryschoolsin2013.LondonBoroughofBarkingandDagenham.2012.URL:http://www.lbbd.gov.uk/Education/Admissions/Documents/RSS2013.pdf.Accessed:2012-10-18.(ArchivedbyWebCite®athttp://www.webcitation.org/6BVOM2pTi);LondonBoroughofBarkingandDagenham.TheRightSecondarySchool:Informationforparentsaboutmovingtosecondaryschoolsin2012.LondonBoroughofBarkingandDagenham.2011.URL:http://www.lbbd.gov.uk/Education/Admissions/Documents/RSS2012.pdf.Accessed:2012-10-18.(ArchivedbyWebCite®athttp://www.webcitation.org/6BVOUK84I)

3http://www.openabm.org/model/3364/version/1/

4Inrealschools,pupilsinyear11maybeaged15or16dependingontheirbirthdate.However,thetemporalresolutionofthemodelisoneyearandchildagesareupdatedsimultaneouslysoweassumepupilsareaged11duringschoolyear7,12duringyear8,etc.untilbeingage15duringyear11.

5Notethatrankingstrategiesforbothmovingandapplicationincludesituationsinwhichparentsdonotconsideranyschoolssatisfactorytosendtheirchildto.Inthisunsatisfactorysituationintherealworld,parentsmayhavethemeanstomovetoalocationoutsidetheircurrentLEAwheretheythinktheytheirchildwillgetaplaceatasatisfactorystateschool.Alternatively,iftheyhavethemeanstheymayremovetheirchildfromthestateschoolsystemandsendthemintoprivateschooling.Neitheroftheseoptionsisrepresentedbythecurrentmodelstructure,whichisessentiallyaclosedsystem.

6Inreality,schoolplacesareallocatedbytheLocalEducationAuthority(LEA)andnotbyindividualschools.However,theschool-drivenallocationprocedureusedinthemodelhereisconsistentwiththelogicusedbyanLEAanddoesnotrequiretheuseofancillarymodelobjectsotherthanschoolsandparents.

7Inthetablemismeanregressioncoefficientofalinearregressionbetweenthetwovariables,pisthemeannumberof

timestepsinwhichp>0.05fortherelationshipbetweenthevariables,andr2isthemeancoefficientofdeterminationforthelinearregressionmodel.Allvaluesarefor80timestepsin25modelreplicates.

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 18 15/10/2015

Page 19: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

8Inthetablemismeanregressioncoefficientofalinearregressionbetweenthetwovariables,pisthemeannumberof

timestepsinwhichp>0.05fortherelationshipbetweenthevariables,andr2isthemeancoefficientofdeterminationforthelinearregressionmodel.Allvaluesarefor80timestepsin25modelreplicates.

9Notethatwepresentonlysevencombinations,asthecombinationwithallthreeassumptionstrueisequivalenttoRuleSet1inTable3.

References

ALLEN,R.andVignoles,A.(2007).Whatshouldanindexofschoolsegregationmeasure?OxfordReviewofEducation,33(5),643–668.[doi:10.1080/03054980701366306]

ALLEN,R.,Burgess,S.andMcKenna,L.(2010).TheearlyimpactofBrightonandHove'sschooladmissionreforms.CentreforMarketandPublicOrganisation.WorkingPaperNo.10/244

ALLEN,R.,Burgess,S.andMcKenna,L.(2013).Theshort-runimpactofusinglotteriesforschooladmissions:earlyresultsfromBrightonandHove'sreforms.TransactionsoftheInstituteofBritishGeographers38(1),149–166.[doi:10.1111/j.1475-5661.2012.00511.x]

BRADLEY,J.E.,Kirby,A.M.andTaylor,P.J.(1978).Distancedecayanddentaldecay:AstudyofdentalhealthamongprimaryschoolchildreninNewcastleuponTyne.RegionalStudies,12(5),529–540.[doi:10.1080/09595237800185501]

BURGESS,S.andBriggs,A.(2010).Schoolassignment,schoolchoiceandsocialmobility.EconomicsofEducationReview,29(4),639–649.[doi:10.1016/j.econedurev.2009.10.011]

BUTLER,T.andHamnett,C.(2007).TheGeographyofEducation.UrbanStudies,44(7),1161–74.[doi:10.1080/00420980701329174]

BUTLER,T.andHamnett,C.(2011).Ethnicity,ClassandAspiration:UnderstandingLondon'snewEastEnd.ThePolicyPress,Bristol.

BUTLER,T.andHamnett,C.(2012).Prayingforsuccess?FaithschoolsandschoolchoiceinEastLondon.Geoforum43(6),1242–1253.[doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2012.03.010]

CONNOLLY,P.(2006).TheeffectsofsocialclassandethnicityongenderdifferencesinGCSEattainment:AsecondaryanalysisoftheYouthCohortStudyofEnglandandWales1997–2001.BritishEducationalResearchJournal,32(1),3–21.[doi:10.1080/01411920500401963]

EPSTEIN,J.M.(1999).Agent-basedcomputationalmodelsandgenerativesocialscience.Complexity,4,41–60.[doi:10.1002/(SICI)1099-0526(199905/06)4:5<41::AID-CPLX9>3.0.CO;2-F]

EPSTEIN,J.M.(2006).GenerativeSocialScience.PrincetonUniversityPress,Princeton.

FOSSETT,M.andDietrich,D.R.(2009).Effectsofcitysize,shape,andform,andneighborhoodsizeandshapeinagent-basedmodelsofresidentialsegregation:areSchelling-stylepreferenceeffectsrobust?Environmentandplanning.B,Planning&design,36(1),149–169.[doi:10.1068/b33042]

GALE,D.andShapley,L.S.(1962).Collegeadmissionsandthestabilityofmarriage.TheAmericanMathematicalMonthly,69(1),9–15.[doi:10.2307/2312726]

GIBBONS,S.andTelhaj,S.(2007).AreSchoolsDriftingApart?IntakeStratificationinEnglishSecondarySchools.UrbanStudies,44(7),1281–1280.[doi:10.1080/00420980701302346]

GUDSON,K.(2011).EducationPolicy,SpaceandtheCity:Marketsandthe(In)visibilityofRace.Routledge,London.

HAMNETT,C.,Ramsden,M.andButler,T.(2007).Socialbackground,ethnicity,schoolcompositionandeducationalattainmentinEastLondon.UrbanStudies,44(7),1255–1280.[doi:10.1080/00420980701302395]

HAMNETT,C.andButler,T.(2011).'Geographymatters':theroledistanceplaysinreproducingeducationalinequalityinEastLondon.TransactionsoftheInstituteofBritishGeographers,36(4),479–500.[doi:10.1111/j.1475-5661.2011.00444.x]

HARLAND,K.andHeppenstall,A.J.(2012).UsingAgent-BasedModelsforEducationPlanning:IstheUKEducationSystemAgentBased?In:A.J.HeppenstallHeppenstall,A.T.Crooks,L.M.See,andM.Batty(Eds.),Agent-BasedModelsofGeographicalSystems,(pp.481–497)Springer.[doi:10.1007/978-90-481-8927-4_23]

HARRIS,R.J.andJohnston,R.J.(2008).Primaryschools,marketsandchoice:studyingpolarizationandthecorecatchmentareasofschools.AppliedSpatialAnalysisandPolicy1(1),59–84.[doi:10.1007/s12061-008-9002-8]

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 19 15/10/2015

Page 20: Aspiration, Attainment and Successjasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10/10.pdfEducation, Inequality, Aspiration, Schools, School-Place Allocation, Parental Choice Introduction 1.1 It has

HATCHER,R.(2011).TheConservative-LiberalDemocratCoalitiongovernment's"freeschools"inEngland.EducationalReview,63(4),485–503.[doi:10.1080/00131911.2011.616635]

LAURIE,A.J.andJaggi,N.K.(2003).Roleof'vision'inneighbourhoodracialsegregation:avariantoftheSchellingsegregationmodel.UrbanStudies,40(13),2687–2704.[doi:10.1080/0042098032000146849]

MAROULIS,S.,Guimerà,R.,Petry,H.,Stringer,M.J.,GomezL.M.,Amaral,L.A.N.andWilensky,U.(2010a).ComplexSystemsViewofEducationalPolicyResearch.Science,330,38–89.[doi:10.1126/science.1195153]

MAROULIS,S.,Bakshyy,E.,Gomez,L.andWilensky,U.(2010b).AnAgent-BasedModelofIntra-DistrictPublicSchoolChoice.http://ccl.northwestern.edu/papers/choice.pdf.Archivedat:http://www.webcitation.org/6BsXYmTOL

MCLAFFERTY,S.(1982).UrbanStructureandGeographicalAccesstoPublicServices.AnnalsoftheAssociationofAmericanGeographers,72(3),347–354.[doi:10.1111/j.1467-8306.1982.tb01830.x]

MILLINGTON,J.D.A.,O'Sullivan,D.,Perry,G.L.W.(2012).Modelhistories:Narrativeexplanationingenerativesimulationmodelling.Geoforum,43,1025–1034.[doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2012.06.017]

O'SULLIVAN,D.(2008)Geographicalinformationscience:agent-basedmodels.ProgressinHumanGeography,32,541–558.[doi:10.1177/0309132507086879]

O'SULLIVAN,D.(2009).ChangingNeighborhoods—NeighborhoodsChangingAFrameworkforSpatiallyExplicitAgent-BasedModelsofSocialSystems.SociologicalMethods&Research,37(4),498–530.[doi:10.1177/0049124109334793]

PORTUGALI,J.(2000).Self-organizationandthecity.Springer.[doi:10.1007/978-3-662-04099-7]

SIMINI,F.,González,M.C.,Maritan,A.andBarabási,A.L.(2012)Auniversalmodelformobilityandmigrationpatterns.Nature,484(7392),96–100.[doi:10.1038/nature10856]

TANG,Y.,Parsons,S.andSklar,E.(2007)ModelingHumanEducationData:FromEquation-BasedModelingtoAgent-BasedModelingIn:Antunes,L.andTakadama,K.(Eds.)MABS2006,LectureNotesinComputerScience,444241–56.

THRUPP,M.,Lauder,H.andRobinson,T.(2002).Schoolcompositionandpeereffects.InternationalJournalofEducationalResearch,37(5),483–504.[doi:10.1016/S0883-0355(03)00016-8]

WILLMS,J.D.(2010).Schoolcompositionandcontextualeffectsonstudentoutcomes.TheTeachersCollegeRecord,112(4),3–4.

http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/17/1/10.html 20 15/10/2015