an estimated model with macrofinancial linkages for india · 2010. 1. 28. · have since...

45
An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India Rahul Anand, Shanaka Peiris, and Magnus Saxegaard WP/10/21

Upload: others

Post on 02-Oct-2020

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India

Rahul Anand, Shanaka Peiris, and

Magnus Saxegaard

WP/10/21

Page 2: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

© 2010 International Monetary Fund WP/10/21 IMF Working Paper Asia and Pacific Department

An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India

Prepared by Rahul Anand, Shanaka Peiris, and Magnus Saxegaard1

Authorized for distribution by Laura Papi

January 2010

Abstract

This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF. The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate.

This paper develops a small open economy dynamic stochastic general-equilibrium model with macrofinancial linkages. The model includes a financial accelerator--entrepreneurs are assumed to partially finance investment using domestic and foreign currency debt--to assess the importance of financial frictions in the amplification and propagation of the effects of transitory shocks. We use Bayesian estimation techniques to estimate the model using India data. The model is used to assess the importance of the financial accelerator in India and the optimality of monetary policy. JEL Classification Numbers: E52, E58, E61 Keywords: monetary policy, financial accelerator, macro-financial linkages, optimal policy,

bayesian estimation Author’s E-Mail Address: [email protected]; [email protected]; [email protected]

1 The authors wish to thank Kalpana Kochhar, Laura Papi, Andy Berg, Nicoletta Batini, Eswar Prasad, and participants at seminars at the IMF and ISI Delhi for their helpful comments and suggestions.

Page 3: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

1 Introduction

Among macroeconomic practitioners there is growing recognition of the link-ages between the �nancial sector and the real economy and, in particular, therole that balance sheets play in the transmissions of shocks to the economy.These linkages were highlighted during the September 2008 global �nan-cial crisis and the resulting slowdown on the global economy. In particular,Bernanke and Gertler (1989) showed in a seminal paper that the presence ofasymmetric information in credit markets and monitoring costs would makethe external �nance premium faced by borrowers dependent on the strengthof their balance sheets (their net worth). Moreover, because of the procycli-cal nature of net worth, this premium would tend to fall during booms andrise during recessions. Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999) (BGG here-after), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), and othershave since demonstrated that these �nancial frictions may signi�cantly am-plify both real and nominal shocks to the economy. In the literature, thislink between the cost of borrowing and net worth has become known as the��nancial accelerator�.In addition, Krugman (1999), Aghion, Bacchetta, and Banerjee (2001)

and others have argued that exchange rate and interest rate �uctuations�through their e¤ect on balance sheets�are likely to have more serious con-sequences in emerging market economies that in industrialized countries. Acontributing factor to this is�as noted by Elekdag, Justiniano, and Tchakarov(2005)�that borrowers in emerging market economies tend to rely more onforeign currency borrowing. In this setting, a depreciation could trigger adeterioration in the balance sheets of borrowers with a negative net openforeign exchange position, eroding their net worth and increasing the costof borrowing. By reducing the demand for capital, this erodes the value ofborrowers� existing capital stock and their net worth, putting further up-ward pressure on borrowing costs. Papers exploring the importance of the�nancial accelerator for emerging market economies dependent on foreigncurrency borrowing include Elekdag, Justiniano, and Tchakarov (2005) andBatini, Levine, and Pearlman (2009).In this paper, we develop and estimate a small open-economy Dynamic

Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model that incorporates the �nan-cial accelerator mechanism proposed by BGG in a setting where �rms areable to borrow in both domestic and foreign currency. The model is esti-mated on post-1996 Indian data using Bayesian estimation techniques. This

2

Page 4: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

is, to our knowledge, the �rst attempt at estimating a DSGE model for India.India provides an interesting backdrop for our analysis. India�s mone-

tary policy framework has evolved considerably over the past decades (RBI2009). In particular, the opening up of the economy in the early 1990s and�nancial sector liberalization has been re�ected in changes in the nature ofmonetary management (Mohan 2004). The basic objectives of monetarypolicy�maintaining price stability and ensuring su¢ cient credit to supportgrowth�have remained unchanged. However, the opening up of the capitalaccount�while necessary for providing su¢ cient capital for investment pur-poses and for reducing the cost of borrowing�exposes the economy to suddenstops in capital �ows. In particular, volatile capital �ows and its impact onthe exchange rate have implications not only domestic demand and in�ation,but for �nancial stability, with the result that maintenance of �nancial sta-bility is of increasing concern to the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) (Mohan2004). In order to meet these multiple challenges, the RBI has switched froma more traditional monetary targeting framework to a indicator based ap-proach which seeks to strike a balance between price stability and reducingexchange rate volatility. However, as noted in the Rajan report on �nan-cial sector reform (Rajan 2008), further re�nements to the monetary policyframework may be necessary to cope with the rise in capital in�ows.Over the last 5 years capital in�ows have more than quadrupled, amount-

ing to nearly 10 percent of GDP in 2007 and far exceeding the current accountde�cit. There has also been signi�cant volatility as highlighted by the sharpout�ows during the last quarter of 2008 and �rst quarter of 2009 and thesubsequent dramatic recovery. These sharp swings in capital �ows makesit di¢ cult for the RBI to strike a balance between its di¤erent objectives,resulting in spurts of exchange rate volatility when a particular level of theexchange rate becomes too di¢ cult to sustain, either because of in�ationarypressures or because sterilization operations become too costly or harder tomanage (Rajan 2008).The trade-o¤s policymakers face in the conduct of monetary policy will

largely be determined by type of shocks hitting the economy and the strengthof macro-�nancial linkages�in particular the role that capital �ows and bal-ance sheets play in the transmissions of shocks to the economy (IMF 2009).Given the key role played by the corporate sector�fuelled to a large extent bybank credit and increasingly external commercial borrowing (ECB) denom-inated in foreign currency�in India�s rapid economic growth in recent years(Oura 2008), these macro�nancial linkages have likely grown in importance.

3

Page 5: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

In particular, the importance of bank credit as a source of �nancing increasesthe importance of corporates�net worth as a tool to mitigate asymmetric in-formation in credit markets while rising ECBs makes the balance sheet ofcorporates more sensitive to exchange rate �uctuations.At the same time, India is equipped with a large equity market whose

development has to a large extent been fuelled by large in�ows from foreigninstitutional investors (FIIs). IMF (forthcoming) shows that stock marketcapitalization�an commonly used indicator of corporates�net worth (see e.g.Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2007))�is one of the key determinants ofthe �ow of ECBs. As a result, equity market developments�including theamount of in�ows from FIIs�are likely to have a direct bearing on the costof �nancing for corporates in India, further increasing the importance ofmacro�nancial linkages in the economy.The rest of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the

main components of the model. Section 3 brie�y describes the data andthe estimation methodology before we present the results of the estimationin Section 4. In section 5 we employ the estimated model to analyze theoptimality of monetary policy in India before a �nal section concludes.

2 The Model

The model is an expanded version of the small open-economy DSGE modeloutlined in Saxegaard (2006b). The augmented model features a �nancialaccelerator mechanism similar to that proposed by BGG to study the e¤ectof �nancial frictions on the real economy. The model incorporates �nancialfrictions by assuming that �rms have to borrow at a premium over domesticand foreign interest rates to �nance part of their capital acquisition cost asin Christensen and Dib (2006), and Gertler, Gilchrist, and Natalucci (2007).Under this framework, information asymmetry between lenders and borrow-ers creates the �nancial friction by establishing a link between the cost ofborrowing and the �nancial health of the �rms. The external �nance pre-mium, in turn, is inversely related to the net worth of the entrepreneurs.Figure 1 provides a visual representation of the estimated model.

4

Page 6: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Figure1:FlowChartoftheModel

Hou

seho

lds

Entre

pren

eurs

Ret

aile

rs

Cap

ital P

rodu

cers

Res

t of W

orld

Cen

tral B

ank

Fisc

al A

gent

Labo

rWag

es

Cap

ital

Borr

owin

g

Inte

rmed

iate

 Goo

dsIn

vest

men

t

Con

sum

ptio

n

Gov

ernm

ent C

onsu

mpt

ion

Taxe

s

Expo

rts

Impo

rts

Prof

its

Lend

ing/

Borr

owin

g

Inte

rest

 Rat

e

Inve

stm

ent

5

Page 7: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

The basic structure of model consists of four kinds of agents - house-holds, entrepreneurs, capital producers and retailers. Households consumea composite of domestic and imported goods and provide labor. They haveaccess to foreign capital markets and make deposits which are used by en-trepreneurs to purchase capital. Entrepreneurs produce intermediate goodsusing labor and capital purchased from capital producers. They �nance theacquisition of capital partly through their net worth and partly through bor-rowing domestically and abroad. Entrepreneurs produce intermediate goodsunder perfect competition and sell their product to retailers who di¤erentiatethem at no cost and sell them either in domestic market or export overseas.Retailers operate in a monopolistically competitive environment and face aquadratic adjustment costs in changing prices à la Rotemberg (1982). Capi-tal producers use a combination of the existing capital stock and investmentgoods purchased from retailers and abroad to produce capital. The marketsfor capital, labor and domestic loans are competitive. The model is com-pleted with a description of the �scal and monetary authority. Our modeldi¤ers from BGG in its characterization of monetary policy using a modi�edTaylor-type rule. We assume that the Reserve Bank of India adjusts short-term interest rates in response to in�ation, output, and nominal exchangerate changes.In order to provide a rationale for monetary stabilization policy, three

sources of ine¢ ciency are included in the model: (a) monopolistically com-petitive retail markets; (b) sluggish price adjustment in retail sector; (c)capital adjustment costs. While relatively simple, the framework capturesmany of the rigidities which previous studies have found are important todescribe the dynamics in the data and serves as a useful starting point fordeveloping a DSGE model for India.

2.1 Household

The economy is populated with a continuum of in�nitely lived householdswith preferences de�ned over consumption, Ct (j), and labor e¤ort, Lt(j).The objective of household j is to maximize the expected value of a dis-counted sum of period utility functions:

E0

1Xt=0

�tU (Ct (j) ; Lt (j)) (1)

6

Page 8: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

� 2 (0; 1) is the consumer subjective discount factor and U is a period utilityfunction. We include habit persistence according to the speci�cation:

U (Ct (j) ; Lt (j)) = �c;t (1� b) ln (Ct (j)� bCt�1)��L;t Lt (j)

(2)

where Ct�1 is lagged aggregate consumption and b 2 (0; 1). �c;t and �L;tare preference shocks to the marginal utility of consumption and the supplyof labour, respectively. Note that in symmetric steady-state where Ct (j) =Ct�1; the marginal utility of consumption is independent of the habit per-sistence parameter b. The aggregate consumption bundle, Ct (j) ; consists ofdomestically produced goods, CH;t; and an imported foreign good, CF;t , andis given by:

Ct(j) �h�1� (CH;t(j))

��1� + (1� �)

1� (CF;t(j))

��1�

i ���1

(3)

where CH;t is an index of consumption of domestic goods given by the con-stant elasticity of substitution (CES) function:

CH;t(j) =

�Z 1

0

CH;t(s)"t�1"t ds

� "t"t�1

(4)

where s 2 [0; 1] denotes the variety of the domestic good. The parameter� 2 [0;1] is the elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreigngoods. The parameter "t > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between varietiesproduced within the country, while � 2 [0; 1] can be interpreted as a measureof home-bias.We assume that households have access to foreign �nancial markets or

nominal contingent claims that span all relevant household speci�c uncer-tainty about future income and prices, interest rates, exchange rates and soon. As a result each household faces a single intertemporal budget constraint:

PtCt (j) + etBt+1 (j) + Pt� t + Ptdt(j) = etBt (j) (1 + ift�1) + (5)Z 1

0

�t(s)ds+WtLt (j)

+(1 + it�1)Ptdt�1(j)

7

Page 9: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

where Bt is net holdings of a foreign currency one-period bond that maturesin period t paying an interest rate of ift�1. Households make a deposit dt witha �nancial intermediary, which earns an interest of it.

R 10�t(s)ds represents

receipts of the pro�ts from domestic retailers owned by the household in theeconomy. � t is the lump sum tax in the economy andWt is the nominal wagerate per unit of labor.1 Pt is the CPI price index given by:

Pt ���(PH;t)

1�� + (1� �)(PF;t)1��� 1

1�� (6)

where PH;t is the domestic price index given by:

PH;t =

�Z 1t

0

PH;t(s)1�"tds

�1=(1�"t)(7)

and PF;t is the price of imported goods.2

Households choose the paths of fCt(j); Lt(j); dt(j); Bt+1(j)g1t=0 to maxi-mize expected lifetime utility (1) subject to the constraint (5) and the initialvalue of B0:The consumer�s problem can therefore be written as:

maxCt;dt;Bt+1;Lt

Et

1Xt=0

�t

8>>>>>><>>>>>>:

U (Ct (j) ; Lt (j))

��t

266664etBt+1 (j)�

etBt (j) (1 + ift�1) + Ptdt�(1 + it�1)Ptdt�1+Pt� t �WtLt (j)�R 10�t(s)ds+ PtCt (j)

377775

9>>>>>>=>>>>>>;(8)

Ruling out Ponzi type schemes, we get the following �rst order conditions:

(1� b) �c;tCt (j)� bCt�1

= �tPt (9)

�L;tLt (j) �1 = �tWt (10)

1The only role of the �nancial intermediary in this model is to channel the deposits ofhouseholds to enterpreneurs.

2We assume that the price of imported goods are set in the same manner as the domesticprices in the exporting country i.e. the price of imports adjust sluggishly and is given byan equation similar to equation 40.

8

Page 10: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Given the well documented departures from uncovered interest parity (UIP),we follow Kollman (2002) and introduce an exogenous shock into the con-sumers �rst-order condition for foreign currency bond holdings. The �rst-order conditions for deposits and foreign currency bond holdings are thereforegiven by:

1 = (1 + it)Et

��t;t+1

PtPt+1

�(11)

1 = (1 + ift )Et

��t;t+1

PtPt+1

et+1et

�(12)

where �t;t+1 = � �t�t+1

=�c;t(Ct+1(j)�bCt)�c;t+1(Ct(j)�bCt�1)

is the stochastic discount factor. Up

to a log-linear approximation equations (11 )and (12) imply Et ln (et+1=et) �it�ift :The optimum allocation of expenditure between domestic and importedgoods is given by

CH;t(j) = �

�PH;tPt

���Ct(j) (13)

CF;t(j) = (1� �)

�PF;tPt

���Ct(j) (14)

and the demand for each variety of domestic goods is given by:

CH;t(s) =

�PH;t(s)

Pt

��"tCH;t(j) (15)

For simplicity, we assume that changes in the exchange rate are passedthrough immediately to the import price so that PF;t = utott

"t("t�1)etP

�t where

utott is a shock to the terms of trade of the economy.

2.2 Production Sector

2.2.1 Entrepreneurs

We model the behavior of entrepreneurs as proposed by BGG . We follow themodeling framework of Gertler, Gilchrist, and Natalucci (2007) and Elekdag,Justiniano, and Tchakarov (2005) while introducing a �nancial accelerator inan open economy context. Entrepreneurs combine labor, hired from house-holds, and capital, purchased from capital producers, to produce intermediate

9

Page 11: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

goods in a perfectly competitive setting. They are risk neutral and have a�nite horizon for planning purposes. The probability that an entrepreneurwill survive until the next period is �; so the expected live horizon is 1

1�� .3

The number of new entrepreneurs entering the market each period is equal tothe number of entrepreneurs exiting, implying a stationary population. Toget started, new entrepreneurs receive a small transfer of funds from exitingentrepreneurs.At the end of each period t, entrepreneurs purchase capital kt+1, to be

used in the subsequent period at a price qt:They �nance capital acquisitionpartly by their net worth available at the end of period t, nt+1 , and partly byborrowing domestically and by raising foreign currency denominated debt.Total borrowing, Bt, is given by:

Bt = qtKt+1 � nt+1 (16)

where qt is the real price per unit of capital. The fraction of loan raiseddomestically, Bd

t , is exogenous to the model and is given by $: Thus,

Bdt = $Bt = $(qtKt+1 � nt+1) (17)

and

Bft = (1�$)(qt�1Kt � nt)) (18)

where Bft , is the amount of loan raised from abroad. Entrepreneurs use

Kt units of capital and Lt units of labor to produce output, Y Wt , using a

constant returns to scale technology:

Y Wt � �tK

t L

1� t ; 2 (0; 1) (19)

where �t is a stochastic disturbance to total factor productivity. The entre-preneur maximizes pro�t by choosing Kt and Lt subject to the productionfunction given by equation (19). The �rst order conditions for this optimiza-tion problem are:

Wt = (1� )PWH;t

Y Wt

Lt(20)

3This assumption ensures that entrepreneur�s net worth (the �rm equity) will never beenough to fully �nance the new capital acquisition.

10

Page 12: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

rkt =PWH;t

Pt(1� )

Y Wt

Kt

(21)

where PWH;t is the price of the wholesale good.

4 The expected marginal realreturn on capital acquired at t and used at t + 1 yields the expected grossreturn Et(1 + rkt+1), where

Et(1 + rkt+1) = Et

�rkt+1 + (1� �)qt+1

qt

�(22)

and � is the rate of depreciation of capital and rkt+1 is the marginal produc-tivity of capital at t+ 1.Following BGG, we assume that there exists an agency problem which

makes external �nance more expensive than internal funds. While entrepre-neurs costlessly observe their output, which is subject to random outcomes,lenders cannot verify output outcomes of entrepreneurs costlessly. After ob-serving the outcome, entrepreneurs decide whether to repay their debt or todefault. If they default, lenders audit the loan and recover the outcome lessmonitoring costs. This agency problem makes loans riskier and thus lenderscharge a premium over the risk free rate. Thus, entrepreneurs�marginal ex-ternal �nancing cost is the product of the gross premium and the gross realopportunity cost of funds (the riskless interest rate) that would arise in theabsence of capital market frictions.Therefore, the expected marginal cost of borrowing, Etft+1 ,is given by:

Etft+1 = ��

nt+1qtKt+1

�Et

h(1+it)�t+1

i+�

�nt+1qtKt+1

�Et

h(1+ift )

��t+1

RERt+1RERt

i(23)

�0< 0 and �(1) = 1

where � is the gross �nance premium which depends on the size of theborrower�s equity stake in a project (or, alternatively, the borrower�s leverageratio). �t = Pt

Pt�1, is the gross domestic in�ation, ��t =

P �tP �t�1

, is the gross world

in�ation and RERt is the real exchange rate de�ned as:5

RERt =etP

�t

Pt(24)

4Since the �rms are perfectly competitive this is equivalent to saying that PWH;t =MCWt :

5We have assumed that law of one price holds for all di¤erentiated goods.

11

Page 13: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

We characterize the risk premium, � by�

nt+1qtKt+1

��, where � represents

the elasticity of the external �nance premium with respect to a change inthe leverage position of entrepreneurs. As nt+1

qtKt+1falls, the entrepreneur relies

on uncollateralized borrowing (higher leverage) to a larger extent to fund hisproject. Since this increases the incentive to misreport the outcome of theproject, the loan becomes riskier and the cost of borrowing rises.6 Entrepre-neurs demand for capital depends on the expected marginal return and theexpected marginal cost of borrowing. Thus, the entrepreneur�s demand forcapital satis�es the following optimality condition:

Et(1 + rkt+1) = �

�nt+1qtKt+1

�Et

�(1 + it)

�t+1

�(25)

+�

�nt+1qtKt+1

�Et

"(1 + ift )

��t+1

RERt+1

RERt

#(26)

Equation (25) provides the foundation for the �nancial accelerator. It linksentrepreneurs��nancial position to the marginal cost of funds and, hence,to the demand for capital. Also, movements in the price of capital ,qt ,may have signi�cant e¤ects on the leverage ratio. In this way the modelcaptures the link between asset price movements and collateral stressed inthe Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) theory of credit cycles.7 At the beginning ofeach period, entrepreneurs collect their returns from capital and honor theirdebt obligations. Aggregate entrepreneurial net worth evolves according to:

nt+1 = �Vt + (1� �)Gt (27)

where Vt is the net worth of the surviving entrepreneurs carried over fromthe previous period, 1� � is the share of new entrepreneurs entering and Gt

6When the riskiness of loans increases, the agency costs rise and the lender�s expectedlosses increase. A higher external �nance premium paid by successful entrepreneurs o¤setsthese higher losses and ensures that there is no change to the return on deposits forhouseholds.

7Though the behavior described above is true for an individual entrepreneur, we appealto the assumptions in BGG that permit us to write it as an aggregate condition. See BGGand Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997) for details. It implies that gross �nance premium may beexpressed as a function of the aggregate leverage ratio, i.e. it is not entrepreneur speci�c.

12

Page 14: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

(which is exogenous in the model) are the transfers from exiting to newlyentering entrepreneurs. Vt is given by:

Vt =

264�1 + rkt

�qt�1Kt ��

�nt

qt�1Kt

� h(1+it�1)

�t

i($(qt�1Kt � nt))

���

ntqt�1Kt

��(1+ift�1)

��t

RERtRERt�1

�(1�$)(qt�1Kt � nt))

375 (28)

As equations (27) and (28) suggest, the principal source of movementsin net worth stems from unanticipated movements in returns and borrowingcosts. In this regard, unforecastable variations in asset prices, qt, is the mainsource of �uctuations in

�1 + rkt

�: On the cost side, unexpected movements

in in�ation and exchange rates are the major sources of �uctuations in networth. An unexpected de�ation or depreciation, for example, reduces entre-preneurial net worth, thus enhancing the �nancial accelerator mechanism.Entrepreneurs going out of business at time t consume and transfer somefunds to new entrepreneurs out of the residual equity (1 � �)Vt. Thus theconsumption by the entrepreneurs is given by:

Cet = (1� �)(Vt �Gt) (29)

2.2.2 Capital Producers

Capital producers combine the existing capital stock, Kt, leased from the en-trepreneurs to transform an input It, gross investment, into new capital Kt+1

using a linear technology.8 The aggregate capital stock evolves according to:

Kt+1 = (1� �)Kt + �I;tIt � �

2

�ItKt

� �

�2!Kt (30)

where �I;t is a shock to the marginal e¢ ciency of investment (as in Green-wood, Hercowitx, and Hau¤man, 1988).Gross investment consists of domestic and foreign �nal goods and we

assume that it is in the same proportion as in the consumption basket:

It �h�1� (IH;t)

��1� + (1� �)

1� (IF;t)

��1�

i ���1

(31)

8This setup follows Bernanke et al. (1999) and assumes that capital producers rent thecapital stock from entrepreneurs and use it to produce new capital. Since this takes placewithin the period we assume that the rental rate is zero.

13

Page 15: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Optimal demand for domestic and imported investment is therefore given by:

IH;t = �

�PH;tPt

���It (32)

IF;t = �

�PF;tPt

���It (33)

and the price of investment is the same as the domestic price index given byequation (6).We assume that capital producers face a quadratic capital adjustment

costs speci�ed as��2

�ItKt� ��2�

Kt. Capital producing �rms maximize ex-

pected pro�ts:

MaxIt

Et

(qt

"�I;tIt �

2

�ItKt

� �

�2!Kt

#� It

)(34)

and the corresponding �rst order condition for the supply of capital is givenby:

qt

��I;t � �

�ItKt

� �

��= 1 (35)

2.2.3 Retailers

There is a continuum of retailers s 2 [0; 1]. They purchase wholesale goodsat a price equal to the nominal marginal costs, MCW

t (the marginal cost inthe entrepreneurs�sector) and di¤erentiate them at no cost.9 Then they selltheir product in a monopolistically competitive domestic and export market.Final good domestic output, YH;t , is the CES composite of individual retailgoods:

YH;t =

�Z 1

0

YH;t(s)"t�1"t ds

� "t"t�1

(36)

9The entreprenuers sell their goods in a perfectly competitive market, so PWt =MCWt .The retail sector is used only to introduce nominal rigidity into the economy. Since theydi¤erentiate goods costlessly, the marginal cost of producing �nal goods is same asMCWt :

14

Page 16: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

The corresponding price of the composite consumption good, PH;t, is givenby equation (7). Using equation (36), the demand curve facing each retailercan be written as:

YH;t(s) =

�PH;t(s)

Pt

��"tYH;t (37)

For simplicity we assume that the aggregate export demand function: Qxt =

[PX;t=P�t ]��t ; �t > 0.

Price Setting by Retailers Following Ireland (2001) and Rotemberg(1982), there is sluggish price adjustment to make the intermediate goodspricing decision dynamic. This ensures that monetary policy has real e¤ectson the economy. Following, Julliard, Karam, Laxton, and Pesenti (2004) weassume that the retailers face an explicit cost of price adjustment measuredin terms of the intermediate goods given by:

#

2

�Pd;t(s)=Pd;t�1(s)

�� 1�2(Qd

t +Qxt ) (38)

where # � 0 is the parameter determining the cost of price adjustmentrelative to last period�s price level and the steady state domestic in�ation,�; respectively. Following Saxegaard (2006b), real pro�ts are given by:

�t [PH;t(s); PX;t(s)] =

�PH;t(s)

Pt� MCW

t

Pt

� �PH;t(s)

PH;t

��"tQdt (39)

+

�etPX;t(s)

Pt� MCW

t

Pt

� �PX;t(s)

PX;t

��"tQxt

�#2

�PH;t(s)=PH;t�1(s)

�� 1�2(Qd

t +Qxt )

where Qdt is the total domestic demand and Q

xt is the total exports. et is the

nominal exchange rate, expressed as the domestic currency price of foreigncurrency, so that an increase in et implies a depreciation of the domesticcurrency. Note also that we allow for a shock to the elasticity of substitutionbetween di¤erentiated goods "t; which determines the size of the markup ofintermediate goods �rms. Alternatively, the shock to "t can be interpretedas a cost-push shock of the kind introduced into the New Keynesian modelby Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (1999).

15

Page 17: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

The optimal price setting equation for the non-tradable price can then bewritten as:

PH;t ="t

("t � 1)MCW

t � #

("t � 1)Pt�H;t�

��H;t�

� 1�

(40)

+#

("t � 1)PtEt

��t;t+1

YH;t+1YH;t

�H;t+1�

��H;t+1�

� 1��

where we have used the fact that all retailer �rms are alike to impose symme-try and where we assume that the law of one price holds in the export marketso that PX;t = PH;t=et. Equation (40) reduces to the well-known result thatprices are set as a markup over marginal costs if the cost of price adjustment# = 0. In general however, the goods price will follow a dynamic process andthe �rm�s actual markup will di¤er from, but gravitate towards, the desiredmarkup. Pro�ts from retail activity are rebated lump-sum to households (i.e.households are the ultimate owners of retail outlets).

2.3 The Government

The �scal authority is assumed to purchase an exogenous stream Gt of the�nal good which is �nanced by the collection of lump-sum taxes.10 Forsimplicity, we do not assume that the �scal authority has access to domesticor international capital markets. Its period-by-period budget constraint isgiven by:

Gt = � t (41)

Government buys both domestic and foreign �nal goods and we assume thatit is in the same proportion as the consumers:

Gt �h�1� (GH;t)

��1� + (1� �)

1� (GF;t)

��1�

i ���1

(42)

Optimum demand for government domestic and imported consumption isgiven by:

10We assume for simplicity that government only consumes domestic goods.

16

Page 18: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

GH;t = �

�PH;tPt

���Gt (43)

GF;t = �

�PF;tPt

���Gt (44)

In choosing a speci�cation for the monetary policy reaction function, weassume a simple Taylor rule type function given by:

it = �i(it�1) + (1� �i)�i + ��(�t �

��) + �Y (Yt �

�Y ) + �q(qt �

�q) + � i;t (45)

where ��; �Y and �q are the weights on in�ation, output and the deprecia-tion rate of the nominal exchange rate. Parameter �i captures interest ratesmoothing, and where �{ is the steady state interest rate. � i;t, is a monetarypolicy shock to capture unanticipated increase in the nominal interest rate.Equation (45) is essentially a simple Taylor rule with partial adjustment. Weinterpret this rule as being a form of �exible in�ation targeting in the senseof Bernanke and Mishkin (1997).

2.4 Market Clearing and Aggregation

Domestic households, exiting entrepreneurs, capital producers, and govern-ment, and the rest of the world buy �nal goods from retailers. The economy-wide resource constraint is therefore given by:11

YH;t = CH;t + CeH;t + IH;t +GH;t +Qx

t = Qdt +Qx

t (46)

where:Qdt = CH;t + Ce

H;t + IH;t +GH;t (47)

and Qxt is the quantity exported and GH;t, is the Government�s demand of

domestically produced goods. The national accounting equation is given by:

Pt�ZZt = Pt(Ct+Cet+It+Gt)+PX;tQ

xt�PM;tQ

mt +

#

2

�PH;t(s)

�PH;t�1(s)� 1�2PH;tYH;t

(48)

11Following Bernanke et al. (1999), we ignore monitoring costs in the general equilib-rium.

17

Page 19: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

where Qmt is total imports and ZZt is real GDP.

12

The model allows for non-zero holdings of foreign currency bonds byhouseholds and foreign currency denominated debt by entrepreneurs. Inparticular, it is well known (see inter alia Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2003))that unless adjustments are made to the standard model, the steady state ofan small open-economy model with foreign currency bonds will depend uponinitial conditions and will display dynamics with random walk properties.In particular, if the domestic discount rate exceeds the real rate of returnon foreign currency bonds, then domestic holdings of foreign currency bondswill increase perpetually. Beyond the obvious conceptual problems of such anoutcome our analysis is constrained by the fact that the available techniquesused to solve non-linear business cycle models of the type considered hereare only valid locally around a stationary path.Fortunately, a number of modi�cations to the standard model are avail-

able which enable us to overcome this issue. In this paper, we follow Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2003) and specify a foreign debt elastic risk-premiumwhereby holders of foreign debt are assumed to face an interest rate thatis increasing in the country�s net foreign debt. In particular, ift , the inter-est rate at which households and entrepreneurs can borrow foreign currencyequals the exogenous world interest rate plus a spread that is a decreasingfunction of economy�s net foreign asset position:

(1+ift ) = (1+i�t )��d

h((Bt + Lft )=P

�t � #t)� ((B + Lf )=P � � #)

i=; �d � 0

(49)where �d is a parameter which captures the degree of capital mobility in themarket for foreign-currency borrowing and lending by households and isthe steady-state value of exports. As in Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2003)we include the steady-state level of debt so that the risk-premium is nil insteady state. Note that under perfect capital mobility (�d = 0), the countrywould face an in�nite supply or demand of foreign capital and the modelwould not have a well-de�ned steady state. As Kollmann (2002) points out,the model in this case becomes a version of the permanent income theory ofconsumption, with non-stationary consumption and net assets.

12Real GDP can alternatively be written as (1� �)�PF;tPt

���(Ct + C

et + It +Gt):

18

Page 20: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

2.5 Speci�cation of the Stochastic Processes

We include a number of shocks in order to ensure that the model is not sto-chastically singular and in order to be better able to reproduce the dynamicsin the data. In particular, the number of exogenous shocks must be at least aslarge as the number of observed variables in order to estimate the model us-ing classical Maximum Likelihood or Bayesian methods. Our model includesthirteen structural shocks: three shocks to technology and preferences (�t;�c;t; � l;t); three foreign shocks to world interest rates, world in�ation, and theprice elasticity of exports (i�t ; �

�t ; Q

xt ), two shocks to investment e¢ ciency

and �rms�markup�� in;t; ��;t

�, two �nancial shocks to the cost of borrowing

by entrepreneurs and the survival rate of entrepreneurs��n;t; �v;t

�, a mone-

tary policy shock, a government spending shock�� i;t; �G;t

�; and a UIP shock�

�uip;t�. With the exception of the monetary policy shock, which is assumed

to be a white noise processes, all shocks are assumed to follow a �rst-orderautoregressive process.13

3 Data and Estimation Strategy

We estimate the model using the Bayesian estimation module in DYNAREJuillard (2001). Bayesian inference has a number of bene�ts. First, it formal-izes the use of prior empirical or theoretical knowledge about the parametersof interest. Second, Bayesian inference provides a natural framework for para-meterizing and evaluating simple macroeconomic models that are likely to befundamentally mis-speci�ed. Thus, as pointed out by Fernandez-Villaverdeand Rubio-Ramirez (2004) and Schorfheide (2000), the inference problem isnot to determine whether the model is �true�or the �true�value of a par-ticular parameter, but rather to determine which set of parameter valuesmaximize the ability of the model to summarize the regular features of thedata. Finally, Bayesian inference provides a simple method for comparingand choosing between di¤erent mis-speci�ed models that may not be nestedon the basis of the marginal likelihood or the posterior probability of themodel. In particular, Geweke (1998) shows that the marginal likelihood isdirectly related to the predictive performance of the model which provides a

13In addition to our thirtheen structural shocks, we follow the approach adopted inJulliard, Karam, Laxton, and Pesenti (2004) of allowing for measurement errors in thedata.

19

Page 21: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

natural benchmark for assessing the usefulness of economic models for policyanalysis and forecasting.Bayesian estimation requires construction of the posterior density of the

parameters of interest given the data. If we denote the set of parameters to beestimated as � using observations on a set of variablesX, the posterior densitycan be written as p (�jX). The posterior density is thus the probabilitydistribution of �, conditional on having observed the data X. It forms thebasis for inference in the Bayesian framework. Following Bayes law, theposterior density is proportional to the product of the prior density of theparameters p (�) and the distribution of the data given the parameter setf (Xj�):

p (�jX) = p (�) f (Xj�)f(X)

(50)

where f(X) is the marginal distribution of the data. The conditional distri-bution function of the data given the parameter set f (Xj�) is equivalent tothe likelihood function of the set of parameters given the data L (�jX) :Thelikelihood function can be calculated from the state-space representation ofthe model using the Kalman �lter (see Ljungqvist and Sargent (2004) fordetails). Bayesian inference therefore requires (i) the choice of prior densitiesfor the parameters of interest, and (ii) construction of the posterior from theprior densities and the likelihood function. The remainder of this sectiondiscusses brie�y how to construct the posterior distribution. The choice ofprior is discussed later, together with the estimation results.Given the likelihood function and a set of prior distributions, an approx-

imation to the posterior mode of the parameters of interest can be calcu-lated using a Laplace approximation. The posterior mode obtained in thisway is used as the starting value for the Metropolis-Hastings algorithm (seeBauwens, Lubrano, and Richard (1999) for details). This algorithm allowsus to generate draws from the posterior density p (�jX). At each iteration,a proposal density (a normal distribution with mean equal to the previouslyaccepted draw) is used to generate a new draw which is accepted as a drawfrom the posterior density p (�jX) with probability p. The probability p de-pends on the value of the posterior and the proposal density at the candidatedraw, relative to the previously accepted draw. We generate 100000 drawsin 4 chains in this manner, discarding the �rst 50000 draws to reduce theimportance of the starting values.

20

Page 22: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

3.1 Data

To estimate the model we use information on ten key macroeconomic vari-ables for India running from 1996Q2 to 2007Q4: GDP, private consumptionexpenditure, investment, exports, imports (all expressed in constant prices),the real exchange rate, the rate of depreciation of the nominal exchange rate,wholesale price in�ation, the nominal interest rate, and the Bombay StockExchange SENSEX Index.14 The 3-month Treasury Bill rate is used as aproxy of the nominal interest rate and the real e¤ective exchange rate calcu-lated by the IMF is used as proxy for the real exchange rate. As in Christiano,Motto, and Rostagno (2007) we use the value of the stock exchange index(de�ated using the wholesale price index) to proxy the net worth of entre-preneurs. All variables are expressed as deviations from a Hodrick-Prescotttime trend and, with the exception of the real and nominal exchange rates,the nominal interest rate, and the SENSEX, are seasonally adjusted usingthe X12 �lter. All data are taken from the CEIC database.

3.2 Calibration of Steady-State Parameters

As in Saxegaard (2006a), we calibrate the parameters in the model that deter-mine the steady state based on �ndings from previous studies and the data.We then estimate the parameters that determine the dynamic properties ofthe model away from the steady-state. The list of calibrated parameters in-clude the rate of time preference, �, the depreciation rate of capital, �, thecost share of capital, , the price elasticity of aggregate non-tradables andimports, �, the price elasticity of exports, &, the share of non-tradables inthe WPI, �, the steady-state markup for retailers, "=(" � 1), in addition toseveral steady-state ratios which are set so as to replicate the average in thedata. The calibrated parameter values and the implied steady-state ratiosare summarized in table 1.The substitution elasticity between imported and domestically produced

goods is set at 1.5, close to the value used by Saxegaard (2006a) for thePhilippines, while the elasticity of substitution of exports, &, was set to 2.4, avalue consistent with the steady-state export to GDP ratio. With the shareof non-tradables in the WPI, �, set at 0.8, this corresponds to a steady-stateexport to GDP ratio of 19 percent and a steady-state import to GDP ratio

14More recent data is not included given the increased volatility associated with theglobal �nancial crisis.

21

Page 23: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Table 1: Calibrated ParametersParameter Value Description

� 1:5 Price elasticity of non-tradables and imports& 2:4 Price elasticity of exports

�d; 1� �m 0:8 Share of non-tradables in CPI�= (� � 1) 1:09 Steady state markup factor for intermediary goods

0:33 Cost share of capital� 0:025 Quarterly depreciation rate of capital� 1:0451=4 Steady state in�ation

1 + i 1:071=4 Steady state domestic interest rate�� 1:0251=4 Steady state in�ationsg 0:27 Steady state government absorption

of 21 percent. The share of government expenditure in GDP is set at 11percent as in the data. The steady-state markup factor is set to 9 percent sothat " = 12: The technology parameter is set at 0.33 which is consistentwith much of the literature. As in much of the literature, the depreciationrate is set at 10 percent per annum, implying a value of � of 0.025.We set the steady-state annual nominal interest rate at 7 percent which

corresponds to the annualized average quarterly rate for the period we havedata on. Similarly, steady-state in�ation was set equal to 4.5 percent whichcorresponds to the average seasonally adjusted quarterly WPI in�ation overthe period on an annualized basis. Intertemporal optimization by consumersimplies that the subjective discount rate, �, is set equal to 0.994 which isthe inverse of the quarterly real steady-state interest rate. We set worldin�ation equal to 2.5 percent on an annual basis which implies a steady-statedepreciation rate of the nominal exchange rate of 2 percent on an annualbasis and a world interest rate of 5 percent per annum.

3.3 Prior Distribution of Estimated Parameters

Our choice of prior distributions for the estimated parameters is guided bothby theoretical considerations and empirical evidence. Given the lack of sig-ni�cant empirical evidence, however, we choose relatively di¤use priors thatcover a wide range of parameter values. For the structural parameters, wechoose either gamma distributions or beta distributions in the case whena parameter� such as the autoregressive shock processes� is restricted by

22

Page 24: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

theoretical considerations to lie between zero and one. Given the lack ofevidence regarding the policy reaction function of the Reserve Bank of India,we use uniform distributions for the parameters of the monetary policy rule.Finally, as in much of the literature the inverted gamma distribution is usedfor the standard errors of the shock processes. This distribution guaranteesa positive variance but with a large domain. The choice of priors for theparameters to be estimated is summarized in table 2.As mentioned previously, we assume that �rms incur a quadratic cost

of price adjustment, measured in terms of current in�ation, relative to theprevious periods in�ation rate. We use the gamma distribution to restrictthe adjustment cost parameters (#d; #x) to the positive manifold and, giventhe lack of evidence on the degree of nominal rigidity in emerging markets,specify a mean of 100 with a standard deviation of 20. As noted by Gali andGertler (1999) an adjustment cost of 100 corresponds approximately to theassumption that �rms change prices (or in�ation) every 3.74 quarters. Thereis considerable uncertainty surrounding the appropriate value of the capitalcost adjustment cost parameter (�) in the model. While Kollmann (2002)�nds a value of 1.43 in their model, Ireland (2001) and Ireland (2003) �ndvalues above 30. The mean of the prior on the capital adjustment cost para-meter (�) is set at 15 (as in Kollmann (2002)) with a gamma distribution.Our choice of prior distributions for the parameters of the monetary policy

reaction function is based on the fact that there is little evidence regardingthe Reserve Bank of India�s interest rate setting behavior.15 As a result, wechoose uniform priors for the feedback parameters on in�ation, output, andthe rate of exchange rate depreciation in the policy rule with a relativelylarge domain. In particular, we choose uniform prior distributions with aminimum of 0 and a maximum of 3 for the feedback parameter on WPIin�ation (��) and the rate of exchange rate depreciation

��q�. This encom-

passes the estimates found by Mohanty and Klau (2004). For the feedbackparameter on the output gap

��y�; we choose a uniform distribution with a

minimum of -1 and a maximum of 1. This is consistent with the �nding inMohanty and Klau (2004) that several emerging market central banks do notbase their policy response on movements in the output gap in a systematicfashion. The lagged interest rate prior (�i) follows a beta distribution with

15A notable exception is Mohanty and Klau (2004) who �nds that the parameters of themonetary policy reaction function in India are much lower than in other countries in Asia.A more detailed comparison between their results and ours is done in the next section.

23

Page 25: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

mean 0.7 and standard deviation of 0.2. This is consistent with the estimatein Mohanty and Klau (2004).The prior on the habit persistence parameter (b) is assumed to follow a

beta distribution to ensure that it remains bounded between 0 and 1. Weassume a mean of 0.5 and a standard deviation of 0.2 for the prior distri-bution. The mean of our prior is lower than the values used inter alia byJulliard, Karam, Laxton, and Pesenti (2004) and Smets and Wouters (2003)re�ecting the assumption that a higher share of consumers in India is likelyto be cash-constrained and thus unable to smooth consumption. However,the relatively large standard deviation implies that the prior distribution isrelatively di¤use and covers a broad range of estimates.As in Dib, Mendicino, and Zhang (2008), we choose a prior with a gamma

distribution for the elasticity of the external �nance premium. We assumea mean of 0.07 which is consistent with previous �ndings in the literature(see inter alia (Elekdag, Justiniano, and Tchakarov 2005), (Christensen andDib 2006), and (Dib, Mendicino, and Zhang 2008)) and a standard deviationof 0.02. For the risk premium on foreign-currency borrowing (�d) we use agamma distribution with a mean of 0.0019, as in Saxegaard (2006a), and astandard error of 0.002.Finally, for the priors of the autoregressive parameters and the standard

errors of the stochastic processes, we follow the same procedure as in Smetsand Wouters (2005) and Julliard, Karam, Laxton, and Pesenti (2004). Thepersistence parameters are given a prior with a beta distribution to restrictthe domain between 0 and 1. The mean of the distribution for each of theautoregressive parameters is set at 0.8. For the standard errors, we use theinverted gamma distribution with a di¤use prior. The inverted gamma distri-bution is commonly used for standard errors as it gives support to all positivevalues of the parameter and has characteristics which ease the computationalburden of the estimation processes. In order to specify the precise mean ofthe prior distribution for the standard errors of the structural shocks, wehave relied on the variance decomposition of the model. In other words, weexperimented with di¤erent sized shocks until we arrived at a speci�cationwhich entailed a reasonable contribution of each of the structural shocks tothe total variability of our observed variables. This approach was preferredto relying on previous studies given that the importance of shocks cannot bedirectly inferred from the size of their standard errors due to normalization

24

Page 26: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

issues.16 In any case, the use of a di¤use prior reduces the importance of themean of the prior distribution on the outcome of the estimation.

4 Empirical Results

Table 2 reports the estimated posterior model together with the 90 percentileof the posterior distribution. Figure 2 provides a visual representation ofthis information by plotting the prior and posterior distribution for eachparameter that is estimated, together with the posterior mode. These plotsallow us to make some statements about the relative importance of the priorand the data in the construction of the posterior distribution. Overall, ourmodel yields plausible parameter estimates for the parameters of the modelwhich are broadly in line with results from previous studies.The estimate of the elasticity of the external �nance premiumwith respect

to �rm leverage � is equal to 0.057. This is slightly below the estimate of0.066 for Korea in Elekdag, Justiniano, and Tchakarov (2005) and somewhathigher than estimate in Dib, Mendicino, and Zhang (2008) using Canadiandata. The investment adjustment cost parameter � is estimated at 23.0,signi�cantly higher than the prior mean. As pointed out by Christensen andDib (2006), capital adjustment costs have an important interaction with the�nancial accelerator. If capital adjustment costs are high, the price of capitalwill tend to be more volatile. As net worth responds directly to the priceof capital (through capital gains and losses), it a¤ects the external �nancepremium faced by corporates, leading to increased investment volatility.The habit persistence parameter (b) is estimated at 0.499, implying that

there are signi�cant delays in the e¤ect of interest rate changes on aggregateexpenditure, and consumption in particular. As we expected, these estimatesare somewhat lower than found in other studies including Saxegaard (2006a)and Smets and Wouters (2005) given the higher share of cash-constrainedconsumers in India. With regards to the cost of price adjustment, our es-timates suggest that domestic prices are more sluggish relatively to what istypically found in the literature. Moreover, the plots of the posterior in �g-ure 2 suggest that the data is quite informative about this parameter. Ourestimate of the cost of adjusting import prices, however, is close to the prior,which is not surprising given that we do not include data on import pricesin our sample.

16See Lubik and Schorfheide (2005) for details.

25

Page 27: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

With regards to the estimates of the policy rule parameters, our resultsindicate that the Reserve Bank of India places a relatively high weight oncontrolling the rate of depreciation of nominal exchange rate. In particularthe estimate of e, the coe¢ cient that measures the response of monetarypolicy to exchange rate movements, is 3 times higher than �, the coe¢ -cient on in�ation. Moreover, the results suggest that output stabilizationdoes not play a signi�cant part in the conduct of monetary policy, with theestimate of Y insigni�cantly di¤erent from zero. Because the model is esti-mated in levels, a simple transformation is necessary to be able to interpretthese numbers. In particular, they imply that annual nominal interest rateincrease by 0.9 percentage points if annual in�ation is 1 percentage pointabove its equilibrium value. Similarly, annual interest rates increase by 1percentage point if the nominal exchange rate depreciates by 1 percent morethan the equilibrium rate of depreciation. Interestingly, these estimates aresigni�cantly higher than the estimates found by Mohanty and Klau (2004) intheir study of the monetary policy reaction function for India. Their resultssuggest a 0.13 percentage point increase in annual interest rates if annual in-�ation increases by 1 percentage point, while a 0.18 percentage point increasein annual interest rates if the real exchange rate depreciations by 1 percent.While the fact that Mohanty and Klau (2004) is a partial equilibrium studymeans that their results are not directly comparable to ours, it is noteworthythat they also �nd a relatively strong response to movements in the exchangerate in India.Finally, our estimates of the shock processes suggest that the shock to the

markup and the price elasticity of exports are the most persistent stochasticprocesses. The persistence of the shock to uncovered interest parity suggeststhat departures from uncovered interest parity are pervasive in the data. Ourestimates of the standard errors of the structural shocks are also reported in 5.However, as pointed out by Lubik and Schorfheide (2005), the interpretationof these is not straightforward and is dependent on the scale of the variables.

4.1 Cross-validation with alternative models

As suggested by Christensen and Dib (2006) we compare the �t of our model,the Estimated FA model, against an alternative model without a �nancialaccelerator. The alternative model, which we call the Estimated No-FAmodel, is identical to the FA model with the exception that the parame-ter that captures the elasticity of the external �nance premium with respect

26

Page 28: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Figure 2: Prior and Posterior Distributions

0 100 200 3000

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02

0.025

0.03Domestic  Price Adj. Cost

­100 0 100 200 3000

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02

0.025

0.03Import Price Adj. Cost

­0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.150

10

20

30

40

50External Finance Premium Elastic ity

0 10 20 30 400

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

Capital Adj. Cost

­0.5 0 0.5 1 1.50

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3Habit Persis tence

­0.5 0 0.5 1 1.50

1

2

3

4

5Monetary Policy Rule: Interest Rate Smoothing

­1 0 1 2 3 40

0.5

1

1.5

2Monetary Policy Rule: Inflation

­4 ­2 0 2 40

5

10

15

20

25

30Monetary Policy Rule: Output

0 1 2 3 40

0.5

1

1.5

2Monetary Policy Rule: Exchange Rate

Posterior Prior

27

Page 29: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

to �rm leverage is constrained to equal zero. In addition, as suggested bySchorfheide (2000), we compare the �t our estimated model against a less re-strictive non-structural reduced form Bayesian vector autogression (BVAR)estimated using the popular Litterman prior (Sims and Zha 1998). This pro-vides a stringent test of the ability of our model to replicate the dynamicsin the data and thus of its usefulness as a tool for policy analysis. Indeed,it is partly evidence suggesting that empirical DSGE models with a su¢ -cient number of structural shocks compare favorably with BVARs which hasprompted the increased interest in DSGE models in policy making.17

Bayesian econometrics provides a natural framework for assessing theempirical performance of di¤erent mis-speci�ed models. Using Bayes Lawagain we can write the posterior probability of a model Mi as:

p(MijX) =p(Mi)L(MijX)

f(X)

where p(Mi) is the prior belief attached to model i and L(MijX) is thelikelihood of the model given the data. Bayesian model selection is based onthe posterior odds ratio of a particular model M1 against another model M2

which is given by:p(M1jX)p(M2jX)

=p(M1)L(M1jX)p(M2)L(M2jX)

where L(M1jX)L(M2jX)�the ratio of marginal likelihoods for di¤erent models�represents

a summary measure of the evidence provided by the data for choosing be-tween two competing models.Table 2 reports the marginal likelihood of the Estimated FA model, the

Estimated No-FA model, and BVARs estimated on the same data set at lags1 to 4. The higher marginal likelihood in the Estimated FA model relativeto the Estimated No-FA Model suggests that the introduction of a �nan-cial accelerator mechanism does improve the model�s ability to capture themovements observed in the data. As in Elekdag, Justiniano, and Tchakarov(2005), however, the Estimated FA model does not compare favorably to aBVAR with one lag although it dominates BVARs with more lags. This isnot surprising as the marginal likelihood falls with increasing model com-plexity and increases with model �t. The improved �t of our Estimated FAmodel relative to a BVAR with one lag does not compensate for its higher

17See inter alia Smets and Wouters (2005), Julliard, Karam, Laxton, and Pesenti (2004),and Lubik and Schorfheide (2005).

28

Page 30: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Table 2: Model ComparisonMarginal Likelihood

Estimated FA model 876:49Estimated No-FA model 873:64BVAR(1) 1148:54BVAR(2) 420:19BVAR(3) 673:25BVAR(4) 743:61

complexity. Nevertheless, the fact that the Estimated FA model outperformsBVARs with more than one lag does provide some evidence in support of theEstimated FA model as a tool of policy analysis.

4.2 Impulse Responses

A useful way to illustrate the dynamics of the estimated model and theimportance of the �nancial accelerator is to consider the impulse responsefunctions when the �nancial accelerator is present and when it is not. Theresponse of some key macroeconomic variables to a 100 bps increase in thenominal interest rate are shown in �gure 3, to a positive technology shockin �gure 4, and to a shock to borrowing costs in �gure 5. Each variable�sresponse is expressed as the percentage deviation from its steady-state level,with the exception of the rate variables, which are in percentage points. In�gures 3 to 5 the impulse responses generated in the estimated FA modelare shown in black. The impulse responses generated when the �nancialaccelerator is not present are shown in green. As in Christensen and Dib(2006), we generate these impulse responses by setting the elasticity of theexternal �nance premium with respect to �rm leverage equal to zero, butkeeping all the other parameter estimates from the estimated FA model. Thedi¤erence between the black and the green lines should give an indication ofthe impact of the �nancial accelerator on a particular variable after a givenshock.Figure 3 shows that the presence of a �nancial accelerator ampli�es and

propagates the impact of a contractionary monetary policy shock. In bothmodels, the increase in the nominal interest rate raises the cost of domesticborrowing for consumers and thus leads to a contraction in consumption. Italso raises the demand for domestic bonds and thus appreciates the domes-

29

Page 31: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Figure 3: The Economy�s Response to a 100 Bps Contractionary MonetaryPolicy Shock

0 5 10 15 20­0.5

­0.4

­0.3

­0.2

­0.1

0Output

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­0.2

­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0Consumption

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­1.5

­1

­0.5

0Investment

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­0.25

­0.2

­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0Capital

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­0.3

­0.2

­0.1

0

0.1Real Exchange Rate

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­5

0

5

10

15

20x 10­3 Interest Rate

perc

enta

ge p

oint

s

0 5 10 15 20­0.2

­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05Inflation

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­1.5

­1

­0.5

0Net Worth

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 200

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04Premium

perc

ent

Financial Accelerator No Financial Accelerator

30

Page 32: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

tic currency, while the net worth of entrepreneurs declines because of thedeclining return to capital and higher real interest costs associated with ex-isting debt (the debt-de�ation e¤ect). Output contracts both as a result ofdecreased domestic demand and a result of decreased competitiveness follow-ing the appreciation of the real exchange rate. The contraction in demandin turn leads to a fall in in�ation. In the presence of the �nancial accelera-tor, the external �nance premium increases as a result of the decline in networth and rising leverage. This pushes up the real borrowing cost for entre-preneurs, putting downward pressure on investment and the price of capitalwhich further reduces net worth. This reduction in net worth leads to a fur-ther increase in the cost of borrowing (the premium goes up), thus reducingcapital, investment and output further (second round e¤ects). This mech-anism ampli�es the magnitude and the persistence of transitory monetarypolicy shocks as evident from the impulse responses.Figure 4 shows that the �nancial accelerator has less of an impact fol-

lowing a positive shock to technology. The technology shock increases thereturn to capital and thus leads to an increase in investment and output. Atthe same time, the improvement in technology reduces �rms�marginal costsand thus reduces in�ation. The higher return to capital and lower in�ationhave opposite e¤ects on net worth but in our model the positive impact ofthe higher return to capital dominates. This is partly due to the endogenousresponse of monetary policy which pushes up nominal interest rates, therebyreducing the amount of de�ation. When the �nancial accelerator is active,the rise in net worth pushes down the risk premium faced by entrepreneursand leads to a larger response of investment and capital. While output issomewhat more volatile when the �nancial accelerator is present, the impactif signi�cantly less than following a shock to monetary policy.Figure 5 also shows that the �nancial accelerator ampli�es the e¤ects of a

�nancial shock such as a shock to the borrowing costs faced by entrepreneurs.In both models, the higher borrowing costs depresses the demand for newcapital and thus lowers investment, output, and in�ation. The decline inabsorption, in turn, reduces the demand for non-tradables and causes a realexchange rate depreciation. The exchange rate depreciation (which raisesthe external borrowing cost of entrepreneurs), together with the decline inin�ation, reduces entrepreneurs�net worth. In the presence of the �nancialaccelerator, this increases the entrepreneurs�risk premium and reduces thedemand for capital further. As a result, the decline in investment and outputis much larger when the �nancial accelerator is present.

31

Page 33: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Figure 4: The Economy�s Response to a 1 Percent Improvement in Technol-ogy

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Output

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 200

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4Consumption

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Investment

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 200

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2Capital

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 200

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25Real Exchange Rate

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­0.015

­0.01

­0.005

0

0.005

0.01Interest Rate

perc

enta

ge p

oint

s

0 5 10 15 20­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05Inflation

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Net Worth

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­0.02

­0.015

­0.01

­0.005

0Premium

perc

ent

Financ ial Accelerator No Financial Accelerator

32

Page 34: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Figure 5: The Economy�s Response to a 1 Percent Increase in Enterpreneur�sBorrowing Cost

0 5 10 15 20­2.5

­2

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0Output

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0Consumption

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­15

­10

­5

0Investment

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­2.5

­2

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0Capital

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Real Exchange Rate

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­0.03

­0.02

­0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03Interest Rate

perc

enta

ge p

oint

s

0 5 10 15 20­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0

0.2Inflation

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 20­20

­15

­10

­5

0Net Worth

perc

ent

0 5 10 15 200

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5Premium

perc

ent

Financial Accelerator No Financial Accelerator

33

Page 35: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Table 3: Parameters of an Optimal Policy Rule�i �� �Y �q

Estimated Policy Rule 0:83 0:89 0:02 2:44Optimal Policy Rule 0:995 5:75 0:00 1:05

As in previous studies, therefore, the �nancial accelerator ampli�es andpropagates the impact of shocks on investment. The impact of the �nan-cial accelerator on other variables including output and in�ation depends,however, on the type of shock. Following a contractionary monetary policyshock and a shock to entrepreneurs�cost of borrowing, output and in�ationvolatility increases when the �nancial accelerator is present. The �nancialaccelerator has much less of an impact, however, on the economy followinga shock to technology. This is consistent with the results in other studiesincluding Christensen and Dib (2006).

5 Optimal Policy

How does the estimated monetary policy rule compare to an policy rulewhich maximizes consumer welfare? To answer this question we search forthe parameters of the monetary policy reaction function in equation 45 thatmaximizes a second-order approximation of consumer welfare.18 The resultsof this exercise are presented in table 3, while the volatility implied by thedi¤erent rules and the resulting consumer welfare is presented in table 4.The parameters of a policy rule that maximizes welfare di¤ers signi�cantly

from the parameters of the estimated policy rule. Our results suggest thatthe estimated policy rule places too little emphasis on in�ation stabilizationand too much emphasis on stabilizing the rate of depreciation of the nominalexchange rate. The lower than optimal weight on in�ation stabilization in theestimated policy rule, coupled with a signi�cantly higher than optimal weight

18In the non-stochastic �exible-price equilibrium or steady-state, monetary policy isneutral in the sense that all the monetary rules we consider imply the same non-stochasticsteady-state for the economy. Furthermore, given that up to a �rst-order (Taylor series)approximation consumer welfare is equal to its non-stochastic steady-state value, changesin the monetary policy regime will only have second-order (or higher) e¤ects on welfare. Asa result, we follow the majority of the literature in approximating welfare using a second-order Taylor series approximation to expected utility. This method leads to a loss-functionsimilar to that widely assumed in the earlier literature on monetary policy evaluation.

34

Page 36: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

on exchange rate stabilization, suggests that the RBI places more emphasison stabilizing the rate of depreciation than on reducing in�ation volatility.As a result, in�ation volatility is higher under the estimated policy rule thanunder the optimal rule, while exchange rate volatility is lower. Both theestimated rule and the optimal rule feature signi�cant interest-rate inertia,which implies that the authorities react to in�ation much more aggressivelyin the long run than in the short run.19 At the same, time the emphasison stabilizing the rate of depreciation of the nominal exchange rate in theestimated policy rule comes at the expense of higher volatility in the realeconomy (despite the fact that the weight on output stabilization is broadlysimilar in both rules), while the volatility of �nancial sector variables�inparticular borrowing costs and net worth�is also higher.We calculate a second-order accurate measure of consumer welfare asso-

ciated with di¤erent monetary policy regimes as in Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe(2004). In particular, we calculate the expectation of lifetime utility as oftime zero, V0, associated with a particular monetary regime, denoted withthe superscript, r:

V r0 � E0

1Xt=0

�tU (Crt ; L

rt ) (51)

conditional on the economy being at its non-stochastic steady-state at timezero.In order to evaluate the cost of the estimated monetary policy rule relative

to the welfare optimizing rule, we follow Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2004) andcalculate the fraction of a consumer�s consumption that would make themindi¤erent between di¤erent regimes.20 In particular, � is de�ned as thefraction of the household�s consumption under the optimal policy rule thatconsumers would have to give up to be as well o¤ under the empirical policyrule as under the optimal policy rule so that a value of ��100 = 1 representsone percent of permanent consumption. Formally � is de�ned as:

V est0 = E0

1Xt=0

�tU�(1� �)Copt

t ; Loptt

�(52)

19Interest rate interia is in fact somewhat higher in the optimal rule re�ecting possiblythe impact interest rate volatility has on the volatility of net worth and thus the realeconomy.20It is fairly common in the literature to only look at the implementable rules rather than

truely optimal "Ramsey allocation" that can not be implemented. This is the approachwe follow in this paper.

35

Page 37: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

where V est0 denotes the expectation of lifetime utility as of time zero under

the estimated policy rule while Coptt and Loptt refer to the amount of labour

and consumption under the optimal rule. For the particular functional formin our model this implies:

� = 1� e

h1��

�c;t(1�b)(Vest0 �V opt0 )

i(53)

where V opt0 denotes the expectation of lifetime utility as of time zero under

the optimal policy rule. From table 4 we see that the welfare loss underthe sub-optimal estimated policy rule is equivalent to a not insigni�cant 0.4percent of permanent consumption.21 This is close to the welfare gain foundby Kollmann (2002) but lower than that found by Ambler, Dib, and Rebei(2004).It is useful to compare our results to those in Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe

(2007) who calculate welfare maximizing policy rules using a closed-economymodel calibrated using U.S. data and to those in Leith, Moldovan, and Rossi(2009) who analyze the welfare maximizing policy rule under di¤erent de-grees of habit persistence. We also compare our results to those in Ambler,Dib, and Rebei (2004) who look at an open-economy model estimated us-ing Canadian and U.S. data, although their results are not directly com-parable to ours given the inclusion of money growth in the policy rule andthe absence of interest rate smoothing. Both Leith, Moldovan, and Rossi(2009) and Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2007) �nd that a signi�cant degree ofinterest rate smoothing�albeit less than in our model�is optimal and con-tributes to substantially lower macroeconomic volatility. Leith, Moldovan,and Rossi (2009) and Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2007) also �nd that a highweight on in�ation stabilization, and a zero weight on output stabilizationis optimal. Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2007) restrict the weight on in�ationstabilization to be less than 3 on the grounds that higher values may not beimplementable. However, they note than in the absence of such a restrictionthe optimal weight is 332. Similarly, Leith, Moldovan, and Rossi (2009) �ndthat an estimate around 30 is optimal for the amount of habit persistence weestimate in our model. Ambler, Dib, and Rebei (2004) on the other hand,�nd a much lower optimal weight on in�ation (1.2) and a higher weight onoutput stabilization (0.2).

21In other words, consumption in every period over the life-time of a consumer wouldbe 0.4 percent lower under the estimated rule than under the optimal rule.

36

Page 38: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Table4:StandardDeviationsofKeyMacroeconomicVariables

GDP

Cons.

Inv.

Nom.ER

RealER

Nom.IR

WPIIn�.

NetWorth

Premium

Welfare

Cons.Cost

EstimatedPolicy

Rule

0.1100

0.0547

0.0520

0.0020

0.0126

0.0025

0.0036

1.6081

0.0059

-120.0098

0.004

OptimalPolicy

Rule

0.0971

0.0537

0.0485

0.0064

0.0134

0.0029

0.0013

1.4621

0.0053

-119.6640

...

37

Page 39: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Figure 6 illustrates our results by simulating the path of output, in�ation,the rate of depreciation of the nominal exchange rate, and the nominal in-terest rate under the estimated policy rule and the optimal policy rule, usingthe estimated path of the stochastic shocks in the model. These plots con�rmthat in�ation volatility would have been lower if monetary policy had beenconducted according to the optimal policy rule. This was particularly truetoward the end of 2004 (WPI in�ation increased to 8.1 percent y.o.y. in thethird quarter of 2004) and in 2006/07. At the same the rate of depreciation ofthe nominal exchange rate displays a signi�cantly higher amount of volatilityduring the whole sample period under the optimal rule. Finally, the simula-tion of the nominal interest rate suggest that interest rates would have beenhigher toward the end of the sample�given the relatively high in�ation�ifmonetary policy had been conducted according to the optimal policy rule.

6 Concluding Remarks

The aim of this paper has been to estimate a DSGE model with macro�-nancial linkages for India and to use it to analyze the conduct of monetarypolicy. The DSGE model used is an extension of the model developed inSaxegaard (2006b) augmented to include a �nancial accelerator mechanismsimilar to that proposed by BGG to study the e¤ect of �nancial frictions onthe real economy.As is increasingly common in this literature, the model was estimated us-

ing Bayesian estimation techniques. Bayesian estimation techniques providea natural framework for evaluating macroeconomic models that are bound tobe mis-speci�ed along several dimensions. Our results yielded plausible es-timates for the model parameters, although an examination of the posteriordistributions suggested that the data was not informative about a number ofparameters. In addition, the cross validation tests suggest that the introduc-tion of a �nancial accelerator mechanism does improve the model�s abilityto capture the dynamics observed in the data. Furthermore, we provide evi-dence that our model with the �nancial accelerator provides a �t of the datathat outperforms a BVAR at more than one lag.Our results when using the model to examine the conduct of monetary

policy�using consumer welfare as the benchmark against which to analyzealternative policies�suggest that the RBI puts a higher than optimal weighton stabilizing the rate of depreciation of the nominal exchange rate and a

38

Page 40: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Figure 6: Path of Key Macroeconomic Variables Under Di¤erent Policy Rules

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008­0.4

­0.2

0

0.2

0.4GDP

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008­5

0

5

10x 10­3 WPI Inflation

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008­0.02

­0.01

0

0.01Rate of Depreciation of the Nominal Exchange Rate

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008­0.04

­0.02

0

0.02

0.04Nominal Interest Rate

Empirical Policy  Rule Optimal Policy Rule

39

Page 41: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

lower than optimal weight on in�ation stabilization even in the presence of�nancial accelerator e¤ects. This comes at the expense of higher in�ationvolatility as well as higher volatility in the real economy and in �nancial sec-tor variables. However, exchange rate volatility is substantially lower underthe monetary policy reaction function implied by the data relative to thewelfare optimizing policy rule. In welfare terms, our analysis suggests thatthe optimal policy rule entails a welfare gain equivalent to 0.4 percent ofpermanent consumption relative to the empirical policy rule.

7 Appendix

8 Bibliography

References

Aghion, P., P. Bacchetta, and A. Banerjee (2001). Currency crises andmonetary policy in an economy with credit constraints. European Eco-nomic Review 47, 1121�1150.

Ambler, S., A. Dib, and N. Rebei (2004). Optimal taylor rules in an esti-mated model of a small open economy. Technical report.

Batini, N., P. Levine, and J. Pearlman (2009). Monetary and �scal rulesin an emerging small open economy. Working paper WP/09/22, Inter-national Monetary Fund.

Bauwens, L., M. Lubrano, and J.-F. Richard (1999). Bayesian Inferencein Dynamic Econometric Models. Princeton: Oxford University Press.

Bernanke, B. and M. Gertler (1989). Agency costs, net worth, and business�uctuations. American Economic Review 79, 14�31.

Bernanke, B., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist (1999). The �nancial acceleratorin a quantitative business cycle framework. In Handbook of Macroeco-nomics. Amsterdam: North Holland.

Bernanke, B. S. and F. S. Mishkin (1997, Spring). In�ation targeting: Anew framework for monetary policy? Journal of Economic Perspec-tives 11 (2), 97�116.

40

Page 42: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Table 5: Parameter Priors and Posterior EstimatesPrior Posterior

Param eter Description Density M ean/M in S.D ./Max Mean 90% Interval

i Interest Rate Smooth ing Beta 0.7 0.2 0.829 0.647 0.999

� In�ation Stab ilization Uniform 0 3 0.890 0.002 1.737

Y Output Stab ilization Uniform -1 1 -0.017 -0 .049 0.014

e Exchange Rate Stab ilization Uniform 0 3 2.438 1.852 3.000

b Habit Persistence Beta 0.5 0.2 0.499 0.150 0.885

#d Cost of Non-tradable Goods Price Adjustm ent Gamma 100 20 118.220 84.184 151.489

#m Cost of Imported Goods Price Adjustm ent Gamma 100 20 100.043 67.992 151.489

�1 Capita l Sto ck Adjustm ent Costs Gamma 12 2 23.008 19.430 26.462

E lastic ity of External F inance Prem ium Beta 0.07 0.02 0.057 0.038 0.074

�� Technology Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.808 0.658 0.959

�i�

Foreign Interest Rate Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.831 0.718 0.945

���

Foreign In�ation Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.785 0.643 0.948

�� Markup Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.860 0.731 0.978

�uip UIP Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.794 0.654 0.931

�l Labour Supply Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.806 0.650 0.966

�c Marginal U tility Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.810 0.658 0.959

�in Investm ent E¢ ciency Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.785 0.640 0.947

�Qx

Export E lastic ity Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.857 0.759 0.961

�G Governm ent Sp ending Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.640 0.465 0.821

�n Borrow ing Cost Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.809 0.675 0.958

�v Survival Rate Shock Persistence Beta 0.8 0.1 0.805 0.656 0.958

"� Size of Technology Shock InvGamma 0.005 In f 0 .005 0.001 0.009

"i�

Size of Foreign Interest Rate Sho ck InvGamma 0.001 In f 0 .001 0.000 0.002

"��

Size of Foreign In�ation Shock InvGamma 0.001 In f 0 .001 0.000 0.002

"� Size of M arkup Shock InvGamma 1 Inf 1 .198 0.270 2.219

"uip Size of U IP Shock InvGamma 0.001 In f 0 .001 0.000 0.002

"l Size of Labour Supply Shock InvGamma 0.01 In f 0 .010 0.002 0.021

"c Size of M arginal U tility Shock InvGamma 0.01 In f 0 .016 0.003 0.028

"i Size of M onetary Policy Shock InvGamma 0.005 In f 0 .004 0.002 0.007

"in Size of Investm ent E¢ ciency Shock InvGamma 0.05 In f 0 .048 0.012 0.092

"Qx

Size of Export E lastic ity Sho ck InvGamma 0.1 In f 0 .320 0.190 0.454

"G Size of Governm ent Sp ending Shock InvGamma 0.01 In f 0 .068 0.052 0.083

"n Size of Borrow ing Cost Shock InvGamma 0.001 In f 0 .002 0.000 0.004

"v Size of Survival Rate Shock InvGamma 0.001 In f 0 .002 0.000 0.004

41

Page 43: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Carlstrom, G. and T. Fuerst (1997). Agency costs, net worth, and business�uctuations. American Economic Review 87, 893�910.

Christensen, I. and A. Dib (2006). Monetary policy in an estimated dsgemodel with a �nancial accelerator. Technical report.

Christiano, L., R. Motto, and M. Rostagno (2007, October). Shocks, struc-tures or monetary policies? the euro area and us after 2001. NBERWorking Papers 13521, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

Clarida, R., J. Gali, and M. Gertler (1999). The science of monetarypolicy: A new Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Litera-ture XXXVII.

Dib, A., C. Mendicino, and Y. Zhang (2008). Price level targeting in asmall open economy with �nancial frictions: Welfare analysis. Technicalreport.

Elekdag, S., A. Justiniano, and I. Tchakarov (2005). An estimated smallopen economy model of the �nancial accelerator. Working paperWP/05/44, International Monetary Fund.

Fernandez-Villaverde, J. and J. Rubio-Ramirez (2004). Comparing dy-namic equilibrium models to data: A Bayesian approach. Journal ofEconometrics 123, 153�187.

Gertler, M., S. Gilchrist, and F. M. Natalucci (2007, 03). External con-straints on monetary policy and the �nancial accelerator. Journal ofMoney, Credit and Banking 39 (2-3), 295�330.

Geweke, J. (1998). Using simulation methods for Bayesian econometricmodels: Inference, development and communication. Sta¤ Report 249 .Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

IMF (2009, October). World Economic Outlook. Washington: Interna-tional Monetary Fund.

Ireland, P. (2001). Sticky-price models of the business cycle: Speci�cationand stability. Journal of Monetary Economics 47, 3�18.

Ireland, P. N. (2003, November). Endogenous money or sticky prices?Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (8), 1623�1648.

Juillard, M. (2001, April). Dynare: A program for the simulation of ra-tional expectation models. Computing in Economics and Finance 2001213, Society for Computational Economics.

42

Page 44: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Julliard, M., P. Karam, D. Laxton, and P. Pesenti (2004). Welfare-basedmonetary policy rules in an estimated DSGE model of the U.S. econ-omy. mimeo. Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Kiyotaki, N. and J. Moore (1997, April). Credit cycles. Journal of PoliticalEconomy 105 (2), 211�48.

Kollmann, R. (2002). Monetary policy rules in the open economy: E¤ectson welfare and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 49,989�1015.

Krugman, P. (1999). Balance sheets, the transfer problem, and �nancialcrises. International Tax and Public Finance 6, 459�472.

Leith, C., I. Moldovan, and R. Rossi (2009, July). Optimal monetary policyin a new keynesian model with habits in consumption. Working PaperSeries 1076, European Central Bank.

Ljungqvist, L. and T. J. Sargent (2004, January). Recursive Macroeco-nomic Theory, 2nd Edition, Volume 1 of MIT Press Books. The MITPress.

Lubik, T. and F. Schorfheide (2005). A Bayesian look at new open econ-omy. mimeo.

Mohan, R. (2004). Challenges to monetary policy in a globalizing context.RBI Bulletin 2004a.

Mohanty, M. S. and M. Klau (2004, March). Monetary policy rules inemerging market economies: issues and evidence. BIS Working Papers149, Bank for International Settlements.

Oura, H. (2008, March). Financial development and growth in india: Agrowing tiger in a cage? IMF Working Paper 08/79 . (Washington:International Monetary Fund).

Rajan, R. (2008). A hundred small steps: Report on the committee on�nancial sector reforms. Technical report, Planning Commission, Gov-ernment of India.

RBI (2009). The evolution of monetary policy, 2003-04. Special volume ofits reports on currency and �nance (volume i), Reserve Bank of India.

Rotemberg, J. (1982). Sticky prices in the United States. Journal of Po-litical Economy 90, 1187�1211.

43

Page 45: An Estimated Model with Macrofinancial Linkages for India · 2010. 1. 28. · have since demonstrated that these –nancial frictions may signi–cantly am-plify both real and nominal

Saxegaard, M. (2006a). Fiscal and monetary policy in an estimated modelof the philippine economy. Manuscript.

Saxegaard, M. (2006b). Monetary policy rules in a small open economywith external liabilities. Manuscript.

Schmitt-Grohe, S. and M. Uribe (2003). Closing small open economy mod-els. Journal of International Economics 61, 163�185.

Schmitt-Grohe, S. and M. Uribe (2004). Solving dynamic general equilib-rium models using a second-order approximation to the policy function.Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 28, 755�775.

Schmitt-Grohe, S. and M. Uribe (2007, September). Optimal simple andimplementable monetary and �scal rules. Journal of Monetary Eco-nomics 54 (6), 1702�1725.

Schorfheide, F. (2000). Loss function-based evaluation of DSGE models.Journal of Applied Econometrics 15, 645�670.

Sims, C. A. and T. Zha (1998, November). Bayesian methods for dynamicmultivariate models. International Economic Review 39 (4), 949�68.

Smets, F. and R. Wouters (2003). An estimated dynamic stochastic generalequilibrium model of the Euro area. Journal of European EconomicAssociation 1, 1123�1175.

Smets, F. and R. Wouters (2005). Comparing shocks and frictions in U.s.and Euro area business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. Journalof Applied Econometrics 20(2), 161�183.

44