the case for free trade and the role of rtas p. j. lloyd and donald maclaren university of melbourne...

Post on 27-Mar-2015

216 Views

Category:

Documents

3 Downloads

Preview:

Click to see full reader

TRANSCRIPT

The Case for Free Trade and the The Case for Free Trade and the Role of RTAsRole of RTAs

P. J. Lloyd and Donald MacLarenUniversity of Melbourne

Seminar on

Regional Trade Agreements and the WTORegional Trade Agreements and the WTOGeneva, 14th November 2003

2

Introduction1. Predictions of trade theory2. Evidence from CGE models3. Hub and spokes arrangements4. Effects of RTAs on multilateral trade negotiations5. Conclusions

The Case for Free Trade and the Role The Case for Free Trade and the Role of RTAsof RTAs

3

RTA

Country 2 ROW

Country 1

4

1. Predictions of Trade Theory1. Predictions of Trade Theory

• The theory of RTAs on which GATT Article XXIV could have been based

• Viner’s contribution:– trade creation and trade diversion– “... where the trade-diverting effect is predominant, one

at least of the member countries is bound to be injured, the two combined will suffer a net injury, and there will be injury to the outside world and to the world at large.”

• During the 1950s and 1960s it was demonstrated that parts of Viner’s predictions may not hold, e.g., trade diversion did not necessarily imply a lowering of welfare

5

• Modern analytics for a single, open economy with perfect competition and constant returns to scale (first-generation assumptions), can use a compensation function:

B = e ( p, u ) – g ( p, v ) – ( p – p* ) m (1)

where e is national expenditure, g is national product and ( p – p* ) m is trade tax revenue

B measures the compensation needed to allow households in the economy to reach a given level of utility

6

Suppose this economy joins an RTAThen p will change as tariff rates are adjusted from pre-RTA

MFN levels to preferential RTA levelsThen

B = e g Rwhich can be expanded, after some algebra, to give

B = + trade volume + intra-union terms of trade + extra-union terms of trade (2)

The sign of B is ambiguous

If B < 0, the country gains; and if > 0, it loses

However, there is a presumption that members gain from the RTA

7

This expression for B also shows clearly that measuring changes in trade volumes alone will not predict whether a country gains or loses

Other assumptions:– imperfect competition (love of variety and economies of scale):

second generation models– investment, factor accumulation and growth: third generation models

Second and third generation models tend to strengthen the presumption that members gain

For second-generation models, equation (2) becomes

B = + trade volume + intra-union terms of trade + extra-union terms of trade + output + average cost + varieties

8

What are the welfare effects for excluded countries which, pre-RTA, traded with the members?– In first generation models, theory predicts that excluded

members, as a group, lose, although some individual countries may gain

– In second generation models, theory predicts that these losses may be greater than in first-generation models

What does the evidence from computable general equilibrium (CGE) models suggest?

9

2. Evidence from CGE Models2. Evidence from CGE Models

Structure:– data base of bilateral trade flows– data base of transportation costs and tariff rates– tariff on good i from region r to region s– behavioural equations– accounting identities

Caveats:– design of the experiment– values of the elasticities– the Armington assumption and CES functions: biases

Summary of Results:

10

• Formation of NAFTA (Brown et al. (1992)):– using a second generation model they found that

• each member gained• 31 excluded countries lost

– using a third generation model they found that• the gains to Mexico were three times greater• the excluded countries lost

• EU Single market (Haaland and Norman (1992)):– using a second generation model and representing deeper integration by

a 2.5% reduction in intra-EU trade costs, they found that• EU gained 0.64% of GDP (internal markets integrated) and 0.40% (internal

market segregated)• EFTA lost 0.22% and 0.15% of GDP, respectively

– conclusion: excluded members lose but the size depends on assumptions about market structure in the RTA

• Asia-Pacific Region

11

Table 1: Welfare Changes as a percentage of base period GDP

Bilateral PlurilateralHub and spokes

Global

RegionJapan-

Singapore

Japan- S.Korea-

China

ASEAN + 3

APEC (pref’ial)

Japan 0.00 0.25 0.34 0.74 0.98

Singapore 4.06 0.87 4.12 0.72 6.94

S. Korea 0.00 0.80 1.18 1.63 1.83

China 0.00 2.09 1.96 3.19 4.51

APEC 0.01 0.16 0.25 0.58 0.84

Total members

0.05 0.50 0.64 0.58 n.a.

Total non-members

0.01 0.03 0.06 0.12 n.a.

World 0.00 0.09 0.11 0.27 0.56

Source: Scollay and Gilbert (2001)

12

Conclusions about gainers and losers:– global, multilateral trade liberalisation generates the

greatest gains to the world economy– the size of the gains is dependent upon the underlying

theory, the base period and the design of the experiment

– countries, in aggregate, lose from being excluded from an RTA

– the larger the RTA, the larger are these losses– in principle, a Pareto improvement is possible but in the

absence of inter-regional transfers, RTAs are undesirable for outside countries

13

3. Hubs and Spokes3. Hubs and Spokes

The configuration of RTAs has changed:– from a given country being a member of one and only one

RTA, if a member at all– to the same country being a member of more than one RTA

The configuration today has been described as hub and spokes

The hub may be:– a single country, e.g., the U.S. or Singapore– a group of countries (plurilateral hub), i.e., an RTA itself, e.g.,

ASEAN

The spoke may be:– a single country– an RTA (plurilateral spoke)

14

Country 1:Hub

Country 2:Spoke

RTA1

ROW

RTA2 Country 3:Spoke

15

•USA

•Chile•Peru

•Russia•Korea

•Hong Kong

•China

•Japan

•AustraliaCER

ASEANCambodia VietnamMyanmar LaosMalaysia PhilippinesIndonesia Brunei

•Thailand

NAFTA

Singapore

•Canada

•Mexico

•New Zealand

•Papua New Guinea

RTAs in Effect in the APEC region, 2003

16

Hubs and spokes create:– two layers of discrimination:

• the hub enjoys access to each and every spoke on a preferential basis: as most hubs are developed countries, it is to them that the bulk of the gains have gone

• each spoke enjoys preferential access only to the hub• each hub and each spoke discriminates against non-

members

– complex rules of origin– forces for RTAs to coalesce into regional blocs– increased discrimination against excluded countries,

particularly developing and least-developed countries

17

4. Effects of RTAs on Multilateral 4. Effects of RTAs on Multilateral Trade LiberalisationTrade Liberalisation

The growth of RTAs may affect the rate of multilateral liberalisation by:– affecting the pace of liberalisation from MTNs: the

‘building block’ or ‘stumbling block’ debate– affecting the pace of unilateral liberalisations

Evidence on the first:– if based on theory, is ambiguous, depending on whether

the objective is welfare maximising or political self-interest

– if based on empirical evidence pre-Cancún, RTAs have not slowed the pace

– post-Cancún, the EU and the U.S. have signalled a passive role in MTN but a pro-active role in RTAs

18

Evidence on the second is mixed:– countries in ASEAN, CER and Latin America have

continued to liberalise unilaterally within their RTAs– within NAFTA, Mexico and Canada have done likewise– neither the EU nor the U.S. has engaged in significant

unilateral liberalisation over two decades

19

5. Conclusions5. Conclusions

• the growth in RTAs has substantially increased discrimination in world trade

• with the creation of plurilateral hubs and spokes, that discrimination has become multi-layered

• rules of origin have become more complex• Article XXIV of GATT has failed to protect the

interests of outside countries because:– it was based on inadequate trade theory– it is inconsistent with “the elimination of discriminatory

treatment in international commerce” (preamble to GATT 1947, see WTO (1995))

20

• “the elimination of discriminatory treatment in international trade relations” appears in the preamble to the Marrakesh Agreement establishing the WTO (WTO (1995)) and yet it, too, is being ignored by those Members who are forming RTAs

21

ReferencesReferences

Brown, D. K., A. V. Deardorff and Stern, R. M. (1992), “A North American Free Trade Agreement: Analytical Issues and Computational Assessment”, The World Economy, 15, 11-29

Haaland, J. and V. Norman (1992), “Global production effects of European integration”, in L. A. Winters (ed.) Trade Flows and Trade Policy after ‘1992’, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

Scollay, R. and J. P. Gilbert (2001), New Regional Trading Arrangements in the Asia Pacific?, Institute for International Economics, Washington, D. C.

Viner, J. (1950), The Customs Union Issue, Carnegie Endowment, New York

WTO (1995), The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations: The Legal Texts, Geneva

top related