peru - policies to stop hyperinflation - vol 2

Upload: ricardo-lago-economica-consulting

Post on 07-Jul-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    1/149

    Report o.7460-PE

    Peru

    Policieso StopHyperinflation

    and

    nitiateEconomic ecovery

    (InTwo Volumes) Volume l:AnnexesandStatisticalAppendix

    December5,1988

    CountryDepartmentV

    LatinAmerica nd he Caribbean egional ffice

    USE ONLY

    U.,~~~~~~~~

    Document f heWorldBank

    hasa restricted istribution ndmaybeused y recipients

    n the performancef theirofficial uties.tscontentsmaynot otherwise

    disclosed ithoutWorldBank uthorization.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    2/149

    CURRENCY

    EQUIVALENTS

    Currency

    Unit

    = Inti

    (I/.)

    Official

    Exchange

    Rate

    (Effective

    ecember

    1,

    1988)

    I/.

    1.00

    =

    US$0.002

    US$

    1.00

    =

    I/.

    500

    FISCAL

    YEAR

    January 1 to December 31

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    3/149

    FOR OFFICIAL

    USEONLY

    PREFACE

    This report was prepared and drafted prior to the announcement f

    two packages of economic

    measures by the Peruvian Government,

    first in

    September

    1988 and then in November 1988. A description

    f these measures

    as well as an update on the current state of the economy is contained in

    the Addendum provided in the last section of Volume I.

    This report is based on findings and analysis of Bank

    economic

    missions which visited Lima in October 1987, November/December 987, and

    March/April 1988. Support for the Bank work with the Government was

    provided by the United Nations DevelopmentProgramme (UNDP). Participation

    in the missions, which varied in size and composition, as as follows:

    William Tyler (Mission hief); Ricardo Lago (Deputy h.tCsion hief ani

    principal

    author); Ulrich Lachler

    (trade and exchange rate policies);

    Daniel Oks (consultant, acroeconomics); eno Malatinszky (public

    enterprises); icardo Martin (projections); ernando Rezende (consultant,

    taxation); Javier Escobal

    (consultant, griculture); ruce Herrick

    (consultant, abor

    markets); Cesar Burga (projections, tatistical nnex,

    and research assistance). Pedro Mercader (UNDP Lima Representative)

    accompanied he work of the missions in Lima and provided valuable guidance

    and overall support. Valuable comments on an earlier draft were provided

    by Rudiger Dornbusch. Michel del Buono provided

    a short note on the

    state

    of the energy sector. Brian Wesol provided research assistance in one of

    the missions. Dorothy

    Jenkins provided secretarial

    ork throughout the

    cycle

    of the report. Milagros Aquino-Divino rovided secretarial

    assistance in the final stage of

    the report.

    This report was discussed in great detail with the Government's

    economic team in Lima during October/November

    988 by Messrs. Tyler

    and

    Lago.

    While there was general

    agreement etween the Bank

    and the

    Government's

    economic team

    as to the diagnosisand analysis of the

    situation,the Government's conomic team stressed political and social

    constraints

    o taking strong

    policy action to forestall yperinflation nd

    indicated the need for

    a more gradual policy

    approach.

    This

    document has a restricteddistribution

    and may be used by recipients

    only in the performance

    of their officialduties. Its contents may not otherwise be disclosedwithout WorldBank authorization.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    4/149

    PERU- POLICIES TO

    STOP HYPERINFLATION

    ND

    INITIATE ECONOMIC

    ECOVERY

    TABLEOF CONTENTS

    VOLUME

    :

    THEMAIN

    REPORT

    Page

    No.

    COUNTRY ATA

    EXECUTIVE UMMARY i

    RESUMEN

    JECUTIVO

    xvi

    CHAPTER I. THE EVOLUTION

    OF THE PERUVIAN CONOMY

    .............

    1

    A. Background

    ............,

    1

    B. Recent History ................................

    1

    C.

    The Diagnosis of

    the Economy in 1985

    and

    Strategy

    of the Incoming PRA Government .....

    3

    D. The Implementation

    f the Policies,

    July

    1985 to December 1986

    .................. 4

    E. The Results in 1986: Reactivation

    nd

    Disinflation

    ................................

    9

    F.

    Economic Policy

    in 1987 ....................... 12

    G. Economic Perfor.mance

    n 1987: Stagnatio

    i of

    Production and

    Intensification f

    Inflationary

    ressures ...................... 19

    H. Economic Policy during January-August

    988 ....

    21

    CHAPTER

    II. THE ECONOMIC PROSPECTS

    IN THE ABSENCE OF

    MAJOR

    POLICY

    EFORMS . ....... .. ...........

    23

    A. The Diagnosis

    of the Current

    Crisis ...........

    23

    B.

    The Likely Evolution of

    the Economy

    without

    Major Corrective

    easures ........... 28

    CHAPTER

    III. THE MAIN

    ECONOMIC ISSUES

    AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS

    38

    A.

    Public Finance

    ..... ......

    .............9

    1.

    The Tax System:

    Evolution, Structure,

    and Recommendations

    .....................

    41

    2. Prices

    and Tariffsof State Enterprises:

    Evolutions, tructure, nd

    Recommendations

    .........................

    47

    3. Public Investment:

    ecent Trends and

    Recommendations

    .........................

    54

    4. The

    Central Bank's

    Quasi-Fiscal eficit:

    Definition, easurement, nd

    Recommendations

    .........................

    56

    B. Externial ector Policies

    ..

    60

    1. Exchange

    Rate Policy:Evolution,

    Structure,

    and Recommendations..........

    60

    2. Import Restrictions:

    tructure,

    Assessment, and

    Recommendations.........

    68

    3. Export Incentives: tructure,

    Assessment,

    and Recommendations.........

    76

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    5/149

    -

    ii

    -

    C. Other Resource Allocation Issues . .............0

    1. Financial

    olicy: Main

    Issues and

    Recommendations .

    .

    80

    2. Price Controls: Structure nd

    Recommendations.........................

    85

    3. Agricultural Pricing

    and Subsidies:

    ?olicies, ssessment, nd

    Recommendations......................... 87

    4. Labor Market Issues and Recommendations ...

    92

    5. The State Enterprise

    Sector ...............

    96

    CHAPTER IV. ECONOMIC POLICY TO STABILIZE NFLATION ND

    SET THE CONDITIONS FOR MEDIUM-RUN

    GROWTH .......... 99

    A. The Preconditions or Stabilization............ 99

    B. Resumption of Growth and the Foreign Debt

    Problem .....................................

    100

    C. Overall Macroeconomic trategy ................ 103

    D. Illustrative volution of the Economy under

    Stabilization nd Structural djustment ..... 112

    ADDENDUM

    - AN UPDATE

    ON

    RECENT DEVELOPMENTS

    ..

    .. . 120

    VOLUME

    II:

    ANNEXES

    AND STATISTICAL PPENDIX

    A;NNEXES* ....

    ...........................................................

    1

    Annex 1.

    Inflation nd Inflationary inance

    ...... 1

    Annex 2. The Inflation Tax: Theoretical

    Derivation and Calculation for

    1980-87. .. . 4

    Annex 3. The Central Bank's Quasi-Fiscal efieit..

    17

    Annex 4. Main Characteristics f the Peruvian

    Tax System

    .... .................

    28

    Annex 5. Misalignment

    of Prices and Tariffs of

    State Enterprises:

    A Preliminary

    Calculation

    ...........................

    38

    Annex 6. The Working of the "Mesa de

    Negociacion"

    f Foreign

    Exchange

    Certificates.......................... 41

    Annex 7. The Financial System: Institutional

    Characteristics.......................

    42

    Annex 8. Population,

    ncome Distribution, nd

    Labor

    Market Segmentation.............

    47

    Annex 9. The State Enterprise Sector ............. 58

    Annex 10. The Interaction

    f Fiscal and

    Monetary

    Policy ................................

    79

    Annex 11 Reserve Requirements

    nd their

    Remuneration

    ..........................

    92

    Annex

    12 Brief Background n the Agricultural

    Sector ................................ 93

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    6/149

    - iii -

    STATISTICAL APPENDIX

    ......

    ...............................

    ...... 95

    I.

    POPULATION

    AND EMPLOYMENT

    ... ...... ......................

    , 5

    1.1 Total Population

    istribution

    . . 95

    1.2

    Demographic

    Indicators

    .

    .

    96

    1.3 Enploymentand Labor Productivity ........... 97

    1.4 Un- and

    Under-Employment

    ...................

    98

    II. NATIONAL ACCOUNTS

    ......................

    .

    .

    99

    2.1 GDP by Sectoral

    Origin (Constant ntis)

    ..... 99

    2.1(A)

    Real GDP Average

    Growth Rates (Percentages)..

    100

    2.2 Nominal GDP by

    Sectoral Origin

    (Current ntis) ...........................

    101

    2.2(A) GDP:

    Percentage Distribution

    ................ 102

    2.2(B) GDP

    Deflators

    .................

    103

    2.2(C) GDP Deflators:

    Yearly

    Percentage Changes .... 104

    2.3 GDP

    by Expenditures

    Constant ntis)

    ........ 105

    2.4 GDP by Expenditures(Current ntis) ......... 106

    2.5 Domestic

    Irncome.............................

    107

    2.5(A) (PerceLatageistribution) .............

    108

    2.6 Gross Capital Formation

    y

    Goods and Origin-..

    109

    2.7 Real GDP Per Capita .........................

    110

    2.8 Per

    Capita GDP by

    Departments . .11....... i

    III.

    BALANCEOF PAYMENTS

    .............................

    .... 112

    3.1 Summary

    Balance of

    Payments .

    ......... 112

    3.1(A) (As

    a Percent of GDP)

    .............

    113

    3.2 Merchandise

    Exports

    by Commodities

    (Current

    Dollars) .................................. 114

    3.3 Merchandise

    xports by Commodities

    (Constant

    Dollars) 115

    3.4 Merchandise

    i.tportsCurrent

    ollars)

    116

    3.5

    Merchandise Imports

    (Constant ollars)

    117

    3.6 Export,

    Import ar.A erms of

    Trade Indexes... 118

    IV. EXTERNALDEBT .................

    -..**e...

    .......... 119

    4.1

    Total External

    Debt Outstanding

    and

    Disbursed

    ................................

    119

    4.2 ServicePayments, isbursements

    nd

    Outstanding

    mounts of External Public.

    Debt ..................................... 120

    V. PUBLIC FINANCE

    .........................

    121

    5.1 Non-Financial

    ublic Sector

    Operations ...... 121

    5.1(A) (As a Percent

    of GDP) .......................

    122

    5.2 Central Government

    Operations ............... 123

    5.2(Al (As a percent of GDP) .......................

    124

    5.3 Non-Financial ublic

    Enterprise Operations

    .. 125

    5.3(A)

    Non-Financial ublic Enterprise perations

    .. 126

    5.3(B) Non-Financial ublic

    Enterprise perations

    by Company ................................

    127

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    7/149

    - iv -

    5.4 Current Revenue of the Central Government

    by Source

    .

    .

    128

    5.4(A)

    (As a Percent

    of GDP)

    .. 129

    5.5

    Current Expenditures f the Central

    Government .......

    130

    5.5(A) (As a Percent of GDP) .............. 131

    5.6 Fiscal Cost of Exemptions on

    Import

    Tariffs by Sectors . . 132

    VI. MONETARY STATISTICS

    ................................

    .....

    133

    6.1 Summary Accounts of the Consolidated

    Financial ystem ..............,......

    133

    6.2

    Summary Accounts

    of the Consolidated anking..

    System ...................................

    134

    6.3

    Summary Accounts

    of the Central Reserve Bank..

    135

    VII. PRODUCTION STATISTICS

    ........ ..........

    136

    7.1 Agricultural

    Production ...................... 136

    7.2 Volume Index of

    Manufacturing roduction

    .....

    137

    'VIII.RICES AND EXCHANGE RATE .................................... 138

    8.1 Consumer Price Indexes for Metropolitan ima.. 138

    8.2

    Exchange Rates ............................... 139

    8.3 Real Exchange Rate Index ..................... 140

    COUNTRYMAP

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    8/149

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    9/149

    ANNEX 1

    INFLATION AND INFLATIONARY INANCE

    1. The purpose

    of this annex is to

    study the relationship

    etween the

    inflation

    rate and the

    real resources

    rom inflationary inance

    (seigniorage). In particular, he focus

    is placed on identifying

    he shape

    of the trade-off

    etween the inflation

    ate (as a tax rate) and the amount

    of real resources hat can be transferred o the government from a given

    demand for

    money (as a tax base).

    This trade-off an

    be termed as a Laffer

    curve,

    in analogy with the theory of taxation.

    From analyzing this

    trade-

    off it

    can be calculated he inflation rate that

    maximizes revenues

    from

    inflationary

    inance. It

    is found that in the case

    of Peruvian economy,

    that inflation

    rate is between 500

    percent and 600 percent

    per annum, and

    the maximum revenue

    from inflation

    is just over 10 percent

    of GDP.

    2.

    The demand for

    money utilized here

    is the simple Cagan

    formulation:

    M/p

    = A exp (-anl)

    (1)

    Where M/p

    = real broad money;

    = inflation rate:

    y = real GDP

    Since in Peru

    interest rates on Bank deposits are

    very low compared

    to

    inflation and the share of deposits

    in broad money is declining

    rapidly, it

    is assumed

    for simplicity

    hat the nominal return of all broad money

    is

    zero.

    3. The government's

    ea'l evenuefrom irnflation

    R) is:

    R

    = (M/kp) 1 =

    [A exp (-%l)Y

    ]/k (2)

    Where k =

    money supply multiplier.

    To maximize inflationary evenues:

    d

    R/dfl = A [exp

    (-&ll) -anl

    exp (-al) ]/k

    0

    This can be

    written as:

    (A exp (-dl)y/k)

    1-5U)

    0

    The maximum revenues re reached

    at n (max)

    I/a (3)

    Also when n = o or f

    = w ==) R (Min)

    = 0

    4. To infer the

    value of the

    parameter "a'.

    the following

    onvenient

    expression of (1) can be used:

    (M/p)/y = A exp

    (-acl) or y/(M/p)= exp (fIa)/A

    Since V = py/M =

    income velocity of money; therefore:

    V = exp (Ia)/A

    (4)

    Taking

    logs and

    then derivatives:

    d log V ldH =

    a

    or (dV/V)/dll

    a

    (5)

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    10/149

    5. The variables

    of expression (5) can be proxied by the growth rate

    of velocity and the increase in inflation rom the second semester of 1987

    to the first semester of 1988. Thus:

    d V/V

    t Av/v =

    1163/bO9

    =

    0.44

    Since: M/P (at Dec. 1987)

    =

    1163; Real GDP (average uly-Dec. 1987)

    =

    121;

    and M/p (at June 1988) = 809; Real GDP (average

    Jan.-May 1988) = 121

    In addition:AH

    =

    3.62 1.38 2.24

    Since: n (July to Dec. 1987) = 138 (annual rate)

    I

    (Jan. to June 1988) = 362 (annual rate)

    Therefore the estimate of "a" is: (AV/v) /An 0.44/2.24 0.196 and,

    as a result, the inflation ate that maximizes inflationary inance is:

    n

    (max) I/a

    =

    1 / 0.196

    =

    5.1 or 510 percent per annum

    Chart 1-1

    I

    ' I- , i l,,_

    hS.d. Pr.j

    irfe.8 I e'1Ir'i;. ":'r.'@ )

    P

    .

    -1

    Lil

    ~ fl

    t..:1~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~y

    .0

    ;I l;

    I' 'ij}

    l

    gill [f { kv [ 0

    (' t f l t 2 at

    r.

    .i V-, 1 1. i 1,,>,-I I

    X.

    ,-

    X

    l ,r IT."3 jr LI. ' r1 I tX 1 ; - V- '.27 O -), i

    ^

    ' r l eDi)coP 1: °C O

    *1~~~~~~~inlt3 n-1LItltl[Fl9i

    ~I i1ol3n rsfi1

    6. To find out the numerical expression of equation (2), it is also

    necessary to calculate . This can be done using expression (4) and

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    11/149

    -3-

    substituting he values of V and

    11

    observe' in 1987 1/

    V - 10.9 = (1/A) exp (0.196 1.15)

    -=)

    A = 0.11

    Therefore, the expression for revenue

    from inflation (equation (2)) is:21

    R/y

    =

    0.065 x exp

    (-0.19611) x

    II (6)

    This equation calculates the government's revenue from inflation as a

    percentage of GDP. The Laffer curve implied by equation (6) is plotted in

    Chart 1-1.

    7. It can be seen in the figure that the maximum revenue from

    inflation s about 12 percent of GDP and that this is reached at a steady

    state inflation f between 5002 and 6002. For inflation rates beyond 600Y

    percent the model becomes unstable and the revenue from inflation rops

    exponentially owards zero. (Note that for each (revenue/GDP) oint in the

    vertical axis there are two solutions (two inflation ates) in the

    horizontal axis; one solution is at low inflation--along he efficient and

    stable portion of the Laffer curve, and the other solution is at high

    inflation--that s in the inefficient r unstable portion of the curve.

    The second solution is, therefore, in the hyperinflationary ath).

    1/ The value used for V, 10.9, is equal to nominal GDP (1987) divided broad

    money supply (as of end of 1986); that is GDP/M_. Because this measure

    of velocity is more suitable for inflationary evenue calculations than

    the alternative DP/M. The inflation rate in 1987 was 115 percent.

    2/ The money supply multiplier

    in 1987/88 was k = 1.7.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    12/149

    -4-

    ANNEX

    2

    THE INFLATION

    TAXs THEORETICALDERIVATIONAND CALCULATION

    FOR 1980-87

    A. Introduction

    1. The purpose

    of this annex is

    to propose a broad measure

    of the

    inflation

    ax and a method

    to estimate it for Peru in

    the 3980-87 period.

    2. The textbookconventional

    easurement f

    the inflation tax

    is

    restricted to

    the inflation-erosion

    f non-interest earing

    public debt

    (e.g.,currency). However, currency is not

    the only public liability

    hich

    can

    be amortized through

    inflation. The

    real value of other forms of

    public debt, such

    as bonds, fixed int0rest loans, or

    interest bearing

    reserve requirement

    f the commercial

    anks in the Central Bank, is also

    eroded by increases in

    the price level. Thus,

    a broader measure

    of the

    inflation

    ax ought to focus on the inflation-amortization

    f the principal

    of all public

    debt instruments

    (monetary nd financial) ot compensated

    y

    interest payments.

    The difference

    between monetary and

    financial debt

    instruments, hough, is that the latter

    bear an interest hich

    tends to

    compensate

    (partially r

    totally) the debt-holderfor the amortization

    f

    debt in

    real terms induced

    by inflation. Accordingly,

    the inflationtax

    proposed here

    refers only

    to that portion

    of the inflation-amortization

    f

    debt

    which is not compensated

    y interest

    payments. To illustrate

    this,

    consider the case of currency.

    Since currency

    is a zero-interest

    liability, there is no interestcompensation or the inflation-induced eal

    amortization f it and, hence,

    all that real amortization

    s inflation

    ax.

    In the case

    of financial ebt, since

    it bears a nominal interest rate which

    compensates (partially

    t least) debt-holders

    or inflation-induced

    apital

    losses, the

    inflation tax will

    be smaller than the total inflation-

    amortization

    f

    debt.

    3. Estimating

    the inflation tax

    according to this definition requires

    knowledge

    of the component

    f nominal interest

    rates which is

    a

    compensation(to debt-holders)

    or inflation-induced

    apital

    losses. That

    component

    is, of

    course, equal

    to the nominal

    interest rate minus the

    "benchmark" eal interest rate.l/ To simplifythe calculation rocess,it

    is first

    assumed that the

    full amount of nominal

    interest rates is

    compensation

    for the inflation-erosion f

    debt. This obviously

    implies

    that the benchmark real interest

    rate is zero.

    In a second

    calculation,

    though,

    it is assumed

    that the benchmark

    real interest rate is

    5 percent.

    This,

    in turn, implies

    that the compensation

    or inflation-amortization

    f

    debt is

    approximately

    qual to the percentage ominal

    interest

    rate minus 5

    percent (see Footnote

    1).

    4. In principle,

    in order to

    estimate accuratelythe inflation tax,

    all assets

    and liabilities

    f the consolidated

    ublic sector,and their

    corresponding

    nterests nd returns,

    ould be

    required. However, in Cae

    1/

    More rigorously, ((l + i)/(l + R)] - 1, where

    'i" is the nominal

    rate of

    interest and

    "R" is the

    real rate of interest.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    13/149

    - 5 -

    calculation resented here, only a small number of interest rates of

    financial ssets and liabilities re considered. This implies, on

    occasion, imputing the same interest rates to different types of assets and

    liabilities. However, the approximations re good enough to provide

    reliable estimate of inflation ax proceeds.

    5. Estimating

    the broadly defined inflation ax requires assessing

    the inflation tax base first. This task is best done by consolidating he

    balance sheets of the non-financial

    ublic sector and the financial

    public

    sector. The Consolidated Public Sector (CPS) balance sheets arrived at

    provides the sought tax base for the inflation ax calculations erformed

    below. It also provides the base for the inflation subsidy calculations,

    the inflation subsidy being defined below as the inflation-erosion f net

    financial ssets of CPS in hands

    of the private sector which is not

    compensated y interest payments.

    6. The plan of this Annex is as follows. The first step taken to

    calculate the inflation ax (IT) is to derive the CPS balance sheet; this

    is done in Section B. The IT calculations re performed in

    Section C.

    Finally, comments on the evolution f the IT and its relationship ith the

    macroeconomic nvironment re left to *Section .

    B. The Consolidated Public Sector Balance Sheet

    7. The balance sheets of the non-financial nd financial ublic

    sectors are presented in the first sub-section. Then the CPS balance sheet

    is analyzed. The last subsection shows a table with the different interest

    rates imputed to different groups of assets and liabilities.

    The Balance Sheets

    8. The sectors (and subsectors) ere chosen considering the

    presentation

    f the monetary accounts of the financial ystem utilized by

    the Central Reserve Bank and reported in "Nota Semanal". The sectors and

    the notation employed are:

    - The Non-Financial ublic Sector (NFPS), of which the Central

    Government is part (the other main subsectors eing public sector

    enterprises, rovincial governments nd decentralized gencies.)

    - The System of Public Sector Banks (PB), (excluding

    ommercial

    banks and COFIDE)2/ hich is formed by the Central Reserve Bank

    (CRB), the Banco Nacion (BN) and the Banca de Fomento

    (BF).

    2/ The Banca Asociada and the recently nationalized commercial anks were

    not considered public financial institutions ecause, despite their

    state property, their lending to private sector is financed through

    private sector deposits and cancels out. The remainder (requirements n

    the Central Bank) are already considered as a liability f the Central

    Bank and, hence, form part of the base of the inflation ax in any case.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    14/149

    - 6 -

    -

    The Consolidated ublic Sector (CPS), hich comprises

    both PB

    and NFPS.

    -

    The Foreign Sector (F), composed

    of foreign creditors nd

    debtors.

    -

    The Non-Financial omestic Private Sector

    (SPR)

    - The Financial

    System

    (FS), which includes

    (apart from PB) the

    group of Non-Public

    Financial Institutions (NPB). NPB includes, in turn,

    CommercialBanks (BC) (see

    Footnote 2) and the Non-Banking

    Financial

    System

    (NB)

    (of which COFIDE, the Development inance

    Corporation, and

    "Financieras" re the most important institutions).

    -

    A miscellaneous tem is the specified

    n the monetary accounts

    as "Otros" (0).

    The assets and liabilities onsidered are:

    - Deposits (D)

    - Foreign Currency Deposits (FCD)

    -

    Loans (L)

    -

    Net Loans (NL)

    - Real Capital (K)

    - Bonds

    (B)

    -

    Reserves (R)

    - Currency in Circulation (C)

    9. An asset, (e.g., D) held by sector i (e.g., BC) and originating n

    a

    transaction ith sector (e.g., CRB) is

    written as D[i,j]. In our

    example this would

    be D[BC,CRB] hich refers to deposits of

    BC on the CRB

    (these are

    principally legal

    and excess reserves

    of BC held in CRB). Note

    that in this

    case D[BC,CRB]

    appears as a liability

    n the balance

    sheet of

    the CRB and as

    an asset of BC. When

    an asset is held

    by more than one

    sector

    (or when it is

    originated in transactions

    ith more than one sector)

    this is indicated

    y a dash; e.g.,

    DrSPR-BC,BN] efers

    to deposits of SPR

    and

    BC at BN.

    10. The other items reported in the balance sheets are:

    - Net Worth (NW)

    - Other Accounts

    Net (OCN). A description

    f OCN is provided

    in

    ANNEX III.

    11. The simplified

    alance sheets of the NFPS, the CRB, BN and BF are

    reported in the following table:

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    15/149

    Table 2-1: THE BASIC BALANCE

    SHEETS

    (A

    -

    Assets/L

    -

    Liabilities)

    i. A Non-Financial Public Sector L

    K[NFPS,SPR-F]

    L(CRB,NFPS]

    D[NFPS,CRB] L*[BN,NFPS] /a

    D[NFPS.BN] I L[BN,NFPS]

    D[NFPS,BF] L[BC,NFPS]

    D[NFPS,BC]

    I L[BF,NFPS]

    L[NB,NFPS]

    B[BC-SPR,NFPS]

    /b

    NL[F,NFPS]

    NW[NFPS]

    il.

    A Central Reserve Bark L

    R[CRB,F] | NL[F,CRB]

    L[CRB,BF]

    I C[SPR,CRB]

    L[CRB,BC]

    I

    D[BN,CRB] /c

    L[CRB,NB]

    I

    D BF,CRB /c

    L[CRB,BN] I D[BC,CRB]

    L[CRB,GC] D[SPR,CRBJ

    OCN[CRB] | FCD[FS,CRB] /d

    L[CRB,O] I D[O,CRB]

    | D[NFPS,CRB]

    i NW[CRB]

    iii. A Banco Nacion L

    R[BN,F] I NL[F,BNJ

    OCN[BN] D(SPR,BN]

    L[BN,NFPS]

    I FCD[SPR,BN]

    L[BN,SPR] | D[NFPS,BN]

    D[BN,CRB] /c | L[CRB,BN]

    L[BN,BC] | D[BC,BN]

    L[BN,BF] | L[BF,BN]

    L*[BN,NFPS] /a

    I

    NW[BN]

    iv. A Banca de Fomento L

    R[BF,F]

    I

    NL[F,BF]

    L[BF,NFPS] D[SPR,BF]

    LfBF,SPR] I

    FCD[SPR,BF]

    D[BF,CRB]

    /e I L[CRB,BF]

    L[BF,BN] L[BN,BF]

    LIBF,BC] D[BC,BF]

    OCN[BF] D[NFPS,BF]

    NW[BF]

    /a With CRB resources.

    /b Includes "Bono Tipo C" issued by COFIDE.

    /c Includes legal reserves on FCD.

    /d Excludes legal reserves on FCD of BF and BN.

    /e Includes legal reserves on FCD.

    The Consolidated Public Sector Balance Sheet

    12. The balance

    sheet of the CPS reported in Table 2-2 was obtained

    consolidating

    the balance sheets of NFPS, CRB, BN

    and BF. Assets and

    liabilities

    of the CPS were grouped into different

    categories, each of

    which was imputed a different interest rate (see Table

    2-3).

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    16/149

    -8 -

    Table

    2-2z

    THE CONSOLIDATEC

    UBLIC SECTOR

    BALANCE

    SHEET

    A

    Consolidated

    ublic

    Sector

    L

    K[NFPS,SPR]

    LF

    =

    NL[F,NFPS]

    NL[F,CRB]

    +

    OCN[CRB-BF-BN]

    + NL[F,BN]

    +

    NL[F,BF]

    R[CRB-BN-BF,F]

    | NW

    L[PB,BC-SPR]

    L[BF,BC]

    + | C

    +

    L[BN,BC]

    + B[SPR-BC,NFPS]

    + L[CRB,BC]

    | L[NPB,NFPS]

    L[BC,NFPS]

    +

    L(BF,SPR]

    i

    + L[NB,NFPS]

    +

    L[BN,SPR]

    | EME

    =

    FCD[FS,CRB]

    +

    L[CRB,NB]

    i EMN = D[BC,CRB]

    + D[SPR,CRB]

    D[NFPS,BCJ

    j

    + D(O.CRB]

    FCD[SPP.,BN-BF]

    D(SPR-BC,BN-BF]

    Notation:

    EFL are

    reserve requirements

    (including

    xcess

    reserves)

    n FCD

    of FS in CRB.

    EMN are reserve

    requirements

    (including

    xcess

    reserves)on

    deposits

    of NPB and

    SPR in

    CRB.

    LF are

    net foreign

    loans

    to CPS.

    NW stands

    for total

    public

    sector

    net worth.

    C

    is currency in circulation.

    Imputed

    Interest

    Rates

    13.

    The data

    source

    for each

    type of asset

    was the

    Central

    Reserve

    Bank's

    publication

    "Nota

    Semanal"

    (NS),

    various numbers.

    The

    interest

    rates

    imputed

    to the groups of

    assets

    of the

    CPS balance

    sheet

    are

    described

    in

    Table

    2-3 (all interest

    rates are

    effective

    rates

    and are

    averages

    for

    the period).

    Most

    of the

    interest

    rate data

    was

    provided

    by

    the

    "Subgerencia

    el

    SectorMonetario"

    of the

    CRB (SGSM).

    The LIBOR

    intere.t

    rate was

    obtained

    from

    the IMF FinancialStatistics (IMF-FS).

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    17/149

    Table 2-3: IMPUTED INTEREST ATES

    Asset Group

    Interest Rate (Description nd Notation) Source

    C institutionally ixed at zero

    B[SPR,NFPS] i(b): average

    return on "Bonos Tipo

    C"

    of COFIDE for

    1984-87; does

    not

    account for fiscal

    benefit (these

    bonds are tax-deductible)

    NS

    L[NPB,NFPS]

    i(nDb): is the interest

    rate of BC for

    90 days "Descuento" oans (for 1980-85)

    and for 360 days loans (for 1986-87) SGSM

    EMN

    i(emn): until

    1983 is the

    passive

    interest rate for saving deposits;(data n

    remuneration f reserves was not available),

    since 1984 it is the remuneration f

    reserves

    ("encaje xigible") f BC SGSM

    EME i(el2e): s

    1

    plus the LIBOR 90 days

    interest

    rate times 1

    plus

    the rate

    of

    devaluation f the official exchange rate IMF-FS

    minus one

    and NS

    D[SPR,BC-BF]

    i(ci): interest rate of "Cedulas

    Hipotecarias"

    SGMS

    FCD[SPR,BN-BF] i(fcd): idem i(eme)

    L(PB,BC-SPR]

    i(red): rediscounting

    nterest rate of

    Banco Agrario until 1984

    and a simple

    average

    of "Selectivo

    grario" and

    "Fomento gropecuario" oans thereafter

    SGSM

    D[NFPS,BC] i(dep): fixed term deposits for 90-180

    days at BC

    SGSM

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    18/149

    - 10 -

    C. Calculation f the Inflation ax (IT)

    14. The broad inflation tax is defined here as the inflation-

    amortization

    of the principal of monetary and financial

    liabilities f the

    CPS held by the domestic private

    sector which is not compensated y

    interest

    payments. To illustrate this assume

    that the only two public debt

    instruments

    re currency and fixed int rest short-term onds. In the case

    of currency,

    since it bears an institutionally ixed zero rate of interest

    (i.e., there is no compensation or the inflation-amortization f the

    stock), the inflation ax is equal to the whole inflation-amortization f

    the stock (that is, the loss in real value of the stock of currency). On

    the other hand, bond holders are compensated for the inflation-induced rop

    in value of the real stock of bonds by interest payments. If the interest

    rate does not suffice to compensate for the inflation-amortization f debt,

    the difference between the inflation-induced mortization f principal and

    the interest payments (i.e., the uncompensated nflation-amortization f

    debt)

    is

    deemed the inflation ax

    on bonds.

    15.

    Accordingly, mploying ominal interest rates to measure the

    compensation

    or the inflation-amortization f debt

    (that is, assum'ng a

    zero "benchmark"

    eal interest rate), the IT on a given debt instrument,

    measured in units of "goods" at the beginning of the period, is equal to

    the product of the stock of debt and the difference between the rate of

    inflation nd the nominal interest rate of that stock, all divided by one

    plus the

    rate of inflation. The total IT is then equal to the sum of the

    ITs

    on all public debt instruments.

    16. Therefore, employing he notation of the CPS balance sheet derived

    in paragraph 12, the total IT is:

    (1) IT = (1/1+inf)*(C*inf

    B[SPR,NFPS]j(inf i(b)) +

    + L[NPB,NFPS]*(inf i(npb))+ EMN*(inf i(emn))+

    +

    EME*(inf i(eme))+ D[SPR,BC-BF1*(inf i(ci)

    + FCD[SPR,BF-BN]*(inf

    i(fcd))}

    where:

    inf is the rate of inflation.

    17. A similarapproach can be employed to define and calculate the

    inflation subsidy (IS)

    which the CPS gives to the domesticprivate sector.

    The IS arises

    when the private sector

    borrows from the CPS at interest

    rates

    which are below

    the rate of inflation. In this case the inflation-

    erosionof private

    financial liabilities xceeds

    the cost of holding them,

    and there is an implicit subsidy

    to financial debtors. More

    precisely, the

    IS is defined as the

    inflation-amortization

    f financial ssets of the CPS

    in hands of the private sector which is not compensated

    y interest

    payments.

    Following the notation of

    the CPS balance sheet of Section

    B the

    IS can be calculated as follows:

    (2) IS = (l/l+inf)*{L[PB,BC-SPR]*(inf

    i(red))

    + D[NFPS,BC)*(inf i(dep))}

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    19/149

    -

    11

    -

    18. The net inflation-induced inancial ealth transfer from the

    private and the public sector is termed net inflation ax (MIT), and can be

    expressed s the difference between the IT and the I:

    (3) NIT = IT - IS.

    19. From the conceptual point of view inflationary

    axation can arise

    both from: (a) inflationary isperceptions, hich make inflation igher

    than originally anticipated, hereby rendering x-post real interest rates

    lower than ex-ante interest rates; or (b) institutional igidities in the

    determination f interest rates, which impede agents from adjusting ominal

    rates to anticipated inflation. In general, assessing the relative signi-

    ficance of both sources of inflationary axation (inflation isperceptions

    and institutional igidities) nvolves considerable ifficulty. The main

    difficulty stems from the fact that inflation xpectations re non-

    observable. However, the system of fixed and artificially ow interest

    rates, which have been prevailing in Peru since 1976 (and in particular

    since 1985), suggests that institutional igidities ave been the principal

    explanatory actor of the IT on financial ssets/liabilities.

    20. From equation (1) it is clear that only public financial and

    monetary liabilities eld by the domestic private sector are considered a

    source of IT. Real assets (such as K[NFPS,SPR]) re excluued because,

    unless their relative price changes, their nominal value moves along with

    inflation. Foreign liabilities (such as LF) or assets (such as R(CRB-BN-

    BF,F]) are neglected since their rate of return in domestic currency is

    equal to the external real interest rate plus domestic inflation nder

    purchasing power parity and, therefore, hey are perfectly indexed assets.3/

    21. The account OCN[CRB-BN-BF], hich approximates umulative

    operational osses of public banks (mainly the CRB, see ANNEX III), can be

    viewed as a non-performing sset (that is an asset with zero nominal

    return). Or else, the CPS balance sheet could have been presented

    substracting his item from the right-hand side of the balance sheet in

    which case the CPS net worth would have been smaller by a similar amount.

    3/ Under purchasing power parity:

    dev. = inf - inf*

    where: dev is the rate of devaluation

    inf is the domestic rate of inflation

    inf* is the foreign rate of inflation.

    The domestic currency nominal return on the foreign asset is equal to

    the sum of the foreign interest rate and the devaluation rate:

    i* + dev = i* - inf* + inf=

    = r* + inf

    where: i* is the foreign nominal interest rate and

    r* is the foreign real interest rate.

    Assuming that the external real interest rate is zero, the nominal

    return on the foreign asset is equal to inflation nder purchasing

    parity, i.e. the inflation-erosion f the foreign asset (prior to

    devaluation).

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    20/149

    - 12 -

    22. The data

    employed stocks

    f assets rd liabilities nd interest

    rates) re reported n Table 2-4. and the estimates f the IT, IS and NIT

    are in Table 2-5.

    Tabt. 2-4s l130c IOF AU ALIAIRZ3

    MD

    DIwa 95155

    ItO lost i 168 1is4 19W

    1956 19t?

    Stt ke (average,

    ill.1.tl8)

    C

    219 U

    582 71 :,6f 1,817 12,1W 23,1W

    st(W,Sp1 1

    418 1,030

    2,02

    8,218

    LO4P

    ,PJ

    */

    21

    as 61 1" m 7" 1,804 2,68

    E1 148 213 247 404

    725

    1,018 14,52t 20,58

    eM el

    180

    238

    68 1 06 4.o13 6,"6 5.04 6,444

    o(IPl,-6P 141 25 421 I4 1,244 2,6*0 5,828 11,124

    FGC6P3,I-IW

    41

    6a

    112

    2n

    ON 2,512 1,171 4,274

    LLft,K-5P11j me

    6t# 1.21t 2,608 6,064 120,9

    24,85S

    47,797

    D(WPNS,K S 14

    21

    a8

    110

    *U 1. 2,042

    nteret

    notes

    and In"flatio

    I(b) 33.1 6. 57. a 63.6 62.0 6.0 48.2 10.4

    i(np) 68.0 71.4

    6*.6 7.4

    *7.8

    119.6 40.0 6.5

    l(_,)

    8

    t2.6

    6.

    67.4

    66.6 60.0 76,4 38.8

    U8.

    I() 58.1

    72.6 116.0 114 1U8.3 160.6 6.6 158.6

    I(ci) *87.

    62.2

    61.6 66.0 78.5 72.1

    21.7 14.8

    i(fcd)

    55.1

    72.6 116.0 156.4 116.2 160.6

    6.6 158.6

    I(red)

    25.3 87.5

    870. 47.6 71.2 50.7 25.1

    24.4

    I (dep) 54.

    023. 70.6

    74.0

    60.2 1.5

    28.6 21.0

    l,,letlfi /60.6

    72.7 72.0 121.1 I.

    118.$

    61.0 114.5

    1906-IV 1997-1 1927-11 1917-411 167.11

    Stock.

    (averarm. gill. KatIe)

    C 14,100 16,216 16,216 24,637

    81,616

    (plR,WISl @/

    1,714

    1,62 1,714

    1,680 2,245

    LD6,WFPS) k/ 1,56

    1,5U 1,988 2,?72

    8,672

    EO 10,764 20,60 24,062 26,246 51,76

    EI IE

    8,7 24 8,670 8,581

    8,27 5,"7

    OESPRIM6-17] 6,920

    *,172

    9,l11 11,250 13,482

    PCOISPOIN48p 2,748

    2,604 2.751 2,747 4,275

    L(' ,C-1,J 28,064

    88,061

    $8,155 45*,68

    156.87

    DWPMS,K]

    1,721 2,206 2,264

    2,064 1,9S4

    Interest ate and Jntlet_et 9/

    I(b) S.t

    10.7 10.6 10.7 10.9

    I(npb) 6.0

    U.S 6.6

    6.0

    7.2

    I(am)

    6.8 6.8 O.& 7.7 7.0

    i(aea) 1.5 7.4

    9.0 2.2 114.9

    I(el) 6.0 5.0 5.4

    5.6 5.3

    l(fed) 1.S 7.4

    *.0

    2.2 114.9

    I(red)

    5.6

    5.6 5.6 5.6

    6.6

    I (dep)

    6.7 6.7 6.7 6.1

    6.0

    inflation

    l

    12.7

    1U.5 16.2

    22.7

    24.0

    I1 r

    1064 elY 'ksa. Tilpe C of COPIOII for 106-Ge alee Central

    GOver,mt

    banda In

    found for 1960.-U

    Apprite.td by

    L[C , IIF).

    e/ EMEOVre ti.atet net

    lgal rearvae on FC of SRI

    and tC bacause It

    slte

    co eritae

    legal rautrvte

    on fCD of

    ON

    and

    IF.

    ndilrect *atletes of the

    letter (aNlch

    are

    net

    reported In Nate S_rnal)

    suggest

    that EMS

    my

    _av bea overettilted 1S percent In

    196, 26

    perent Ia

    1966

    and 1i percent In 1ii7.

    d/ Anual

    Interet rates .ape In efectIve prcentao tare.

    The annual rate of Inflation (bta

    the Ieant ontU of the year end the leet month of

    the Previoet year) according to te coneumr Price Index of Lie.

     

    Qu"terIy Interea raOte 1 quarterly eff* ctiV Percentage.

    The quarterly rte of infltiotn (betae the leat eattf tib quarter a"d the eat

    otentb f the previous quarter) accordin, to the ceatamr pIet Index of Liet.

    Sourctt AlI

    a*eet

    eteche eare aepla avere" obtalned ftre "t Smaati

    (various numbrs). ibt Intereat rate serles were provided by the

    aS3|wt5g"io

    del Sector .ntaterlo' of the

    M

    and llf' P'nanaclal

    Statletite.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    21/149

    - 13 -

    Table 2-5: INFLATION

    AX ESTIMATES a/

    Inflation Inflation Net Inflation

    Tax (IT) Subsidy (IS) Tax (NIT IT-IS)

    (Intis) Z GDP) (Intis) (Z GDP) (Intis) (Z GDP)

    Annual

    1980 135 2.3 69 1.2 66 1.1

    1981 185 1.7 122 1.1 63 0.6

    1982 74 0.4 250 1.4 -175 -1.0

    1983 536 1.6 893 2.7 -357 -1.1

    1984 23r 0.3 1,162 1.6 -923 -1.3

    1985 5,037 2.5 5,532 2.8 -495 -0.3

    1986 11,783 3.2 5,868 1.6 5,914 1.6

    1987

    30,843 4.2 20,622

    2.8 10,221

    1.4

    Quarterly b/

    1986-IV 3,587 0.8 1,867 0.4 1,720 0.4

    1987-I 6,141 1.2 3,849 0.8 2,292 0.5

    1987-II 6,613 1.0 4,415 0.6 2,198 0.3

    1987-III 10,925 1.4 4,974 0.6 5,951 0.7

    1987-IV 7,164 0.8 9,001 1.0 -1,837 -0.2

    a/ The above calculations re based on equations: (1) for the IT, (2) for

    the IS and (3) for the NIT. These assume that

    the benchimark eal

    interest rate is zero (See Footnote 1).

    b/ Since INE does not provide quarterly figures of GDP, the

    annualized

    quarterly

    figures of GDP employed were

    obtained by multiplying the

    annualized quarterly level of GDP reported by the CRB (base 1970) by

    the ratio between

    the annual GDP figures of CRB and INE.

    23.

    The inflation tax and inflation subsidy calculations ere repeated

    assuming a 5 percent

    benchmark real interest rate (instead

    of the zero

    percent assumed before). This implies that the interest compensatior.or

    inflationis smaller than the nominal

    interest rate by approximately

    5 percentage points.4/ The results are reported in

    Table 2.6.

    4/ More rigorously and following

    he notation of Footnote 1, the

    compensation for inflation is, [(1

    +

    i/1.05)1 1 where

    i is the nominal

    interest rate.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    22/149

    - 14 -

    'rable-6: INFLATION AX ESTIMATES

    a/

    Inflation Inflation Net Inflation

    Period Tax (IT) Subsidy (IS) Tax

    (NIT)

    (intis) (%GDP) (intis) (ZGDP) (intis) (ZGDP)

    1980 160.0 2.6 80.6 1.4 79.4 1.2

    1981 222.3 2.1 145.5 1.4 76.8 0.7

    1982 155.5 0.9 298.4

    1.7 -142.9 -0.8

    1983 679.9 2.1 983.0 3.0 -303.1 -0.9

    1984 652.2 0.9 1,401.0 1.9 -748.8 -1.0

    1985 6,395.6 3.2 5,781.9 2.9 613.7 0.3

    1986 13,139.0 3.6 6,827.0 1.8 6,312.0 1.8

    1987 31,564.0 4.3 22,095.0 3.0 9,469.0 1.3

    a/ The above estimates re based on equations (1) for the IT, (2) for the

    IS and (3) for the NIT, assuming that the benchmark, real interest rate

    is 5 percent; i.e. in equations (1) and (2) i () should be replaced by

    (1 + i ())/1.05 1 (see Footnote 4.)

    D. The Inflation ax: Evolutionand Its Relationsh

    with the Macroeconomic

    nvironment

    24. Coinciding ith the program of economic

    liberalization mplemented

    in 1981-84, the inflation tax and the net inflation tax followed a downward

    trend (only temporarily nterrupted

    n the case of the inflation ax in

    1983, see Tables 2-5

    and 2-6). This was mainly due to higher interest

    rates on public financial liabilities inflation

    ctually rose) and the

    dollarization f the economy

    (in 1982-85 the average return on foreign

    currency

    deposits was on average 37 percent higher than the rate of

    inflation, see paragraph 26). Since 1985, the inflation ax rose steadily

    from 0.3/0.9 percent of GDP in 1984 to 4.2/4.3 percent of GDP in 1987

    (according o whether the benchmark real interest rate is 0 or 5 percent

    respectively). Inflation, ogether with low nominal interest rates and a

    dedollarized conomy (as measured by the share of foreign currency deposits

    in total liabilities f the financial ystem), were the factors to blame

    for the inflation tax increase.

    25. In 1983, as the drop in the conventional ax

    revenue led to a

    record fiscal deficit, inflationary axation grew from 0.4/0.9 percent of

    GDP

    to 1.6/2.1 percent. A similar pattern was

    reproduced in 1986-87. In

    those circumstances nflation ressures ere the result of

    high public

    deficits and expansionary

    financial olicies. The exchange rate was frozen

    in 1985 and lagged behind

    inflation ntil the fourth quarLer

    of 1987, and

    no major adjustments

    n public sector prices and tariffs

    were implemented

    until

    early 1988. Inflation nd the policy

    of lowering ominal interest

    rates, i.e., lowering the compensation or the inflation-induced rosion of

    the principal of debt, propelled jump in the 1987 inflation ax level to

    three times its average 1984-85 level (measured s a percent of GDP).

    Between the same periods the tax revenue of the central government dropped

    from 11.7 percent of GDP to 8.5 percent.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    23/149

    - 15

    -

    26.

    The

    dollarization

    f

    the economy

    in

    1983-85

    was

    the

    result

    of

    the

    attempt

    by

    private

    agents

    to

    escape

    the inflation

    ax

    as well

    as the

    liberal

    measures

    which

    allowed

    foreign

    currency

    deposits

    in the

    financial

    system.

    On

    the

    other

    hand,

    although

    since 1985

    dedollarization

    ollowed

    mainly

    from

    the

    suspension

    f

    convertibility

    f

    foreign

    currency

    deposits

    into foreign currency, he policy of fixing the exchange rate (and the

    subsequent

    real

    appreciation)

    lso

    played

    a role.

    This

    became

    particularly

    obvious

    after

    the

    official

    exchange

    rate

    devaluations

    f

    the last

    quarter

    of

    1987

    have

    raised

    significantly

    he

    return

    on foreign

    currency

    deposits.

    However,

    by

    then,

    the

    low share

    of

    foreign

    currency

    deposits

    in

    total

    financial

    liabilities

    ad

    left

    depositors

    eakly

    hedged

    against

    inflationary

    axation.

    27.

    Inflation

    as

    also

    induced

    financial

    ealth

    transfers

    (implicit

    subsidies)

    from

    the

    public

    to the

    private

    sector.

    A

    measure

    of these

    is

    given

    by

    the

    inflation

    ubsidy

    estimated

    in

    Section

    C. The

    inflation

    subsidy

    rose

    from 1.2/1.4

    percent of GDP in 1980 to 2.7/3 percent in 1983

    (according

    o

    whether

    the benchmark

    real

    interest

    rate

    is zero

    or

    5

    percent).

    Thereafter,

    it

    exhibited

    an oscillatory

    ehavior

    reaching

    a

    level

    equivalent

    to

    2.8/2.9

    percent

    of GDP

    in 1985

    and

    2.8/3

    percent

    in

    1987.

    28.

    However,

    the

    on average

    higher

    level

    of

    the

    inflation

    ubsidy

    did

    not suffice

    to

    neutralize

    the

    upward

    trend

    in

    the

    inflation

    ax.

    As

    a

    consequence,

    the

    average

    net

    inflation

    ax

    (the

    difference

    etween

    the

    inflation

    tax and

    subsidy)

    has risen

    from

    -0.41-0.8

    ercent

    of GDP

    in

    1984-85

    to

    1.5/1.6

    percent

    in

    1986-87.

    Between

    the

    same

    periods

    the

    central

    government

    tax

    revenue

    dropped

    from

    11.8

    percent

    of

    GDP to

    8.8

    percent. This suggests that there

    has

    been

    strong

    substitution

    etween

    conventional

    and

    inflationary

    ources

    of

    taxation.

    Since

    the

    inflation

    ax

    is a

    more

    regressive

    ind

    of tax

    (from

    the

    income

    distribution

    oint

    of

    view),

    this

    substitution

    s bound

    to

    have

    had adverse

    social

    effects.

    29.

    Moreover,

    to

    the

    extent

    that the

    beneficiaries

    f

    the

    inflation

    subsidy

    tend to

    differ

    from

    those

    who

    bear

    the inflation

    tax

    burden,

    inflation

    ay

    have

    distributional

    ffects

    even

    if the

    net

    inflation

    ax

    was

    zero.

    Since

    the

    recipients

    of subsidized

    redit

    are

    producers

    (themost

    important

    eing

    agricultural

    roducers),

    inflation

    s

    bound

    to induce

    transfers

    f financial

    ealth

    from

    cash holders

    and

    bank

    depositors

    to

    poor

    "campesinos" nd other beneficiaries f subsidized RB credit. Although

    this could

    be

    justified

    n

    income

    distribution

    rounds

    if the holders

    of

    liquid

    assets

    were

    sufficiently

    icher

    than

    the

    beneficiaries

    f subsidized

    credit,

    it

    could

    not

    be justified

    on

    efficiency

    grounds

    since it

    implies

    taxing

    savings

    and

    the

    use

    of money

    (a

    commodity

    ith

    high

    productivity

    that

    society

    can

    produce

    at negligible

    cost).

    Since,

    in

    addition,

    there

    is

    evidence

    that

    poorer

    consumers

    are the

    main

    holders

    of cash,

    it

    is

    not

    warranted

    to

    tax

    them

    in

    order

    to finance

    the poor,

    but

    perhaps

    not

    necessarily

    oorer

    "campesinos".

    Taxing

    the rich

    through

    direct

    conventional

    taxes is

    a more

    desirable

    venue.

    A similar

    reasoning

    ould

    be

    applied

    for

    wealth

    transfers

    etween

    private

    agents

    through

    the

    banking

    system: low and middle income bank depositorssubsidizefirmswho are large

    enough

    to

    be

    able

    to borrow

    from

    banks.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    24/149

    - 16 -

    30. Under the present circumstances, s further relative price

    realignments

    eem inevitable nd,

    given that the nearly depleted level of

    foreign exchange reserves cannot cushion further demand pressures, the

    policy of maintaining low nominal interest rates can only enhance the risk

    of inflationary

    axation. Moreover, since the process

    of financial

    disintermediation s quite advanced and accelerating, .e., the inflation

    tax base is shrinking ast, collecting a similar level of inflation revenue

    would require ever increasing inflation rates.

    31. Unless serious fiscal measures are undertaken the monetary effects

    of the fiscal and financial imbalance ill fuel the inflationary rocess to

    even more worrying levels. The socially regressive ffects of inflationary

    taxation are bound to show quickly into a further deterioration f the

    government's olitical strength and into greater social disintegration.

    This, though, may be

    the cost that society and the government s

    part of it

    has to bear in order to be ready to accept the fiscal and financial remedy.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    25/149

    -17-

    ANNEX3

    THE CENTRAL BANK'S QUASI-FISCAL

    EFICIT

    A.

    Introduction

    1.

    The Central Reserve

    Bank's (CRB) intervention

    n Peru's financial

    and foreign

    exchange markets has

    created subsidies

    to the private sector

    with budgetary implications. Those

    subsidies, onventionally

    eferred to

    as the quasi-fiscal

    eficit of the CRB,

    have recently become an important

    source

    of primary money

    creation. The sources

    of the quasi-fiscal

    deficit

    (QFD) examined here are

    interest rate and

    foreign exchange losses.

    Interest

    rate losses occur when the interest

    the CRB pays on its

    liabilities

    (mainly reservesof the financial

    ystem, since currency

    in

    hands of the public

    pays zero interest)

    s higher than

    the interest it

    receives on

    its assets (mainly

    credit to the government,

    redit to the

    Banca de Fomento, rediscountfacilitiesand international eserves).

    Foreign

    exchange losses arise

    when the average

    buying price of foreign

    exchange

    by the CRB exceeds

    the average selling

    price. During the 1985-87

    period

    foreign exchange losses

    were due to the

    fact that the average

    exchange rate

    paid to exportersand other sellers

    of foreign exchange

    (including hose

    offering foreign exchange

    to the governmentin the open

    market) exceeded,

    on average, the exchange

    rate charged to

    importers nd

    financial ebtors.

    2.

    Interest rate losses

    were

    estimated

    y two

    methods: i) directly,

    from analyzing

    the movements in

    the sub-account ermed

    "Costo por

    Regulacionde Exceso de Liquidez"of the CRB account "Otras Cuentas Netas"

    (which, reportedly, easures

    precisely interest

    rate losses); and ii)

    indirectly,

    hrough measurement

    of the average

    return on CRB assets

    and

    liabilities. ikewise, foreign

    exchange losses were

    also estimated:

    i)

    directly,

    through inspection

    f the movements in the sub-account

    ermed

    "Diferencial

    ambiario" of

    the CRB account "Otras

    Cuentas Netas";

    and ii)

    indirectly, omparing

    average buying and

    selling exchange rates.

    For

    reasons given below

    (paragraph 8) the direct measurement

    f QFD is deemed

    more

    reliable that' he

    indirect one. The

    adequacy of the direct measurement

    of the QFD hinges on the

    specific accounting

    ethodology

    employed by the

    CRB of Peru.

    Thus, it cannot be assured that

    the same approach

    will be

    valid for similar

    studies of other

    countries. The indirect easurement

    f

    QFD, apart from

    serving as a check

    for the direct

    measurement, ermits

    assessing the

    composition f

    foreign exchange

    and interest rate losses

    (which

    the direct measurement

    does not convey). The

    direct estimate

    of QFD

    is

    performed in Section B and the indirect

    estimate

    in Section C. The

    evolution

    of QFD is analyzed

    in Section D.

    B. Direct Estimate to The

    Quasi-Fiscal

    Deficit (QFD)

    Foreign

    Exchange Subsidies

    3.

    The sub-account

    Diferencial ambiario" of the

    CRB account "Otras

    Cuentas Netas" measures: i) foreign exchange losses due to the difference

    between buying

    and selling exchange

    rates; and ii) accounti-g capital

    losses/profits rising

    from changes in

    the Inti valuation of the CRB's

    assets

    (including old)

    and liabilities enominated n foreign

    currencies

    due to

    either changes in the inti/US$ exchange

    rate or to changes

    in the

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    26/149

    -18-

    rates f other

    relevant urrencies and old) gainst

    he US$. However,

    here the focusis only on tte former

    osses ince hey

    entail subsidy nd

    its financing eads

    o monetary xpansion.For

    his reason his item should

    be added

    to the

    public

    ector eficit.

    y contrast

    he

    latter

    losses/profitsre capital

    ains/lossesn the

    CRB net position

    n foreign

    exchange nd therefore o not entail er se monetary xpansion. herefore,

    the exercise hatfollows s

    concer.ed ith

    estimating hich

    part of the

    movement n the account

    Diferencialambiario" eflects

    osses ue to

    exchange ate subsidies.

    e refer enceforth o this item as "foreign

    exchange ubsidies" FES)

    o distinguish t

    from the more general

    erm

    'foreign

    exchange

    losses".

    4.

    More precisely, hanges

    n the sub-accountDiferencialambiario"

    (CDC) easure,

    part from FES, the change n value f the net foreign

    exchange osition FEP) f the CRB (termed Posicion

    e Cambio III" in CRB

    publications)t the beginning

    f the period. hus, if FEP,(t-l,t)s the

    FEP of time (t-l) alued

    t exchange ates f time t:

    (1) CDC = FES

    - [FEP(t-l,t)

    FEP(t-1,t-l)]

    The FEP measures

    ross foreign xchange eserves including old) inus

    short nd

    long run foreign iabilities

    f the CRB (principallyith

    the

    IMF, i.e.

    SDR's) nd minus foreign urrency bligations

    ith domestic

    residents. he

    main components f FEP

    which are not denominatedn US$ are

    gold reserves nd SDR's liabilitieso the IMF. It is assumed

    or

    simplicity nd in the

    absence f proper nformationhat the rest of the

    assets/liabilities

    re stipulated

    n US$. ThusFEP can be written:l/

    (2) FEP'(t,t)

    =

    e(t)x[G*(t) g(t)

    -

    S*(t) x s(t) + R*(t)]

    where:

    e (t) is the inti/US$ xchange ate at time t.

    G* (t) is

    the stock f gold at time t (in

    physical nits).

    g (t) is the

    CRB accounting rice

    of gold at time t in

    USs.

    S*

    (t) is the stock f SDR' liabilities

    ith the IMF at

    time t.

    s

    (t) is the exchange ate

    of SDR's at time t in

    US$.

    R* (t) are othernet assets/liabilities

    f the CRB (after

    deducting oreign

    urrency bligationsith

    residents)t time t in US$.

    1/ Note that stocks n Intis ear a

    " '

    n and

    stocks n other currencies

    bear a " * n

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    27/149

    -19-

    It thus follows that the change in value between time (t-l) and time (t) of

    the FEP existing at the beginning f period (t) is:

    (3) FEP'(t-l,t)-FEP'(t-l,t-l) G*(t-l) x [g(t) x e(t)

    -g(t-1) x e(t-1)] - S(t-1)

    x

    [o(t) x e(t) -

    s(t-l) x e(t-l)]

    + R*(t-l) x [e(t) - ^(t-l']

    =

    e(t) x G*(t-l) x lg(t) - g(t-l)]

    -

    e(t)

    x S*(t-l)x[s(t)

    - s(t-l)]

    + [e(t) - e(t-l)] x [G*(t-l)

    x g(t-l) - S*(t-l) x s(t-l)

    + R*(t-l)]

    =

    e(t) x G*(t-l) x [g(t) - g(t-l)]

    -e(t)

    x S*(t-1) x [s(t - s(t-l)]

    + [e(t) - e(t-l)] x FEP'(t-l,t-l)

    The first term measures the revaluation f gold due to the appreciation f

    gold with respect to the US dollar; the second term

    measures the

    revaluation f SDR's due to the appreciation f SDR's with respect to the

    US dollar; and the third term

    captures the revaluation f the FEP of (t-l)

    due to the inti devaluation

    ith respect

    to the US dollar. Substituting

    "changes in the FEP"

    of equation (3) in equation

    (1) we arrive at the

    expression for FES employed for its direct estimate:

    (4) FES' = CDC + e(t) x G*(t-l) x [g(t)

    -

    g(t-l)]

    -

    e(t) x

    S*(t-1) x [s(t) - s(t-1)] + [e(t) - e(t-1)] x

    FEP'(t-l,t-l)

    5. The official benchmark exchange rate (MUC) is the accounting rate

    used by

    the CRB for the inti valuation

    of foreign exchange

    assets/liabilities. However, actual transactions ake place at a set of

    premia and discounts on it. Other transactions ake place at the rate of

    the Mesa de Negociacion (MN). These rates constitute he basic system of

    multiple exchange ra'.es t which trade and capital transactions ake place.

    In order to estimate directly FES arising from multiple exchange rates the

    other items of equation (4), that is, changes in the dollar valuation of

    gold and SDR's, and the revaluation f the net foreign exchange position

    due to domestic devaluations, ust be estimated. Annex Table 3.1 reports

    estimates for each of these items and the resulting irect estimate of FES

    based on equation (4):

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    28/149

    -20-

    Tabl- $-Is DIRECTESTIMATEF FOREIGN XCHANGEUBSIDIES

    (in illon lntl.)

    1986-I 1986-II 1958-I 1986-Il 1987-I 1987-II

    A. Changesn the

    'Diferencial

    CamblarioO/ 6,012 4,878 2,870 -366 -2,045 23,011

    8. Gold pprociationia

    a vie theUSS b/ -618 0 0 0 3806 1040

    Ce t)

    x O*(t-1) (g(t) -

    g(t-1))J

    C. Revaluationf SDR's

    liabilitiesiea via

    thaUSs c/ 185 88a 687 180 722 2,498

    tE(t) S*(t-1) (s(t) -(t-l))]

    D. Revaluationf foreign

    exchangeosition FEP)

    due to devaluationsf

    the official xchange

    rate /

    -8,a89 -1,479

    0 0

    211 -7,528

    [(e(t) *(t-1)) FEP'(t-1,t-I)]

    E. Foreign xchange

    Subsidy FES) W88 2,611 2,183 -646 749 14,626

    [E = A

    +

    8 C e D]

    from

    equation

    4)

    a/ Obtained rom the CRB account Otras uentas etss8I

    Change n the CR8 accountingrice f gold, n USS, ultpliledy the

    beginnlng of period tock f

    gold oserves nd theend f period UC

    exchange ate.

    Change n the US$ value ,f SDR's nd

    the end of period UC exchange

    rate.

    The not foreign xchangeposition

    termed Posicione Cambi) ll1

    In

    -

    CRB publications)

    n US dollars ultipliedy the Increase

    n he

    exchange ate Intis er dollar very onth quarters in 1986-I) hen

    there

    as a devalustion.

    he

    total EP reported s equal o

    the

    sum of

    all monthly

    (quarterly) revaluation.

    Source: Note omenal variousumbers) nd *Subgerenciael

    Sector oneterlo'f Cha.

    Financial Losses

    6.

    The QFD is also composed of financial,

    r interest rate, losses.

    As it was mentioned before these losses derive from the fact that the CRB

    has an average return on its assets smaller than the average cost of its

    funds. Financial losses are

    measured with precision by the sub-account

    "Costo por Regulacion de Exceso de Liquidez" of the CRB account "Otras

    Cuentas Netas". Table 3.2 reports both estimates of financial losses (the

    change in value of the sub-account Costo por Regulacion de Exceso de

    Liquidez") and foreign exchange subsidies (derived in Table 3.1). Their

    sum, QFD, is also reported in Annex Table 3.2 (in nominal terms, in real

    terms and as a proportion of GDP).

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    29/149

    -21-

    TABLE

    .2: DIRECT STIMATES

    F CFD */

    (in illion ntla)

    86-I 86-II 1986

    86-I 86-II 1988 87-I 87-II 1987

    A. Financial

    Losses l/

    -mlt. I7.

    0 899

    899 1,641

    8,783

    5,874

    1,7683 4,337 6,100

    B.

    Foreign

    Exchange

    Subsidy /

    -mil. /. 869

    2,611 2,879 2,188

    -646 1,688 749

    14,626 16,874

    C.Quai-

    Fiscal

    D etict

    A + B

    -mil. I/. 868 3,410

    8,778

    3,824

    8,188

    7,012 2,612 18,962 21,474

    -U

    ODP 0.2

    1.7 1.9 1.0

    0.8 1.8 0.3 2.6 2.8

    Memorandumtem:

    Nominal CDP

    -nil.

    1/. 199,846

    881,022

    760,168

    Notes. a/

    TheCRB sub-accountCosto orRegulacion

    Exceso e Liquldozw.

    Si Foreign

    exchange ubsidy (FES)

    obtained In Table 3.1.

    Source:

    Nota Seminal (various

    numbers), INE, Table 3.1 nd

    Subgerencla del Sector

    MonetarloCR8).

    C.

    Indirect Estimate of

    the Quasi-Fiscal Deficit

    7.

    In order to provide

    a double check

    of the previous estimates, an

    additional exercise

    was carried out.

    In this exercise: a)

    foreign exchange

    subsidies were calculated

    through comparing

    buying and selling

    exchange

    rates

    of the foreign exchange

    transactions of the CRB; and b) financial

    losses,

    through comparison

    of interest rates applicable

    to CRB's financial

    assets

    and liabilities.

    Foreign Exchange Subsidies

    (FES)

    8. Ideally,

    if the volume of

    purchases of foreign

    exchange by the CRB

    equalled the

    volume of sales, FES could be calculated

    by subtracting the

    weighted

    average exchange rate of all purchases

    from the weighted

    average

    exchange rate of all sales, and

    multiplying that difference

    by the volume

    of purchases

    (or sales). In general,

    though, the

    volume of purchases

    differs from the volume of sales, i.e.

    the CRB either accumulates

    or draws

    down foreign

    exchange reserves. In this

    case, a convenient procedure to

    calculate

    FES is to select a :^eference r accounting exchange

    rate. The

    measurement of FES

    will of course vary with the choice

    made of the

    reference

    exchange rate.

    The reference rate may

    be, for example, the

    average historic cost of foreign

    reserves, some

    sort of market average

    exchange

    rate or, as in the

    case of the CRB, the official MUC exchange

    rate.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    30/149

    -22-

    9. More formally,

    FES can

    be measured

    as follows:21

    (5) FES = (ep - e) x P - (es -e) x S

    where: P is the volume of

    purchases

    S is the volume of sales

    e is the reference exchange rate

    ep is the purchase price of foreign exchange

    es is the selling price of foreign exchange

    i.e. FES arise whenever the CRB buys foreign exchange at a price

    above the

    reference exchange rate, or sells foreign exchange at a price belnw the

    reference exchange rate. If the first

    term is positive (the second term is

    negative) the CRB is purchasing

    (selling) foreign exchange above the

    reference price, and is therefore making a loss (gain). Thus, if both the

    purchase and selling

    price are above the reference exchange rate there will

    be FES if the first term is larger than the second one. Note that if the

    volume of sales equals the volume of purchases, the previous formula

    becomes the product of the volume of transactions and the difference

    between the purchase and sale exchange rates.

    10. The indirect estimate of FES performed here is based on equation

    (5). To facilitate comparisons with the direct estimate of FES obtained in

    the previous section, the accounting exchange rate used by the CRB (that

    is, the KUC rate) was chosen as the reference exchange rate.

    11. The indirect estimate of FES provided here measures only FES

    originated: in import and export transactions and in CRB direct purchases

    of foreign exchange from residents in the open market. Due to

    the lack of

    data any other balance of payment transaction are excluded. Hence, the

    calculation here is only partial and it is conducted to identify the main

    items that explain FES, but in no way

    are meant to challenge the direct

    estimates of the previous section. Based on equation 5, total FES were

    calculated as

    the difference between the sum of items a) to c) below:

    a) The flow of CRB purchases of foreign exchange from exporters

    was multiplied by the average spread between the purchase

    price and the MUC exchange rate

    (that is, the CRB accounting

    exchange rate). This captures FES originated in purchases to

    exporters.

    b) The flow of CRB purchases of foreign exchange from residents

    in the free market was multiplied

    by the average spread

    between the average buying price and the MUC exchange rate.

    This measures FES originated in purchases to residents.

    C) The flow of CRB sales of foreign exchange to importers was

    multiplied by the average spread between the sale price and

    the MUC exchange rate. This measures FES originated in sales

    to importers. Note that the difference between a) and c;

    measures FES originated in foreign trade alone.

    2/ Following the presentation of the Paraguay Country Economic Memorandum

    (Report No. 7031-PA, Annex III).

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    31/149

    -23-

    12.

    The indirect

    estimate

    of FES,

    and

    the corresponding

    ata

    employed,

    are reported

    in Annex

    Table

    3-3.

    It

    can be

    seen that

    FES in

    this

    calculation

    iffer

    considerably

    rom

    the

    direct

    estimates

    f FES

    performed

    in the

    previous

    section.

    This may

    be due,

    apart

    from

    the omissions

    mentioned

    above,

    to the

    lack

    of proper

    weighted

    average

    exchange

    rates for

    items a) to c) as well as to the lack of a reliable figureof CRB purchases

    of foreign

    exchange

    to residents.

    Table 8.8:

    NDIRECT

    CTIMATE

    FFOREIGN

    XCHANGE

    UBSIDIES

    86-I 8S-II

    1986

    86-I

    86-II

    1986 87-I 87-II

    1987

    A.

    Flows f

    Purchases

    ndSales

    million

    Sf)

    $.

    Exports

    1,493

    1,527

    3,020

    1,210 1,299

    2,609

    1,254

    1,306

    2,659

    2. Imports

    782

    788 1,570

    1,051

    1,474

    2,626

    1,821

    1,682 2,903

    3.

    Purchaseo o

    Residents

    /

    -

    861

    361

    395 82

    477

    88

    202

    238

    B. Average

    xchange

    ate

    Premium ver

    he MUC

    (intis

    er US$)

    4. Exports

    -0.03

    0.13 0.06

    0.32

    0.96

    0.64

    2.77 6.73

    4.76

    5. Imports

    0.00

    0.04 0.02

    0.17

    1.08

    0.62

    2.60 4.28

    3.39

    8. Purchases

    Residents

    0.00

    8.46

    1.72 .46

    3.8

    86.8

    6.40 22.80

    13.80

    C. Foreign

    xchange

    ubsidies

    FES) /

    7. Exports

    (1x4)

    -46

    198

    163 398

    1,261

    1,644

    8,471

    8,782 12,263

    8. Imports

    (2x6)

    0 -33

    -33

    -181 -1,669

    1,740

    3,298

    -6,771

    10,089

    9. Foreign

    rade

    (7 8) -46

    186

    120

    212

    -808

    -96

    173 2,011

    2,184

    10.Purchases

    o

    Residents

    3 x 6)

    0

    1,211

    1,211

    1,383

    300 1,863

    194

    4,601

    4,696

    11.Total ES

    (9 + 10)

    -46

    1,376

    1,331

    1,676

    -8 1,667

    387

    86,12

    8,879

    -as

    X GDP

    (0) (0.7) (0.7)

    (0.4)

    (0) (0.4)

    (*06)

    (0. 6)

    (0.9)

    Memorandum

    tem:

    Nominal DP

    (million

    f Intis)

    199,845

    381,022

    760,166

    a'

    Corresponds

    o the

    CR8 accounts:

    aptacion

    e Excedentes

    e laBancao

    ntil uly

    1987;

    nd

    *Compras

    Residentes'

    hereafter.

    b/ FES

    originated

    xclusively

    n trade

    ransactions,

    urchases

    o residents

    nd

    redemption

    f reserve

    equirements

    n foreign

    urrency

    eposits.

    Source:

    oteSemanal

    various

    umbers)

    nd

    "Subgerenciael

    Sector

    xterno'

    CRB).

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    32/149

    -24-

    Financial

    Losses

    13. The indirect estimate of financial osses of the CRB was obtained

    subtracting otal interest paynments eceived on its assets from total

    interests aid on its liabilities:

    (6)

    FIL = i(l) x L - i(a) x A

    wheres FIL

    are CRB's financial losses.

    i(l) is the weighted ave'age interest rate on CRB'

    liabilities.

    i(a) is the weighted average interest

    rate on CRB's

    assets.

    L is

    the total stock of CRB's interest earing

    liabilities.

    A is the total stock of CRB's interest earing assets.

    14. The CRB receives interest

    on its credit to the financial nd

    public sectors and on its net international eserves, nd it pays interest

    on deposits

    of the financial nstitutions n the CRB (primarily eserve

    requirements f commercial anks). To measure interests received and paid

    by the CRB the followinginterest rates were imputed.

    Returns on CRB's Assets

    a) On credit to the public sector (including anco Nacion): a

    weighted average of the interest rate charged

    to Banco

    Nacion and

    0.01% (which is the interest

    rate on the

    consolidated

    entral government ebt at the

    CRB).

    b) On credit to the

    financial system:a weighted average

    of

    the interest rate of credit to Banca de Fomento ("Fomento

    Agropecuario"),

    ith a two-thirds eight, and rediscounts

    to

    commercial banks and the

    Banca de Fomer.to commercial

    rediscounting or 1985-I) with a one-third eight.3/

    3/ A proper weighted average interest rate for credit to the financial

    system requires considering large number of interest rates and credit

    stocks. Since these were not available, the weights were chosen (somehow

    arbitrarily) aking into account that: a) in 1986-87 more than half of

    the credit to the financial ystem went to the "Banco Agrario" and

    approximately ne-third ent to commercial banks; b) the interest rate

    on the "Fomento gropecuario" line lied somewhere in between the zero

    interest rate charged to "campesinos" f the "Trapecio ndino" region

    and the interest rate on other promotional redit lines of the Banco

    Agrario.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    33/149

    -25-

    c) On net international eserves: he LIBOR 3 months interest

    rate multipliedby one times the rate

    of devaluation.

    Interest costs on CRB's liabilities

    a) On currency in circulation: ero.

    b) On reserve requirements n domestic currency depositst the

    remuneration f domestic currency reserves of commercial

    banks (see Annex 11).

    c) On reserve requirements n foreign currency deposits: the

    LIBOR 3 months interest rate (minus one p.p. for 1986 and

    minus 3.5 p.p. for 1987) multiplied by one times the rate of

    devaluation.

    15. The data employed and the indirect estimate of CRB financial

    losses (FIL) are reported in Annex Table 3.4. The indirect estimate of FIL,

    based on equation (6), is equal to the sum of the product of average

    stocks

    of liabilities nd their corresponding nterest rates (according o para.

    14) minus the sum of the product of average stocks of assets and their

    corresponding nterest rates.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    34/149

    -26-

    Table

    : I DIRECT STIMATE

    F FINANCIAL OSSES

    Stocks of: 1986-I 1985-I 1966-I 1986-II 1987-I 1967-11

    A. Average tocks f CR8

    assets nd

    Liabilitiesmillton ntis)

    a) Assets

    1.

    Not Credit o Public ector 471 -862 -1,231 978 6,007 18,148

    2. Credit o the Fin. ystem 3,910 6,803 7,608 10,723 16,376 28,109

    3. Net Internet.eserves 9,842 16,844 19,318 16,686 12,962 6,987

    b) Liabilities

    4. Legal eserves f

    Fin.

    System n Domestic

    Currency 1,426 7,898 17,811 21,366 24,363 a3,374

    S. Legal eserves f Fin.

    System n Foreign

    Currency 8,463 8,926 5,998 4,192 3,842 4,998

    B. Interest

    ates

    n

    CR8 Assets

    nd

    Liabilities

    effectivennual

    -) Assets

    6.

    Loan

    o Public ector 21.4% 22.6% 13.3%

    9.2% 13.3%

    6.3%

    7. Loans o the Fin. System 95.6% 32.3% 18.2%

    14.9% 14.9% 10.4%

    S. Net International

    Reserves 19.3% 9.3%

    7.6% f.2% 8.4% 16.0%

    b) Liabilities

    9. Legal eserves n

    Dom. Currency 101.2% 8.3% 37.8% 37.8% 37.8% 31.2%

    10.Legal eserves n

    Foreign urrency

    19.3% 9.3% .65% 6.2%

    4.1% 8.1%

    C. Financialosse measured

    s:

    (1/2)x[(4)x(9)+(6)x(10)-(1)x(6)-(2)x(7)-(3)x(8)]/

    1985-I 1986-II 1986 1986-I 986-II 1986 1987-I 987-II 1987

    11. Financial

    Losses

    451 3,620 4,071 3,761 3,786 7,547

    3,669 4,003 7,672

    -mill.

    I/.

    -as % GDP

    0.4 1.6 1.9 1.2

    0.9 2.1

    0.6

    0.5 1.0

    Note: ominal DP

    -mil. /. 199,845 381,022 760,168

    / Since ll Interestates reexpressed n annual erms hesemestral evel f

    financial osses

    as obtained ividing et

    Interestayments

    y two.

    Sources: ote

    emanal various

    umbers) or

    section ; and

    "SubgerencIael

    Sector

    onstarlolnd *Superintendencia

    e Banco Seguros"

    CRB)

    for section .

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    35/149

    -27-

    D. Evolution

    of the Quasi-Fiscal eficit

    16. The

    discussion below

    is based on the direct

    estimate of the QFD.

    This is bound to be more accurate because data on neither of the following

    (required

    or the indirectestimate) as available:

    i) a proper

    weighted

    average interest rate of CRB assets and liabilities; nd ii) a weighted

    average exchange rate for CRB's services and napital transactions. owever,

    the indirect estimate of QFD remains useful for assessing the evolution f

    several components of foreign exchange subsidies nd financial losses.

    17. The size of the QFD has varied considerably long the period. It

    roie from 0.2 percent of GDP in 1985-I to 1.7 percent in

    1985-II, mainly as

    a consequence f foreign exchange subsidies nduced by CRB purchases of

    foreign exchange in the open market (at a premium over the official

    exchange rate). The QFD dropped

    slightly to approximately .9 percent of

    GDP during

    the two semesters f 1986. Foreign exchange subsidies from this

    source remained important

    uring 1986-I and, financial losses were more

    important in 1986-II.

    The downward trend of QFD was drastically

    reversed in

    the second half of 1987 whien, trongly impulsed y foreign exchange

    subsidies, FD represented .5 percent of GDP (5.0 percent

    in annualized

    terms). The latter were caused by a growing spread of the average export

    exchange rate over the average import exchange rate and, to a lesser

    degree, by

    CRB purchases of

    foreign exchange

    in the open market.

    18. Throughout the peri3d, financial losses (the other component f

    the QFD) stemmed from CRB financing f the central government and the

    financial system at an interest rate which, on average, was below the cost

    of its funds (that is, a weighted

    average between zero, which is the cost

    of currency,and the remuneration f reserves of the financial system).

    Interest rate losses were particularly mportant in 1986-II and 1987-II

    when they represented percent

    and 0.6 percent of GDP respectively.

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    36/149

    - 28 -

    ANNEX4

    MAIN CHARACTERISTICSOF THE PERUVIAN

    AX SYSTEM

    1.

    The modifications ntroduced in the past

    three years reduced

    the

    number of taxes that composes the

    Central Government revenues. Minor taxes

    were either derogated or transferred o the responsibility f the local

    governments.

    A major reform was

    introduced in income tax following

    recommendations

    o broaden its base and reduce exemptions. In addition,

    special taxes on assets revaluation nd the

    capitalization f profits

    were

    derogated. In turn, taxes on the holding or transfer of property

    (including

    ehicles and on

    gambling) ere

    transferred o the

    municipal

    sphere). A description f the main components of the present system

    follows.

    A. Income Taxes

    Net Income Tax

    2. Net income of private and public enterprises s subject to this

    tax, which applies to distinct forms of corporations s defined by law

    (sociedades nonimas, empresas publicas, sociedades de respornsabilidad

    limitada, ooperativas). Unipersonal

    omestic firms are exempt. Foreign

    enterprises are subject to the tax on the part of their income generated in

    Peru. Capital gains receive the same treatment pplied to other sources of

    income. The usual deductions, .g., expenditures incurred on production,

    interest, depreciation, arry over of previous year losses, are used to

    obtain the taxable income.

    3. Taxpayers ay choose among three options to estimate their monthly

    obligations:

    (a) fixed percentages f the tax due in previous year,

    whose values are set annually by Government decree.

    The percentages pplied in 1987 were 10 percent of

    1985 liabilities January, nd February) and 15, 16

    and 25 percent of 1986 debts for the periods March-

    June, July-September nd October-December,

    respectively. These percentages ave been rising

    in the recent years to allow for a greater

    inflation. For 1988, the two first payments were

    set at 25 percent of 1986 profits, and the

    Government intends to readjust this value at

    shorter intervals;

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    37/149

  • 8/18/2019 Peru - Policies to Stop Hyperinflation - Vol 2

    38/149

    - 30 -

    (b) duodecimos

    of the estimated tax liabilities or the

    same year,

    based on projections

    ade

    at the

    moment

    of the first payment.

    Employers are requiredto withhold duodecimos

    of the expected

    taxes due by

    their respective employees.

    8. Rates. The progressive chedule is the

    following:

    Income

    Level (in l'IT)

    Rates

    (Percent)

    Up to 15

    8

    15 to 20

    10

    20

    to 25

    12

    25

    to 33

    16

    33 to 41 20

    41

    to 50

    25

    50 to 60

    31

    60

    to 72

    38

    Over

    72

    45

    *

    UIT

    stands for Unidad Impositiva

    ributaria.

    One UIT is equal to

    27,300

    Intis (March1988).

    9. Deductionsfrom gross income

    are made in the

    form of credits

    against

    the tax. The most important eductions--the

    imits

    are shown