30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - cepalarchivo.cepal.org/.../ss2015/chilesince1999_040715.docx ·...

50
04/07/15(text9269w;total=11,462w) CHILE SINCE 1999: FROM COUNTER-CYCLICAL TO PRO-CYCLICAL MACROECONOMICS * Ricardo Ffrench- Davis ** ** Abstract: In the 15 years from 1999 to 2013, Chilean GDP growth averaged 3.9%. Although this was above the 3.2% Latin American average, it represented a sharp drop from the country's sustained 7% annual growth recorded in 1990- 98, the first nine years after its return to democracy. This article seeks to explain this significant outcome reversal. Given the absence of deep backwards steps in the microeconomic approach, we focus on macroeconomic policies. Two cycles are distinguished: a) 1999-2007, between contagion from the Asian crisis and a peak in economic activity in 2007 before the contagion from the global crisis, and b) 2008-2013, between the start of recession in 2008 and a GDP peak in 2013, just before a significant new deceleration. We show that the adoption of inflation targeting combined with full opening of the capital account and exchange-rate liberalisation successfully kept inflation low and avoided balance of payments crises, but implied that the economy was usually operating below potential output, while the exchange rate and current account became extremely unstable. Pro-cyclical financial markets and the price of copper again became active channels of transmission of external instability to domestic macroeconomic markets. On the other hand, fiscal policy moved from being rather neutral to effectively counter- cyclical in 2009-10, but it became pro-cyclical in 2011-13. Macroeconomic pro-cyclicality discouraged capital formation and productivity. Real macroeconomic instability was a determinant variable underlying the worsened growth outcome. The paper * To be published in Comparative Economic Studies, September 2015, Palgrave Journals; online since April 2. I appreciate the research support of Nicolás Fernández and Simón Ballesteros and the highly useful comments of the editor Paul Wachtel and a referee. **** Professor of Economics, University of Chile; PH.D. University of Chicago. 1

Upload: others

Post on 10-Aug-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

04/07/15(text9269w;total=11,462w)

CHILE SINCE 1999: FROM COUNTER-CYCLICAL TO PRO-CYCLICAL MACROECONOMICS*

Ricardo Ffrench-Davis****

Abstract: In the 15 years from 1999 to 2013, Chilean GDP growth averaged 3.9%. Although this was above the 3.2% Latin American average, it represented a sharp drop from the country's sustained 7% annual growth recorded in 1990-98, the first nine years after its return to democracy.

This article seeks to explain this significant outcome reversal. Given the absence of deep backwards steps in the microeconomic approach, we focus on macroeconomic policies. Two cycles are distinguished: a) 1999-2007, between contagion from the Asian crisis and a peak in economic activity in 2007 before the contagion from the global crisis, and b) 2008-2013, between the start of recession in 2008 and a GDP peak in 2013, just before a significant new deceleration.

We show that the adoption of inflation targeting combined with full opening of the capital account and exchange-rate liberalisation successfully kept inflation low and avoided balance of payments crises, but implied that the economy was usually operating below potential output, while the exchange rate and current account became extremely unstable. Pro-cyclical financial markets and the price of copper again became active channels of transmission of external instability to domestic macroeconomic markets. On the other hand, fiscal policy moved from being rather neutral to effectively counter-cyclical in 2009-10, but it became pro-cyclical in 2011-13. Macroeconomic pro-cyclicality discouraged capital formation and productivity.

Real macroeconomic instability was a determinant variable underlying the worsened growth outcome. The paper concludes with some policy proposals for speeding development convergence.

JEL E63, O11,O23,N16,F31,F62macroeconomic policies, cycles, real stability, development, Chile

INTRODUCTION

During the late 1990s, macroeconomic policies in Chile underwent a deep

change with respect to the approach adopted immediately after the return to

democracy in 1990.1 In the early 1990s, the new authorities implemented a

quite comprehensive counter-cyclical macroeconomic approach that included

systematic prudential regulation of capital inflows, actively managed exchange-

rate flexibility and a monetary policy concerned with not only inflation but also

* To be published in Comparative Economic Studies, September 2015, Palgrave Journals; online since April 2. I appreciate the research support of Nicolás Fernández and Simón Ballesteros and the highly useful comments of the editor Paul Wachtel and a referee. **** Professor of Economics, University of Chile; PH.D. University of Chicago.1 Economic reforms, policies and outcomes in Chile since the military coup of 1973 are covered in Ffrench-Davis (2010c); an update in Spanish is in Ffrench-Davis (2014).

1

Page 2: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

sustained growth, implying balances in the external and fiscal sectors and of

employment. This approach was highly successful, delivering a 7.1% average

GDP growth in 1990-98, with a sharp reduction in poverty, higher employment

and some improvement in income distribution.

That outcome was in marked contrast to the 2.9% average GDP growth

and rise in poverty and inequality seen during the previous 16 years under the

Pinochet dictatorship.2 A key feature of the neo-liberal experiment of those

years was high stability of consumer prices (CPI). However, during most of the

period, this was accompanied by great real economic disequilibria, severe

unemployment, external imbalances and unstable aggregate demand. In this

context, depressed capital formation was the main variable determining the

meagre 2.9% GDP growth achieved in 1974-89.3

The successful record of the 1990-98 period was broken by contagion

from the Asian crisis. In the fifteen years from 1999 to 2013, average growth

declined from the previous 7.1% to 3.9%. Although above the 3.2% average for

Latin America,4 this implied a sharp drop with respect to Chile's track record in

the 1990s.

In this chapter, I seek to explain this significant reversal. Given that there

were not important backwards steps as regards microeconomic policies, it

focuses on macroeconomic policies stressing the quite significant changes

between the two periods. We show that the adoption of inflation targeting

combined with full opening of the capital account and full liberalisation of the

exchange rate was successful in keeping inflation low and avoiding balance of

payments crises, but implied that the real economy --the production and use of

GDP-- usually operated below potential output and the exchange rate became

2 The economy experienced two deep recessions (in 1975 and 1982) and overheating in 1989, with GDP growth fluctuating between plus 10% and minus 17%, with the 2.9% cumulative average for the 16 years (Ffrench-Davis, 2010c, Chapter I).3 Between 1973 and 1989, the development gap with respect to the G-7 increased. Per capita income (PPP) in Chile fell from 29% of that of the G-7 in 1973 to 25% in 1989; in other words, development divergence prevailed.4 Interestingly, Latin America's GDP growth was similar in 1990-98 and in 1999-2013. In the first period, Chile far outpaced the region while, in the latter, it tended to converge with the region's poor performance.

2

Page 3: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

extremely unstable, both of which depressed the sources of economic growth.5

The causes of the significant change in policy approach are explored.

Four macroeconomic policies are analysed: the monetary, exchange-rate

and capital-account policies of the Central Bank and the fiscal policy of the

Finance Ministry, as well as the degree of coordination between both

institutions. After a brief description of the macroeconomic framework (Section

1), two cycles are distinguished in the evolution of policies and outcomes: i)

1999-2007, from the peak of economic activity before contagion from the Asian

crisis through the five-year recession that followed and the subsequent

recovery, led by rising commodity prices, up to a peak in 2007 before the start

of contagion from the global crisis (Section 2); and ii) 2008-13, from contagion

by the global crisis through the 2010-13 recovery process (Section 3). Section 4

concludes with some policy lessons for speeding development convergence.

1. The macroeconomic frameworkWhen a democratically-elected government came to power in March 1990,

there was a new “independent” Central Bank, established in December 1989 by

General Pinochet, a week before the presidential election that was evidently

going to be won by the opposition to the dictatorship. Since then, the Bank has

been headed by a board with five members --one of whom is replaced each two

years-- nominated by the President with the approval of the Senate. In the initial

board, “negotiated” with the opposition, there were two representatives of the

dictatorship, two of the democratic opposition and one “independent”. The Bank

is responsible for the stability of the currency and the normal working of

domestic and foreign payments. While the first objective has been understood

as stability of the CPI, interpretation of the other two objectives has varied.

Monetary policy is implemented mostly through the monetary policy interest rate

which applies to Central Bank operations with commercial banks.

Until 1996, the Central Bank cooperated closely with the Finance Ministry

and together they implemented a set of counter-cyclical or prudential

5 There is a series of outstanding works by Latin Americans on an approach concerned with the real economy, beyond the CPI. I cite three of them: ECLAC (2010) on economics and inequality; Ocampo (2011) on macro/micro links and Frenkel and Rapetti (2011) on exchange rate policy. An excellent related book is Ocampo and Ros (2011). I summarise my views on macroeconomics for development in Ffrench-Davis (2010b).

3

Page 4: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

macroeconomic policies. Subsequently, however, the Bank stressed its

“independence”.

In 1990, in parallel to the return to democracy in Chile, capital inflows into

Latin America increased sharply. The Chilean authorities reacted with counter-

cyclical measures consistent with their objective of developing exports with

value-added and maintaining equilibrium of the real economy with a non-outlier

real exchange rate and a level of aggregate demand consistent with potential

GDP. Counter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

Central Bank imposed an un-remunerated reserve requirement (URR, encaje in

Spanish) on all capital inflows (except FDI capital), that fluctuated between 20%

and 30% of the incoming amount and had to be held at the Bank for 90-360

days. The intensity of the regulation (rate and time retained) was related to the

strength of the supply of inflows and the gap between aggregate demand and

potential GDP (Ffrench-Davis, 2014, Chapter VIII; Magud and Reinhart, 2007).

Given the Chilean economy's apparent immunity to the Mexican (Tequila) crisis

in 1995 and an international fashion in favour of open capital accounts, the URR

was gradually weakened and then suspended in 1999.

Since 1986, the banking sector has been strictly regulated and

supervised. This followed the severe banking crisis of 1982, associated with an

unregulated privatisation and liberalisation of the domestic financial sector in

1975. Notwithstanding strong pressures for relaxation of regulation in around

1990, after several Latin American countries adopted the Washington

Consensus, the Chilean authorities maintained a rather prudential stance.

The exchange rate was subject to a crawling-peg regime (Williamson,

2000; Edwards and Rigobón, 2009), with a band managed by the Central Bank

and was, in general, linked to the evolution of both domestic and trade partners'

inflation and the current account.

The fiscal budget showed an average surplus of 2% of GDP in 1990-98.

Increased social expenditure and public investment was financed with a tax

reform launched in the first months after the return to democracy. The private

pension administrators (AFPs) created in 1981--an increasingly important

institutional agent--, were gradually authorised by the Central Bank to invest

part of their assets abroad, with the percentage of total portfolio rising from 6%

to 12% by 1997. In practice, however, they invested less than 1% abroad,

4

Page 5: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

principally because they considered the domestic market more profitable, with

expectations of exchange rate appreciation as a determinant variable.

Table 1 summarises several macroeconomic indicators. Figures are

presented for the successful 1990-98 period; the cycle that started in 1999 and

ended in 2007 before contagion from the global crisis; and the cycle that started

in 2008 and ended in 2013. Within these two cycles, the figures for the

recessive 1999-2003 and 2009 sub-periods are shown.

Table 1

2. In between the Asian and global crises

a) A recessive macro environment dominated by a pro-cyclical capital account: 1999-2003

In the late 1990s, the Central Bank gradually weakened the successful counter-

cyclical policies it had adopted at the start of the decade. In September 1999,

amidst contagion from the Asian crisis, it renounced to the managed flexibility of

the exchange rate (ER) and adopted a fully free floating rate.6 During the

previous couple of years, the exchange rate had appreciated significantly,

contributing to anchor inflation. Now, however, given the negative external

shocks, there was an evident need for a large devaluation which, announced as

a permanent commitment of the Bank to a fully flexible rate, was left to the

market. By that time, there was already an important relevant recessive gap

(the output gap between potential GDP and actual GDP, or recessive gap, RG)

which deterred the pass-through effect of the devaluation that took place. At

the same time, counter-inflation was taking predominance over other

macroeconomic targets, with a gradual move towards formal inflation targeting.

The adoption of this approach, now in agreement with the Finance Ministry,7

was announced in 1999, defining a 2-4% annual target as from 2001, with the

aim of permanent convergence to a 3% rate within a 12-24 month period

(Massad, 1999; Central Bank, 2007).

6 The managed flexibility implemented in 1990-95 gradually lost consistency in 1996-97, allowing an appreciation led by pro-cyclical capital inflows (Ffrench-Davis, 2010c, Chapters VIII and IX). On the effectiveness of managed flexibility see Edwards and Rigobón (2009).7After close coordination in 1990-95 in implementing a set of counter-cyclical policies, several expressions of lack of coordination emerged in 1996-98, particularly with respect to exchange-rate policy, with the government criticising its pro-cyclical bias. However, by 1999, the Finance Minister appeared to have accepted the formal adoption of “inflation targeting”. See http://www.bcentral.cl/politicas/sesiones-consejo/pdf/Sesion794E.pdf.

5

Page 6: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

The 12-24 month period was intended to take account of the lags in the

effects of monetary policy and to allow inflation to gradually accommodate to

deviations from the target, thus avoiding the costs to economic activity in cases

of fast convergence with the target (Corbo, 2004; de Gregorio, 2006). Finally,

among other monetary reforms, the policy interest rate used by the Bank was

changed from a real rate (linked to the CPI) to a nominal one.

The Bank declared that, with a freely floating exchange rate,8 it had

gained monetary policy independence, while ER fluctuations eased the

economy's adjustment to shocks and avoided misalignments of the rate. The

first was partly true; the latter was quite wrong as events later showed. One

determinant factor of misalignments was the full opening --for both foreign

inflows and residents' outflows-- of the capital account in 2001.9 The increasing

relaxation of the regulation of AFP outflows was of particular importance. In the

midst of contagion from the Asian crisis, --which naturally implied great scarcity

of foreign currency-- the ceiling on AFPs' investments abroad was raised from

12% to 16% of their total portfolio in January 1999 (Figure 1) when the domestic

economy was already suffering the recessive effects associated with the

binding external restriction (BER) generated by the contagion. Indeed, in 1998-

99, there was a huge outflow of funds by the AFPs, as shown in Figure 1, in a

highly pro-cyclical behaviour, implicitly encouraged by the policy design.

Figure 1

In those days the belief that opening the capital account implied

importing macro stability was fashionable internationally. In line with that

“conventional wisdom”, the Central Bank completed the liberalisation of the

capital account in April 2001, restating its commitment to a fully free exchange

rate. In contrast to the expectation of “importing stability”, actually a recessive

environment prevailed until 2003, led by a BER that was reinforced by a net

outflow of domestic portfolio equivalent to 3% of GDP in 2002-03. Chilean

investors, in fact, joined international markets in their pro-cyclical behaviour.

8 The Bank usually used the expression “flexible”, implicitly implying “fully flexible” with only exceptional interventions and no explicit exchange-rate or current account “targeting”.9 It should be noted that the policy tool of the reserve requirement on capital inflows, systematically used in 1991-95, is still available to the Bank (though with some bounds), if it decides to make use of this counter-cyclical regulation in the case of future capital surges.

6

Page 7: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

The binding external restriction generated a sharp depreciation trend,

which led the Bank to intervene twice in the foreign exchange market, in 2001

and 2002. Before the second intervention in October 2002, the price of the

dollar had increased 61% (to $742 per USD)10 since the liberalisation of the

exchange rate and the subsequent opening of the capital account. Arguing that

there was too much volatility,11 the Bank intervened through programmes of

auctions of foreign currency and paper indexed to the price of the dollar and

payable in pesos, that were announced for several months ahead. This was the

opposite of a discretionary intervention seeking to guide the exchange rate.

In the meantime, the recessive gap persisted, with actual GDP growing

less than the periodic official estimate of the increase in potential GDP. The

foreign exchange market started to change in the second quarter of 2003, when

the price of copper began to show an upward trend. By December, it had

jumped 40% and the exchange rate again retook a significant appreciation

trend. The gap started falling under the pull of the income and expectations

effects of commodity prices on domestic demand.

Monetary policy was active but highly gradual, notwithstanding the

recession's abrupt arrival in 1999. The Central Bank's behaviour reflected its

inflation-targeting priority. Figure 2 shows that, during the recessive years, the

CPI was usually below the centre of its target band. After sharply increasing the

monetary policy rate (MPR) to 14% (over the CPI) in 1998, in a bid to deter

capital outflows in the face of Asian crisis contagion, the Bank started to reduce

the rate gradually. In July 2001, in a significant policy shift, the real MPR was

replaced by a nominal rate, fixed at 6.5%.12 Gradual reductions continued until

early 2004 when the rate reached 1.75%. Figure 3 compares the Chilean MPR

and that of the United States.10Note that we mention the nominal price of the dollar but the relevant figure is that of the real exchange rate of a basket of currencies of Chile's main trade partners, as calculated by the Bank monthly. This is the data used in the curve in Figure 6, below. The peaks and minimums of the basket and the dollar coincide when the stronger force is the position of the peso and not that of the dollar with respect to the euro or other currencies.

11See press release of October 10, 2002 at http://www.bcentral.cl/prensa/comunicados-consejo/otros-temas/.12The MPR was indexed to the CPI (actually, to the Unidad de Fomento, UF, linked to the CPI with one month lag), which was replaced by a nominal interest rate in a quest for further reductions in inflation. A discussion in favour of the change can be found in Morandé (2002). See Shiller (2008) for a strong argument in support of the UF in Chile as an effective tool for generating segments of long-term savings and lending.

7

Page 8: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

Figures 2 and 3

In order to address the mismatch in recessive situations between the

public resources required for social programmes and temporarily depressed tax

revenue, a structural fiscal policy was implemented in 2001(Ffrench-Davis,

2010a). This implied maintaining an expenditure level consistent with

sustainable medium-term fiscal revenue as calculated using estimates of future

GDP and copper price trends. This instrument allowed the authorities to avoid

public expenditure curtailments in depressed periods and avoid increases when

the economy is overheated and tax revenue exceed their structural level.

This innovative fiscal rule was accompanied by three features that are

not intrinsic to this policy tool. One was the definition of a target of a structural

surplus of 1% of GDP which, after some time, would inevitably lead to a net

creditor position, probably a non-desirable situation for a developing economy.13

Second, it defined Chile's trend GDP including the intense recessions it has

suffered, assuming that upward deviations are equal to downward deviations.

Consequently, average trend GDP tends to move below potential GDP or the

productive frontier.14 Thirdly, the features of the Chilean rule implied a neutral

fiscal policy with respect to the economic cycle by maintaining a stable path of

expenditure. This represented progress on the traditional pro-cyclical norm of

balancing the actual fiscal budget on an annual basis, but stopped at neutrality

without reaching counter-cyclicality. In fact, up to late 2008, the new rule did not

move decidedly towards including counter-cyclical changes in public

expenditure and taxes when the economy was in recession or overheated.

An existing Copper Stabilisation Fund (CSF) represented an outstanding

factor of macroeconomic stabilisation. It contributed to the implementation of the

structural budget, thus allowing a move from pro-cyclical to neutral fiscal

policies during the recessive years. This valuable “credibility asset” was,

however, underutilised in 1999-2003 because, as discussed below, the

13 By 2008, the Treasury was a heavy creditor, particularly in foreign currency. It had accumulated US$22.7

billion in funds equivalent to 13% of GDP (Table 3). Correspondingly, in a belated decision, the structural surplus target was reduced to 0.5% of GDP in 2008 and to 0% in 2009.14 Conventional measurements use a sort of Hodrick-Prescott filter, assuming symmetrical deviations of actual GDP above and below trend GDP. In the real world --particularly under the globalization of financial volatility--, actual GDP tends to fluctuate mostly below potential GDP. See Ffrench-Davis (2014, Annex I) where estimates are presented of a production function excluding time series observations in which actual GDP is evidently out of equilibrium.

8

Page 9: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

authority refused to move to a comprehensive counter-cyclical macroeconomic

policy. Nonetheless, it contributed to stabilise fiscal expenditure, improving its

quality and moving fiscal policy from pro-cyclical to neutral.15 The evidence

provided by the 1999-2003 recession shows that there was a need to move

further towards effective counter-cyclical policies in order to contribute to faster

recovery of economic activity in recessive situations.

After 1999 it became increasingly evident that the macroeconomic pull

from abroad anticipated by the authorities, had been delayed, increasing the

social and economic costs of the RG. In this context, gradual monetary policy

and the neutral fiscal policy were unable to provide a strong boost to domestic

demand. It can be argued that a domestic shock should have then been

implemented, taking advantage of the accumulated strength of the Chilean

economy: (i) a government with minimal debt, an actual fiscal surplus of 1.8% of

GDP (average 1990-98) and a significant sovereign fund; (ii) a moderate total

external debt, with a low share of short-term liabilities; (iii) a Central Bank

without external liabilities and with high net international reserves; (iv) a low

actual and underlying inflation rate, persistently below the centre of the inflation

target;16 (v) real exchange rate appreciation that, along with the excessive

external deficit of 1998, had already been corrected in 1999, and (vi) a private

sector able to produce some 5-7% more than it was contributing to GDP in

those years.17

However, as indicated, the economic authorities rejected the proposal of

a positive public domestic shock, arguing that “markets would evaluate such an

action negatively” (by “markets”, of course, meaning financial markets). The

negative impact of downgraded risk ratings and higher spreads for Chilean

borrowers would, they asserted, outweigh the positive reactivating effect. Most

business media and the opposition supported and praised this official stance.

Moreover, some criticised the actual fiscal deficit resulting from implementation

15There were some counter-cyclical components, such as emergency job programmes when unemployment rose and, in 2002, an unemployment insurance scheme was launched. This is financed by contributions by both private-sector workers and employers to the worker's individual account and government contributions to a "solidarity fund". In September 2009, some 85% of private-sector payroll employees were contributing to the scheme. This high coverage was accompanied by modest benefits and a minimal use of the solidarity fund (see Ffrench-Davis, 2010c, Chapter VII). 16 Annual CPI inflation averaged 2.2% in 2001-04, below the 3% centre of the target band.17 Actual GDP growth averaged 2.6% in 1999-2003, while most estimates of the rise in capacity were around 4% or somewhat above. Note that potential GDP had grown about 7% per year in 1990-98.

9

Page 10: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

of the structural 1% surplus. Fortunately, the government was able to sustain

the structural principle adopted formally in 2001, thus progressing from a pro-

cyclical to a neutral fiscal policy by maintaining the trend of expenditure

notwithstanding the drop in revenue seen during that recessive situation. As

indicated above, it did not, however, moved towards a strong counter-cyclical

increase in expenditure. Actual GDP rose just 2.6% in 1999-2003 (Table 1,

above), a poor performance but better than the 1.3% recorded by Latin America

as a whole under contagion from the Asian crisis.

It is revealing of the failure in the macroeconomic approach adopted

since 1999, that over 85% of the drop in GDP growth between1990-98 and

1999-2003 was located in the domestic market which depends directly on

domestic macroeconomic policies (3.9 points out of 4.5 points; Table 1).

The effect of the recessive gap on capital formation was a determining

variable of the much weaker growth performance. A significant gap between

actual GDP and the production frontier is usually followed by a drop in

productive investment. In fact, the gross investment ratio diminished

substantially and, in 2003, was still three points below the 23% ratio recorded in

1998.18 That was a consequence of an economy that had a high output gap that

averaged some 6% of GDP in those years (Figure 5.A, below and Ffrench-

Davis, 2010c, Table IX.1). That gap reflects a real imbalance because the

economy was underutilising a significant share of the available productive

resources. As shown repeatedly, the larger the recessive gap the larger tends

to be the drop experienced by investment ratios. As well as depressing the

future growth of potential GDP, lowered capital formation tends to reduce the

quality of the labour market.

It should be stressed that RG remained high for a whole quinquenium, in

an economy with a minor public debt, fiscal responsibility and a stabilisation

fund linked to the copper price.

b) Recovery led by a positive terms-of-trade shock, 2004-07

18These figures for gross fixed investment ratios are from the National Accounts calculated by the Central Bank with base year 2003. The depreciation of the capital stock represented around 13% of GDP. Thus, these three points implied a 30% fall in net capital formation. It should be remembered that the estimate of trend GDP fell from 7% to a 4% plateau.

10

Page 11: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

The international commodity boom that started in 2003 implied a large positive

shock for the Chilean economy. Its terms of trade, led by the copper price,

improved by the equivalent of 6% of GDP between the recessed year of 2003

and 2004. A significant share of this improvement leaked into greater transfers

of profits abroad but a surplus equivalent to around three points of GDP

remained. This surplus eliminated the BER and fuelled recovery of depressed

domestic demand, permitting an increase in the utilisation rate of productive

capacity.

The boom in export prices intensified further in the years through to

2008. In 2007, the net positive effect of improvement in the terms of trade, after

discounting a higher outflow of profits, jumped to 9% of GDP, supporting the

rise in domestic demand.

Given the large output gap prior to this positive external shock, domestic

supply was able to respond with rising GDP and low inflation pressures

(inflation remained below the centre of the 2-4% target band set by the

autonomous Central Bank). Thus, the exogenous shock contributed to a major

jump in actual GDP growth from its 2.6% average in the recessive quinquenium

of 1999-2003 to 5.6% in 2004-07,19 without any significant reform of domestic

macroeconomic or microeconomic policies. The generalised improvement in the

terms of trade directly enhanced the spending capacity of the private sector,

reduced the output gap and improved the fiscal budget, with expectations once

again showing broad optimism. After the usual lag, productive investment also

began to rise.

Recovery continued gradually so that, by the beginning of 2008 before

contagion from the global crisis began, the recessive gap had been reduced,

albeit not fully eliminated. It had been present since 1998, in sharp contrast with

1991-97 when it was practically absent.

In the meantime, the Central Bank once again allowed the real exchange

rate to appreciate. Between early 2003 and 2008, the nominal price of the US

dollar fell by almost 40%, contributing to anchor inflation and further increase

(distorting) domestic purchasing power with a fast rising imports share (Table 1,

row 6, above).

19 It is noteworthy that actual GDP growth also climbed in Latin America from 1.3% in 1999-2003 to 5.7% in 2004-07.

11

Page 12: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

Consequently, the macroeconomic disequilibrium implied by the output

gap was also associated with that of the exchange rate. Given some import

liberalisation and large exchange rate appreciation, the increase in domestic

demand was strongly biased toward imports. In fact, imports doubled the speed

of export volume in 2004-08 (Figure 4), but the trade imbalance was hidden by

the high copper price (Table 2). Indeed, the foreign currency market was

operating with a highly short-termist bias, behaving as if the current copper

price were sustainable; the consequence was a mal-adjustment of the free

exchange rate.

Figure 4 and Table 2

Notwithstanding the Bank´s bias for a free exchange rate, it intervened in

April 2008, buying dollars in public auctions in the face of strong pressure from

some analysts and exporters. The reason it gave for this intervention was not

an excessive appreciation of the exchange rate but the need to increase

international reserves during the rest of the year (again a programme, but now

to purchase an amount of foreign currency equivalent to 5% of GDP), given the

worsening of the international environment that was becoming apparent. In

parallel, the Bank was raising the MPR (Figure 3, above). The auctions were

suspended in September with the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers.20

The international scenario played a relevant role, naturally enhanced by

the openness of the Chilean economy. There were positive features for Chile

such as the spectacular price of copper and other key exports which, as

indicated above, allowed the Treasury to accumulate sizable savings against

possible future bad years. In addition, world trade volume was dynamic up to

the arrival of the international financial crisis. On the other hand, international

food prices were climbing and, from mid-2007 to mid-2008, the price of food in

the Chilean CPI increased by 22%, generating significant inflationary pressures

and explaining about half of the nearly 10% annual inflation recorded at the

peak of the commodities boom (by the third quarter of 2008; see Ramos, 2008).

This was mainly imported inflation but, by late 2008, when monthly inflation in

Chile was already negative, the monetary policy interest rate (8.25%) exceeded

that of the United States by over seven points. The Central Bank's measures

20 The nominal exchange rate depreciated 17% between the first auction in April and the last one in September 2008. Depreciation then accelerated as a result of contagion from the global financial crisis.

12

Page 13: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

consistently revealed that its priority was the inflation target at the expense of

growth and employment.

Chile's leadership within Latin America on economic growth was lost in

2004-07 when its average GDP growth was similar to that of the region as a

whole.

c) The 1999-2007 cycle in briefIn all, growth in this cycle was low compared with the potential of the domestic

economy and highly positive external shocks. Average growth in this cycle was

a modest 3.9%, with the recovery as from 2003 offset by the economy's meagre

performance between 1999 and 2003.

There prevailed a combination of the excessive priority given to inflation

--supported by a distorting unstable real exchange rate, a sliding of the

economic policy approach towards a more neutral stance and the belief that

actual GDP was already too close to potential GDP. This was an approach that

received frequent support from the neo-liberal specialists. In particular, Chile

received strong praise from the IMF for implementing plain "inflation targeting"

and a free exchange-rate policy. In 2010, the IMF authorities were to recognise

that they "were wrong" in much of their previous economic focus to which,

unfortunately, Chile had adhered since 1999.21

Chile experienced a large and long-lasting recessive gap arising from a

binding external constraint that predominated over the domestic macroeconomy

for five years. If one believes in the working of markets, it is hard to deny that

those five years must have weakened “animal spirits”. The recessive gap (RG)

only started to diminish in late 2003 under the pull of commodity prices. The

important recovery that followed, without significant microeconomic or political

changes, confirms the previous macroeconomic weakness since, as indicated

above, the merits of the Chilean economy were already present in 1999-2003.

Thus, the conditions for a domestic reactivating shock had been at hand since

the previous excessive external deficit and over-appreciated exchange rate of

1998 --usually obstacles to a recovery of economic activity-- had been corrected

in 1999.

21 See Blanchard et al. (2010), for a highly relevant “regret” from the IMF.

13

Page 14: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

As from 2003, an opportunity was, therefore, again, lost to implement an

abrupt positive domestic shock, now in an over-optimistic international

environment and with notable fiscal surpluses --5.4% of GDP in 2004-07 (Table

2, below). In fact, it took four more years for the economy to approach its

production frontier. A mix of factors directly explains that weak recovery process

as from 2004. One ingredient is located in the Central Bank which overshot the

rise of the interest rate and allowed the exchange rate to revalue quickly, further

discouraging production of tradables. In addition, the Finance Ministry sterilised

“too much” of the positive impact of the copper price jump whilst allowing most

of the negative impact of increasing oil prices to penetrate the domestic

economy. A great virtue --the existence of the stabilisation scheme-- overshot,

sterilising in excess. When contagion from the global crisis reached Chile in

2008, actual GDP had not yet touched potential GDP.22 Public expenditure rose

faster than GDP, but was insufficient for an abrupt recovery.

Over and above that lost potential GDP, the fact that the drop in

economic activity was abrupt and recovery was quite gradual implied significant

forgone output during the downward and recovery stages (Figure 5.A). The

persistent RG during the whole period meant that both labour and capital were

underutilised. That fact, moreover, deterred productive investment and

productive spirits, with an impact on both future potential and actual GDP.

Figures 5.A and 5.B

Clearly, the exchange rate remained an outlier, with high mid-term

instability and a strong tendency towards overshooting (towards sharp

depreciation in the downturn and sharp appreciation in the boom). Over the

course of the cycle, the nominal price of the dollar moved between $476

(1/1999), $743 (2/2003), $514 (12/2005) and $443 (03/2008). These wide

fluctuations illustrate the exchange rate's considerable instability, with a

predominant trend towards excessive appreciation as from 2003 as shown by

the evolution of trade volume (Figure 4, above on trade, and Figure 6, below on

evolution of the real exchange rate).

22 The sharp rise in the CPI in 2007-08 could be interpreted as an overheating generated by the rise in domestic demand. However, as discussed above, it was mostly related to the jump in international food prices.

14

Page 15: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

3. The approach since the global crisis

a) Contagion from the global crisis and early recovery, September 2008-2009

When contagion from the global crisis reached Chile in 2008, the main

domestic macroeconomic variables experienced significant recessive

adjustments.23

The capital account reverted abruptly and the price of copper dropped

from US$4 per pound in early 2008 to US$1.40 in December. The international

financial turbulence of the last quarter of 2008 and acute deterioration of the

volume and value of exports had a direct impact on economic activity. After

growing at an average 8% in 2004-08, domestic demand fell by 8% in the first

semester of 2009 over the same period in 2008, while GDP contracted by 3%.

In response, the government implemented an outstanding policy shift. In

2008, it had already progressively implemented an active counter-cyclical fiscal

policy. During 2009, the effects of the strong negative external shock produced

by the financial and trade ramifications of the international crisis were gradually

displaced by the positive pull of domestic policies focused on mitigating the

adverse effects of the crisis on economic activity and social indicators. In fact,

although fiscal income fell by 10% in 2008 and 20% in 2009, reflecting

depressed domestic demand and reduced revenue from copper, spending was

increased by a vigorous 17% in 2009 (and 9% in 2008). The public sector

managed an actual (as opposed to structural) deficit of 4.4% of GDP, thanks to

the policy space created by the solid budgetary position built up in previous

years (Table 2).

In the stimulus measures adopted, there was an emphasis on low-

income housing and massive investment in public works. In addition,

CODELCO, the state copper producer, was capitalised with a government

contribution equivalent to 0.6% of GDP, designed to finance its investment

projects, while the capital of Banco Estado, the state bank, was augmented by

50%, allowing it to increase lending to small and mid-sized firms (SMEs).

23 The impact on the domestic economy and the policy response are discussed in Ffrench-Davis and Heresi (2015).

15

Page 16: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

A number of taxes in key sectors, including on fuel, borrowing and SMEs,

were temporarily reduced. Families in the lowest 40% income bracket received

two vouchers, each for the equivalent of 30% of the minimum monthly wage per

non-working family member. In addition, the solidarity pillar of the pension

system, which had been created prior to the crisis under a reform implemented

in 2008, was strengthened in 2009, expanding coverage of solidarity pensions

to 50% of the population (Arenas, 2010). While this was a structural distributive

measure, it also contributed to economic recovery.

A subsidy was introduced for the hiring of low-income young people,

providing an incentive for employment of this highly vulnerable group. In 2009,

the extent of the unemployment insurance scheme and access to its solidarity

fund were enhanced, including workers with short-term contracts, while counter-

cyclical features were introduced in its benefits.

The capital account saw a significant repatriation of the savings held in

sovereign funds to finance the fiscal deficit of 4.4% of GDP, reducing the over

US$20 billion accumulated by 2008 to US$11 billion in late 2009 (Table 3). This

counter-cyclical behaviour on the part of the Treasury was accompanied by

spectacular outflows on the part of residents, principally the AFPs.24 This again

confirmed that the liberalisation of residents´ capital flows played a negative

pro-cyclical role as had also been the case in 1998-99.

Table 3

The autonomous Central Bank embarked on a gradual reduction of the

MPR only in January 2009 (Figure 3, above). After a series of cuts, it reached

0.50% in July 2009. However, the cost of credit remained high for several

months before the cuts in the MPR were slowly transferred to credit users,

particularly SMEs. There is an asymmetry in the speed of increases in the cost

of loans during the boom and of decreases during the recessions, with an anti-

SMEs bias.25 Meanwhile, commercial banks reported annual rates of return of

over 20%, while GDP and employment had fallen.

It is important to note that a 1% drop in GDP in 2009 was determined by

the decrease of the quantum of exports, while the domestic economy, which 24 The AFPs recorded net outflows equivalent to 10% of annual GDP in 2009. See Ffrench-Davis (2014, Table X.1).25 For instance, for small loans (up to the equivalent of around US$7,500), the spread over the annual MPR rose from an already huge 27 percentage points in 2007 to 33 points in 2009, while for larger loans (over US$190,000), it increased from 2.6 to 4 percentage points (SBIF, 2014).

16

Page 17: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

only contracted slightly in late 2008 and during the first semester of 2009,

experienced a smaller impact. This was in contrast to the previous recession

when the external shocks had stronger recessive multiplying effects on the non-

export economy (Table 1, rows 3 and 4). These external negative shocks were

given data but the government was able to sustain production for the domestic

market, halting the negative multiplier effect of the imported recessive forces in

the third quarter. During the last couple of months of 2009, GDP exhibited an

increase of 3.9% (change over 12 months).26 It was domestic market activity,

supported by the counter-cyclical fiscal policy that led the recovery of economic

activity in the final months of the Bachelet administration.

Undoubtedly, the copper price boom, which had restarted by mid-2009

(with a jump to a high US$3.35 per pound in January 2010), contributed to the

recovery of private expectations and fiscal income, driving up domestic

demand. In addition, once the greatest uncertainties on international financial

markets dissipated in 2009, large firms gradually regained access to bond

markets. In all, the rather neutral structural fiscal balance (SFB) became

effectively counter-cyclical, with the financial support of the sovereign fund, and

the government was able to execute the budget in a rather timely and efficient

way.

b) Continued recovery with external and fiscal imbalances, 2010-13The recovery of economic activity and actual GDP was interrupted temporarily

by an earthquake and tsunami on 27 February 2010 (27F). Following this

severe interruption --which, according to the Bank, destroyed an estimated 1.0-

1.5% of potential GDP-- there was, however, still a wide recessive gap or policy

space for substantial recovery of economic activity during several further

quarters.

A few weeks after 27F, now at the beginning of the administration of

President Piñera, recovery restarted. The already higher domestic demand that

had resulted from the counter-cyclical policies of 2009 increased further due to

Treasury spending on post-earthquake reconstruction. Given that there was still

significant underutilised installed capacity, accelerated public spending, pulling

26Monthly Central Bank estimate of economic activity (IMACEC). For more details, see Ffrench-Davis (2014, Table X.4).

17

Page 18: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

up domestic demand, was consistent with a movement towards macroeconomic

balance as long as this recessive gap remained.

Recovery continued through to 2012, giving a 5.7% average growth of

actual GDP in 2010-12. In order to understand what happened, it is important

to distinguish between reuse of available productive capacity and the creation of

new capacity and to look at what occurred with the sustainability of the recovery

process. This involves diverse macroeconomic variables such as external

balance and fiscal budget trends and their link to productive development.

In 2010-12, domestic demand expanded faster than output, boosting

actual GDP without creating inflationary pressures. This implied moving

towards a fundamental real macroeconomic balance; that is, using available

potential GDP. Naturally, the gap decreased during the adjustment process,

raising employment and stimulating capital formation. As the gap narrowed,

with actual and potential growth converging, the speed diminished and actual

GDP growth weakened to 4.1% in 2013. A new cycle started then.

It is evident that the 5.7% increase in actual GDP between 2010 and

2012 included a significant recovery of capacity that was underutilised at the

peak of the recession. In order to avoid the common mistake of disregarding

what happened before recovery, it is necessary to measure performance

between comparable GDP peaks, given their proximity to installed capacity. If

the 2007 peak is taken as a base, actual GDP growth to the peak of 2013

averages 3.9%;27 and if we correct for the destruction caused by the

earthquake, the average growth in 2008-13 appears to be 4.1%.28 This is

identical to 2013, slightly above the rate achieved in the previous decade

(1999-2007) but much lower than the 7.1% recorded in 1990-1998.

Recovery and reaching the production frontier had positive impacts on

employment and capital formation. Despite the persistence of multiple

expressions of precariousness, there is no doubt that unemployment dropped

and formalisation of employment improved. For instance, up-to-date payments

into the social security system (the private AFPs) increased from 54.5% of the

27 Over the course of 2008, there was evidence of the effects of the crisis; GDP only grew 3.3%, below estimates of the increase in potential GDP. Consequently, 2007 is used here as the previous annual peak.28 Given that this destruction was not due to economic policy, an estimate of the negative impact of the earthquake --1.0-1.5% of potential GDP, according to the Central Bank-- must be added to the increase in actual GDP in order to measure the effectiveness of economic policy.

18

Page 19: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

labour force in 2008 to 59.6% in 2013, returning to their pace of formalization in

the years before contagion from the global crisis.29

The investment ratio experienced a recovery with respect to its

depressed level in 2009. However, in current pesos, it was running at 23.6% of

GDP in 2013, down from a peak of 24.7% in 2008. In constant pesos, on the

other hand, there was an increase from 24.7% in 2008 to 25.8% in 2013,

explained by the Central Bank's calculation that the average relative prices of

investment had decreased such that a given monetary expenditure permitted

the acquisition of 9% more in equipment, machinery and construction.30

The volume of exports remained depressed, reflecting the effect of

slowing international trade, the burden of the exchange-rate policy failure and

the persistence of an absence of productive development policies. In this cycle

the annual increase in volume of exports reached just 1.3% (Table 4). In

addition, diversification into higher value-added activities and linkages with the

rest of the domestic economy weakened. As such, the weight of recovery of

economic activity continued to be carried by the domestic market. In fact,

around 5/6 of the increase in output recorded in 2010-12 were demanded by

the domestic market.31 Naturally, given that effective demand was reaching the

level of potential output in 2012, completing the recovery of domestic output, it

sharply lost speed in 2013.

Table 4

In the transition towards the elimination of the recessive gap, an outlier

exchange rate appreciation soon reappeared and some new permanent fiscal

expenditure were created without a corresponding increase in permanent fiscal

income.

After the exchange rate experienced a strong appreciation to $443 per

dollar in March 2008 (when over-optimism still predominated), there was a

sharp devaluation to $649 in late 2008 (Figure 6, below). A period of

fluctuations then ensued, reflecting prevailing uncertainty but with the

expectation that Chile was emerging from the crisis. As a result, the rate

appreciated to $463 in 2011. Naturally, the free market rate was equilibrating

29 There had been an increase of 9 percentage points between 2002 and 2008.30 Calculations based on the new 2008 chain mobile base of national accounts. 31 See Ffrench-Davis (2014, Table X.4).

19

Page 20: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

the balance of payments but des-equilibrating the current account, resulting in

great uncertainty and misleading information to the producers of tradables.

Figure 4, above, and Table 4 show that imports grew much faster than

exports as they had done in 2004-2007. While the quantum of imports climbed

by 46% between the peak of 2007 and 2013, the quantum of exports rose by a

meagre 8%. Part of the difference was covered by the notably high price of

copper while the remainder appeared as a current account deficit of 3.4% of

GDP in both 2012 and 2013. As regards fiscal policy, a 7% health insurance

tax on pensions was partially eliminated, taxes on lending and on personal

income were reduced and a maternity leave subsidy was increased while the

tax on companies' profits rose from 17% to 20%.The net effect was that the

SFB exhibited a 1.2% deficit, despite benefiting from a fast-rising estimate of

the trend copper price (Table 2, row 4).

As a result, when the recessive gap was disappearing in 2012 and early

2013, two macroeconomic imbalances prevailed: an outlier appreciated

exchange rate and a fiscal budget based on an excessively high copper price.

This is reflected in the real trade disequilibrium. At the same time, in 2012, the

government used revenue from mining firms that were equivalent to a current

copper price of US$3.30 per pound as compared to less than US$1 used by

the Finance Ministry in 2004-07 (Table 2).32

c) The 2008-13 cycle in briefIn contrast to the approach in force since the late 1990s, the government

adopted a set of strong counter-cyclical policies at the start of this new cycle,

taking advantage of the assets and credibility that the Chilean economy had

accumulated, including the sovereign stabilisation funds. Notwithstanding the

drop in tax revenue, fiscal expenditure was increased and some taxes were

temporarily reduced. This strong counter-cyclical fiscal policy was the main

force compensating for the negative external shocks and did so quite quickly.

By the last quarter of 2009, economic activity was exhibiting a significant

recovery. Subsequently, there was also a faster recovery of economic activity

in comparison with the previous cycle. By late 2012, the RG had disappeared,

32 The SFB, measured with a nominal trend copper price of US$1.00 per pound, exhibited a surplus of 1.2% of GDP in 2004-07.

20

Page 21: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

implying a smaller cost in foregone output as shown in Figure 5.B in contrast

with Figure 5.A above.

Beyond this initial counter-cyclical progress, fiscal responsibility

deteriorated as the economy recovered. The government raised some

permanent expenditure without a matching increase in permanent fiscal

income. Even, although the copper price was quite high, there was an actual

deficit in 2013. Also, the SFB moved from a surplus in the first cycle to a deficit

in the second one, despite the positive impact of a fast-rising estimate of the

trend copper price (Table 2, row 4).33

In the case of trade and growth, there was a striking weakening of export

performance. After several years in which Chile's real exports had risen faster

than world trade,34 exports expanded by a weak annual 1.3% in this cycle, while

world trade grew by 2.5%. More worryingly, exports other than copper rose by

even less (0.9%, see Table 1), implying a step-back in diversification, a sign of

“Dutch disease”.

Evidently, world trade was depressed, but Chile's exports were even

more depressed. One explanatory variable is exchange-rate policy, with the

rate's instability and tendency to appreciate whenever a recovery stage

appears. Exchange-rate policy, of course, also underlies the fast rise of imports

(and their negative impact on SMEs).35

The Central Bank generally has argued that the actual real exchange

rate was close to “the historical average”; the data it offers uses to disregard

significant changes in import tariffs and export subsidies. Figure 6 presents the

evolution of the real exchange rate since its liberalisation in 1999, the reduction

of import tariffs from 11% to an average 1% and the elimination of a 10%

subsidy for non-traditional exports.36 After taking into account both policy

33 This is the main, albeit, simplified outcome. The relevant copper price is that in real terms (deflated by the international inflation relevant for Chile, measured monthly by the Central Bank and estimated at 71% in 1999-2013). In addition, climbing copper production costs, mostly related to falling ore grades, must be considered. Nonetheless, in all, the real proceeds for Chile from copper have been more favourable in recent years than in the 1990s.34 For instance, the quantum of exports rose by 9.9% annually in 1990-98 while world trade increased 6%.35 Due to the many free trade agreements signed by Chile in the past decade, SMEs face imports with a practically zero tariff, minor non-tariff restrictions and an unstable RER. At the same time, the net effect of the set of policies appears to be negative for export diversification, notwithstanding the preferences received in the free trade agreements. 36 The fact that --after a significant increase in the 1990s when GDP grew by 7.1%--, total factor productivity slowed sharply as from 1999 was also disregarded. This change affects the sustainable level of the “equilibrium” RER.

21

Page 22: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

changes, Figure 6 shows that the RER was usually below the adjusted curve. In

addition, the RER has experienced mid-term instability, with deep appreciation

during the two recovery stages. For investors in the production of tradables, this

has tended to offset the favourable investment and credit mood of recovery

periods.37 One evident proof of the outlier evolution of the RER is the gap

between the evolution of the volume of imports and that of exports as seen in

Figure 4, above.

Figure 6

Finally, average growth of actual GDP was rather similar in both cycles --

close to 4%-- and the RER and the current account behaved pro-cyclically in

both cases. Factor productivity and product diversification also stagnated, in

marked contrast to the 1990s. This backwards step in economic development

dynamism is common to the two episodes.

4. Final remarks After a promising start in the early 1990s when the Chilean economy

experienced nine years of 7.1% average GDP growth, it departed from what

can be termed macroeconomics for development.38 During the 15 years

between 1999 and 2013, effective demand exhibited ups-and-downs that had a

significant impact on the real macroeconomy in terms of both the rate at which

potential GDP was utilised and its actual growth rate. Those pro-cyclical failures

were reinforced by pro-cyclical instability of the exchange rate and the current

account.

It can be argued, and correctly so to a degree, that, since the late 1990s,

there have been two severe negative external shocks. The fact is that they

implied macroeconomic instability that made the implementation of counter-

cyclical policies more, rather than less, necessary. Chile, however, dismantled

most of what it had created in the 1990s, instead of improving it. In addition,

37 It is fashionable to repeat that, with the adoption of a floating exchange rate, the domestic economy became immune to external shocks. The fact is that foreign exchange crises are eliminated but at the expense of transferring great instability to the real economy, particularly the allocation of resources between tradables and non-tradables, and to the level and composition of aggregate demand, deterring development. On convergent views on the link exchange rate/development see Frenkel and Rapetti (2011); Rodrik (2008), Williamson (2000) and (2008). 38 Also used in the Latin American literature are the expressions “financierism” or “nominal stability” for the neo-liberal approach and “productivism” or “real economy” for a “neo-structuralist” or macro for development approach. See ECLAC (2010, Chapter II), Ffrench-Davis (2010b) and Ocampo (2011).

22

Page 23: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

Chile benefited from notably high copper prices that were far more favourable

for the Treasury and private exporters than in the 1990s. We have, therefore, to

explain why the excellent performance of 1990-98 was followed by two cycles in

which GDP growth averaged less than 4%. Obviously negative external shocks

have some negative effects on growth; but it is unsustainable to assert that all

of over three points of GDP, in 15 years, are fully explained by negative external

shocks. That would coincide with the most extreme “dependentism” of the

1960s.

The focus of this paper --the issue of macroeconomics for development--

reveals that the domestic macroeconomic environment worsened as from 1999.

For instance, a rather close balance of aggregate demand and potential GDP

was achieved only in 1989, 1991-98, 2007 and 2012-13, with a relevant

recessive gap prevailing for the rest of the time, while the current account in

constant prices and the ER were extremely unstable.

Notwithstanding significant domestic “policy assets”, the macroeconomic

situation was driven by a volatile capital account and volatile copper prices.

Both these macroeconomic evils had been avoided in the early 1990s but, as

from 1999, the authorities adopted both, paying the price in terms of two costly

cycles with significant instability of the real economy.

The persistent RG during the two cycles meant that both labour and

capital were underutilised, with a drop in actual total factor productivity. The RG

also deterred productive investment to the detriment of future GDP.

The Chilean economy is quite open policy-wise. Nonetheless, value-

added by exports accounts only for close to 30% of GDP and 70% of GDP is

consumed or invested in the domestic economy. This is the part of GDP where

the output gap is mostly located; the performance of this major share of GDP is

directly affected by domestic macroeconomic policies. This implies that, for a

good performance of actual GDP, there must be an active macroeconomic

policy, involving an economy working near the productive frontier and with right

or sustainable macro-prices, particularly the exchange rate which determines

the main relative price between tradables and non-tradables. The longer the

recessive gaps, the deeper the structural damage for job creation, capital

formation, fiscal revenue, and worsened balance sheets of firms, throwing some

of them into unfair and inefficient stagnation or even bankruptcy.

23

Page 24: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

The RER is a crucial allocating variable. Following the adoption of the

free exchange rate in 1999, a severe inconsistency has prevailed between

exchange-rate policy and the apparent consensus of fostering exports with

higher value-added, while SMEs have faced external competition under

reduced import tariffs and an appreciated exchange rate.

There is a need to rebalance the targets of macroeconomic policy, taking

into account four inputs beyond the priority for CPI inflation: first, consider the

evolution of the composition of the CPI, without ignoring the incidence of an

appreciated exchange rate on the price of tradables; second, taking note of the

sustainability of the evolution of the exchange rate (does it respond to the

evolution of relative productivities à la Balassa-Samuelson or rather to the

short-term balance of payments?); third, concern for the evolution of the output

gap, seeking to achieve “low inflation” with “high” employment, a sustainable

exchange rate and sustained GDP growth; and, last, the need for deep

coordination between the monetary and fiscal authorities.

In order to avoid the usual conflict between a counter-cyclical monetary

policy and a pro-cyclical exchange rate produced by an open capital account

with a free exchange rate, an additional policy tool is required and counter-

cyclical regulation of the capital account becomes unavoidable. One policy tool

still available to Chile is the reserve requirement that can be imposed by the

Central Bank while a complementary tool would be counter-cyclical regulation of

institutional investors such as the AFPs.

Finally, it is necessary to strive for a fiscal policy that moves forward

towards a strong counter-cyclical approach.39

It is essential to find the way back to sustainable real macroeconomic

equilibrium. Along with deep microeconomic development-friendly reforms (pro-

SMEs and pro-employment), this would allow Chile to return to sustained higher

rates of GDP growth and achieve a progressive reduction in inequality. Beyond

39 A related issue is the tax burden and its composition. Only minor and, in some cases, regressive adjustments were made after the major overhaul introduced in 1990. The government which took office in 2014 considered that the current tax burden was insufficient to finance the public goods required for inclusive development and the composition of revenue was not progressive. There were three main challenges: (i) the need to dismantle clearly regressive exemptions and channels for tax avoidance and to combat evasion, (ii) to increase taxation of wealth and profits, and (iii) to enhance pro-productive development linkages of public expenditure and revenue. Some of these challenges were addressed by a tax reform enacted in 2014.

24

Page 25: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

low inflation and fiscal responsibility, this implies an active macroeconomic

policy that focuses on the real economy, working close to potential GDP, with

sustainable external balances and exchange rates that are functional to

productive development. Prolonged recessive cycles structurally damage job

creation, reduce fiscal income and place costly burdens on entrepreneurship

and, particularly, small businesses.

Real macroeconomic failures are a determinant variable underlying the

slowered Chilean development convergence.

REFERENCES

Arenas, A. (2010), Historia de la reforma previsional chilena: una experiencia exitosa de política pública en democracia, OIT, Santiago.

Blanchard, O., G. Dell’Ariccia and P. Mauro (2010), “Rethinking macroeconomic policy”, IMF Staff Position Note, SPN/10/03, Washington, D.C., International Monetary Fund, February.

Central Bank (2007), “La política monetaria del Banco Central de Chile en el marco de metas de inflación”, Banco Central de Chile, Santiago.

______ Informe de Política Monetaria (IPOM), quarterly issues, Santiago.Corbo, V. (2004), “La Estabilidad de Precios y la Autonomía de los Bancos Centrales”,

Conference of President of the Central Bank, October.De Gregorio, J. (2006), “Objetivos Inflacionarios: Una Nota Aclaratoria”, Banco

Central de Chile, Presentaciones de Consejeros del Banco Central, Santiago.DIPRES (2014), “Indicadores del Balance Cíclicamente Ajustado, Metodología y

Resultados 2013”, Dirección de Presupuestos, Santiago.DIPRES, Informe de Finanzas Públicas, several issues, Ministerio de Hacienda,

Santiago.ECLAC (2010), Time for Equality: closing gaps, opening trails, United Nations,

Santiago. Edwards, S. and R. Rigobón (2009), “Capital controls on inflows, exchange rate volatility

and external vulnerability”, Journal of International Economics 78, pp. 256-67.Ffrench-Davis, R. (2014), Chile entre el neo-liberalismo y el crecimiento con equidad,

quinta edición, JCSáez Editor, Santiago.______(2010a), “The structural fiscal balance in Chile”, Journal of Globalization and

Development (Berkeley Electronic Journals), Vol. 1, No 1, January. ______(2010b), “Macroeconomics for development: From ‘financierism’ to

‘productivism”, CEPAL Review, No. 102, December, pp. 7-26.______(2010c), Economic reforms in Chile: from dictatorship to democracy, Palgrave

Macmillan, London and New York.______ and R. Heresi (2015), “La economía chilena frente a la crisis financiera: respuestas

contra-cíclicas y desafíos pendientes”, in J.L. León, ed., Crisis global, respuestas nacionales. La recesión en América Latina y Asia Pacífico, Observatorio América Latina Asia Pacífico, Montevideo, pp. 248-75.

Frenkel, R. and M. Rapetti (2011), “Exchange rate regimes in Latin America”, in Ocampo and Ros (2011).

25

Page 26: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

Magud, N. and C. Reinhart (2007), “Capital controls: an evaluation”, in S. Edwards (ed.), Capital controls and capital flows in emerging economies: policies, practices and consequences, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 645-74.

Massad, C. (1999), “Exposición del Presidente del Banco Central de Chile al Senado con Ocasión de la Presentación del Informe Anual 1999”, Presentaciones de Consejeros del Banco Central, Santiago.

Morandé, F. (2002), “Nominalización de la tasa de política monetaria: Análisis y Debate”, Cuadernos de Economía, Año 39, Nº 117, pp. 239-52, Santiago.

Ocampo, J.A. (2011), “Macroeconomy for development: Countercyclical policies and productive transformation”, CEPAL Review, No. 104, pp. 7-35, August.

______ and J. Ros (2011), eds., The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Economics, Oxford University Press, New York.

Ramos, J. (2008), “La economía chilena actual: adios al milagro, bienvenido el blindaje”, El Mostrador(electronic media, Santiago),October.

Rodrik, D. (2008), “The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.

_____ and A. Subramanian (2008), “Why did financial globalization disappoint”, draft,March.

SBIF (2014), “Tasas de Interés Promedio del Sistema Bancario”, Superintendencia de Bancos e Instituciones Financieras, Santiago. Data available in SBIF, Información Financiera: http://www.sbif.cl/sbifweb/servlet/InfoFinanciera?indice=4.0

Shiller, R. (2008), The Subprime Solution, Princeton University Press, NJ.Williamson, J. (2000), “Exchange rate regimes for emerging markets: reviving the

intermediate option”, Policy Analyses in International Economics 60, Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.

_____ (2008), “Do development considerations matter for exchange rate policy?”, in K. Cowan and S. Edwards (eds.), Current account and external financing, Banco Central de Chile, Santiago.

Table 1Selected macroeconomic indicators, 1990-2013

(average rates of growth, and % of GDP)

    1990-98 1999-13 (1999-03) 1999-07 (2009) 2008-131 GDP per capita 5.4 2.8 1.4 2.7 -2.0 2.9

26

Page 27: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

2 GDP 7.1 3.9 2.6 3.9 -1.0 3.93 GDP exported 9.9 4.3 5.5 6.4 -4.5 1.3

(2.0) (1.4) (1.4) (1.6) (-1.1) (0.3 )

4 GDP non-exported 6.5 3.8 1.7 3.1 0.1 4.9 (5.1) (2.5) (1.2) (2.3) (0.1) (3.6)

5Non-copper exports 10.3 4.9 7.1 7.6 -3.6 0.9Non-traditional exports* 14.1 - 7.9 8.5 -10.3 -

6 Imports 12.7 7.5 3.0 8.3 -16.2 6.57 Current account (% of current GDP) -3.0 0.0 -0.9 0.9 2.0 -1.38 Terms of trade index (1989 = 100) 88 148 96 123 165 185

9 Gross investment ratio (% of current GDP) 25.1 21.5 20.9 20.6 21.8 22.9

10 Net investment ratio (% of real GDP)** 13.1 12.1 11.9 12.2 10.7 12.0

11 Fiscal expenditure 6.6 6.2 4.0 5.4 16.5 7.312 Fiscal balance (% of current GDP) 1.8 1.1 -1.0 1.8 -4.4 0.013 CPI (Dec. to Dec.) 11.2 3.2 3.4 3.8 -0.6 2.914 Real average wage 3.9 2.1 1.7 1.9 4.8 2.515 Real minimum wage 5.3 3.5 4.8 3.6 4.8 3.2Sources: Abridged from Ffrench-Davis (2014, Tables I.7 and VI.6), based on Central Bank and National Institute of Statistics (INE) data updated to 2013. All growth rates are in real terms. Figures in brackets in rows 3 and 4 represent the contribution of exports and non-exports to GDP growth, respectively. * Excludes from non-copper exports nine groups of large items; at present includes about 5,000 items. **Net investment in fixed capital at constant prices was adjusted in 2010 for an estimated 3% drop in the stock of capital due to the destruction caused by the 27F earthquake; it reduced the 1999-2013 average ratio by 0.5 points and that of 2008-13 by 1.2 points.

Table 2Fiscal indicators, 2001-2013

  2001-03 2004-07 2008 2009 2010-12 2013

1. GDP actual (% annual real change) 3.2 5.6 3.3 -1.0 5.7 4.12. GDP trend (% annual real change) (previous year consultation)* 4.2 4.6 5.0 4.9 4.7 5.0

27

Page 28: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

3. Copper price actual (nominal US$/Lb) 0.74 2.31 3.16 2.34 3.68 3.324. Copper price mid-term trend (nom. US$/Lb) 0.90 1.00 1.37 1.99 2.58 3.065. Fiscal balance actual (% of current GDP) -0.7 5.4 3.9 -4.4 0.5 -0.66. Structural fiscal balance (% of current GDP) 0.9 1.2 0.0 -1.2 -1.2 -0.57. Fiscal income (% annual real change) 4.1 18.2 -9.5 -20.4 13.7 -1.48. Fiscal income (% of current GDP) 20.4 23.5 24.2 19.0 22.1 21.09. Fiscal expenditure (% annual real change) 3.8 7.2** 9.3 16.5 4.8 4.110.Fiscal expenditure (% of current GDP) 21.1 18.1** 20.3 23.4 21.7 21.6

Sources: Ffrench-Davis and Heresi (2015), based on data from the Central Bank and DIPRES (2014).Notes: Values correspond to a simple annual average for each period. Real GDP growth figures are from the National Accounts in 2003 prices; as from 2006, the rates of change of the new chained base, reference 2008, are used. All rates of change are in real terms. For figures presented as % of GDP, the GDP at current prices, reference 2008, is used.* Trend GDP corresponds to calculations of the Finance Ministry, based on inputs provided by the Advisory Committee on Trend GDP. The figures in row 2 correspond to estimates from the annual consultation of trend GDP for the budget of the next year. Given that the Trend GDP Committee delivered the first estimate for the next budget year in 2002, the values used for 2001 and 2002 are the estimates presented in the 2002 report. **Fiscal expenditure in constant prices rises faster than GDP, but falls as share of current GDP, because this variable increases notably due to the boom of export prices in this 2004-07 period with respect to 2001-03.

Table 3

Sovereign funds, 2008-2013(US$ current millions)

 FEES FRP

FEES+FRP (% of annual

GDP)2008 20,211 2,507 12.6%2009 11,285 3,421 8.5%2010 12,720 3,837 7.6%2011 13,157 4,406 7.0%2012 14,998 5,883 7.8%2013 15,419 7,335 8.2%

Source: DIPRES and Central Bank.Notes: Consolidated Treasury assets at the end of each year in the Economic and Social Stabilisation Fund (FEES) and the Pension Reserve Fund (FRP). The last column shows the total amount accumulated in both funds as a percentage of GDP of the respective year. GDP in US$ corresponds to the series at current prices, reference 2008, divided by the average nominal exchange rate of the year.

Table 4Macroeconomic disequilibrium indicators, 2008-2013

(indexes 2007=100; and average annual % changes)

  2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Averageannual growth

28

Page 29: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

Appreciation zone Depreciation zone

Investment abroad

RERInvestment

abroadlimit

(%)1. GDP 103.7 102.6 108.5 114.8 121.0 125.9 3.92.Quantum of exports 99.3 94.8 97.0 102.3 103.5 107.9 1.33.Quantum of imports 111.2 93.2 117.4 135.7 142.4 145.6 6.54.Real fiscal expenditure 109.3 127.4 135.7 139.9 146.5 152.4 7.35.Real fiscal income 90.5 72.0 92.4 103.0 104.4 103.0 0.56.Real fiscal non-copper income 101.5 91.8 107.7 123.6 132.0 136.1 5.37.Domestic demand 108.3 102.2 116.1 126.8 135.6 140.2 5.8

Source: Taken from Ffrench-Davis (2014, Table IX.5), updated to 2013. Based on Central Bank figures for GDP, exports, imports and domestic demand from the chained base, reference 2008 series. Nominal fiscal figures from DIPRES (2014), deflated by the annual average CPI, here scaled to 2007=100; rows 4 to 6 correspond to the central government, row 6 excludes fiscal revenue from CODELCO and the ten largest mining companies.

Figure 1Pension fund outflows and real exchange rate, 1995-2000

(% of total portfolio, 1986=100)Sources: Taken from Ffrench-Davis (2010, Table IX.1), based on Central Bank and Pension Fund Superintendency figures.

Figure 2 Actual and target inflation, 1999-2013

(12-month % change in CPI)

29

Page 30: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

Source: Based on figures from Central Bank for inflation target and from National Institute of Statistics (INE) for monthly rates of change of the CPI.Notes: In 1999 the Central Bank defined a target of 4.3% for the year and of 3.5% for the following year. It then established a 2% to 4% band, centred on a 3% target as from 2001.

Figure 3 Chilean and US monetary policy rate, 1998-2013

(annual %)

Source: Based on monthly Central Bank figures. Notes: The Monetary Policy Rate (MPR) in Chile has been set in nominal terms since August 2001. Prior to this date, the MPR was expressed as an annual percentage over the CPI.

Figure 4 Evolution of exports and imports of goods and services, 2004-2013

(cumulative changes, index 2004=100)

30

Page 31: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

Sources: Based on Central Bank figures in prices of 2003. As from 2006, growth rates of the chained 2008 series are used. Exports and imports correspond to the volume (quantum) of goods and services. The figures between the two curves show the cumulative excess of imports over exports since 2004, as a percentage of exports.

Figure 5A. Potential and actual GDP, 1997-2007

(millions of constant US$)

31

42%

25%

Page 32: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

B. Potential and actual GDP, 2008-2013(millions of constant US$)

Sources: Adapted from Ffrench-Davis (2010c, appendix to Chapter I), updated with data from Central Bank for actual GDP and stock of capital.

Figure 6Chile: Real exchange rate (RER), 1999-2014

(index 1986=100)

32

Page 33: 30/01/15(9270w+1787=11,057+225) - CEPALarchivo.cepal.org/.../SS2015/ChileSince1999_040715.docx · Web viewCounter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The

1999Feb.99Mar.99Apr.99May.99Jun.99Jul.99Ago.99Sep.99Oct.99Nov.99Dec.992000Feb.00Mar.00Apr.00May.00Jun.00Jul.00Ago.00Sep.00Oct.00Nov.00Dec.002001Feb.01Mar.01Apr.01May.01Jun.01Jul.01Ago.01Sep.01Oct.01Nov.01Dec.012002Feb.02Mar.02Apr.02May.02Jun.02Jul.02Ago.02Sep.02Oct.02Nov.02Dec.022003Feb.03Mar.03Apr.03May.03Jun.03Jul.03Ago.03Sep.03Oct.03Nov.03Dec.032004Feb.04Mar.04Apr.04May.04Jun.04Jul.04Ago.04Sep.04Oct.04Nov.04Dec.042005Feb.05Mar.05Apr.05May.05Jun.05Jul.05Ago.05Sep.05Oct.05Nov.05Dec.052006Feb.06Mar.06Apr.06May.06Jun.06Jul.06Ago.06Sep.06Oct.06Nov.06Dec.062007Feb.07Mar.07Apr.07May.07Jun.07Jul.07Ago.07Sep.07Oct.07Nov.07Dec.072008Feb.08Mar.08Apr.08May.08Jun.08Jul.08Ago.08Sep.08Oct.08Nov.08Dec.082009Feb.09Mar.09Apr.09May.09Jun.09Jul.09Ago.09Sep.09Oct.09Nov.09Dec.092010Feb.10Mar.10Apr.10May.10Jun.10Jul.10Ago.10Sep.10Oct.10Nov.10Dec.102011Feb.11Mar.11Apr.11May.11Jun.11Jul.11Ago.11Sep.11Oct.11Nov.11Dec.112012Feb.12Mar.12Apr.12May.12Jun.12Jul.12Ago.12Sep.12Oct.12Nov.12Dec.122013Feb.13Mar.13Apr.13May.13Jun.13Jul.13Ago.13Sep.13Oct.13Nov.13Dec.132014Feb.14Mar.14Apr.14May.14Jun.14Jul.14Ago.14Sep.14Oct.14Nov.14Dic.1470

75

80

85

90

95

100

105

110

115

RER

RER Average 1986-2004

Average adjusted by changes in Tariffs and "Reintegro Simplificado" 1999-2004

RE

R

743

472

649

443475

613

Sources: Ffrench-Davis (2014, Figure A.3), based on Central Bank monthly average figures for the real exchange rate of a broad basket of currencies of Chile's trade partners, DIPRES for the collected effective tariff and "simplified reimbursement" to non-traditional exports.Notes: The gap between the straight and the dotted lines show the compensatory adjustment to the RER necessary to maintain the competitiveness of tradables production, considering the 10 percentage point drop in import tariffs and the eliminated 10% reimbursement for non-traditional exports (which are the share of exports with higher price elasticity). The numbers presented in the RER curve correspond to the monthly average of nominal Chilean pesos per dollar at the corresponding dates.

33