causality and determinants of government

32
Causality and Determinants of Government Spending and Economic Growth: The Philippine Experience 1980-2004 JODYLYN M. QUIJANO* and Dante R. Garcia** ABSTRACT This paper presents evidence using Granger-causality test that there is no support of Wagnerian hypothesis in the Philippines. Johansen’s co- integration and vector-error correcting method established a long-run relationship between government spending and economic growth from 1980 - 2004. It was found that short-run changes in real GDP have significant positive effects on government spending and that about 1.38 percent of the discrepancy between the actual and the long-run, or equilibrium, value of real GDP is eliminated or corrected each year. Using stepwise multiple regression analysis, private investment, degree of openness, and people power movement were identified as significant factors affecting government spending. On the other hand, factors like private investment, supply of revenue, public debt, degree of openness, political stability, and the commencement of the World Trade Organization were found to be statistically significant affecting economic growth. Keywords: econometrics, Granger-causality test, Wagner theory, Johansen’s co-integration, government spending, economic growth. 1

Upload: vunhu

Post on 02-Jan-2017

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Causality and Determinants of Government

Causality and Determinants of Government Spending and Economic Growth:

The Philippine Experience 1980-2004

JODYLYN M. QUIJANO*and Dante R. Garcia**

ABSTRACT

This paper presents evidence using Granger-causality test that there is no support of Wagnerian hypothesis in the Philippines. Johansen’s co-integration and vector-error correcting method established a long-run relationship between government spending and economic growth from 1980 - 2004. It was found that short-run changes in real GDP have significant positive effects on government spending and that about 1.38 percent of the discrepancy between the actual and the long-run, or equilibrium, value of real GDP is eliminated or corrected each year.

Using stepwise multiple regression analysis, private investment, degree of openness, and people power movement were identified as significant factors affecting government spending. On the other hand, factors like private investment, supply of revenue, public debt, degree of openness, political stability, and the commencement of the World Trade Organization were found to be statistically significant affecting economic growth.

Keywords: econometrics, Granger-causality test, Wagner theory, Johansen’s co-integration, government spending, economic growth.

__________________________* Ph.D. Holder in Economics, University of Santo Tomas, Metro-Manila, Philippines. Oct. 2005** Ph.D. Holder and Professor, University of Santo Tomas, Metro-Manila, Philippines.

1

Page 2: Causality and Determinants of Government

I. INTRODUCTION

There have been numerous articulations of the propositions

concerning the causes of economic growth and until now it is still an

enduring subject to discuss on. The country’s initial conditions and

availability of resources are both important factors of growth. While much

of the literature seem to depend on differences in country’s characteristics,

past studies have concluded that shock variables like terms of trade,

external transfers, change in number of war-related casualties per capita

on the national territory, presence of debt crisis, and government spending

can explain better the growth persistence.

The role and size of government are inter-related to each other.

Oftentimes, bigger size as reflected on its spending means greater roles to fulfill.

In the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, the provision of

public goods and services was perceived to be the primary role of

government. Mueller (2003) cites other equally important roles of

government such as being eliminator of externalities and redistributor of

income and wealth.

The Philippine Medium-Term Development Plan (MTDP) 2004-2010

apparently stipulates that government is expected to provide framework of

political stability, rule of law, sound macroeconomic policy, and physical

and human infrastructures within which an enterprise can flourish.

2

Page 3: Causality and Determinants of Government

Consequently, as government embraces more roles, there is accompanied

increase in its spending.

The central problem from an economic point of view as far as

government spending is concerned is not its level or rate of growth but

rather its effects on the potential rate of growth of the economy. Two

approaches of investigating it were recognized. One set of studies has

explored the quantitative impact of changes in government expenditure on

national income. Among them are Afxentiou (1982), Beck (1982),

Musgrave & Musgrave (1984), Saunders and Klau (1985), Ram (1986),

Nagarajan & Spears (1989), Yousefi and Abizadeh (1992), and Ahsan,

Kwan & Sahni (1996). Parallel efforts have also been made studying the

underlying causal process affecting government expenditure and economic

growth using Granger-causality test. Among the studies conducted were

Sahni and Singh (1984), Ram (1986), Singh (1996), Ansari et al. (1997),

Ghali (1998), Thornton (1999), Burney (2002), and Al-Faris (2002).

The existence of a possible long-run equilibrium relationship

between economic growth (national income) and public expenditure growth

where the former Granger-causes the latter is the basic thrust of

Wagnerian hypothesis. Several empirical studies using Granger-causality

test which conform the validity of Wagnerian hypothesis include the works

of Yousefi and Abizadeh (1992), Hsieh and Lai (1994), Ansari et al. (1997),

Osoro (1997), Thornton (1999), Islam (2001), Al-Faris (2002), Chang

3

Page 4: Causality and Determinants of Government

(2002). Country-specific studies confirming Wagner’s hypothesis are those

of Khan (1990) for Pakistan, Gyles (1991) for the United Kingdom, Lin

(1995) for Mexico, Nomura (1995) for Japan, and Singh (1996) for India.

Keynesian fiscal policy, on the other hand, subscribes to the notion

that it is government spending that Granger-causes economic growth.

Among empirical works that yielded results confirming it are Hsieh and Lai

(1994), Ansari et al. (1997), Ghali (1998), Rodrick (1998), Fasano and

Wang (2001), Burney (2002), Chang (2002), and Perotti (2002). However,

none of them has specifically investigated the validity of Wagnerian

hypothesis in the context of the Philippines.

A lot are saying that Philippines is heavily adopting Keynesian

economics but this needs to be validated empirically. As it experienced a

lot of economic changes from 1980-2004 then an empirical study

examining government spending and growth effects of political freedom,

people power movement, different types of crisis, and commencement of

World Trade Organization is of great interest. This is in addition to the

examination of the effect of private investment, supply of revenue,

employment rate, total outstanding public debt, and degree of openness to

government spending and economic growth.

Thus, the aim of this paper is to identify the true nature of

government spending and economic growth using Granger-causality test

and to model their short-run dynamics using Johansen’s cointegration test

4

Page 5: Causality and Determinants of Government

and vector-error correction model. Another objective of this paper is to

determine the significant variables affecting them using multiple regression

analysis.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section II

presents the theoretical framework, Section III the data and empirical

results, and Section IV the conclusion.

II. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

A classic approach in explaining growth of government spending is

the Wagnerian hypothesis stating that in the process of economic

development, government economic activity increases relative to private

economic activity (Wagner, 1876). In this facet, government spending (GS)

is an endogenous variable Granger-caused by economic growth (EG) and

other economic variables as shown in Equation 1.

(1) GS = α + β1 EG + β2 EV + μt

where: GS = government spending

EG = economic growth

EV = other explanatory variables

μt = error term

Wagner offered three reasons why this would be the case. First, the

administrative and protective functions of the state would substitute public

for private activity. Second, economic development would lead to an

5

Page 6: Causality and Determinants of Government

increase in “cultural and welfare” expenditures. And third, government

intervention would be required to manage and finance natural monopolies.

However, the relationship between economic growth and public

expenditure is perceived to be reversed within the Keynesian

macroeconomic framework. A fiscal expansion is expected as a result of

multiplier effect on output behind its assumption of price rigidity and the

possibility of excess capacity. A four-sector model shows an equilibrium

income when output equals demand (O’Sullivan & Sheffrin, 2003).

( 2 ) output = demand= {(C + I + G + (X – M)}

where: C = consumption

I = investment

G = government spending

(X-M) = net export

There are many factors affecting growth. Growth theory does not

only address the causes of economic growth but its implications to the

relative wealth of nations as well. The neo-classical growth models (as

developed by Solow, 1956 and Swan, 1956) for decades had been useful

in explaining growth in terms of income per capita which is exogenously

given (Wagner’s hypothesis). Their important assumption is that only

during the transition of economies to their steady state can economic

policy affect the rate of growth. Consequently, most researches focused

on the “division and stabilization of cake” instead of its “enlargement”.

6

Page 7: Causality and Determinants of Government

On the other hand, Romer (1989) and Lucas (1988) pioneering

works on the endogenous growth theory initiated the change on the role of

the government drastically. In all of its models, the government can either

directly or indirectly influence growth. The former growth theory implies the

government’s active role in providing subsidies while the latter implies a

once and for all necessary increase in investments.

Other than government spending, factors that have been identified

affecting long-run growth are, among others, private investment (Ghali,

2003), supply of revenues (Eken et al., 2000), population (Balisacan and

Mapa, 2004), degree of openness (Romer, 1989), trade intensity

(Grossman and Helpman, 1991), globalization (Rapacki, 2002), political

freedom (Brons et al., 2000), political stability (Olson, 1982), and fiscal

policies (Barro, 1990 and Glomm & Ravikumar, 1994 and 1997).

III. METHODOLOGY

Data and Variable Definitions

Data used in this study are annual series covering the period of 1980-

2004. The variables are in millions except employment rate and tax effort.

Variables are defined as follows:

GS = ln government spending

EG = ln real gross domestic product

EVS = ln significant explanatory variables obtained

PI = ln private investment

7

Page 8: Causality and Determinants of Government

SR = ln supply of revenues

ER = ln employment rate

PD = ln total outstanding public debt

DO = ln degree of openness

ln = the natural logarithm

DUMMY VARIABLES

PF = political freedom

where: 0 stands for year that election was not held

and 1 stands for year that election was held

CR = political, social, and economic instabilities

where: 0 stands for year that crisis was not experienced

and 1 stands for year that crisis took place

GB = globalization

where: 0 stands for pre-WTO, 1980-1994

and 1 stands for post-WTO, 1995-2004

PP = people power movement

where: 0 stands for pre-people power movement, 1980-1985

and 1 stands post-people power movement, 1986-2004

Economic growth is proxied by real GDP using 1985 as base year.

Supply of revenue is measured by the tax effort which is the ratio of total

tax collection to GDP while total outstanding public debt refers to the

obligations incurred by the government and all its branches, agencies, and

8

Page 9: Causality and Determinants of Government

instrumentalities including those of government monetary institutions.

Lastly, the degree of openness refers to the ratio of total export to real

GDP.

Data were obtained from the Philippine Statistical Yearbook and

Fiscal Statistics Handbook. These are the compilation reports made by

authoritative sources that include National Statistical Coordination Board

(NSCB), Bureau of Internal Revenue (BIR), Bureau of Customs (BOC),

Department of Labor and Employment (DOLE), National Economic

Development Authority (NEDA), Bureau of the Treasury (BOT), and

Department of Budget and Management (DBM).

The assigned values for the dummy variables were based from

historical facts such as the years when the local and national elections and

People Power took place. The occurrence of different types of crisis was

based from the special report of Andaya (2004) and Manasan (2004). On

the other hand, the WTO’s verity and its effects which served as bases in

examining the Philippine context spring forth from many works such as

those of Kopp (2000), and Balle and Vaidya (2002).

Empirical Results

It is common for economic variables to be stationary not in levels but in

first differences. This necessitates to apply Augmented-Dickey Fuller (ADF) test

as it assures that the probability structure of these variables are stable and they

9

Page 10: Causality and Determinants of Government

qualified for meaningful regression equation. It requires using an Augmented

Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test to reject the null hypothesis that a series is first

difference stationary or ~I(1) in this form:

(1) ∆ Yt = β 1 + β 2 t + ζ Yt-1 + α ∑ ∆ Yt-1 + ε t

where ∆ is the difference operator, Yt is the economic variables, Yt-1 is

their lagged differences to ensure that the residuals are white noise, and ε t

is the stationary random error (Dickey and Fuller, 1981). The test is carried

for all variables in level form first. As reported in column two of Table 1,

none of the test statistics can reject the null hypothesis of non-stationarity

since computed ADF did not exceed the critical values of ADF in the

bottom.

Apparently, each series is not stationary in level form. The ADF was

applied to the transformed series of each variable to check for the

possibility of stationarity in first differences, Third column reports that

computed ADF’s now exceed its critical values at 1, 5, and 10 percent

levels. Thus, the null hypothesis that the series is ~I(2) is rejected.

Table 1 Test Results for Unit RootsVARIABLES

AUGMENTED DICKEY-FULLER STATISTIC

LEVEL VARIABLES FIRST DIFFERENCE

Government Spending (GS) -2.086886 -3.357065*

Economic Growth (EG) -1.425864 -3.925132**

Private Investment (PI) -2.138746 -3.500650*

Supply of Revenues (SR) -0.103162 -3.603992*

Employment Rate (ER) -3.651567 -5.694969***

10

Page 11: Causality and Determinants of Government

Public debt (PD) -1.757545 -3.911684**

Degree of Openness (DO) -2.596166 -5.216117***The critical values for ADF are -4.4167, -3.6219, and -3.2474 for 1%***, 5%**, and 10%*, respectively.

Before applying the Johansen’s cointegration procedure, it is

necessary to determine the lag length of the VAR equation (2) which

should be high enough to ensure that the errors are approximately white

noise but small enough to allow estimation. In this paper, the lag length, k,

is chosen on the basis of the minimum value of Akaike Information

Criterion (AIC). The result of the test in the next table indicates that the

optimal lag length is four.

Table 2 TEST OF THE OPTIMAL LAG LENGTH OF VAR EQUATION

LAG 1 2 3 4 5 6 7AIC -7.138768 -5.415793 -4.608671 -4.364723 -4.708021 -4.998807 -5.211933

The cointegration is then applied in accordance to the methodology

suggested by Johansen (1988), and generalized in Johansen and Juselius

(1990). The process is used to investigate the long-run relationship

between government spending and economic growth and to ensure that

the regression is not spurious (i.e., meaningful). The time series Xt,

according to Johansen’s procedure is modeled as a vector autoregressive

(VAR) model in this form:

(2) ∆Xt = α + ∑ τi Xt-1 + π Xt-1 + λDt + η t

11

Page 12: Causality and Determinants of Government

where Xt is the vector of non-stationarity containing government spending

and real GDP, ∆ is the first-difference, α is the constant term, Dt is

stationary series, and η t is the random error.

Using the optimal lag length, k = 4, Table 3 shows the existence of

one cointegrating vector at 5% significance level as the likelihood ratio

exceeds the critical value at that level.

Table 3 JOHANSEN COINTEGRATION TEST AT LAG LENGTH (k) 4

Date: 09/10/05 Time: 06:00Sample: 1980 2004Included observations: 20Test assumption: Linear deterministic trend in the dataSeries: LNGOVTSPENDG LNREALGDP Lags interval: 4 to 4

Likelihood 5 Percent 1 Percent HypothesizedEigenvalue Ratio Critical Value Critical Value No. of CE(s) 0.667919 25.69094 25.32 30.45 None * 0.166541 3.643422 12.25 16.26 At most 1

*(**) denotes rejection of the hypothesis at 5%(1%) significance level L.R. test indicates 1 cointegrating equation(s) at 5% significance level

Unnormalized Cointegrating Coefficients:LNGOVTSPENDG LNREALGDP @TREND(81)

-0.144747 -6.177454 0.228847 0.522192 4.667166 -0.133207

Normalized Cointegrating Coefficients: 1 Cointegrating Equation(s)LNGOVTSPENDG LNREALGDP @TREND(81) C

1.000000 42.67769 -1.581019 -566.9367 (212.019) (7.68386)

Log likelihood 94.75686

The test was performed using an unrestricted intercept term in VAR

which assumes the existence of a deterministic time trend in the data.

Thus, they exhibit long-run stability. Under the unnormalized condition,

insignificant t value of government spending reveals that it is weakly

exogenous while real GDP is strongly exogenous. New estimates of

12

Page 13: Causality and Determinants of Government

coefficient when weak exogeneity restriction on government spending is

imposed are measured under the normalized condition. Its t value

(212.019) means that the real GDP is the one more deviating from its

equilibrium in the short-run. This necessitates the use of vector-error

correction model to measure the short-run dynamics.

The vector-error correction model which was first used by Sargan

(1964) is used with nonstationary series that are known to be cointegrated

(Danao, 2002 and Hatanaka, 1996). This model, as reflected by (α0) error

correction term in Equations 3 and 4, is used in identifying the short-run

adjustment toward its long-run equilibrium.

(3) GSt = αo + 1 GSt-1 +. ..+αnGSt-n + β1EG t-1 +…+ βnEG t-n + et

(4) EGt = αo + 1 EGt-1 +. ..+αnEGt-n + β1GS t-1 +…+ βnGS t-n + et

Table 4. ESTIMATES OF THE VEC MODEL

Date: 09/10/05 Time: 02:55 Sample(adjusted): 1985 2004 Included observations: 20 after adjusting endpoints Standard errors & t-statistics in parentheses

Error Correction: D(LNGOVTSPENDG) D(LNREALGDP)CointEq1 -0.005424 -0.013815

(0.00579) (0.00249)(-0.93637) (-5.55342)

D(LNGOVTSPENDG(-4)) -0.109405 0.091754 (0.27184) (0.11673)(-0.40246) (0.78605)

D(LNREALGDP(-4)) -0.326273 -0.509328 (0.36311) (0.15592)(-0.89856) (-3.26658)

C 0.036187 0.039827 (0.01041) (0.00447) (3.47550) (8.90797)

R-squared 0.203556 0.759289 Adj. R-squared 0.054223 0.714156 Log likelihood 38.21895 55.12588 Akaike AIC -3.421895 -5.112588

13

Page 14: Causality and Determinants of Government

Schwarz SC -3.222748 -4.913441 Determinant Residual Covariance 2.63E-07 Log Likelihood 94.75686 Akaike Information Criteria -8.375686 Schwarz Criteria -7.828034

These results show that short-run changes in real GDP have

significant positive effects on government spending and that about .013815

percent of the discrepancy between the actual and the long-run, or

equilibrium, value of real GDP is eliminated or corrected each year. On the

other hand, result also reveals that short-run changes in government

spending are statistically insignificant affecting real GDP.

The Johansen’s cointegration test (Table 3) reveals an initial finding

that real GDP is an exogenous factor affecting government spending. To

validate its accuracy, the Wagnerian hypothesis in the context of the

Philippines is examined using Granger-causality test. GSt is said to be

Granger-caused by EGt if the coefficients on the lagged of EGt are

statistically significant. The same is true for the other way around.

On the other hand, a bilateral causality is said to exist when both

coefficients are statistically significant, and there is independence when

both are statistically insignificant (Granger: 1981). The Granger-causality

test is a Wald test with the null hypothesis that GSt does not Granger-

cause EGt. The bivariate regressions that are run by the Eviews program

for this particular study are in these forms:

14

Page 15: Causality and Determinants of Government

(3) GSt = ro + j GSt-j + bi EGt-i + et

(4) EGt = go + i EGt-i + j GSt-j + ut

where: GSt and EGt are two stationary series representing government

spending and real GDP, respectively and i and j stand for lag lengths.

Table 4. GRANGER-CAUSALITY TEST OF GOVERNMENT SPENDING AND REAL GDP

Pairwise Granger Causality TestsDate: 09/12/05 Time: 15:52Sample: 1980 2004Lags: 4 Null Hypothesis: Obs F-Statistic Probability LNGOVTSPENDG does not Granger Cause LNREALGDP

21 2.69082 0.08235

LNREALGDP does not Granger Cause LNGOVTSPENDG 0.64987 0.63779

Test results in Table 4 show that the hypothesis that government

spending does not Granger-cause real GDP should be rejected but the

hypothesis that real GDP does not Granger-cause government spending

cannot be rejected. Therefore, it appears that Granger causality runs one-

way only from government spending to real GDP. This supports the notion

that Keynesian economics prevails in the Philippines, rather than

Wagnerian.

This part presents the significant determinants of both government

spending and economic growth. Table 5 provides the summary results for

government spending while Table 6 summarizes the significant factors

affecting economic growth using stepwise multiple regression analysis.

The log-linear regression model was chosen over the linear model on the

15

Page 16: Causality and Determinants of Government

bases of R2 value criterion, underlying theory, expected signs of the

coefficients of the explanatory variables, and their statistical significance

(Gujarati, 1999). This kind of model measures the elasticity of the

dependent variables (government spending and real GDP) with respect to

the explanatory variables chosen in this study on the basis of the past

empirical studies. Nonstationarity of data necessitates an application of the

first difference method while Prais-Winsten estimation method corrects the

initial results against serial autocorrelation which is common among time

series data (Gujarati, 1999).

Regression analysis for quantitative data was applied first to

determine separately the significant variables of government spending and

economic growth. These were regressed then with qualitative data

(Equations 5a and 6a).

(5) ln GS = + 1 lnPI + 2 lnSR + 3 lnER + 4 lnPD + 5 lnDO+I

(5a) ln GS = + 1…n lnEVS+ n+1 PF + n+2 CR +n+3GB +n+4 PP +I

(6) ln EG = + 1 lnPI + 2 lnSR + 3 lnER + 4 lnPD + 5 lnDO+I

(6a) ln EG = + 1…n lnEVS+ n+1 PF + n+2 CR +n+3GB +n+4 PP +I

Table 5. LOG-LINEAR MODEL OF GOVERNMENT SPENDINGWITH DUMMY VARIABLES

ln GS = 4.490 + .323 ln DO*+.204 ln PI*+ .145 ln SR** + .245 ln PD** -.043 PF - .039 CR (12.518) (10.523) (4.329) (1.654) (1.485) (-.973) (-.862) (.359) (.031) (.047) (.088) (.165) (.044) (.045)

+ .106 GB + .026 PP**(1.078) (1.374)(.059) (.019)

*Significant at .05, t = 1.746**Significant at .10, t = 1.337

16

Page 17: Causality and Determinants of Government

With t -values and standard error on the parenthesesR2 = .960 F = 245.236Adj. R2 = .958 F tab = 2.74D.W. = 1.892 df = 16 ; n = 24

Findings reveal in Table 5 that degree of openness and private investment

are significant at five percent level while supply of revenues, total outstanding

public debt, and people power movement are significant at ten percent level.

Since the coefficient of the dummy variable- people power movement- is

statistically significant, it can be inferred that there is difference in the average

government spending between the pre-people power movement and post-people

power movement. Its positive sign tells that government spending relatively

increased during the last years of Marcos. As indicated by R2, 96 percent of the

total variation in government spending is explained by variables used in this

analysis. Similarly, the computed F value is also very high as it affirms that the

whole model itself is statistically significant.

Table 6. LOG-LINEAR MODEL OF REAL GDP WITH DUMMY VARIABLES

ln EG = 8.654 + .168 ln DO*+ .303 ln SR*- .102 ln PD*+.177 ln PI* + .067 GB* - .017 CR* (15.391) (1.816) (-6.443) (-4.963) (3.952) (2.310) (1.834) (.562) (.093) (.047) (.021) (.045) (.029) (.009)

+ .049 PF + .020 FG(.585) (.320)(.083) (.063)

*Significant at .05, t = 1.746**Significant at .10, t = 1.337With t -values and standard error on the parenthesesR2 = .986 F = 274.883Adj. R2 = .983 F tab = 2.59D.W. = 1.979 df = 16 ; n = 24

Table 6 reports that degree of openness, supply of revenue, public

debt, private investment, globalization and presence of crisis are significant

at five percent level. Political, economic, and social instabilities adversely

17

Page 18: Causality and Determinants of Government

affect economic growth while the commencement of WTO clump up

economic growth. Holding other things constant, degree of openness

increases economic growth by .168 percent for its every one percent

increase. On the other hand, every one percent increase of private

investment, ceteris paribus, results to .177 percent increase of economic

growth. Since the computed F exceeds the tabulated F value, 2.59, then

as a test of overall significance, it is safe to conclude that the whole model

is statistically significant. As indicated by R2, almost 99 percent of the total

variation in economic growth is explained by the variables used in this study.

IV. CONCLUSION

From the results of this study four points merit emphasis. First, a

standard Johansen’s cointegration test for the existence of a long-run

relationship between government spending and real gross domestic

product was established. Over the period of 1980-2004, their positive

relationship has been established. Second, an evidence of Wagnerian

hypothesis in the short-run was identified. This result follows that economic

growth serves as an exogenous factor of government spending.

However, the Granger-causality test has proven that the Keynesian

proposition of government spending as a policy instrument to promote

long-run economic growth is supported by the data for the period covered.

Third, private investment, degree of openness, and people power

18

Page 19: Causality and Determinants of Government

movement are significant factors affecting government spending. And

lastly, significant factors affecting Philippine economic growth are private

investment, supply of revenue, total outstanding public debt, degree of

openness, globalization, and different types of crisis.

REFERENCES

Afxentiou, P.C. (1982). “Economic development and the public sector: An evaluation”. Atlantic Economic Journal (10), 32-38.

Ahsan, S., Kwan A., and Sahni B. (1996). “Cointegration and Wagner’s hypothesis: time series evidence for Canada”. Applied Economics (28), 1055-1058.

Al-Faris, A.F. (2002). “Public expenditure and economic growth in the Gulf Cooperation Council Countries”. Applied Economics (34), 1187-1193.

Ansari, M, Gordon, D., and Akuamoah C. (1997). “Keynes versus Wagner: public expenditure and national income for three African countries”. Applied Economics (29), 543-550.

Balisacan, Arsenio M. and Mapa, Dennis S. (2004). “Quantifying the impact of population on economic growth and poverty: The Philippines in an East Asian Context”. Paper presented in Hong Kong during the 9th Convention of the East Asian Economic Association, 13-14 November 2004.

Balle, Frank and Vaidya, Ashish. (2002). “A regional analysis of openness and government size”. Applied Economics Letters (9), 289-292.

Barro, Robert J. (1990). “Economic growth in a cross section of countries”. Quarterly Journal of Economics (106), 407-444.

Beck, M. (1982). ‘Toward a theory of public sector growth”. Public Finance (37), 313-56.

Bird, R.M. (1971). “Wagner’s law of expanding state activity”. Public Finance (51), 185-200.

Burney, Nadeem A. (2002). “Wagner’s hypothesis: evidence from Kuwait using cointegration tests”. Applied Economics (34), 49-57.

Chang, Tsangyao (2002). “An econometric test of Wagner’s law for six countries based on cointegration and error-correction modeling techniques”. Applied Economics (34), 1157-1169.

19

Page 20: Causality and Determinants of Government

Eken, S., T., Helbling, and A. Mazarei (2000). “Fiscal policy and growth in the Middle East and North Africa Region”. International Monetary Fund Working Paper no.101.

Fasano, Ugo and Wang Qing (2001). “Fiscal expenditure policy and non-oil economic growth: Evidence from GCC countries”. International Monetary Fund Working Paper no. 195.

Ghali, Khalifa H. (1998). “Government size and economic growth: Evidence from a multivariate cointegration analysis”. Applied Economics (31), 975-987.

Glomm, G. and B. Ravikumar (1994). “Growth effects of government spending on education”. Mimeo.

Granger, C.W.J. (1981). “Some properties of time series data and their use in econometric model specification”. Journal of Econometrics 16(1), 121-130.

Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1991). “Innovation and growth in the global economy”. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.

Gyles, A.F. (1991). “A time-domain transfer function model of Wagner’s Law: the case of the United Kingdom economy”. Applied Economics (23), 327-330.

Islam, Anisul M. (2001). “Wagner’s law revisited: cointegration and exogeneity tests for the USA”. Applied Economics Letters (8), 509-515.

Jin, Jang C. (2000). “Openness and growth: an interpretation of empirical evidence from East Asian countries”. Journal of International Trade and Economic Development 9(1), 5-17.

Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990). “Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration with applications to the demand for money”. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics (52), 169-210.

Khan, A.H. (1990). “Wagner’s law and the developing economy: a time-series evidence from Pakistan”. The Indian Journal of Economics, (38), 115-123.

Kopp, Andreas (2000). “Openness, intermediate imports, and growth”. Kiel Institute of World Economics Working Paper no. 996.

Lucas, R.E. (1988). “On the mechanics of economic development”. Journal of Monetary Economics (22), 3-42.

Manasan, Rosario G. (2004). “The Philippines fiscal position: Looking at the complete picture”. PIDS Policy Notes no.2004-07.

Miller, Roger Leroy (2003). “The Macroview Economics Today”.Pearson Education Inc.,

Addison Wesley, USA.

20

Page 21: Causality and Determinants of Government

Musgrave, R.A. and Musgrave, P.B. (1984). “Public finance in theory and Practice 4 th

ed”. McGraw-Hill, New York.

Nagarajan P. and Spears A. (1989). “Causality between government expenditure and economic growth: A comment”. Public Finance (44), 134-138.

Osoro, Nehemiah E. (1997). “Public spending, taxation, and deficits”. African Economic Research Consortium Research Paper no.62.

O’Sullivan, Arthur and Sheffrin, Steven (2003). “ Economics: Principles in action”. Prentice Hall, Needham, Massachussetts.

Perotti, Roberto (2002). “Fiscal policy in good times and bad”. Quarterly Journal of Economics (114), 1399-1436.

Ram, Rati (1986). “Government size and economic growth: A new framework and some evidence from cross-section and time series data”. American Economic Review 76(6), 191-203.

Rapacki, Ryszard (2002). “Public expenditure in Poland: Major trends, challenges and policy concerns”. Post-Communist Economies 14 (3), 341-359.

Rodrik, Dani (1998). “Why do more open economies have bigger governments?”. Journal of Political Economy 106(5), 997-1031.

Romer, Paul M. (1989). “Increasing returns and long-run growth”. Journal of Political Economy (94), 1002-1037.

Sahni, J. and Singh A (1984). “Causality between public expenditure and national income”. The Review of Economics and Statistics (66), 630-644.

Saunders, P. and Klau, F. (1985). “The role of the public sector: causes and consequences of the growth of government”. OECD Economies Studies, Special Issue, 11-239.

Seyfferth, Anne (1990). ‘economic development in the Philippines in a Far Eastern Context”. Economics Institute for Scientific Economic Policy (44), 112-125.

Singh, G. (1996). “Wagner’s law— a time series evidence from the Indian economy”. The Indian Journal of Economics (44), 349-359.

Solow, R.M. (1956). “A contribution to the theory of economic growth”. Quartely Journal of Economics (70), 65-94.

Swan, T. (1956). “Economic growth and capital accumulation”. Economic Record (32), 334-361.

Thornton, John (1999). “Cointegration, causality, and Wagner’s Law in 19th century Europe”. Applied Economics Letters (6), 413-416.

21

Page 22: Causality and Determinants of Government

Wagner, Adolf (1876). “Three extracts on public finance”. In classics in the theory of Public Finance (Eds) R.A. Musgrave and A.T. Peacock. St. Martin’s Press, New York.

Yousefi, Mahmood and Abizadeh, Sohrab (1992). “Wagner’s law: New evidence”. Atlantic Economic Journal 20(2) 100-110.

22