an empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

48
An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival compared to capitalist firms and survival between different co-op types in the United Kingdom 201174165 Supervisor: Dr Eike Mark Rinke Submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Bachelor of Arts in International Relations with Quantitative Research Methods POLIS May 2020 Word count: 9,992

Upload: others

Post on 15-Apr-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival compared to

capitalist firms and survival between different co-op types in the United

Kingdom

201174165

Supervisor: Dr Eike Mark Rinke

Submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Bachelor of Arts in

International Relations with Quantitative Research Methods

POLIS

May 2020

Word count: 9,992

Page 2: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

2

Abstract

Cooperatives are democratically controlled enterprises functioning in market economies

and are prevalent in the United Kingdom. What sets them apart from regular capitalist

firms is the fact that they relegate decision making to the entirety of their workers/owners

as opposed to only listening and considering the opinions of owners/shareholders. This

paper seeks to test three things. Firstly, it asks the question: why are cooperatives

created? Secondly, an analysis of hazard ratios and survival are presented when

discussing co-ops compared to capitalist firms. Finally, an exploratory analysis examines

the differences in survival rates and hazard ratios of different types of cooperatives. The

analysis is relegated to the United Kingdom and is empirical. Statistical methods such as

linear regression and Cox proportional hazards models are used in the empirical analyses.

The main conclusions to be drawn from the paper are threefold. Firstly, Cooperatives are

created during times of disillusionment with capitalism and unemployment. Secondly,

democratically controlled firms have lower hazard ratios and survive better in market

economies than regular capitalist firms during a five-year period. Finally, it is shown that

consumer cooperatives have smaller hazard ratios and tend to survive at higher rates than

worker co-operatives during a five-year period.

Page 3: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

3

Table of contents

I. Introduction II. Definitions

III. Reasons for cooperative creation Literature on disaffection with the capitalist economic system and unemployment Methodology and data Empirical model Discussion: Widening the understanding of co-op creation Limitations Further research

IV. DF and CF survival comparisons

Literature on cooperative versus traditional firm survival Methodology and data Empirical model Discussion: Why do cooperatives survive at higher rates? Limitations Further research

V. Cooperatives in depth

Lack of literature on survival of different cooperative types Methodology and data Empirical model Discussion: Are industrial sectors responsible for different co-op survival rates? Limitations Further research

VI. Conclusions

VII. Bibliography

VIII. Appendix

IX. Notes

Page 4: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

4

I. Introduction

The year 2012 has been declared the international year of cooperatives by the UN,

highlighting the positive effects they have done on communities and economies (Cheney

et al. 2014). What is interesting about these organisations is that they differ from what we

traditionally in our capitalist society would consider to be a company. Rather than the top-

down solution to business, where bosses and shareholders control the enterprise, co-ops

emphasise democratic control and a bottom-up approach to managing a business. The

purpose of this study is threefold: firstly, it aims to explain why a person would embark on

a venture of creating a co-operative with variables such as disaffection with the capitalist

system as well as unemployment playing a positive effect on creation of co-ops. Secondly,

the survival and hazard rates of cooperatives (DF) and traditional capitalist firms (CF) is

analysed to determine which type of company survives better in the market economy.

Finally, an exploratory analysis on different co-op types and their survival and hazard rates

is analysed to determine the most successful types of co-operatives and why they survive

longer than their counterparts. The analysis for all three sections is empirical and relegated

to the United Kingdom. This paper also seeks to contribute to the lack of literature in the

field of research on capitalism and cooperatives by offering confirmatory analyses in the

first two sections and exploratory analysis in the third section. An empirical section will

offer a literature review first, followed by the methodology and data descriptions, empirical

results, discussion, limitations and suggestions for further research. All of the data

manipulations and analyses have been done with Stata 16. To allow for scrutiny and

replication of the analysis, all of the datasets and code are available online1 (Anonymous,

2020).

1 For the direct link to the depository see Notes

Page 5: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

5

Definitions

To begin with an accurate analysis of cooperatives, one has to define them. For this paper,

the definition of a co-op is based on the definition given by the International Cooperative

alliance (n.d.):

An autonomous association of persons united voluntarily to meet their

common economic, social and cultural needs and aspirations through a

jointly-owned and democratically controlled enterprise.

This shall be the working definition of cooperatives as an umbrella term for democratically

controlled enterprises. A traditional business then is defined by a lack of democratic

control of the members/workers of the enterprise. To further this definition, a traditional

business is also considered to be owned by its shareholders/leaders, who are private

individuals (Barkley Rosser Jr and Rosser, 2004, p.7). This is done in order to clear up any

misreading of the study as some may claim that because co-ops as well as CF’s function

in market economies dominated by private property, that would make them capitalist as

well. This is because of the widespread mis(conception) that free markets are only

possible in capitalist economies, however this way of thinking is inherently flawed, as free

market economies have been advocated by anti-capitalist theorists as well (Bockman,

2011). The study seeks to highlight the differences in organisational structure, either

democratic or capitalist. Of course, it must also be mentioned that amid worker-owners in

co-ops there may be a minority of non-owning hired workers (Ben-Ner, 1988, p. 8). Even

so, since only a minority of hired workers do not have decision power over the firm it does

not diminish the distinction between a firm where the majority have sway over what

happens to it and one where only a small fraction of shareholders and owners dictate the

direction of the company.

Page 6: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

6

II. Reasons for cooperative creation

Cooperatives are an organisational alternative to traditional capitalist firms, however, what

motivates someone to embark on a venture to create a co-op as opposed to a CF? There

are, of course a myriad of them and the full discussion of the question is beyond the scope

of this paper. Rather, the reasons discussed in this section will be more ideological and

economical in their nature: a growing dissatisfaction with the current capitalist system and

an increase in unemployment.

Literature on disaffection with the capitalist economic system and unemployment

The theoretical conception of why a cooperative would be created can be derived from the

seminal works of Karl Marx (1848;1867). In the Communist Manifesto Marx (1848, p.14)

proposes the idea that the history of all of society is the history of class struggle. It is

assumed that by and large the capitalist economic system is divided into two opposing

classes: the bourgeoisie (owners of the means of production and employers of workers)

and proletarians (those who work for the capitalists and do not own the means of

production). This relationship is categorised as exploitative by Marx (1848;1867) as

capitalists extract surplus value from the workers, depriving them of the full value of their

labour to expand their own gains. The exploitation leads to antagonisms, which pit the

worker against the capitalist. The way, then, for the relationship to be absolved of

antagonisms is for workers to own the means of production themselves. This is where the

link between Marxist theory and cooperatives intersects, as the voluntary association and

democratic member self-management of co-ops gives them more and sometimes even full

control over the workplace, meaning that the workers are in control of the means of

production. The antagonisms that lead to the unrest of the workers, however, are

controlled by other ways in capitalist economies To begin with, there are material aspects

Page 7: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

7

that states can utilise such as creating social safety nets to the majority of the working

population2 or outright military crackdown on persons who seek to have a democratic say

in the economy (Lenin, 1917). There are also ideological aspects of control that capitalist

societies use to entrench their ideologies. The one discussed in this paper has been

coined by the late theorist Mark Fisher (2009) in his seminal work Capitalist Realism: Is

There no Alternative?. The term “Capitalist Realism” as defined by Fisher (2009, p.8) is

The widespread sense that not only is capitalism the only viable political

and economic system, but also that it is now impossible even to imagine a

coherent alternative to it.

Examples of this way of thinking can be seen in the work of Fukuyama (1989), who

theorises that after the fall of the Soviet Union, the ideological evolution of human societies

has ended, with democratic Western liberal capitalism coming out on top as the universal

and best human system. Indeed, this way of conceptualising the world is diagnosed as the

realism that pervades out societies today by Fisher. However, it does not have to be the

only way to conceptualise politics and the economy. Fisher (2009, p. 22) writes that one

way that capitalist realism can be threatened is to show that it is inconsistent or untenable.

One of the ways it can be made vulnerable is via crises, the main example here being the

2008 financial crisis, which engulfed most of the world and was compared to the 1929-

1933 Great Depression in terms of its magnitude and effects (Eigner and Umlauft, 2015).

The aftermath of the financial crash of 2008 in the UK resulted in the newly appointed

Conservative-Liberal Democrat coalition imposing austerity measures which, the working

persons believed, disproportionately affected their livelihoods in the negative sense

(Mustafa, 2011). The dissolution of social safety nets that served to sustain working

2 These allow for the majority to live comfortable lives and as such mitigate the antagonisms of exploitative capitalist working conditions.

Page 8: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

8

persons enough so they would not feel that their relationship towards the rulers of capital

was inherently antagonistic had begun to be eroded away and as such, alternatives could

begin to flourish in the economic sphere and capitalist realism challenged with that. One of

these alternatives could of course be forming a cooperative that provides democratic

control over the workplace for its workers, mitigating class antagonisms and giving a voice

to those who felt disenfranchised by lack of control over their workspaces. Given the

analysis presented by Fisher and Marx and the crisis that had recently affected the United

Kingdom I hypothesise that more people will break away from capitalist realism, forming

cooperatives as an alternative mode of economic organisation during the years that the

crisis is taking place, and after it. This is due to the system that contains class

antagonisms failing to do so as well as the imposition of austerity measures after the crisis,

further eroding capitalist realism as well as creating a disaffection with dominant mode of

production, which leads to an increase of cooperative creation as an alternative. The first

hypothesis then is:

H1: During crisis years and the years after a crisis the number of created cooperatives will

increase

The increase in unemployment that accompanied the crisis can also be another factor in

facilitating cooperative creation. As more and more potential employers are put out of

business, the more workers are left without jobs and some could decide to band together

in the formation of a DF whilst sharing the initial costs of setting up a business together by

either starting the firm from scratch or buying it from their former employer after the firm

has bankrupted. Indeed, this is supported by empirical literature. Ben-Ner (1988, p.9-10)

shows that the relationship between unemployment increases and the increase in the

number of worker-owned firms created is positive. This is further examined in the study by

also showing how many new conventional capitalist firms were created as unemployment

Page 9: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

9

was going up. The relationship is again positive, however, comparatively the growth for

cooperative numbers is much higher than for CF growth (Ben-Ner, 1988). This idea,

though, has not been touched upon much in empirical literature. For this, it is imperative to

check the validity of such claims and to try to replicate the limited finding of empirical

literature. The formulated hypothesis is:

H2: Increases in unemployment have a positive relationship with the increase in number of

co-ops created

Methodology and data

To test these hypotheses a linear regression model has been created to observe how

crisis years as well as unemployment increases impact cooperative creation during the

timeframe between 2000 and 2018 with both years included. The linear regression model

has been chosen because in the Ben-Ner study (1988, p 9-10) the increases in

unemployment and co-op creation seem to have a lineal positive relationship. For

disaffection this is also acceptable, since there has not been any empirical literature

surrounding the question as of the writing of this paper, and as such there is no

justification for supporting complex models to analyse the first hypothesis. As such, the

simplest OLS model was judged adequate for the study. The data for unemployment UK

has been gathered from Statista (Clark, 2019). The data for co-ops has been collected

from their open data portal (Co-operatives UK, 2019a). Table 13 shows the variables in

depth. The years during crisis have been chosen as 2008 and 2009 due to the fact that in

the UK the recession was active during both of them (Office for National Statistics, 2018).

It is argued that the disillusionment with capitalism is at its baseline value (0) during the

years before the crisis, with it increasing more during the crisis itself (1) and culminating in

3 See Appendix

Page 10: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

10

the years after the crisis (2) as more and more people get affected by the economic

hardships caused by the current economic system’s failures to provide adequate working

conditions and living standards. As both explanatory variables could suffer from the

multicollinearity problem with unemployment being a cause for disaffection with capitalism

as well as years after crisis predicting unemployment increases, diagnostic measures such

as the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF) have been implemented for the model to test for the

increase in variance that possible multicollinearity may create. To test for the accuracy of

the model, prediction errors and out of sample errors for the model are presented later in

the empirical results.

Empirical model

Table 2. Unemployment-Disaffection model for cooperative creation

B SE VIF p-value

Unemployment increase 32.25 6.47 1.22 0.000

Disaffection with

capitalism

52.12 8.76 1.22 0.000

Observations 19

R2 0.867

RMSE 32.63

Before discussing the model in depth, it should be noted for an easier interpretation that

the mean number of cooperatives created during a year is 224 when rounded, with the

biggest number of co-ops created being 374 during the year 2013 and the smallest

number being 110 in 2006. Table 2 shows us that the model gives support for both

hypotheses with both independent variables showing a positive relationship between them

and an increase in the number of created cooperatives. Both values are highly statistically

significant (p<0.001). A one percent increase in unemployment is associated with a

creation of 32 extra cooperatives during that year. In regard to the disaffection with the

current economic system it is found that a one unit increase in dissatisfaction with

Page 11: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

11

capitalism is associated with 52 extra cooperatives created during that year. This means,

that in the years after the crisis 104 extra cooperatives are expected than in the years

before the recession which is a 46% increase when compared to the mean of co-ops

created during an individual year. Diagnostics on the model have also been performed to

see how it performs. The Variance Inflation Factory (VIF) for both of the variables is 1.22

which shows a slight increase in the variance of the model because of independent

variable collinearity. However, this is not a huge problem as models are deemed to be

problematic if VIF for the variables exceeds 5 or 10 (Kutner et al. 2004; Sheather, 2009).

The given R-squared value suggests that the independent variables explain around 87%

of the variance of the dependent variable, showing a good fit of the model. The root mean

squared error (RMSE) has also been presented to show the amount prediction error

present in the model. To analyse this more closely one must look at Table 3 as it shows

the prediction errors and out of sample errors for each individual observation.

Table 3. Individual Prediction and Out of sample errors for the Unemployment-Disaffection model

Year Unemployment

(%) Crisis Year(1) Prediction Error Out of Sample

Error

2000 5.4 B -18.83 -21.38

2001 5.1 B .84 .95

2002 5.2 B 39.62 44.92

2003 5 B 24.06 27.35

2004 4.8 B 31.51 36.03

2005 4.8 B 2.51 2.88

2006 5.4 B -44.83 -50.9

2007 5.3 B 1.39 1.58

2008 5.7 D -32.63 -34.47

2009 7.6 D -39.91 -48.63

2010 7.9 A -54.71 -68.06

2011 8.1 A 26.84 34.49

2012 8 A 27.07 34.2

2013 7.6 A 43.97 52.59

2014 6.2 A -3.88 -4.35

2015 5.4 A 36.92 43.11

2016 4.9 A -21.96 -27.18

2017 4.4 A 6.17 8.34

2018 4.1 A -24.16 -35.04 (1)B-Before Crisis, D-During Crisis, A-After Crisis

Page 12: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

12

It can be seen that the model performs reasonably well at predicting the number of

cooperatives that will be created each year. It is worth noting that the model predicted

more cooperatives created during crisis years than there actually were. This can be

explained in the sense that the effects of the crisis were not fully present, with austerity

measures starting to be imposed during 2010 (Muller, 2019). This assumption has further

grounding if one looks at the years after the imposition of austerity (2011-2018) with more

cooperatives being created during those years (except 2014, 2016 and 2018) than

predicted. It may be that unemployment and disaffection with capitalism may play a bigger

role in cooperative creation than shown by the model, or it could be a myriad of other

reasons that were not considered in this model affecting this increase in co-ops.

Discussion: Widening the understanding of co-op creation

There are multitudes of reasons that co-ops can and are formed in market economies, and

disaffection with the capitalist mode of production and unemployment increases do seem

to affect the creation of co-ops. Whilst the findings suggest a positive relationship, there is

a little amount of literature that tackles with both hypotheses. For disaffection it is only a

theoretical and historical analysis that has been put forth (Marx, 1848;1867, Fisher, 2009).

In the Marxian sense, class antagonisms do seem to cause uproars during periods of

economic hardship, which the 2008-9 crisis exemplified for the United Kingdom. As such, it

is reasonable to assume that as co-ops do provide more worker control and are to some

extent opposed to the capitalist mode of production that workers would choose to join or

create a DF in order to either advance their own interests of wanting a more egalitarian

workplace where they are able to foster change via their own vote and have more say on

day to day matters. Ideological aspects can also be conceptualised as there may indeed

be those who consider themselves fundamentally opposed to capitalism and could not in

the moral sense work in a firm where it is the shareholder-owners making all of the

Page 13: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

13

decisions. Opposition to authoritarian4 rule of corporations is not only a Marxian stance;

democratic theory also approaches this issue on the side of the cooperatives. Dahl (1985,

p.135), one of the most important democratic theorists of our time, gives his ideas on the

matter:

Members of any association for whom the assumptions of the democratic

process are valid have a right to govern themselves by means of the

democratic process (…) We therefore see no convincing reasons why we

should not exercise our right to the democratic process just as we have

already done in the government of the state.

It would make sense that both ideological camps would be interested in creating co-ops

but for different reasons: Marxists because it is a way to subvert the capitalist economic

structure and democratic theorists because it is a way to extend democratic privileges to

the economic sphere as well as the political. Both of these ideological camps can be filled

by newcomers when the capitalist realism of Fisher (2009) is broken down by crises that

shows for some that the capitalist business is an unsustainable idea and therefore one

should seek alternatives to it. Persons could become Marxist in this sense when they are

conscious of their exploitation by the capitalist class as layoffs and decreases in wages

show that their needs are not being met by the ruling elite of a firm. For the same reason

others could be made into companions for democratic theory by crises in the sense that

they show just how little influence a lower or middle class person has when a business

fails because of mismanagements of the global market economy by the minority of

owners. This could lead a person to believe that democracy is essential in the economic

sphere like in the political sphere for an inclusive society as well as better management of

4 Authoritarian in the sense that the persons at the top make all of the decisions in a capitalist firm with little to no input from workers

Page 14: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

14

the world economy. There are also counter arguments that could be made. Perhaps co-

ops are created at higher rates after the crisis because of recognitions from world

renowned organisations? After all, the UN declared 2012 to be the International Year of

Cooperatives and gave them lots of attention, holding conferences and publishing various

research papers about DF’s (Cheney et al. 2014). This, of course, only feeds into the

argument as declaring a year to the co-ops after an economic crisis could be one of the

ways in which capitalist realism is challenged by the UN acknowledging that alternatives to

capitalist modes of production have contributed significantly to our welfare. It does seem

then that theoretically disaffection with capitalism does indeed foster a growth in

cooperative numbers, however, there do not seem to be any empirical studies as of the

writing of this paper specifically focusing on disaffection with capitalism and creation of

cooperatives. As this is the case, it is important to conduct more studies on this topic to

see if the results of the hypotheses hold up to scrutiny and are replicable. For

unemployment increases one again finds a shortage of empirical literature to draw upon,

though this study does find evidence for ideas put forth in Ben-Ner’s (1988) work that

unemployment does indeed play a factor in facilitating the growth of the numbers of co-op

enterprises. The idea makes sense intuitively as the more workers get laid off, the more

they could be able to organise together to form enterprises or buy failing ones from their

former bosses during times of economic hardship. The effect is increased by the recent

advancements in availability of education have increased the entrepreneurial skills of

regular workers (Ben-Ner, 1988, p.22). Even so, capital supply constraints for co-ops are

prevalent (Perotin, 2004, p.83). This effect would be increased during crises years when

one could expect a high unemployment as many of the unemployed workers would not

have capital saved up or a consistent way to get more due to the very nature of being

unemployed.

Page 15: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

15

Limitations

Even though the theory is consistent with the data, there are aspects of the model that

could be improved in future research. Firstly, direct variables, gauging disaffection with

capitalism should be used. To my knowledge, there exists no survey that deals with that

question in the UK and has been done during the timeframe that this model was run. The

model could also have benefitted from control variables like the wealth of the UK,

availability of education to workers and their education level to control for co-op creation.

This would have allowed to more accurately predict the results as well as test some of the

other claims about co-op creation in the research literature.

Further research

As this is a relatively unresearched area, the first idea would be to conduct more empirical

and theoretical studies on this topic in order to see if the proof for the hypotheses can be

replicable. For variables, it is imperative that surveys about the disaffection with capitalism

conducted every year be done in order to provide more accurate disaffection variables.

Furthermore, studies that control for other reasons for co-op creation are welcome to test

the validity of the results and to come to more accurate conclusions.

III. DF and CF survival comparisons

As the reasons for co-op creation have been discussed, it is time to see how they are able

to survive versus traditionally managed firms. This section deals with the hazard ratios and

survival rates between DF’s and CF’s

Literature on cooperative versus traditional firm survival

Better cooperative survival and lower hazard rates are backed by empirical literature,

however it mostly seems to focus on worker cooperatives. Ben-Ner (1988) conducted a

Page 16: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

16

study that compared worker cooperatives and capitalist firms in the United Kingdom during

the timeframe of 1974-1986. An estimation of hazard rates for both types of firms was

made. It was found that worker cooperatives were much more likely to survive at all age

points than traditional capitalist firms. For Perotin (2004, p. 78) the focus was on a cohort

of French firms. Hazard rates were again estimated for both types of firms with worker

cooperatives coming out on top again with a survival rate of 75% compared to 60% of all

French firms combined after the initial four years of creation (in the fifth year following their

establishment). A more extensive study in terms of categories was done by Monteiro and

Stewart (2015) which examined cooperatives compared to capitalist firms in Portugal. The

studies show that at all age points during a five-year period, cooperatives enjoyed greater

survival chances than their capitalist counterparts. To be more precise, Monteiro and

Stewart (2015, p. 110) estimated that around 97% of tested cooperatives had survived 5

years or more, 84% for 20 years or more and 63% had survived for 50 years or more. For

traditional firms the respective percentages were approximately 80%, 45% and 20%. This

was explained by showing that consumer and supplier cooperatives had lower exit

probabilities than CFs, which contributed to their increased survival chances. However,

when going into more depth of the different categories it was found that worker

cooperatives had similar exit probabilities compared to capitalist firms though this was

based on a small sample of worker co-ops. A more explanatory empirical study was done

when comparing DFs and CFs in Uruguay by Burdin and Dean (2009) which stipulates

that the enterprises differ substantially in their economic behaviours with increases in profit

corresponding to bigger increases of wages for cooperatives than capitalist firms as well

as that cooperative employment is more resistant to price shocks than in their capitalist

counterparts. It offers empirical evidence to explain why cooperatives are more resilient,

as higher wages and more stable employment opportunities can be seen as incentives for

Page 17: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

17

why a person would choose to continue to work in a co-op rather than go to a capitalist

firm. This could give members more enthusiasm to keep the company going. The

difference in survival rates is further contrasted by Audretsch (1991, p.443) who found that

around 50% of all businesses in the US die before the age of 6. Similar figures were

reported in the UK by Disney et al. (2003). After review of the academic literature it can be

seen that it suggests that cooperatives are better at surviving after their birth than

traditional capitalist enterprises. It is noted, that most of the papers focus on worker

cooperatives with some adding consumer firms to the analysis and as such are limited

when looking at the entirety of DF and CF comparisons. The hypotheses are:

H1: Cooperatives will have lower hazard rates than traditional capitalist firms in the first

five years of their existence

H2: Cooperative survival rates for five years will be between 75 and 97 percent

H3: Traditional firm survival for five years will be between 50 and 80 percent

The first hypothesis is based on the conclusions of (Ben-Ner, 1988; Perotin, 2004), both of

whom conclude the survival rates for cooperatives are higher than those for traditional

capitalist firms. The second hypothesis is based on Prerotin (2004) estimating co-op

survival at around 75% after five years of existence and Monteiro and Stewart (2015)

whom conclude that the DF survival rate after five years is 97%. As such, I believe that

cooperative survival in the UK will be between those two numbers. The third hypothesis is

based on Audretsch (1991) and Monteiro and Stewart (2015) who placed traditional firm

survival rates after 5 years of existence at 50 and 80 percent, respectively. Thus, I believe

that in the UK the survival rates will be between 50 and 80 percent.

Methodology and data

Page 18: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

18

This section examines the survival rates of cooperatives and traditional capitalist firms for

enterprises born in the year 2012 through the time frame of the years 2012-17. The Cox

proportional hazards model has been chosen as the go-to model for this analysis. It is a

regression model that tests the association between survival time of an individual (in this

case a business) and one or more predictor variables (Cox, 1972). The model produces a

hazard ratio that is to be interpreted as a weighted average of the true hazard ratios over a

selected time period (Stensrud and Hernan, 2020). This is more complicated than regular

OLS or logit regressions and has been chosen because I specifically want to test the

hazards involved in different business types, which the simpler regression models simply

cannot do to the accuracy that the Cox model can. Discussing the data, it must be

mentioned that enterprise births and deaths have been defined in accordance with the

British ONS definition that was used for the 2017 business demography report (Office for

National Statistics, 2019). A birth is identified as a business that existed in the year t but

was not present in the year t-1 or t-2. A death is identified as a business which was active

in year t but was not active in year t+1 or t+2. As such, a business is deemed to have

survived the year if it was active and/or born in the year t and still active in the year t+1.

Data for cooperatives have been gathered from the Co-Operatives UK open organisational

datasets (Co-operatives UK, 2019a) and data for traditional firms has been gathered from

the ONS business demography data (Office for National Statistics, 2019). Some

corrections have been made to the merged dataset as some cooperatives can are labelled

as businesses and as such appear in the ONS data. These comprised 90 cooperatives

and they have been removed from the traditional company data5. After cleaning the

5 Survival times for these cooperatives was checked and 90 of the individual businesses which had the same survival times were removed from the ONS data

Page 19: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

19

dataset, the number of DF’s in the dataset is 370 and the number of CF’s is 269,160.

Variable descriptions and coding can be seen in depth in Table 1.

Empirical model

An interesting note before beginning is that when applying the definitions of firm survival

rates to the cooperative data it was found, as demonstrated by Table 4, that the entire

sample of democratic firms survived their first year. This is quite interesting as the report of

Co-operatives UK (2019b, p.4) stipulates that 95.6% of the sample had survived their first

year of existence.

Table 4. Survival by firm

type

Survival Time (years)

CF DF

0 23,338 0 1 46,759 16 2 39,063 18 3 24,230 16 4 19,560 34 5 116,210 286

Total 269,160 370

Table 5. Cox porportional hazrds model on firm survival

Hazard ratio

Cooperative 0.312***

(0.034)

Observations 269530 Exponentiated coefficients; Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001

This could be a mistake on the part of Co-operatives UK in the sense that they may have

calculated the survival rates differently than in the ONS data. As the nuances of the data

have been discussed, it is time to move on to the model itself. From Table 5 it can be seen

that the hazard ratio is much lower on average for cooperatives compared to capitalist

firms (a 69% difference). The result is highly statistically significant (p<0.001). It seems

Page 20: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

20

then that the first hypothesis is proven by the Cox proportional hazards model:

Cooperatives do indeed have lower hazard rates than traditional capitalist firms. A point of

note here is that testing the proportional hazards assumption yielded mixed results. The

proportional hazards test was statistically significant, which suggests a violation of the it,

however when illustrating it graphically, another trend emerges. When comparing the

Kaplan-Meyer observed survival curves to the Cox predicted survival curves it can be seen

that the predicted survival curves are close to the actual survival curves, which would

mean that the proportional hazards assumption cannot be rejected.

Figure 1. Kaplan-Meyer curves compared to Cox predicted survival curves

Page 21: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

21

Figure 2. Log-log plot of survival probability

Figure 3. Cumulative hazard rates for both types of firms

Page 22: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

22

Figure 4. Smoothed hazard estimates for both types of firms

Figure 5. Kaplan-Meier survival estimates for capitalist firms and cooperatives

Page 23: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

23

The results are demonstrated by Figure 1. The graphical inaccuracies between the

observed and predicted survival probabilities for cooperatives may be affected by the small

sample size.6 The proportional hazards assumption seems to have not been violated when

graphing survival probability on a log-log plot as well. Figure 2 shows this, and as the lines

of survival probability for both firms seem to be roughly parallel, which suggests no

violation of the proportional hazards assumption. More information on firm survival can be

found looking at Figure 3, which illustrates the cumulative hazards of the two types of

companies over a five-year period. It can be seen that the cumulative hazards of CF’s after

five years of creation is around 0.77 and for DF’s it is 0.25. These numbers show the

probability of the business failing over the five-year period for each subject one or multiple

times (Cleves, et al. 2008, p.15). Seeing as it is unlikely for one business to fail multiple

times within a five-year span, it would be better to interpret these findings as a probability

for a capitalist firm to survive its first five years being at 0.23 and 0.75 for a cooperative.

This shows that democratically controlled firms have a much higher probability at surviving

the first five years than their traditional counterparts. To go into more depth concerning

hazard rates one must look at Figure 4. In it, the smoothed hazard estimates for every

year which can be seen with the hazards being higher at all age points for conventional

companies when compared to democratically owned ones. However, different trends in

hazards for both types of companies can be seen. For capitalist firms the hazard increases

until year three and begins to decrease after that with the hazard rate for the fifth year

becoming similar to that of year one. This is in sharp contrast to Evans (1987), who

proposes that the risk for firms to fail decreases with age. The data here shows that the

hazard rates do not increase or decrease monotonically for conventional firms but instead

6 At the time of writing of this paper there seems to be no way to go back in time and increase the co-op sample size for a more accurate analysis.

Page 24: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

24

form a sort of inverted U-shape. This has been described by scholars such as Bruderl and

Schussler (1990), who have found that the risk for a firm to fail increases during the first

few years of existence and then decreases. For cooperatives Figure 4 shows lower overall

hazard rates for cooperatives compared to traditional firms, with risk increasing from years

two to four and decreasing slightly during year five. Year one is excluded, since the entire

sample of cooperatives survived it. The hazard rates for DF’s are similar to the ones

produced by Ben-Ner (1988, p.19) except that in the hazard rates for cooperatives

decreasing after year three rather than after year four as is in the current data. It can be

seen that the current data on hazard rates are on a large part consistent with the existing

literature on company survival. The data also proves the first hypothesis, which suggests

that cooperatives have a lower hazard rate than traditional capitalist firms in the first five

years of their existence. Moving on to the second and third hypotheses. The Kaplan-Meier

survival curves for both company types are illustrated by Figure 5. From it, it can be seen

that 43% of traditional companies survived the initial five-year period since their creation,

whereas 77% of cooperatives did. This proves only the second hypothesis, with survival

rates for coops being between 75% and 97%, but it does not prove the third hypothesis,

with even the most pessimistic prediction of company survival (50%) being higher than the

actual survival rate of traditional companies by seven percent. This is not very surprising

as the hazard rates discussed previously indicated a major difference in risks for traditional

businesses when compared to cooperatives. In conclusion, it has been shown that

hypotheses one and two have been proven by the given data, with hazard rates being

considerably lower for cooperatives than traditional businesses as well as cooperative

survival after five years being 77% which is consistent with the current literature.

Hypothesis three, however, was rejected with projections of conventional company

Page 25: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

25

survival shown in the research literature being higher than the actual survival rates for UK

capitalist firms.

Discussion: Why do cooperatives survive at higher rates?

It has been shown that co-ops have lower hazard ratios and higher survival percentages

than traditional firms, this section seeks to explain why such differences exist as a 34%

difference between survival rates is rather high in the business world. If capitalist firms had

the same survival rate as co-ops, that would have resulted in around 91,500 more

businesses surviving in the UK over a five-year period if they were started in 2012.

The first explanation is increased productivity in cooperatives. The logic goes that since in

market economies profit is one of the deciding factors in business survival, firms whose

workers7 are more productive will accumulate more money, allowing them to survive by

not going bankrupt. A meta-analysis of 74 studies on labour managed firms8 and

participatory capitalist firms9 by Doucouliagos (1995) found that worker participation, profit

sharing and worker ownership contributed were positively correlated with productivity in

democratically owned companies in the majority of cases. For participatory capitalist firms,

correlations between productivity and the independent variables were smaller, sometimes

even negative and less statistically significant than for democratically owned firms. This

showed that DF’s outshined CF’s in terms of productivity which was correlated with

increased worker participation in a firm. It must be kept in note, that firms with high labour

union influence and capitalist firms with no participatory measures for their employees

were not included in this study. However, given that labour managed firms beat CF’s with

7 Workers in this section are used to define all employees of cooperatives, not just those for the category of “worker cooperative” 8 Defined as a company in which all of the workers are able to participate in managing the firm and have one vote per person (Doucouliagos, 1995, p.59) 9 Defined as a company which are hierarchical in structure but implement one or more participation schemes for its employees (Doucouliagos, 1995, p.59)

Page 26: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

26

participatory measures when it comes to productivity, it would not seem likely that CF’s

which do not allow workers to participate in its management would have increased

productivity. Secondly, it was shown by Doucouliagos (1995) that these correlations are

positive, but not very high, showing that the effect of worker participation one productivity

is positive, but does not tell the whole story when talking about productivity differences

between the firms. The positive correlations, however, can be explained theoretically. The

correlation between productivity and workplace democracy can be understood as having a

causal link also in the sense that the elimination of antagonisms between workers and

owners in the workplace creates a better place for labour and allows for a more productive

work environment. This is explained very well by Craig and Pencavel (1995, p. 125) who

show that in regular companies, owners can and do choose policies which enhance the

welfare of the owners/shareholders at the detriment of workers. The idea is further

analysed by Dahl (1985, p. 100, 105, 109) who argues that an owner of a company with

their high wages, pensions and benefits is unlikely to experience any negative effects on

their person from a bad economic situation on mismanagement of the business. Thus, it is

very probable that owners in capitalist firms are more likely to act irresponsibly,

endangering the workers they currently have employed, furthering the divide between

owner and employee. Employee owned companies, by their design, remove this conflict

and as such, worker cooperation and the collaboration between workers and management

becomes more positive and humane, leading to an increase in productivity. This is

demonstrated by Greenberg (1986, p. 41) who concludes that workers in a democratically

controlled firm are more likely to cooperate than those in a conventional business and to

help each other manifesting in more fluid work boundaries where one worker will help

another with a task to facilitate the collective growth of the workplace. This makes sense

as an individual would have more interest in furthering a collective in which the increase of

Page 27: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

27

profit goes directly to the worker rather than to a shareholder not directly involved in the

production process. These factors in turn create more incentive to work and therefore

increases productivity, allowing the business to thrive longer.

Worker management may not only be linked to productivity, but also to better management

of the firm during economically turbulent years, increasing the likelihood of the firm

surviving. An analysis of DF’s and CF’s in Uruguay has shown that when faced with

economic hardships, co-ops and capitalist firms behave differently in regard to economic

shocks (Burdin and Dean, 2009, p. 526). Whilst a crisis for both types of companies results

in a decrease in wages and employees, capitalist firms suffer more by having a much

higher level of layoffs due to their inabilities to establish credible commitments between

workers and owners. Cooperatives, by contrast, do not suffer as many layoffs due to their

unique control structure that can employ more egalitarian ways of dealing with crises. One

of these is demonstrated by Zirakzabeh (1990, p.118) who shows that during economic

crises, workers vote voluntarily to reduce their own wages in order to sustain their

companies’ profitability and long-term survival. This allows for the collective to continue

working productively with minimal layoffs during crisis situations and thus, keep the

company going. The same issue can be viewed from a psychological lens through the

social identity theory. Social identity theory is defined as a framework that analyses in-

group bias through the idea that individuals seek to increase their self-esteem via

memberships in various social groups (e.g. family, social or economic class, country)

(Tajfel and Turner, 1979). This can create conflicts between various social groups, if one is

perceived to be dangerous and/or adverse to another. In this, instance, the place of

conflict is the workplace and the two social identities at play are economic classes – the

workers of a company and its owners. In capitalist firms, these two identities are mostly

non-interchangeable. Only the owners may be considered workers and owners since they

Page 28: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

28

own the company and some can also do work for it, however the workers in the company

do no own it and as such are absent from categorising themselves as both owners and

workers. Of course, it is worth mentioning that not every person may choose to identify

themselves with one or both of these classes, though literature exists that confirms the

idea that class distinctions are present in workplace relationships (Marx, 1848;1867, Dahl,

1985). This distinction between worker and owner in a CF creates conflicts and animosity

between the two camps. Consider the reduction of wages or layoffs from the previous

discussion. In a social identity perspective, layoffs from a capitalist firm would create two

adverse effects: one in the relationship between classes and one between the worker

class itself. For the former an animosity might arise between worker and owner due to the

fact that workers have no say in who gets laid off and cannot vote for other measures of

tackling crises and/or reducing wages. Therefore, the owner class is perceived to be

dangerous by employees, who see themselves and their group as being negatively

affected. For inter-worker relations layoffs and wage reductions have a similar effect. Since

during a crisis the scarcity of resources is exacerbated, and with layoffs and reductions of

wages being independent of worker control, alienation between the workers themselves

occurs. In essence, a Hobbesian war of all against all becomes the norm between

employees as each seeks to survive and is more likely to do damage to the other in order

to get ahead due to limited workspaces and wage benefits. By contrast cooperatives

harmonise the identities of worker and owner by making each member contribute both

labour and capital into the enterprise. Thus, animosities are minimised during crisis years.

Democratic ownership means that members would be much less likely to support layoffs

as they themselves would be in danger, instead preferring other methods, that ensure

minimal loss of employment, such as the reduction of wages to all (Zirakzabeh, 1990,

p.118).

Page 29: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

29

Limitations

It does seem that the data can be explained theoretically, though the empirical model itself

could be improved for the future. Firstly, the absence of control variables such as profit

and number of employees/members could not be added into the model because they were

not present in the ONS business demography data. Because of this, there may be

inaccuracies in hazard rate calculation of both companies. Secondly, the model showed

mixed results about the proportional hazards assumption, which is a core concept of the

Cox model. On the one hand, the mathematical test showed that the assumption is

violated, however, when assessed graphically, it was shown that there seems to be no

violation of the assumption. This can make the results of the model suspect, but more data

on this is required to see if it is truly the case and the results are consistent with the

academic literature on the subject.

Further research

As it stands, the results of the model show a very significand difference between co-op

and CF survival and hazard rates and as such, it is imperative, for both the economy and

science to conduct more studies on this topic as higher survival rates and productivity for a

company should be in every societies’ best interest as it could guarantee more stable

employment and generally better working conditions for employees. The area of co-op

research is still under-developed in economics and more research on this topic would

allow for a better understanding of DF’s and through that, reforms to our economic

structure may take place.

Page 30: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

30

IV. Cooperatives in depth

It has been mentioned that cooperatives do not follow one uniform structure (save for the

fact that they are democratically managed and/or owned) or purpose. In this section the

study looks at the implications of co-operative survival based on various organisational

types. The organisation co-op dataset lists nine categories of ownership classification in its

dataset which are defined as follows by the Co-operatives UK (2019b) open data guide:

Co-operatives – members of cooperatives who are in themselves cooperatives (Co-

operatives UK).

Community of Interest – Individuals or organisations which share a common interest or

characteristic that defines their membership (Energy coops, community shops, supporters

trusts).

Consumers – Cooperatives in which members are individuals who purchase goods or

services from the co-operative itself (Consumer and retail societies, social clubs, sports

clubs)

Employee Trust – Members are employees with at least 75% stake in ownership via a trust

or similar legal entity (Most often but not always employee buyout schemes).

Enterprises – Members are legal entities, this excludes self-employed persons, that use

the cooperative to collectively conduct their activities (Agricultural co-ops).

Multi-stakeholder – Membership is made up from multiple member categories, including

individuals and/or businesses who join the cooperative to work towards a common aim

(School trusts, leisure trusts, housing associations).

Page 31: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

31

Self-Employed – Members are individuals who use the cooperative to collectively support

or conduct their business activities (Freelance cooperatives, collective business services).

Tenants – Members are individuals who rent directly or have shared ownership in a

property or multiple properties (Tenant-run housing cooperatives, residents’ associations).

Workers – Members are individuals who work for and share ownership of the cooperative

(Retail worker cooperatives).

Lack of literature on survival of different cooperative types

Regrettably, there exists very little literature that compares survival rates between different

cooperative ownership classifications. The only types that have been compared are worker

and consumer cooperatives. Sommer et al. (1984) compare the two ownership types.

However, their concern is not associated with survival rates, rather they analyse the

reasons of why persons choose to join either type of co-op. For consumer cooperatives

the main reason seems to be price savings, whereas for worker co-ops the main reason

seems to be the wish for more control over the workplace (Sommer et al., 1984, p. 147).

From this data it is impossible to form hypotheses about the survival length of worker and

consumer cooperatives as well as other types of DF’s and as such this section is focused

more on exploratory analysis rather than the confirmatory analysis seen in previous

sections. As such, no hypotheses are presented.

Methodology and data

To keep hazard ratio data consistent with the previous section of survival analysis, Cox

proportional hazards models are again used to gauge the survival rates of the different

enterprises. The dataset is a modified version of the Co-operatives UK organisations

dataset (Co-operatives UK, 2019a). It is also important to mention that the Co-operatives

Page 32: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

32

dataset is limited in the sense that deaths of enterprises had only begun to be recorded

from the year 2011. To adjust for this four distinct samples of co-ops which were created in

years 2011, 2012, 2013 and 2014 will be analysed. This is done, as the dataset only

extends to the year 2019 and to keep analysis consistent, hazard ratios and survival rates

of five years are used to analyse the enterprises. Moving on it is also important to mention

that two of the categories of ownership have been excluded: Co-operatives and Employee

Trust. The former for the fact that it includes umbrella co-operatives that contain others

and as such are not relevant to individual level enterprise analysis. The latter, however,

are excluded due to only containing a sample size of 1, making the category irrelevant to

the analysis. Furthermore, it must be noted that the sample sizes for each of the types of

DF’s is relatively small as the number of co-ops created during each year ranges from 336

to 259. Dividing this small sample into even smaller categories poses the risk of making

the analysis spurious due to small sizes for each of the categories. Table 1 shows the

variables that have been used in this sections’ analysis. Consumer co-ops have been

selected as a reference category in the model since they are a familiar category, that has

been examined in research literature and is easier to interpret.

Empirical model

Table 6 shows the model specifics. It can be seen that in the 2011 cohort there is no

significant relationship between consumer co-op survival rates when compared to different

types, except for worker co-ops which have hazard ratios that are around 4 times higher

than those for consumer firms. This means that a worker co-op started in the year 2011 is

4 times more likely to fail than a consumer co-op on average. The value is highly

statistically significant (p<0.001). When discussing the 2012 cohort the same pattern

emerges with worker co-ops having hazard rations that are around 5 times higher than

those for the reference category on average. The value remains highly statistically

Page 33: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

33

significant. There is also now a significant difference between the reference category and

tenant co-ops. The latter is around 3 times more likely to fail than the former on average.

Table 6. Cox proportional hazards model on different co-op survival

2011 2012 2013 2014

Community of 0.779 1.714 1.237 5.067*

Interest (0.294) (0.700) (0.454) (3.767)

Enterprise 1.155 2.241 1.026 5.294

(0.735) (1.517) (0.675) (5.294)

Multi- 1.114 0.959 0.913 3.159

Stakeholder (0.516) (0.466) (0.399) (2.533)

Self- 1.527 2.526 0.726 9.878**

Employed (0.972) (1.710) (0.562) (8.267)

Tenant 0.730 3.126* 1.069 7.941*

(0.552) (1.689) (0.703) (7.941)

Worker 3.908*** 4.812*** 1.499 8.582**

(1.339) (1.932) (0.711) (6.710)

N 319 311 336 259 Exponentiated coefficients; Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001

The value is statistically significant (p<0.05). Moving on to the 2013 cohort, it seems that

there is no significant relationship in hazard ratios between consumer and other types of

co-ops. Finally, for the 2014 sample it can be seen that community of interest, self-

employed, tenant and worker co-ops all have higher hazard ratios than consumer firms

(approx. 5, 10, 8 and 8.5 times more likely to fail on average respectively). All values are

statistically significant. After further testing, it seems that all of the models do not seem to

have violated the proportional hazards assumption. Judging from Table 6, it seems that

the only pattern that seems to form is one where worker co-ops are more likely than

Page 34: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

34

consumer co-ops to fail. For this, figures for hazard rates and survival graphs are

provided10.

10 The 2013 cohort is excluded due to non-statistically significant results

Page 35: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

35

Figure 6. Hazard rates and Kaplan-Meyer survival graph for the 2011 cohort

Page 36: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

36

Figure 7. Hazard rates and Kaplan-Meyer survival graph for the 2012 cohort

Page 37: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

37

Figure 8. Hazard rates and Kaplan-Meyer survival graph for the 2014 cohort

Page 38: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

38

From Figures 6, 7 and 8 it can be seen how each type of cooperative survives and their

hazard rates during each of the years. Consumer firms survive at much higher rates than

worker enterprises. After 5 years in existence, the 2011, 2012 and 2014 cohorts of

consumer DF’s had survival rates of 96%, 91% and 96% respectively. Worker enterprises,

by contrast had survival rates of 65%, 56% and 70% for the same years. As for hazard

rates, it seems that for worker enterprises it increases significantly in the initial 3-4 years of

creation and then goes down. Consumer enterprises, by contrast do not have a steep

increase in hazard rates during the initial five years of creation, however the rate does

increase beyond the five years of creation. The exception being the year 2014, where

hazard rates for consumer cooperatives were only present during the fourth and fifth year

of their life, which suggests that in the early stages, consumer co-ops have almost no

chances of failure. Examining the two co-op types further, it is important to note that the

co-operatives tend to exist in different sectors of the economy.

Table 7. Co-op types by sector (created in years

2011-2014) Sector Consumer firm Worker firm

Agriculture 1 5

Arts and culture 1 7

Digital, Media and communication 3 16

Education 0 12

Energy and Environment 0 2

Finance 9 2

Food service, Accommodation and Pubs 0 7

Health and Social Care 0 9

Housing 0 4

Manufacturing 0 13

Membership associations, Social Clubs and Trade Unions 187 6

Professional and Legal services 0 20

Retail 20 18

Sports and recreation 7 1

Transport 1 1

Other 16 12

Total 245 135

Page 39: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

39

Table 7 illustrates this and from the data it can be seen that consumer firms operate

largely as membership associations, social clubs and trade unions, whilst worker firms are

more dispersed in different sectors with the most populous ones being, professional and

legal services, retail, communication and manufacturing. This indicates that there may be

an effect on how survival rates may be affected by sector; however, as this is not part of

the empirical model, it will be addressed in the discussion section.

Discussion: Are industrial sectors responsible for different co-op survival rates?

As there is hardly any literature on different cooperative types, there is not much to go into

in terms of empirical or theoretical results. Examining the sectors in which the two types of

co-ops operate might offer more depth. Table 7 contains the sectors that the 2011-2014

cohorts operated in. What can be seen is that most consumer firms operate as

membership associations, social clubs or trade unions. Worker firms, by contrast, operate

in many different sectors. What is interesting is that consumer firms operate in sectors

which are not as subject to market pressures than worker firms. It seems that consumer

co-ops focus more on connecting persons of similar interests, be it from membership

associations, social clubs or trade unions. Thus, the sectors would not be ones that

operate on a profit-oriented basis, which would not subject them to the randomness of the

market. Worker co-ops, however, operate in sectors where market pressures would be

more severe on a business (i.e. retail, manufacturing, legal services). This shows that

sector may factor into survival rates. As that is a huge topic on its own, it is not feasible to

discuss it here in detail. If market pressures force businesses survive less and consumer

co-ops are not very much affected by it, would it be reasonable to assume that

comparisons between co-ops and capitalist firms would rest more on sector than

ownership? To this the answer is no, as five-year survival rates for worker co-ops, which

Page 40: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

40

operate under the same market pressures as regular capitalist firms is still higher (64%11

compared to 43%). This is somewhat offset by high confidence intervals for worker co-ops;

however, the general trend seems to indicate that around a 21% difference between the

two types of firms is observed, which is quite significant in the business world and would

result in around 56 thousand more traditional businesses surviving the five year period in

the United Kingdom if they had the same survival rates as the worker co-ops.

Limitations

As this analysis is exploratory, it was not possible to suggest very complex models that

accounted for different ways co-ops could be affected instead of co-op type. There was

also a small sample size for all cohorts and that has affected confidence intervals quite

drastically, which stifles the accuracy of the model and analysis.

Further research

The preliminary research has proven to be fruitful and as such more research on this topic

is highly encouraged. In the future, adding industry section and other control variables to

achieve more accurate results is recommended. Sample sizes may remain small, so it is

important to note as it may provide a less accurate empirical analysis; however, for the

time being, this seems to be the only way to conduct research into different co-operative

types.

V. Conclusions

This paper has primarily focused on three topics related to co-operatives: their creation,

their comparison to capitalist firms and comparisons between different co-op types.

11 Average for the worker co-op survival rates of the 2011, 2012 and 2014 cohorts

Page 41: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

41

The first section tried to view co-op creation as influenced by two factors: unemployment

and disaffection with the current capitalist system. The empirical model found support for

the ideas that both increases in disaffection and unemployment caused a higher growth of

cooperatives. A further discussion was presented that shower that disaffection with

capitalism is caused by events that show that the idea of capitalism being the only viable

system in the world today is challenged (such as the 2008-9 financial crash) and the

inherently exploitative relationship that is created by industrial relations under capitalism,

which can be viewed from either a Marxian or Democratic theory perspective.

Unemployment itself may be a part of the dominant economic system and leads to an

increase of co-operative numbers; however, these two factors seem to be only weakly

collinear.

The second section showed that the 2012 cohort of created businesses and co-ops had

significantly different hazard ratios and survival rates. It was found that on average, co-ops

have a hazard ratio that is 69% lower than that for the traditional business. In terms of

survival, it is seen that 43% of traditional companies survive the 5-year period, whereas

77% of co-ops do. This is a massive difference between the two cohorts and shows that

the co-op model does indeed exist as a more stable alternative to capitalist firms in the

market economy. Reasons for why are bountiful, but the two that have been discussed

were better productivity that is generated by increased co-operation that co-ops offer and

better responses to crises, which prioritise keeping as much of the workforce of the

business employed as opposed to capitalist firms, which can suffer massive layoffs during

crises, affecting workers economically and psychologically.

The third section contributed to the exploratory research around cooperatives and tried to

see how hazard ratios and survival rates differ for different types of co-ops. It was found,

that the only generalisable pattern was between consumer and worker firms. Consumer

Page 42: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

42

co-ops performed better survival-wise with their hazard ratios indicating that they are on

average 6 times better at surviving than worker enterprises as well as having a five-year

survival rate of 94% as opposed to worker companies with a 64% five-year survival. The

difference here can be explained by sector, as worker co-ops tend to operate in sectors

where survival is more dominated by gaining profit, whereas consumer co-ops operate

more in sectors that are concerned with organising persons, which means profit may not

be the deciding factor in survival.

All of these topics are promising paths for research into the economy, however, they are

woefully under-research and with this paper it is hoped that a significant contribution has

been made to co-op research as well as that it will inspire more research into the topic.

Page 43: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

43

VI. Bibliography

Anonymous, Author, 2020, "Replication Data for: "An empirical analysis of cooperative

creation, survival compared to capitalist firms and survival between different co-op types in

the United Kingdom"", https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/I35KU4, Harvard Dataverse, V1,

UNF:6:kLQtQtXkAjrnc16oUI/HGA== [fileUNF]

Audretsch, D.B. 1991. New-Firm Survival and the Technological Regime. The Review of

Economics and Statistics. 73(3), p.441.

Barkley Rosser Jr, J. and Rosser, M.V. 2004. Comparative Economics in a Transforming

World Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Ben-Ner, A. 1988. Comparative empirical observations on worker-owned and capitalist

firms. International Journal of Industrial Organization. 6(1), pp.7–31.

Bockman, J. 2011. Markets in the Name of Socialism: The Left-Wing Origins of

Neoliberalism. Redwood City: Stanford University Press

Bruderl, J. and Schussler, R. 1990. Organizational Mortality: The Liabilities of Newness

and Adolescence. Administrative Science Quarterly. 35(3), pp.530–547.

Burdin, G. and Dean, A. 2009. New evidence on wages and employment in worker

cooperatives compared with capitalist firms. Journal of Comparative Economics. 37(4), pp.

517-533

Cheney, G., Cruz, I., Peredo, A.M., Nazareno, E. 2014. Worker cooperatives as an

organizational alternative: Challenges, achievements and promise in business governance

and ownership. Organization. 21(5), pp. 591–603

Page 44: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

44

Clark, D. 2019. Unemployment rate of the United Kingdom 2000-2019. [Online]. [Accessed

March 25, 2020]. Available from:

https://www.statista.com/statistics/279898/unemployment-rate-in-the-united-kingdom-uk/

Cleves, M., Gould, W.W., Gutierrez, R.G., Marchenko, Y.V. 2008 An Introduction to

Survival Analysis Using Stata. 2nd edition. College Station: Stata Press

Co-operatives UK. 2019a. Co-operative open data. [Online]. [Accessed 18 November,

2019]. Available from: https://www.uk.coop/open-data

Co-operatives UK. 2019b. Open Data Guide. [Online]. [Accessed 18 November, 2019].

Available from:

https://www.uk.coop/sites/default/files/uploads/attachments/open_data_guide_10.pdf

Cox, D.R. 1972. Regression Models and Life-Tables. Journal of the Royal Statistical

Society. Series B (Methodological). 34(2), pp.187–220.

Craig, B. and Pencavel, J. 1995. Participation and Productivity: A Comparison of Worker

Cooperatives and Conventional Firms in the Plywood Industry. Brookings Papers on

Economic Activity. Microeconomics. 1995(0), pp. 121-174

Dahl. R.A. 1985. A Preface to Economic Democracy. Berkley: University of California

Press

Disney, R., Haskel, J. and Heden, Y. 2003. Entry, Exit and Establishment Survival in UK

Manufacturing. Journal of Industrial Economics. 51(1), pp.91–112.

Doucouliagos, C. 1995. Worker Participation and Productivity in Labor-Managed and

Participatory Capitalist Firms: A Meta-Analysis. Industrial and Labor Relations Review.

49(1), pp.58–77.

Page 45: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

45

Eigner, P. and Umlauft, T.S. 2015. The Great Depression(s) of 1929-1933 and 2007-

2009? Parallels, Differences and Policy Lessons. SSRN Electronic Journal

Evans, D.S. 1987. The Relationship Between Firm Growth, Size, and Age: Estimates for

100 Manufacturing Industries. The Journal of Industrial Economics. 35(4), pp.567–581.

Fisher, M. 2009. Capitalist Realism: Is There No Alternative?. Winchester: Zero Books

Fukuyama, F. 1989. The End of History? The National Interest. (16), pp.3–18

Greenberg, E.S. 1986. Workplace democracy: the political effects of participation. New

York: Cornell University Press

International Co-operative Alliance. [no date]. Cooperative identity, values & principles.

[Online]. [Accessed November 20, 2019]. Available from:

https://www.ica.coop/en/cooperatives/cooperative-identity

Kutner, M., Nachtsheim, C., Neter, J. 2004. Applied Linear Regression Models. 4th ed.

New York: McGraw-Hill

Lenin, V. I. 1917. The State and Revolution. [Online]. [Accessed 20 November 2019].

Available from: https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1917/staterev/

Marx, K and Engels, F. 1848. The Communist Manifesto [Online]. Moscow: Progress

Publishers. [Accessed 20 November]. Available from:

https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/download/pdf/Manifesto.pdf

Marx, K. 1867. Capital, Volume I [Online]. Moscow: Progress Publishers. [Accessed 30

September]. Available from: https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/

Page 46: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

46

Monteiro, N.P. and Stewart, G. 2015. Scale, Scope and Survival: A Comparison of

Cooperative and Capitalist Modes of Production. Review of Industrial Organization. 47(1),

pp.91–118.

Muller, B. 2019. What is Austerity and How Has It Affected British Society?. The New York

Times. [Online]. 24 February. [Accessed 20 November 2019]. Available from:

https://www.nytimes.com/2019/02/24/world/europe/britain-austerity-may-budget.html

Mustafa, A. 2011. London faces a summer of strike chaos over austerity. Gulf News.

[Online]. 29 June, [Accessed 20 March 2020]. Available from:

https://gulfnews.com/business/analysis/london-faces-a-summer-of-strike-chaos-over-

austerity-1.829578

Office for National Statistics. 2018. The 2008 recession 10 years on. [Online]. [Accessed

20 March 2020]. Available from:

https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/grossdomesticproductgdp/articles/the2008recession10ye

arson/2018-04-30

Office for National Statistics. 2019. Business Demography – 2017. [Online]. [Accessed

November 18, 2019]. Available from:

https://www.ons.gov.uk/businessindustryandtrade/business/activitysizeandlocation/dataset

s/businessdemographyreferencetable

Perotin, V. 2004. Early cooperative survival: the liability of adolescence. Advances in the

Economic Analysis of Participatory & Labor-Managed Firms. 8, pp.67–86.

Sheather, S. 2009. A modern approach to regression with R. New York: Springer

Sommer, R., Schlanger, D., Hackman, R. and Smith, S. 1984. Consumer Cooperatives

and Worker Collectives: A Comparison. Sociological Perspectives. 27(2), pp.139–157

Page 47: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

47

Stensrud, M.J. and Hernán, M.A. 2020. Why Test for Proportional Hazards? JAMA.

Tajfel, H. and Turner, J. 1979. An Integrative Theory of Intergroup Conflict. In: Austin, W.

G. and Worchel, S. eds. The social psychology of intergroup relations. Monterey:

Brooks/Cole

Zirakzabeh, C.E. 1990. Theorizing about Workplace Democracy Robert Dahl and the

Cooperatives of Mondragón. Journal of Theoretical Politics. 2(1), pp.109–126.

Page 48: An empirical analysis of cooperative creation, survival

48

VII. Appendix

Table 1. Variables used during the analysis and their descriptions

Section Variable Label Type Description

III coopscreated Number of Co-ops created Dependent The number of co-operatives created during a given year

III unemployment Unemployment increase Independent Unemployment increase during a given year

III aftercrisis Disaffection with capitalism

Independent

Years before, during or after the 2008-2009 economic crisis. Higher value denotes higher disaffection with the current economic system

III year Year Contextual Denotes the given year for the data

IV diedonyear Died on year Dependent Denotes the year of the lifespan during which the enterprise died

IV regstat Registration status Dependent Denotes whether the enterprise is alive (1) or dead (0)

IV organisation Cooperative Independent

Denotes the type of organisation an enterprise is. 0 for "Capitalist firm", 1 for "Cooperative"

V diedonyear Died on year Dependent Denotes the year of the lifespan during which the enterprise died

V regstat Registration status Dependent Denotes whether the enterprise is alive (1) or dead (0)

V ownership Ownership Classification Independent Denotes the ownership classification of a cooperative

V yrcreated Year created Contextual Denotes which year the enterprise was created on

VIII. Notes

Data and the do files for the replication can be found via this direct link:

https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataset.xhtml?persistentId=doi:10.7910/DVN/I35KU4