globalization and political structure giacomo paper.pdfglobalization and political structure gino...

39
Globalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The rst wave of globalization (1830-1914) was accompanied by a decline in the number of countries from 125 to 54. The second wave of globalization (1950-present) has led instead to an increase in the number of countries to a record high of more than 190. This paper develops a theoretical framework to study the interaction be- tween globalization and political structure. We show that political structure adapts to expanding trade opportunities in a non-monotonic way. Borders hamper trade. In its early stages, the political response to globalization consists of removing borders by increasing country size. In its later stages, however, the political response to globaliza- tion is to remove borders by creating economic unions, and this leads to a reduction in country size. JEL Classication: D71, F15, F55, H77, O57 Keywords: Globalization, political structure, size of countries, international unions. CREI, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE. E-mail: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]. We thank Marta Santamaria and Jagdish Tripathy for excellent research assistance. We acknowledge nancial support from the European Research Council (grant GOPG 240989), the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness (grants RYC-2013-13838, ECO2014-54430-P and ECO2014-59805- P), the Generalitat de Catalunya (grant 2014 SGR 830) and the Institut dEstudis Autonmics.

Upload: others

Post on 14-May-2020

7 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

Globalization and Political Structure∗

Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura

February 2016

Abstract

The first wave of globalization (1830-1914) was accompanied by a decline in the

number of countries from 125 to 54. The second wave of globalization (1950-present)

has led instead to an increase in the number of countries to a record high of more

than 190. This paper develops a theoretical framework to study the interaction be-

tween globalization and political structure. We show that political structure adapts

to expanding trade opportunities in a non-monotonic way. Borders hamper trade. In

its early stages, the political response to globalization consists of removing borders by

increasing country size. In its later stages, however, the political response to globaliza-

tion is to remove borders by creating economic unions, and this leads to a reduction

in country size.

JEL Classification: D71, F15, F55, H77, O57

Keywords: Globalization, political structure, size of countries, international unions.

∗CREI, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE. E-mail: [email protected], [email protected],[email protected]. We thank Marta Santamaria and Jagdish Tripathy for excellent research assistance.We acknowledge financial support from the European Research Council (grant GOPG 240989), the SpanishMinistry of Economy and Competitiveness (grants RYC-2013-13838, ECO2014-54430-P and ECO2014-59805-P), the Generalitat de Catalunya (grant 2014 SGR 830) and the Institut d’Estudis Autonòmics.

Page 2: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

1 Introduction

In 1820, the world was made up of 125 sovereign states. By the end of the first wave of

globalization in 1914, the number of countries had fallen to 54, less than half of the initial

level. The interwar period witnessed a reversal of these trends: trade collapsed and the

number of sovereign states rose to 76 by 1949. Until then, political and economic integration

had proceeded together. Yet, the end of World War II marks the beginning of a new era.

The second wave of globalization that started after 1950 has led trade between nations to

flourish to levels never seen before. But this time the process of economic integration was

accompanied by different changes in the world political structure. On the one hand, the

number of countries has risen to a record high of more than 190, suggesting that more trade

is now accompanied by political fragmentation. On the other hand, however, there has been

a proliferation and growth of international treaties and unions aimed especially at fostering

economic integration, such as the WTO and the European Union.

These trends are illustrated graphically in Figure 1, which shows the historical evolution

of the number of sovereign states in the world, average exports as a share of GDP and the

number of members of the GATT/WTO. The data on the number of states was obtained

from Butcher and Griffi ths (2013).1 However, counting the number of sovereign countries

in the past poses some challenges, especially in remote and underdeveloped areas.2 Hence,

in Figure 2 we plot an alternative measure of political concentration: the average land size

of “internationally recognized”countries and of thirteen major empires since 1830, from the

Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive. The graph tells a story remarkably similar to

Figure 1. During the 1800s, there was a phase of political consolidation in which countries

and empires expanded their territories. But this trend reversed in the decades after World

War II, which saw the collapse of large empires and a steady fall in average country size.

Why did the first wave of globalization lead to political concentration? Why did the

second wave of globalization lead to political fragmentation? To answer these questions,

this paper develops a theoretical framework to study the interaction between globalization

and political structure. We view globalization as a process by which the geographical size

of markets expands. There is wide consensus that globalization started around the mid

nineteenth century and that it was fueled by major technological advancements, sustained

1See Appendix A.1 for more details about the data.2Most importantly, the commonly used “International System”(Singer and Small 1966), including coun-

tries with international recognition, grossly underestimates the number of independent political entities inthe 19th-century developing world.

1

Page 3: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

1810 1830 1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010

Country WTO Trade

Figure 1: Trade share (right axis), the number of countries and WTO membership (leftaxis.) See appendix for details on data.

economic growth and the adoption of market-promoting policies.3 A key premise behind our

work is that borders hamper trade, and globalization makes borders more costly. Consistent

with the evidence in Figures 1 and 2, our theory suggests that political structure adapts

to expanding trade opportunities in a non-monotonic way. In its early stages, the political

response to globalization consists mostly of removing borders by increasing the size of coun-

tries. In its later stages, however, the political response to globalization is to remove borders

by creating economic unions, and this leads to a reduction in the size of countries.

Our theory builds on the classic work of Alesina and Spolaore (1997), who argued that

country size trades off preference heterogeneity and economies of scale. Preference hetero-

geneity across space creates a force towards political fragmentation. Each relevant geograph-

ical unit or “locality”would like to have a government type that is as close to its ideal type

as possible. As the size of a country increases by adding more localities, the resulting gov-

ernment type tends to move farther away from the ideal type of each of them. Thus, the

mismatch between citizens’ideal and actual government type increases with country size.

3See Hugot (2015) and Pascali (2014) for recent papers on the onset of globalization.

2

Page 4: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

1830

18

35

1840

18

45

1850

18

55

1860

18

65

1870

18

75

1880

18

85

1890

18

95

1900

19

05

1910

19

20

1925

19

30

1935

19

46

1951

19

56

1961

19

66

1971

19

76

1981

19

86

1991

19

96

2001

20

06

country empire

Figure 2: Size of countries (left axis) and empires (right axis). Thousand squared miles, seethe appendix for details on data.

Economies of scale create a force towards political concentration. As country size increases,

some fixed costs of setting up and running a government are shared by a growing number of

localities. Thus, the cost of the government also declines with size. Alesina, Spolaore and

Wacziarg (2000) extended this theory to allow for international trade and a border effect.

This creates another force for political concentration. As country size increases, the number

of borders declines and the gains from trade grow. Then, they modeled globalization as

a reduction in the border effect, which weakens the benefits of size and leads to political

fragmentation.4

Our theory departs from this earlier work in two important ways. The first one is our ap-

proach to globalization. Instead of modeling globalization as a reduction in the border effect,

we model this phenomenon as an increase in trade opportunities. This is more consistent

with the notion of globalization as a geographical extension of the market. Many goods and

4In a similar vein, but less directly related to our work, Casella (2001) and Casella and Feinstein (2002)study the interaction between economic and political integration in a model where public goods affects thegains from trade, while Bolton and Roland (1996, 1997) focus on the role of income distribution and factormobility. See Ruta (2005) for a survey of the literature on the economic incentives for countries to integrateor separate, and how these incentives are affected by globalization.

3

Page 5: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

services that were traded only locally in the early nineteenth century were already traded

internationally by the early twentieth century. There are even more that are traded inter-

nationally in the early twenty-first century. Globalization effectively makes borders more

costly, as they affect a growing volume of trade. This change of perspective suggests that

globalization provides incentives to remove borders rather than to create them, and it would

lead us to the conclusion that globalization leads to political concentration.

The second and most important novelty of our theory is to recognize that the notion of

government type is multidimensional. In particular, this notion includes a full description of

the laws and institutions that govern economic and cultural interactions within a country. By

economic interactions, we mean market exchanges of any sort. By cultural interactions, we

mean “the distinctive ideas, customs, social behavior, products, or way of life of a particular

nation, society, people, or period.”5 Thus, it is useful to think about the economic and

cultural types of government.6

This distinction enriches the analysis since it expands the set of possible political struc-

tures. We can think of countries as sets of localities that share the same economic and

cultural types of government. We can then think of economic unions as sets of countries

that share the same economic type of government but not the same cultural type. Going

back to Figures 1 and 2, we can now ask: Why did the first wave of globalization reduce

the number of countries but did not generate economic unions? Why did the second wave of

globalization increase the number of countries and led to the creation of economic unions?

Once these questions have been re-formulated this way, we need only two additional (and

reasonable) assumptions to obtain our main result.

The first assumption is that the border effect is largely due to differences in the economic

type of government, while preference heterogeneity is defined mostly over the cultural type of

government. This suggests the benefits of a political structure consisting of small countries

each of them with its own distinct cultural type, and a large economic union that encompasses

many or all of these countries. This political structure would allow localities to enjoy a

5This is the definition of culture offered by the Oxford English Dictionary. This notion of a group’s cultureis quite broad. It includes not only sharing a common language and history, but also sharing common viewsabout justice and punishment, how to educate children, the size and scope of the welfare system, the needfor redistribution, and so on.

6Thus, our research is also related to the broad theory of fiscal and political federalism. The classiceconomic analysis of federalism (e.g., Oates 1972) focuses on two rationales for centralization: economies ofscale and benefits from policy coordination. Political-economy analyses have emphasized that a countervail-ing cost of centralization is the reduced ability to tailor policy choices to local tastes (Lockwood 2002; Besleyand Coate 2003; Boffa, Piolatto and Ponzetto 2015). We study the evolution of this trade-off in the wake ofglobalization and its implication for the endogenous formation of countries and economic unions.

4

Page 6: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

government that is close to their ideal type. It would also facilitate trade by removing

borders.

The second assumption is that there are limited economies of scope when the cultural

and economic types of government coincide. Having different economic and cultural types is

akin to having two different sets of laws and institutions for market and cultural interactions

or, in short, having two different levels of government. This not only duplicates costs, but

it also introduces transaction costs across levels of government. Earlier research, and most

notably the work of Alesina et al., has adopted the view that economies of scope are so

large that the possibility of having different economic and cultural types of government is

not worth considering. We relax this assumption and allow for limited economies of scope.

The non-monotonic effect of globalization on political structure follows from these as-

sumptions. At early stages of globalization, localities take advantage of increased trade

opportunities by enlarging country size. That is, the cost of reaping the gains from trade

is paid in terms of a larger mismatch between the ideal and actual types of government.

Forming economic unions is not worthwhile since trade is small and the benefits of removing

borders this way are outweighed by loss of economies of scope. As globalization proceeds, the

size of countries increases and the cost of preference mismatch keeps growing. Eventually,

this cost is too large and it is worth giving up economies of scope. The world political struc-

ture shifts from a world with a few large countries to a new world with many small countries

that participate in an economic union. This result is consistent with the observation that

political structure reacted differently to the first and second waves of globalization.

A key aspect of any theory of political structure is a view of how localities interact. In

Section 2, we develop a stylized model of the world with a continuum of localities that are

sovereign and free to sign political contracts among themselves. Such a view of political

interactions can aptly be described as the rule of diplomacy. We show that equilibrium

political contracts take the form of countries and unions. And we describe how the number

and size of countries and unions evolves with globalization. In particular, we find that in the

early stages of globalization, country size grows and there are no economic unions; while at

the later stages of globalization, a world economic union is formed and country size shrinks.

But diplomacy is hardly the only form of interaction in the real world. In Section 3, we

allow a small set of great powers to wage war and build empires. In equilibrium, the world

is partitioned into a set of empires ruled by war and conquest and a free world ruled by

diplomacy. Interestingly, we find that our main result also applies to this world: in the early

stages of globalization, country size grows and there are no economic unions; while at later

5

Page 7: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

stages of globalization, a world economic union is formed and country size shrinks. In both

stages, great powers choose not to build empires and instead join the free world. Diplomacy

rules. The new result now is that there exists an intermediate stage of globalization in which

great powers build empires that grow in size. These empires eventually collapse as the world

enters the third and final stage of globalization and the world economic union makes them

obsolete.7

In Section 4, we break the perfect symmetry of the benchmark model by assuming that

the world is divided into regions and that trade costs and cultural differences vary across

and within regions. We then use the model to rationalize why the process of formation of

unions tends to be gradual and often starts at the regional level. The picture that arises from

our stylized model is therefore rich and suggestive. In Section 5 we show how our analytical

results help us interpret a variety of specific historical experiences. Section 6 concludes.

2 The Symmetric World

In this section, we develop a stylized model of the world that contains the basic ingredients

of the theory: geography, markets and preferences. The model mixes these ingredients

imposing a high degree of symmetry. This allows us to derive our basic results on the effects

of globalization on political structure quickly and intuitively.

The concept of locality is a key primitive in our theory. We model the world as a set of

locations within which there are neither geographical nor cultural distances, and we label

them localities. Thus, localities consist of a group of people sharing common preferences

and inhabiting a particular territory. This approach, which is common in the literature,

simplifies the study of how peoples with different cultures interact and organize themselves

into political entities. But it is silent about how these cultural differences arose in the first

place and how they evolve over time. It also abstracts from domestic conflict.

The concept of globalization is another important primitive in our theory. Geographical

distances introduce trade costs across localities that shelter local markets. We interpret

globalization as exogenous technological change that gradually removes these trade costs

and turns local markets into global ones. In particular, we use the popular traded-nontraded

model in which the markets for traded goods are global, while the markets for nontraded

goods are local. We then model globalization as an increase in the share of traded goods.

7See Martin, Mayer and Thoenig (2008) for a theoretical and empirical analysis of the relationship betweentrade and war.

6

Page 8: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

2.1 Basic setup

We consider a world with a continuum of atomistic geographical units called localities, l ∈[0, 1]. Each locality contains a positive measure of identical individuals. Let Wl be the

welfare of the representative individual of locality l. For short, we refer to this individual as

“locality l.”Then, the welfare of locality l is determined as follows:

Wl = WMl +WG

l , (1)

where WMl is the utility derived from the consumption of market goods, and WG

l is the

utility derived from the services provided by its government. We explain next how these two

variables are determined.

2.1.1 Markets and Trade

There is a continuum of industries producing goods, i ∈ [0, 1]. Let cl (i) be the consumption

of goods of industry i by locality l. The utility function takes the following form:

WMl =

∫ 1

0

ln cl (i) di. (2)

The choice of a symmetric logarithmic or Cobb-Douglas utility function ensures that all

localities spend the same share of their income in each industry.

The production of consumption goods requires differentiated input varieties, m ∈ [0, 1].

Define cl (m, i) as the amount of inputs of the variety m used by locality l in the production

of goods in industry i. Then, we have that:

cl (i) = exp

{∫ 1

0

ln cl (m, i) dm

}. (3)

This production function is symmetric across and within industries. Since we use again the

convenient Cobb-Douglas formulation, each locality spends the same fraction of its income

on all varieties of all industries.

To introduce gains from specialization and trade, we use a simple symmetric version of

the Ricardian model. Each locality is endowed with one unit of labor in each industry. This

unit can produce one unit of the variety with the same index as the locality, i.e. m = l; or

e−η units of any other variety, i.e. m 6= l. Since η > 0, each locality has a technological

advantage in its “own”variety. The parameter η measures the extent to which technologies

7

Page 9: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

differ across localities and, therefore, the potential gains from specialization and trade.

We introduce both technological and policy-induced barriers to trade. In some industries,

the costs of shipping inputs across localities are negligible, while in the rest these costs are

prohibitive. As usual, we refer to these two sets of industries as traded and nontraded,

respectively. We order industries so that traded ones have low indices, i.e., i ∈ [0, τ ]. We

interpret globalization as an increase in τ , which reflects the decline of technological trade

costs.

The presence of borders also imposes costs to trade. Define a variable blm which takes

value β if there is a border between localities l and m, and it takes value 0 otherwise.

Then, we assume that only a fraction e−blm of the goods shipped from l to m arrive to their

destination. Thus, the parameter β measures the size of the border effect. To ensure that

borders do not preclude specialization and trade, we assume that η > β > 0.

A market equilibrium is a set of prices and quantities such that individuals maximize

utility and markets clear. Appendix A.2 shows that there exists a unique market equilibrium

for each possible configuration of borders. In this equilibrium, traded industries specialize

in the locality’s input variety, export essentially all of their production and import the

remaining input varieties. Thus, consumption in traded industries is cl (m, i) = e−blm if

i ∈ [0, τ ]. Nontraded industries are forced to produce locally all input varieties. Thus,

consumption in nontraded industries is cl (m, i) = e−η if i ∈ (τ , 1]. This implies the following

utility from consuming market goods:

WMl = − (1− τ) η − τ

∫ 1

0

blmdm. (4)

Equation (4) is valid for any configuration of borders. An increase in the share of traded

goods raises the consumption of newly traded goods. The size of this gain is proportional

to η for trade that does not cross a border, and it is proportional to η − β for trade thatcrosses a border. Removing borders also raises consumption. The size of this gain equals τβ

per border removed. These results are intuitive and play an important role in the analysis.

2.1.2 Government Type

There is a continuum of basic government varieties, x ∈ [0, 1]. A government for locality l

consists of a pair of density functions gEl (x) and gCl (x) defined over these varieties. Since

these functions are densities, gEl (x) ≥ 0, gCl (x) ≥ 0 and∫ 10gEl (x)dx =

∫ 10gCl (x)dx = 1.

We refer to the functions gEl and gCl as the economic and cultural types of the government

8

Page 10: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

of locality l, respectively. These types constitute a complete description of the laws and

institutions that govern economic and cultural interactions within locality l.

We now introduce three assumptions about government services. The first is that each

locality has a different ideal cultural variety of government. We define and order the basic

varieties such that the ideal one for locality l is x = l. The value of government services for

locality l depends positively on how dense gCl is at x = l, that is, it depends on gCl (l).

The second assumption is that there are economies of scale in the provision of government

services. Building and maintaining a specific government reduces the overall provision of

government services by a total amount φ > 0. Localities that choose the same pair(gEl , g

Cl

)share this cost equally among them.

The third assumption is that there are economies of scope when cultural and economic

types of government coincide. Localities that choose gCl 6= gEl must pay a per capita cost of

κ > 0.

To formalize these assumptions, we write the utility derived from government services as

follows:

WGl = − δ

gCl (l)− φ∫ 1

0Igl=gmdm

− κIgCl 6=gEl , (5)

where δ > 0; Igl=gm is an indicator variable that takes value one if(gEl , g

Cl

)=(gEm, g

Cm

), and

zero otherwise; and IgCl 6=gEl is another indicator variable that takes value 1 if gEl 6= gCl , and

zero otherwise. The first term in Equation (5) says that the value of government services

for locality l grows with the density of its own specific ideal variety in the cultural type of

its government. The parameter δ measures the importance of preference heterogeneity. The

second term in Equation (5) says that the fixed cost of government declines with the number

of localities that share the same government. The parameter φ measures the magnitude

of these economies of scale. The third term of Equation (5) says that choosing different

economic and cultural types of government reduces the value of government services. The

parameter κ measures the magnitude of these economies of scope.

We next introduce a fourth assumption, namely, that having different economic types

creates borders that obstruct trade:

blm = βIgEl 6=gEm , (6)

where IgEl 6=gEm is an indicator variable that takes value 1 if gEl 6= gEm, and zero otherwise. The

idea, of course, is that disparity in economic laws and institutions makes trade more costly.

The parameter β is a measure of these costs.

9

Page 11: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

2.2 Equilibrium Political Structure under Diplomacy

A political structure for the world is a set of governments for all localities, i.e.{gCl , g

El

}l∈[0,1].

Combining Equations (1), (4), (5) and (6), we obtain:

Wl = − (1− τ) η − τβ∫ 1

0

IgEl 6=gEmdm−δ

gCl (l)− φ∫ 1

0Igl=gmdm

− κIgCl 6=gEl . (7)

Equation (7) shows how political structure determines welfare and reveals the key trade-off

that underlies our theory. A desirable political structure should facilitate trade, accommo-

date preference heterogeneity and take advantage of economies of scale and scope. But these

goals cannot be achieved simultaneously and something must give.

To determine the equilibrium political structure, we must make assumptions about how

governments are chosen. A good starting point is the case in which localities are sovereign

and they freely choose their own economic and cultural types of government. Since there is

no heterogeneity within localities, their choices maximize the welfare of their representative

individual. Their choice of cultural type does not affect other localities. But their choice

of economic type does, since it determines borders and therefore trade costs. These policy

externalities provide incentives for localities to engage in diplomacy and negotiate political

contracts.

Localities can sign political contracts to share a government with other localities. We

refer to these contracts and the localities that sign them as countries. Formally, a country

is a set of localities that share the same economic and cultural types of government, i.e.(gCl , g

El

)=(gCm, g

Em

)for all l and m belonging to the country. Countries choose the average

ideal cultural type of their members:

gCl (x) =

1

Sif x ∈ country

0 if x /∈ country, (8)

where S is the combined measure of localities that belong to the country.

Countries can also sign political contracts to share a common economic type of govern-

ment. We refer to these contracts and the countries that sign them as (‘economic’) unions.

Formally, a union is a set of countries that have different cultural types of government, but

share the same economic type of government, i.e. gEl = gEm for all l and m belonging to the

10

Page 12: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

union.8 Unions choose the average ideal type of their members:

gEl (x) =

1

Uif x ∈ union

0 if x /∈ union, (9)

where U is the combined measure of localities that belong to the union. As a result, gCl 6= gEl

for all l belonging to the union.9

How does the world organize itself into countries and unions? A natural benchmark is

that in which bargaining among localities is effi cient and delivers Pareto effi cient outcomes.

In this case, the equilibrium political structure under diplomacy is obtained by solving this

maximization problem: {gCl , g

El

}l∈[0,1] = arg max

∫ 1

0

ωlWldl, (10)

where {ωl}l∈[0,1] is a set of Pareto weights such that∫ 10ωldl = 1. Given all the symmetry

of this world, it seems reasonable to focus on the the case in which the bargaining process

treats all localities in the same way, i.e. ωl = 1. Sometimes this political structure is referred

to as the utilitarian welfare optimum.

To find this political structure, we proceed in three steps. First, we compute the welfare

WN generated by a world without unions:

WN = maxSN∈[0,1]

{− (1− τ) η − τβ (1− SN)− δSN −

φ

SN

}, (11)

where SN is the preferred country size in the absence of unions.10 This political structure

takes full advantage of economies of scope, and country size trades off preference heterogene-

8We could also define ‘cultural’unions analogously. But this is unnecessary since countries would neversign political contracts to share a common type of cultural government, and then choose different economictypes of government.

9We assume that both countries and unions choose the average ideal type of their members for simplicity.But it is not diffi cult to derive this as a result. No additional assumptions are needed to show that countrieschoose the average cultural and economic type of their member localities. To show that unions choose theaverage economic type of their member countries, we would need to assume some preference heterogeneityalso for economic type.10Throughout, we disregard the constraint that the number of countries, which in this case is 1/SN , must

be a natural number. Aside from this constraint, all localities prefer the same optimal country size, soany Pareto-effi cient equilibrium is symmetric. In Appendix A.3 we introduce this integer constraint andshow that the utilitarian welfare optimum remains symmetric and qualitatively analogous to the tractableapproximation we present here.

11

Page 13: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

ity against both economies of scale and facilitating trade:

SN =

√φ

δ − τβ . (12)

The equilibrium size of countries in the absence of unions is increasing with economies of

scale (φ) and the importance of trade (τβ), and it is decreasing with preference heterogeneity

(δ). Equation (12) assumes that δ > φ+ β, so that there is enough preference heterogeneity

to ensure that countries are always smaller than the whole world.

Second, we compute the welfare WU generated by a world with unions. The cost of

forming a union does not change with its size, but its benefit does increase with size. Thus,

the equilibrium union is always the world union, i.e. U = 1. This allows us to write:

WU = maxSU∈[0,1]

{− (1− τ) η − δSU −

φ

SU− κ}, (13)

where SU is the preferred country size with a world union. This political structure gives

up economies of scope in order to remove borders and facilitate trade. Then, country size

trades off preference heterogeneity and economies of scale:

SU =

√φ

δ. (14)

The equilibrium size of countries with a world union is increasing with economies of scale (φ)

and it is decreasing with preference heterogeneity (δ). Country size is always smaller with

a world union than without. The reason is that the union removes one of the incentives for

country size, namely, facilitating trade.

The third step is to determine the equilibrium political structure as follows:

WF = max {WN ,WU} , (15)

where WF is the welfare obtained by a locality in this free world. If WN > WU , the

equilibrium political structure consists of the world being partitioned into countries of size

SN . If instead WN < WU , the equilibrium political structure consists of the world being

partitioned into countries of size SU and a world union. Naturally, in the knife-edge case in

which WN = WU , both solutions are equilibrium political structures.

12

Page 14: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

A little bit of algebra shows that:

WF = − (1− τ) η − τβ −min{

2√φ (δ − τβ), 2

√φδ + κ− τβ

}. (16)

It is straightforward to see that the world union is preferred if and only if 2√φδ + κ− τβ <

2√φ (δ − τβ), hence for high values of τ , β and δ; and low values of φ and κ. A world union

is more useful if trade costs are low, the border effect is sizeable and there is substantial

preference heterogeneity. A world union is less useful if economies of scale and scope are

sizable.

2.3 Globalization and Political Structure

With these results at hand, we can now return to Figures 1 and 2 in the introduction and ask

again: Why did the first wave of globalization reduce the number of countries but did not

generate economic unions? Why did the second wave of globalization increase the number

of countries and led to the creation of economic unions?

To develop some intuition, Figure 3 plots WN , WU and WF as a function of τ . Note that

WF is the upper envelope of WN and WU , and it is depicted as a solid line. As τ increases,

the potential gains from trade increase and so does the incentive to remove borders. This

affects political structure in a non-monotonic way. In particular, there is a threshold level

τU such that WN < WU and there is no world union for τ < τU ; while WN > WU and there

is a world union for τ > τU . This threshold is interior, i.e. τU ∈ (0, 1), for intermediate

levels of economies of scope:

0 < κ < β − 2√φ(√

δ −√δ − β

). (17)

If economies of scope are negligible, the smallest amount of trade leads to the formation of a

world union. If economies of scope are prohibitive, the world union is never an equilibrium.

The comparative statics of this threshold follow directly from our analysis of Equation (16).

The larger is the border effect (β) and preference heterogeneity (δ), the smaller is τU . The

larger are economies of scale (φ) and scope (κ), the larger is τU .

Figure 4 shows how the equilibrium political structure changes with globalization by

plotting the equilibrium size of countries and unions. At low levels of globalization (τ ≤ τU),

expanding trade opportunities lead to an increase in country size. At this early stage of

globalization, the cost of reaping new gains from trade is a growing preference mismatch.

13

Page 15: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

­1.8

­1.7

­1.6

­1.5

­1.4

­1.3

­1.2

­1.1

­1.0

­0.9

tau

W

Figure 3: Globalization andWelfare. The figure shows how equilibrium welfare (WF ) changeswith globalization (τ). The black line is maximum welfare without a union (WN), the greenline with the world union (WU).

It is simply too expensive to create a world union given the small amount of trade. At

high levels of globalization (τ ≥ τU), the preference mismatch has grown too large and

expanding trade opportunities now lead to the creation of a world union. At this late stage

of globalization, the cost of reaping new gains from trade is the loss of economies of scope.

Indeed, the creation of a world union allows countries to revert to a smaller size and reduce

the preference mismatch. Further increases in τ have no effect on political structure.

The symmetric world neatly illustrates the non-monotonic response of political structure

to globalization. It is instructive to compare this result to the finding by Alesina, Spolaore

and Wacziarg (2000) that globalization always reduces country size. Their analysis differs

from ours in two crucial ways. The first one is that, unlike us, Alesina et al. assumed that κ is

prohibitive so that the world union is never an equilibrium and country size is determined by

Equation (12). The second difference is that, unlike us, Alesina et al. interpreted globalization

as a reduction in the border effect β, keeping constant the fraction of traded goods τ (which

was set to one). It follows directly from Equation (12) that a reduction in the border effect

reduces country size. In our model, the border effect is removed endogenously by the creation

of the union, but only when τ is suffi ciently high.

14

Page 16: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

­1.4

­1.2

­1.0

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0.0

tau

lnS

Figure 4: Globalization, Countries and Unions. The figure shows how the world politicalstructure changes with globalization (τ). The black line is the size of each country, the greenline is the world union.

3 War and Conquest

In our baseline model we considered a world in which every locality can choose its own

government freely. Then, the equilibrium political structure is the outcome of free contracting

among equals. This constitutes a useful theoretical benchmark and an ideal state of affairs.

But it hardly reflects historical experience. Alongside diplomacy, war and conquest (or the

threat of it) have played a crucial role in shaping real-world political structure. Thus, we

want to know whether the possibility of war and conquest affects the relationship between

globalization and political structure. And if it does, we also want to know how and why this

happens.

We keep all assumptions as before regarding preferences and technology. But now we

consider an alternative rule to determine political structure. In particular, we assume that

the world contains “great powers”that are able to conquer other localities through war and

form empires. If some of these great powers choose to do so, the world is partitioned into

a set of empires where political structure is determined by war and conquest, and a set of

free countries where political structure is determined by diplomacy. We explain how this all

works next.

15

Page 17: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

3.1 Empire-building

The world contains a finite set of π ∈ N identical “great powers”that are able to conquerother localities through war and form empires. Like a free country, an empire consists

of a set of localities that share the same economic and cultural types of government, i.e.(gCl , g

El

)=(gCm, g

Em

)for all l and m belonging to the empire. Unlike a free country, an

empire does not treat all of its member localities symmetrically. In particular, an empire

contains two distinct sets of localities: the metropolis and the colonies. Let E be the size of

the empire containing a metropolis of sizeM and colonies of size E−M . The key asymmetryis that the empire’s cultural type is the average ideal cultural type of the metropolis:

gCl (x) =

1

Mif x ∈ metropolis

0 if x /∈ metropolis. (18)

Since this implies that colonies have a welfare of WC = −∞, no locality becomes a colonyvoluntarily.

To build an empire of size E, a great power must find allies to build a metropolis, and

then wage war to conquer the colonies. A colonial war is successful if and only if the size of

the metropolis is large enough relative to that of the colonies:

M ≥ µE. (19)

The parameter µ ∈ (0, 1) provides the smallest size of a successful metropolis.

From the perspective of the metropolis, the upside of building an empire is that it forces

the colonies to adopt the average ideal government type of the metropolis. This facilitates

trade and generates economies of scale without creating preference mismatch. The downside

of building an empire is that waging war and holding the empire together reduces the utility

that the metropolis derives from government services by an amount ω > 0. This cost

captures the diversion of government resources from providing public goods in the metropolis

to waging colonial wars.

Localities that do not belong to empires remain sovereign and choose their political

structure through diplomacy. In particular, they form free countries as in the baseline

model.

16

Page 18: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

3.2 Equilibrium Political Structure with War and Conquest

We now determine equilibrium political structure arising from the following three stages:

1. The great powers choose whether to wage war and build empires. Other localities

might become their allies, their colonies, or remain sovereign.

2. Localities that remain sovereign form countries by free and symmetric contracting, as

in our baseline model.

3. Empires and free countries can form economic unions.

We assume that great powers can successfully coordinate with each other on the creation

of their respective empires. Coordination ensures that great powers wage colonial wars

without ever clashing with each other. They agree on their separate spheres of influence, so

they can target disjoint sets of localities to conquer as their colonies. Moreover, the number

of great powers is small enough that all of them can find the desired number of localities to

be used as allies and colonies without having to fight each other.11

To solve for the equilibrium, we first study the incentives of great powers to build empires.

Given the choice of great powers, we then study the equilibrium political structure of the

remaining sovereign localities.

3.2.1 The great powers

Great powers must first decide whether to build an empire and become part of the metropolis

or to forego war. To do this, they compare the welfare of these two options. If the great

powers agree to refrain from waging war and instead jointly choose to form countries and

unions by free and symmetric contracting, the world equilibrium remains the one described

by the previous section. All localities, including the great powers, have welfare WF , which

is still given by Equation (16).

However, great powers may decide to wage war and form empires. In this case, the

welfare WE of a metropolis in an empire outside of an economic union is:

WE = maxE∈[0,1]

{− (1− τ) η − τβ (1− E)− δM − φ

E− ω

}s.t. M ≥ µE. (20)

11Historically, great powers have in fact agreed on such explicit partitions of the world, from the Treatyof Tordesillas in 1494 to the Berlin Conference in 1884.

17

Page 19: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

Naturally, the constraint is binding and M = µE. From the perspective of the metropolis,

there is no reason to convert additional colonies into allies and “worsen” the government

type. The equilibrium size of the empire trades off preference heterogeneity against both

economies of scale and facilitating trade:

E =

√φ

δµ− τβ . (21)

The equilibrium size of empires is increasing with economies of scale (φ) and the importance

of trade (τβ), and it is decreasing with preference heterogeneity (δ). These comparative

statics are the same as for countries. Also, the smaller is the size of the metropolis relative

to that of the colonies (µ) the larger is the empire. We assume that δµ > φ + β such that

an empire never grows as large as the entire world.

Comparing Equation (21) to Equation (12), it is immediate to see that empires are larger

than peaceful countries, because the metropolis does not internalize the cost of the cultural

mismatch imposed on the colonies. Moreover, comparing WE to WF (i.e., Equations 20 and

16) in the case τ → 0 shows that diplomacy prevails in autarky if war is suffi ciently costly:

ω > 2√φδ(1−√µ). (22)

This condition implies that great powers do not wish to conquer colonies merely to compel

them to defray the fixed cost of government. The motivation for imperial expansion lies

instead in the desire to gain access to colonial markets without having to compromise the

great power’s preferred type of cultural government. As a consequence, the great powers

choose to forego warfare in autarky, when market access is worthless. When this condition

is satisfied, war may arise endogenously as a function of globalization, but it is not the

dominant strategy for any value of τ . To focus on this more interesting and realistic case,

from now on, we assume that Condition (22) is satisfied.

Consider now an empire part of an economic union. Since the benefit of forming a union

is increasing in its size, great powers will jointly agree to form the largest possible union.

Moreover, it is straightforward to show that when great powers want to form a world union

the remaining localities are always willing to join it.12 Hence, if the union is chosen, it will

be the world union. However, an additional implication of Condition (22) is that the great

12Intuitively, since free countries are always smaller than empires, they are always keener on joining aworld union and reaping the benefits of reducing barriers to international trade.

18

Page 20: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

powers prefer to forego war if they wish to join an economic union that guarantees unfettered

access to world markets. Hence, economic unions including great powers will be peaceful.

In sum, welfare for great powers is WP = max {WE,WF}. When WE > WF , there are

π empires of size E.13 When WE ≤ WF , instead, diplomacy rules. While we know already

that peace prevails in autarky, great powers may choose to wage war at intermediate levels

of globalization. To see this, note that:

∂τ(WE −WN) = β (E − SN) > 0. (23)

Rising globalization makes empires more appealing relative free countries because in equi-

librium they have larger markets. For the same reason, however, globalization also makes a

peaceful world union more appealing relative to an empire.

3.2.2 The free world

Consider now localities that are neither great powers nor part of an empire. If WF ≥ WE, as

we already discussed above, all localities have welfare WF and the world political structure

is identical to the case without war. IfWF < WE, instead, there are π empires of size E. The

analysis of the remaining 1 − πE sovereign localities, i.e., the “free world”, is quite similar

to that of the previous section. The welfare delivered by a free world without unions is still

described by Equation (11), and the associated equilibrium country size SN is still given

by Equation (12). There is however a new possibility. All localities that do not belong to

empires may form a union. If they choose to do so, it is again the largest possible one. But

now this is the union of all free countries in a world with empires. Since this union has a

combined size of 1− πE, the welfare of its localities is given by:

W̌U = maxSU∈[0,1]

{− (1− τ) η − τβπE − δSU −

φ

SU− κ}. (24)

Empires reduce the size of the free world and therefore the welfare delivered by an economic

union of free countries. Note however that equilibrium country size SU is still described by

Equation (14).

If WN > W̌U , the free world is partitioned into countries of size SN and there is no

economic union. If instead WN < W̌U , the free world is partitioned into countries of size SU

13We assume that great powers coordinate on forming the maximum number of empires rather than joiningeach other’s metropolises. This is feasible given our assumption πE < 1 for all τ .

19

Page 21: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

­1.5

­1.4

­1.3

­1.2

­1.1

­1.0

­0.9

tau

W

Figure 5: Contracts, Conquest and Welfare. The figure shows how equilibrium welfarechanges with globalization (τ). The black line is maximum welfare from contracts (WF ), thered line from conquest (WE).

and there is a union. Comparing Equation (24) to Equation (11), it is easy to see that the

union of free countries is preferred if trade costs are low (τ), the border effect is sizeable (β),

there is substantial preference heterogeneity (δ), and economies of scale (φ) and scope (κ)

are weak. These results were already obtained in the absence of empires, i.e. with πE = 0.

A new result here is that empires (πE) reduce the value of an economic union. The reason,

of course, is that they reduce its size.

3.3 Globalization and Political Structure Again

Let us now return to the analysis of the effects of globalization on political structure that

motivates our analysis. Figure 5 plotsWF andWM as a function of τ . In the most interesting

case that we plot, there are now two relevant threshold values, τE and τU . These thresholds

define three different stages of globalization with distinct equilibrium political structures.

Figure 6 depicts this three-stage evolution by plotting the equilibrium size of empires,

free countries, and unions. At low levels of globalization (τ < τE), the world contains only

free countries that grow in size with trade opportunities. There are no empires or unions.

As globalization proceeds, the size of countries grows and so does the preference mismatch.

When globalization crosses the first threshold (τE ≤ τ < τU), the preference mismatch has

grown too large and the great powers prefer to form empires. The latter allows the metropolis

20

Page 22: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

­1.4

­1.2

­1.0

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0.0

tau

lnS

Figure 6: Countries, Empires and Unions. The figure shows how the world political structurechanges with globalization (τ). The black line is the size of peaceful countries, the red lineis the size of empires, the green line is the world union.

to impose their ideal type of government on the colonies. Thus, empires facilitate trade and

generate economies of scale at the cost of an unbounded preference mismatch in the colonies.

Empires are larger than countries and keep growing as globalization proceeds. Eventually,

globalization crosses the second threshold (τU < τ). At this point, preference mismatch has

grown too large even within empires. Empires collapse and countries revert to a smaller size.

A world union is created. After this, there are no further changes in political structure.

Naturally, it is possible for some configuration of parameters that the world skips one

or two of these stages. For instance, the second stage may not exist if the cost of war is

high (high values of ω and µ). Or the third stage might not exist if economies of scope are

strong (high values of κ). Another possibility not shown in the picture is that, before the

great powers decide to abandon imperial conquest and form the world union, all localities

that don’t belong to empires form a smaller free union. Such a free union is never optimal

if it is too small because there are too many empires (high values of π). In any case, our

objective is not to provide a detailed taxonomy of cases but instead to show that our simple

model is capable of helping us understand the relationship between globalization and political

structure.

21

Page 23: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

4 World, Regions and Countries

The world so far lies in an abstract space in which all localities are symmetric and equidistant.

In reality, geography is much more complex. The world is made of continents and regions,

and more proximate areas tend to be more integrated, both economically and politically. We

can capture some of these aspects with simple modifications of our baseline model. Besides

the added realism, this extension will help us rationalize why the process of formation of

unions tends to be gradual and may start at the regional level.

4.1 Regions

Suppose that the world is divided into r ∈ N symmetric regions, each of them containing a

measure 1/r of localities. There is a measure τ r of goods that are traded only within the

region, among 1/r localities, and a measure τw of goods that are traded with all localities in

the world. As before, consumption of nontraded industries is cl(m, i) = e−η and consumption

of world-traded industries is cl(m, i) = e−blm . In industries that are traded only regionally,

instead, there is partial specialization: cl(m, i) = e−η if m and l do not belong to the same

region and cl(m, i) = e−blm otherwise. Thus, utility derived from consumption of market

goods in a locality belonging to region Rl is:

WMl = − (1− τw − τ rr) η − τw

∫ 1

0

blmdm− τ r∫m∈Rl

blmdm. (25)

Notice that borders within a region have a cost of (τw + τ r) β, while borders across regions

only cost τwβ. This is because the volume of trade is higher within than between regions. It

follows immediately that, other things equal, it is better to form countries (or unions) with

localities in the same region.

Another important aspect that we want to capture is the possible difference in the cost

of forming regional and world unions. To do so, we generalize our description of economies

of scope in the provision of government services. So far, we have assumed that the cost

of providing different economic and cultural types of government does not depend on the

identity of these types. This was a natural assumption, given the symmetry of the model.

However, once we introduce regions, it is equally reasonable to think that sharing government

types with localities within the same region is less costly than sharing them at the world

22

Page 24: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

level. Hence, we now assume:

κ =

{κr if gEl (x) = 0 for all x /∈ Rl

κr + κw otherwise. (26)

The higher cost of sharing economic regulations at the world level may capture the higher

coordination and transaction costs when providing types that are too far apart.

4.2 Diplomacy in a World of Regions

We can now compare welfare across different political structures. As a first step, we focus

on the case without empires, i.e., when the cost of war is prohibitively high. Assume for

simplicity that√φ/(δ − β) < 1/r, which implies that countries are always smaller than

regions. If we identify regions with real-world continents, this seems to be the empirically

more relevant case, especially if we disregard colonial powers. Then, the welfare generated

by a world of countries is:

WN = maxSN∈[0,1/r]

{−(

1− τw −τ rr

)η − τwβ (1− SN)− τ rβ

(1

r− SN

)− δSN −

φ

SN

},

(27)

where optimal country size is still given by Equation (12) with τ = τw + τ r.

A world of regional unions delivers welfare:

WR = maxSU∈[0,1/r]

{−(

1− τw −τ rr

)η − τwβ

(1− 1

r

)− δSU −

φ

SU− κr

}, (28)

where optimal country size is still given by Equation (14) and we have already used the

result that the optimal size of a regional union is the entire region. Finally, welfare in a

world union is:

WU = maxSU∈[0,1/r]

{−(

1− τw −τ rr

)η − δSU −

φ

SU− κr − κw

}, (29)

with the same optimal country size SU .

Once again, the equilibrium political structure is the one associated with the highest

welfare. As in the benchmark model, for τ r = τw = 0, the world is made of countries only.

However, an increase in either τ r or τw, raises welfare in all types of unions relatively more

than in countries. Hence, if the cost of forming unions is suffi ciently low, then globalization

will change the equilibrium political structure from countries to unions.

23

Page 25: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

But what kind of union will arise? ComparingWR andWU shows that the regional union

is preferred to the world union ifτwκw

<1

β

r

r − 1. (30)

Intuitively, the regional union is preferred when the additional hurdle of a global government

is high (κw) and when most of trade is regional, i.e., when regions are large (low r) and

world tradables are scarce (low τw). If κw > β(1 − 1/r), then the regional union always

dominates the world union and the latter will never appear. If instead κw < β(1 − 1/r),

regional unions may still arise first, but may be followed by world unions if τw becomes

suffi ciently high. Finally, since a world union facilitates trade in all traded industries, any

increase in τ = τw + τ r raises welfare in the world union weakly more than in the regional

union. It follows that regional unions may precede the world union but cannot follow it.

4.3 War and Conquest in a World of Regions

We now return to the model of war and conquest. If empires are suffi ciently few in number

and small in size to ensure that regions always contain free countries, then the analysis in the

previous section can be extended in a straightforward way to the case with regions. There is,

however, a different scenario that seems worth exploring. Suppose that all the great powers

are concentrated in one region and all the localities of that region are great powers. This case

corresponds to a world in which one area, which we call the “West,”has developed a superior

military technology. We now briefly sketch the equilibrium political structure focusing on

localities in the West.

The assumption that great powers can successfully coordinate to avoid conflict between

themselves implies that the West will be evenly split into imperial metropolises and each

empire will conquer colonies located in other regions. While localities prefer to form peaceful

countries within a region, great powers that are geographically proximate must seek far away

colonies to avoid clashing with each other. We also maintain the assumption that the world

is suffi ciently large that the great powers can always conquer their desired empires and that

the imperial metropolis does not extend outside the entire region.

The welfare WE of a metropolis in an empire outside of any economic union is:

WE = maxE∈[0,1/rµ]

{−(

1− τw −τ rr

)η − τwβ (1− E)− τ rβ

(1

r−M

)− δM − φ

E− ω

},

(31)

24

Page 26: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

with M = µE, and the preferred size of an empire is:

E =

√φ

δµ− β (τw + τ rµ). (32)

Consider now unions. Note that, by definition, a regional union cannot include outside

colonies (or else the cost of forming it would be κr + κw). It follows that if great powers

decide to form a regional union, it will be of peaceful countries with corresponding welfare

WR. Moreover, under the maintained assumption that Condition (22) holds, world unions

are also ruled by diplomacy, so that they generate welfare WU . Once again, the equilibrium

political structure will correspond to WP = max {WN ,WE,WR,WU}.As in the previous section, globalization increases the benefit of war relative to peaceful

country formation. At the same time, however, globalization increases welfare in unions

more than in countries and empires. Hence, countries can be replaced by empires, and both

countries and empires can be replaced by unions.

Figure 7 shows how the equilibrium political structure changes with globalization, mea-

sured by τ = τw + τ r, in the most interesting four-stage scenario. At low levels of global-

ization, there are only countries composed of localities belonging to the same region. The

size of these countries is represented by black line. As τ increases, the great powers in the

West start to build large empires, conquering colonies in other regions. During these initial

stages, the size of countries and empires grow with globalization. At some point, however, τ

becomes so large that great powers prefer to form peaceful unions. Once the war technol-

ogy is dismissed, however, political integration is more valuable at the regional level. Hence,

cross-regional empires are replaced by regional unions. Finally, as globalization proceed even

further, regional unions are replaced by the world union. As in the previous section, depend-

ing on the values of parameter, it is possible that the world skips some of these stages. Rather

than considering all the possible cases, we next use the model to discuss various historical

episodes.

5 An Interpretation of Historical Experience

We conclude by using our analytical results to attempt a suggestive narrative of the polit-

ical evolution of modern Europe (and the world). Since the late Middle Ages, European

sovereign states on average grew in size until the end of the 19th century, when this trend

was dramatically reversed. For example, Kitamura and Lagerlöf (2015) show that border

25

Page 27: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

­2.0

­1.5

­1.0

­0.5

0.0

tau

lnS

Figure 7: Countries, Empires and Regional Unions. The figure shows how the world politicalstructure changes with globalization for the case τ r = τw = τ/2. The black line is the sizeof peaceful countries, the red line is the size of empires, the brown line is the regional unionand the green line is the world union.

areas declined monotonically from 1500 to 1900, and then started to increase. Our model

seems particularly appropriate to explain this evolution. Medieval Europe was fragmented

into hundreds of small states at a time when trade was insecure and limited to few commodi-

ties. The early modern period saw important changes in both the economic and the political

organization of the continent. With the Commercial Revolution, trade began to flourish and

the feudal system started to be replaced by a smaller number of countries of growing size.

While in 1600 there were 112 sovereign states in Europe and the Near East, at the beginning

of 1800 the number had fallen to 79.

The Industrial Revolution gave trade an even more prominent role and triggered ma-

jor changes in socioeconomic conditions that ultimately made the rise of the nation state

possible. Trade expansion was enabled by the introduction of canals, improved roads and

railways. At the same time, the high degree of political fragmentation at the time of the

Congress of Vienna (1815) was followed by the unification of Germany and Italy (1871) and

the further consolidation of other nation states. The economic rationale of building large

internal markets was especially evident in the case of German unification, which started

with the formation of a custom union (Zollverein) and had as a major consequence the

drastic improvement in transportation infrastructure. This process of political centralization

culminated at the beginning of 1900, when Europe was dominated by just 28 independent

26

Page 28: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

Figure 8: Europe after the Congress of Vienna (1815)

states.

Yet, the twentieth century marks a turning point. It saw the rise of international organi-

zations both at the global level, such as the League of Nations, and at the regional level, such

as the European Community. One of the key objectives of many of these supra-national or-

ganizations was precisely to promote free markets. Simultaneously, Europe entered a stage

of political fragmentation, with the number of independent states growing to 58 in 2000.

This pattern of an initial decline and subsequent increase in the number of countries is not

confined to Europe only. For instance, the number of African countries fell from 36 in 1816

to 4 in 1914, to rise again to 51 in 2000. Similarly, in South-East Asia, this numbers changed

from 37 to 4 and then 20 in the years 1816, 1914 and 2000, respectively.14 However, to better

interpret the political evolutions in these regions, it is important to bring conflict into the

picture.

Our model of war and conquest seems broadly consistent with the rise and fall of colonial

14The number of countries is taken from Butcher and Griffi ths (2013).

27

Page 29: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

Figure 9: Europe before World War I (1914)

empires. In our theory, empires are built to extract trade surplus from the colonies and

disappear when the union is formed to foster free markets. According to historians and in

line with this view, one of the key driving forces behind colonial expansion was the desire to

secure trade and access to scarce resources in an era of revived commerce, but when mercan-

tilist practices where common. The scarcity of land and the desire to avoid powerful rivals

induced European great powers to expand by conquering territories overseas. Despite some

notable setbacks, colonialism continued to grow prior to World War I and finally collapsed

after World War II. The sharp decline of empires started after the creation of international

agreements aimed at promoting economic cooperation. This is no coincidence. In the words

of Spruyt (2005) and Rosecrance (1986), empires dissolved, often peacefully, because the

gains through commerce displaced gains through territorial acquisition.15 There is also evi-

dence that international organizations played a direct role in the process of decolonization.

For example, in 1960 the UN General Assembly voted the Declaration on the Granting of

15Bonfatti (2012) also attributes the fall of empires to the growing importance of trade between industrialcountries relative to trade with colonies.

28

Page 30: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

Figure 10: Europe Today (2014)

Independence to Colonial Countries and Peoples.

Focusing on size, the model shares with Alesina and Spolaore (2003) the prediction that

empires should be larger than democratic countries, a result which is confirmed by a quick

look at Figure 2. Moreover, the model suggest that countries may form and grow for the

desire to increase military might and build an empire or embark into colonial adventures.

This is indeed one of the recognized reasons behind the unification of Germany. Interestingly,

our theory also suggests that great powers switch to the union at higher levels of globalization

than consensual countries.16 Consistently, Figure 2 shows that size started to fall earlier on

for countries than for empires. Finally, the model predicts conflict to initially increase with

globalization and then fall drastically after the formation unions. Data on changes of borders

from Correlates of War seem supportive. The percentage of peaceful changes of borders fell

from 70% in the period 1816-1900 to 62% in the years 1901-1950, and then rose to 89% in

the period 1951-2008. Moreover, promoting peace by tightening economic integration was

16Formally, the emergence of empires unambiguously retards the creation of the world union. Moreover,unions of free countries may emerge earlier, with empires joining later on.

29

Page 31: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

among the explicit goals of the European Union and the WTO.

The model can also be used to interpret the foundation and growth of the United States.

Improvements in transportation technology and the desire to create a large internal market

were important factors in its westward expansion. The abundance of land made it possible

to create one of the largest countries in the world, without the need to seek far away colonies.

Despite its size, the United States avoided the phase of collapse and political fragmentation

by choosing an institutional system with multiple levels of government. In this light, the

experience of the United States follows the main pattern predicted by our theory: the creation

and expansion of the federal government, which can be interpreted as a regional union,

coincided with the fragmentation and loss of political power of individual states.

After the Declaration of Independence, the borders of the original thirteen states extended

up to the Mississippi river while the remaining land was occupied by French and Spanish

colonies (later on part of Mexico) and by many tribes of native Americans living essentially in

autarky. As the federal government acquired land and built roads westward, its territory was

gradually fragmented into the fifty states. This process followed a common pattern. First,

new land was annexed as large “territories;” subsequently this land was broken into new

states. Federal expansion was followed not just by the creation of new states, but also by the

break-up of existing ones. For example, the former Republic of Texas (an independent nation

until 1846) encompassed large parts of current Oklahoma, Kansas, Colorado, Wyoming and

New Mexico; similarly, Georgia, Massachusetts, North Carolina and Virginia all lost land to

form new states.

Finally, our theory has been motivated by modern and contemporary political and eco-

nomic events because our model of trade and globalization seems especially suited to study

the period after the Industrial Revolution. Yet, some of its key implications seems consis-

tent with ancient history as well. For instance, several historians stress the importance of

trade and market size for the expansion of countries. According to Pirenne (1925, 1939),

the Roman civilization was heavily dependent upon Mediterranean trade and it collapsed

when trade ended with the Arab conquest.17 In his view, the cutting of major trade routes

forced individual regions into self-suffi ciency and this contributed to the consequent decline

and fragmentation of Western civilization into the Middle Ages.

17Similary, Friedman (1977) argues that trade increases the value of land and hence promotes territorialexpansion.

30

Page 32: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

6 Conclusion

In this paper, we have studied how the forces of globalization contribute to shape the world’s

political structure. Our theory has shown that the expansion of trade opportunities can help

explain two salient puzzling phenomena in recent history. First, the rise and subsequent fall

in the size of countries observed during the 19th and 20th century. Second, the seemingly

contradictory trends towards more political integration across countries and more political

fragmentation within countries in the second half of the 20th century. Our theory is broadly

consistent with a variety of historical episodes. Despite its simplicity, our model has proved

capable of providing a remarkably rich picture. Yet, there are several important factors

that we have deliberately left aside. We now briefly mention three that seem particularly

promising for future research.

First, in this paper we have focused on economic globalization as an expansion of trade

opportunities. However, in reality globalization is a much more complex process that also

affects cultural preferences. If cultural globalization lowers the preference for heterogeneity,

it will also reduce the cost of removing borders. Hence, cultural globalization may reinforce

political integration, but may also lower the value of economic unions. The equilibrium polit-

ical structure may then be the result of a race between economic and cultural globalization.

In a similar vein, cultural preferences may be affected by the political choices. For example,

historically governments have often taken actions aimed at homogenizing their populations

(Alesina and Reich 2015).

Second, we have modeled economic unions as agreements aimed at facilitating trade.

Although this approach is both simple and realistic, it abstracts from another important role

of unions, namely, to solve cross-border externalities associated with domestic government

activity (Alesina, Angeloni and Etro 2005). Since globalization is likely to exacerbate such

policy externalities (Broner and Ventura 2011; Epifani and Gancia 2009), it increases the

value of forming unions. However, in this case international agreements must be properly

designed to eliminate any incentive for individual countries to free ride.

Finally, our concept of locality abstracts from internal heterogeneity both along cultural

and economic lines. Yet, historical experience suggests that internal conflict has played a

role in many processes of country formation and break-up (Bolton and Roland 1996, 1997).

It would be interesting to see how globalization also affects political structure through its

effect on domestic heterogeneity and conflict.

31

Page 33: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

References

[1] Alesina, Alberto, Ignazio Angeloni and Federico Etro (2005). “International Unions,”

American Economic Review 95, 602-15.

[2] Alesina, Alberto and Bryony Reich (2015). “Nation Building,”NBER Working Paper

No. 18839.

[3] Alesina, Alberto, and Enrico Spolaore (1997). “On the Number and Size of Nations,”

Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 1027—1056.

[4] Alesina, Alberto, and Enrico Spolaore (2003). The Size of Nations. Cambridge, MA:

MIT Press.

[5] Alesina, Alberto, Enrico Spolaore and Romain Wacziarg (2000). “Economic Integration

and Political Disintegration,”American Economic Review 90(5): 1276—1296.

[6] Besley, Timothy, and Stephen Coate (2003). “Centralized versus Decentralized Provision

of Local Public Goods: A Political Economy Approach,”Journal of Public Economic

87: 2611—2637.

[7] Boffa, Federico, Amedeo Piolatto, and Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto (2015). “Political Cen-

tralization and Government Accountability,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, forth-

coming.

[8] Bolton, Patrick, and Gerard Roland (1996). “Distributional Conflicts, Factor Mobility

and Political Integration,”American Economic Review 86(2): 99—104.

[9] Bolton, Patrick, and Gerard Roland (1997). “The Breakup of Nations: A Political

Economy Analysis,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 1057—1090.

[10] Bonfatti, Roberto (2012).“Trade and the Pattern of European Imperialism, 1492-2000,”

Oxford University Department of Economics Discussion Paper No. 618.

[11] Broner, Fernando and Jaume Ventura (2011). “Globalization and Risk Sharing,”Review

of Economic Studies 78(1): 49-82.

[12] Butcher, Charles, and Ryan Griffi ths (2013). “Introducing the International System(s)

Dataset (ISD), 1816-2011.”International Interactions 39(5): 748—768.

32

Page 34: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

[13] Casella, Alessandra (2001). “The Role of Market Size in the Formation of Jurisdictions,”

Review of Economic Studies 68: 83—108.

[14] Casella, Alessandra, and Feinstein, Jonathan S. (2002). “Public Goods in Trade: On

the Formation of Markets and Jurisdictions,” International Economic Review 43(2):

437—462.

[15] Epifani Paolo and Gino Gancia (2009).“Openness, Government Size and the Terms of

Trade,”Review of Economic Studies 76, 629—668.

[16] Friedman, David D. (1977). “A Theory of the Size and Shape of Nations,”Journal of

Political Economy 86(1): 59—77.

[17] Hugot, Jules (2015). “Trade Costs and the Two Globalizations: 1827-2012.”Working

paper, Pontificia Universidad Javeriana.

[18] Kitamura, Shuhei, and Nils-Petter Lagerlöf (2015). “Natural Borders.” IIES Seminar

Paper No. 773.

[19] Lockwood, Benjamin (2002). “Distributive Politics and the Costs of Centralization,”

Review of Economic Studies 69(2): 313—337.

[20] Maddison, Angus (1995). Monitoring the world economy, 1820-1992. Paris: OECD.

[21] Maddison, Angus (2001). The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris: OECD.

[22] Martin, Philippe, Thierry Mayer and Mathias Thoenig (2008). “Make Trade Not War?”

Review of Economic Studies 75(3): 865—900.

[23] Oates, Wallace E. (1972). Fiscal Federalism. New York, NY: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

[24] Pascali, Luigi (2014) “The Wind of Change: Maritime Technology, Trade and Economic

Development.”CAGE Working Paper No. 195.

[25] Pirenne, Henri (1925). Medieval Cities: Their Origins and the Revival of Trade. Prince-

ton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

[26] Pirenne, Henri (1939). Mohammed and Charlemagne. New York, NY: Norton.

[27] Rosecrance, Richard (1986). The Rise of the Trading State: Commerce and Conquest

in the Modern World. New York, NY: Basic Books.

33

Page 35: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

[28] Ruta, Michele (2005). “Economic Theories of Political (Dis)integration,” Journal of

Economic Surveys 19: 1—21.

[29] Singer, David J., and Melvin Small (1966). “The Composition and Status Ordering of

the International System: 1815-1940”, World Politics 18: 236—282.

[30] Spruyt, Hendrik (2005). Ending Empire: Contested Sovereignty and Territorial Parti-

tion. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

34

Page 36: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

A Appendix

A.1 Data Sources

The trade share reported in Figure 1 is merchandise exports as percent of GDP in 1990

prices, from Maddison (1995, 2001). Maddison provides trade data for selected countries in

the years 1820, 1870, 1913, 1929, 1950, 1973 and 1998. To avoid compositional effects, we

report the value of merchandise export as a share of GDP for the set of countries with data

for all the years (Austria, Belgium, France, Italy, Spain, Switzerland, the United Kingdom

and the United States). The trade share computed using the data for all available countries

in every year is very similar to the one displayed in Figure 1.

The number of countries is reported for the same years. Data on the number of countries

in the twentieth century is not very controversial. For the nineteenth century, however,

some leading conventions grossly underestimate the number of countries. For example, the

“International System”developed by Singer and Small (1966) and adopted in the Correlates

of War project or in the Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive, only includes countries

with international recognition. In particular, prior to 1920, the criteria to be recognized as an

independent country were to have population greater than 500,000 and have had diplomatic

missions at or above the rank of charge d’affaires with Britain and France. Clearly, this

definition is too strict for our purposes, which require the identification of even relatively

small political units living in economic and political autarky. We follow Butcher and Griffi ths

(2013) who recognize the problem and offer alternative sets of criteria to identify the number

of countries between 1816 and 2011.

The number of WTO members is from the WTO’s website.

The size of countries and empires displayed in Figure 2 is from the Cross-National Time-

Series Data Archive (CNTS). It provides data on contiguous territorial area in thousand

square miles for all countries existing in a given year according to the International State

System. In a few instances, missing data have been imputed cross-checking major territorial

changes from other sources (China and Persia before 1860). Area of empire is provided

for a consistent sample of 13 countries: Austria-Hungary (later Austria), Belgium, France,

Germany (Prussia), Italy (Sardinia), Japan, Netherlands, Portugal, Russia, Spain, Turkey

(Ottoman Empire), United Kingdom, and United States. For these countries, empire area

includes “overseas” territories (i.e., colonies). Data for the two modern wartime periods,

1914-1918 and 1940-1945 (1938-1954 for Empires) are missing.

European political maps where drawn using the online software GeaCron (http://www.

35

Page 37: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

geacron.com). This software provides a geo-temporal database that can be used to draw

geopolitical maps of any region in the world, in any given historical time period. The

number of independent states in Europe and Near East reported in Section 5 is taken from

Euratlas-Nüssli (http://www.euratlas.com).

A.2 Computing Equilibrium Consumptions

Locality l maximizes

WMl =

∫ 1

0

∫ 1

0

ln cl (m, i) dmdi (A1)

subject to the following budget constraint:∫ 1

0

∫ 1

0

pl (m, i) [cl (m, i)− ql (m, i)] dmdi ≤ 0, (A2)

where ql (m, i) and pl (m, i) are the production and price of input m of industry i in locality

l. The productions ql (m, i) must be consistent with available technology as described in

the text. Since individuals are atomistic, they take prices as given in their maximization

problems.

We claim now that equilibrium prices are given as follows:

pl (m, i) =

{blm if i ∈ [0, τ ]

η if i ∈ (τ , 1]. (A3)

To prove this claim, note first that all localities spend the same on each input: di. Thus,

the world share of spending on each input is also di. Let world income be Y . Then, the

spending on each input is Y di. We next examine productions. Consider first nontraded

industries. Our assumptions on preferences and technology ensure that all localities use the

specialization technology and produce η−1di units of each nontraded input. Thus, the value

of the production of each nontraded input is (η/η)di =di. Consider next traded industries.

The assumption that blm < η ensures that all localities prefer to use the technology based on

specialization. Thus, the value of the production of each traded input is 1× di = di. Since

world income is Y = 1, spending in each input is also di. This proves our claim.18

18It is straightforward to show that this equilibrium is unique. First, rule out variation in the prices oftraded inputs since this would generate excess demand (supply) of cheap (expensive) varieties. Second, ruleout that the relative prices of traded and nontraded varieties be above (below) blm/η since this would leadto an excess demand (supply) of nontraded inputs.

36

Page 38: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

With these prices at hand, we can compute the equilibrium productions and consumptions

described in the text.

A.3 Dealing with Integer Constraints

A world without unions consists of N∗ ∈ N countries of measure Sn > 0 each, such that∑N∗

n=1 Sn = 1 and utilitarian social welfare is W =∑N∗

n=1 SnWn (Sn).

The welfare function

Wn (Sn) = − (1− τ) η − τβ (1− Sn)− δSn −φ

Sn(A4)

is concave in Sn and increasing at Sn = 0. For all τ < (δ − φ) /β it has a unique maximum

at Sn = SN .

Pareto effi ciency then requires that either Sn ≤ SN for all n or Sn ≥ SN for all n, or

else some localities could leave a country with excessive size Sn > SN and join another with

insuffi cient size Sn < SN , raising the welfare of every locality in both countries.

Utilitarian welfare maximization requires all countries to have the same size. If Sm >

Sn > SN then transferring the marginal locality from m to n not only raises its welfare,

but it also raises the welfare of Sm localities by more than it lowers the welfare of Sn < Sm

localities. Likewise if Sm < Sn < SN .

Therefore, once integer constraints are taken into account, the utilitarian welfare optimum

without unions is a partition of the world into a number

N∗ = arg maxN∈N

{τβ

N− δ

N− φN

}(A5)

of identical countries. The maximand has strictly decreasing differences in (N, τ) because

for any τH > τL and and NH > NL,

W (NH , τH)−W (NH , τL) = (τH − τL)β

NH

< W (NL, τH)−W (NL, τL) = (τH − τL)β

NL

. (A6)

Thus, the welfare-maximizing number of countries N∗C is decreasing in τ in the sense of

monotone comparative statics. It is likewise decreasing in β, and increasing in δ and φ.

By the same reasoning, the utilitarian welfare optimum with unions is a partition of the

37

Page 39: Globalization and Political Structure Giacomo paper.pdfGlobalization and Political Structure Gino Gancia, Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto and Jaume Ventura February 2016 Abstract The –rst

world into atomistic countries joined into a number

N∗U = arg maxN∈N

{τβ

N− φN

}(A7)

of identical unions.

38