a new model for investment decision engineering

9
Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 2211-3819 © 2011 Published by Elsevier B.V. doi:10.1016/j.sepro.2011.10.013 Available online at www.sciencedirect.com A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering Linjie He a , * Xiaoyong Zhang b a Hunan Normal University, Changsha Hunan, China b Hunan University, Changsha Hunan, China Abstract On the basis of Brennan’s (1998) dynamic investment decision model and engineering management, this paper builds an investor’s learning-decision model, allowing for the uncertainty of the expected return and the investor’s learning process. In our model, the variable of learning cost is added, which modifies the condition for decision of the investor, and assumes that the investment payoff cannot be observed, if an investor does not pay the learning cost. With the above conditions, this paper derives the optimal result of a three-period decision model on the basis of an investor’s learning behavior and decision engineering. The empirical evidence verifies the result of our model in this paper. Keywords: Investment Decision Model; Learning Behavior; Decision Engineering 1. Introduction In investors’ behavior research, a fundamental problem is investors’ optimal investment decision. Researchers have studied that problem for long, and built various models in the hope of characterizing investors’ optimal investment decision process and solving the optimization problem of investors’ investment decision mathematically. Investors’ behavioral decision model found its origin in Merton (1969) [1] . Merton preset investors’ behavior as consumption and investment: investors distribute their wealth between consumption and investment, expecting to maximize the utility of their final wealth over a period of time. In Merton’s model and other extended models of subsequent researchers, an underlying assumption is that investors face a known investment opportunity set, and the investment opportunity set parameters are the estimations of a certain time point. However, in the first place, investors actually don’t know much about the investment opportunity set in real financial market. The above assumption simplifies the estimation of investment opportunity parameters into point estimation with complete information about the investment opportunity set, and ignores estimation errors, which in turn will reduce investors’ investment decisions into the suboptimal state. Secondly, the portfolio planning process investors face is in fact a dynamic scenario decision making, and the information investors obtain at a certain time point is incomplete with new information available on the parameters as time passes. Consequently, in a dynamic setting, parameters are not fixed. Thirdly, a real investor is an individual with bounded rationality, that is, he is capable of continuous learning * Corresponding author. Tel.: +0-086-731-8882-3894; fax: +0-086-731-8882-3894. E-mail address: [email protected]. © 2011 Published by Elsevier B.V.

Upload: linjie-he

Post on 12-Sep-2016

212 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113

2211-3819 © 2011 Published by Elsevier B.V.doi:10.1016/j.sepro.2011.10.013

Available online at www.sciencedirect.comAvailable online at www.sciencedirect.com

Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

SystemsEngineering

Procedia

www.elsevier.com/locate/procedia

A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

Linjie Hea, *,Xiaoyong Zhangb a Hunan Normal University, Changsha Hunan, China

b Hunan University, Changsha Hunan, China

Abstract

On the basis of Brennan’s (1998) dynamic investment decision model and engineering management, this paper builds an investor’s learning-decision model, allowing for the uncertainty of the expected return and the investor’s learning process. In our model, the variable of learning cost is added, which modifies the condition for decision of the investor, and assumes that the investment payoff cannot be observed, if an investor does not pay the learning cost. With the above conditions, this paper derives the optimal result of a three-period decision model on the basis of an investor’s learning behavior and decision engineering. The empirical evidence verifies the result of our model in this paper. © 2011 Published by Elsevier Ltd. Selection and peer-review under responsibility of Desheng Dash Wu

Keywords: Investment Decision Model; Learning Behavior; Decision Engineering

1. Introduction

In investors’ behavior research, a fundamental problem is investors’ optimal investment decision. Researchers have studied that problem for long, and built various models in the hope of characterizing investors’ optimal investment decision process and solving the optimization problem of investors’ investment decision mathematically.

Investors’ behavioral decision model found its origin in Merton (1969)[1]. Merton preset investors’ behavior as consumption and investment: investors distribute their wealth between consumption and investment, expecting to maximize the utility of their final wealth over a period of time. In Merton’s model and other extended models of subsequent researchers, an underlying assumption is that investors face a known investment opportunity set, and the investment opportunity set parameters are the estimations of a certain time point. However, in the first place, investors actually don’t know much about the investment opportunity set in real financial market. The above assumption simplifies the estimation of investment opportunity parameters into point estimation with complete information about the investment opportunity set, and ignores estimation errors, which in turn will reduce investors’ investment decisions into the suboptimal state. Secondly, the portfolio planning process investors face is in fact a dynamic scenario decision making, and the information investors obtain at a certain time point is incomplete with new information available on the parameters as time passes. Consequently, in a dynamic setting, parameters are not fixed. Thirdly, a real investor is an individual with bounded rationality, that is, he is capable of continuous learning

* Corresponding author. Tel.: +0-086-731-8882-3894; fax: +0-086-731-8882-3894. E-mail address: [email protected].

© 2011 Published by Elsevier B.V.

Page 2: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

106 Linjie He and Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 Linjie He,Xiaoyong Zhang/ Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

to improve his decision making ability. Therefore, when modeling a investors’ decision making, we should take the investor’s learning ability into account, and use new data to update his prior belief continuously—his parameters estimations so as to keep his dynamic investment decision making at the optimal state.

As early as in the 1970s, financial researchers have realized the importance of the uncertainty of the parameters and the investor’s learning in his dynamic decision making process. Williams (1977) [2] pointed out the uncertainty of the parameters will give rise to an investor’s demand on hedging for his investment portfolio. Bawa, Brown, Klein (1979) [3] first considered the uncertainty of the parameters of the return distribution in a single period context. Gennote (1986) [4] discussed the investor’s decision making process in the case of uncertainty of expected investment return. Brennan (1998) [5] derived the effect of a risk asset’s price uncertainty on the investor’s dynamic decision making process in the framework of Merton (1969), and proved that the investor can update his expected investment return through his learning. Xia (2001) [6] has further argued that the investor’s predictability of observable state variables can be improved through his learning. Brennan and Xia (2001) expounded that investors’ uncertainty about the premium increment can be used to explain the stock’s “premium puzzle”. Epstein and Miao (2003) [7] constructed an equilibrium model to solve heterogeneous investors’ investment decision optimization problem. Pastor and Veronesi (2005a, 2005b) [8,9] showed that investors’ uncertainty about expected return on future investment is an important reason that gives rise to the volatility of IPO and the overpricing of Nasdaq stock in 1990s.

In this paper, we build, on the basis of the framework and the model of dynamic investment decision making in Brennan (1998), an investor’s learning-and-decision making model which incorporates the uncertainty of the expected return and the investor’s learning process to mathematically characterize the investor’s real decision making process.

2. Investor’s Learning-and-Decision Making Model

2.1. The Model and Parameter Specification

In Brennan (1998), the dynamic investment decision making model ignores the learning cost, and thus excludes different effects of different learning costs on investors’ decision making behaviors. In this paper, we introduce a learning cost variable, and modify the assumption on individual investors which assumes that, if the investor does not invest (including real investment and just paying for the learning cost) , he cannot observe the investment return. With these modifications, we build an extended model to characterize how an individual investor’s learning behavior influence his optimal investment decision in the security investment decision making process. Our model satisfies the following assumptions: The security market is made up of individual investors, each investor living for T periods, i.e., t= 1, 2, …, T. The

investment horizon is T -1 periods, that is, t= 1, 2, …, T-1; and at the last period, when t= T-1, the investor’s utility power over the terminal wealth is:

1

p

1)(

1

1T

T

WWU

In the T-1 periods investment horizon, the investor chooses an amount xt,, xt≥0; In the security market, there are two assets, i.e., risk free asset (bond) and risk asset (stock), and the risk asset

does not pay interest; In the various periods of his investment process, the outcomes follow a binominal distribution:

x

pxS

1)1()1(

where, p is the probability of a success in trade, and 1-p is the probability of a failure of trade; and 0≤λ≤1. For each trade in the investment horizon, the investor must pay the learning cost c (c>0). Besides, the investor

Page 3: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

107Linjie He and Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 Linjie He,Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

can observe the trade outcome through paying the transaction fee, but does not undertake a real trade (xt,=0); A single investor’s initial wealth is w1, and w1 >>c; A single investor has uncertainty about the probability estimation p. But he has a prior belief for p, that is,

(1) At the initial period of investment, when t=1, his prior belief is a Beta(α1,β1) distribution; (2) If the investor does not pay the transaction fee, he cannot observe the trade outcome; (3) If the investor trades, or choose not to undertake real trade (xt=0) but pays the transaction fee, he will be able

to observe the trade outcome, and updates his belief as a Bayesian investor following the updating rule Beta (α1+Nt, β1+t-Nt ) distribution (Fig. 1).

Wealth:w2 Belief: ),( 11 k

1-p

p

Wealth:w1 Belief: ),( 11

Wealth:w2 Belief: ),( 11 k

Period 3 Period 2 Period 1

Fig.1 A Single Investor’s Learning Rule

2.2. Investor’s Investment Decision Optimization

According to the assumption, we need to consider two aspects. First, in the process of the investment decision making, the investor has 3 investment decision strategies: (1) undertaking real investment and paying the learning cost to observe the trade outcome (i.e., xt>0, c>0); (2) not undertaking real investment, but paying the learning cost to observe the trade outcome (i.e., xt=0, c>0); (3) neither undertaking real investment, nor paying the learning cost to observe the trade outcome (i.e., xt=0, c=0).

Secondly, in the model, we study a single investor living for T periods, with his investment periods 1, 2, …, T-1. The 2 dependent variables for investment decision making model are: the investor’s wealth and his belief. Therefore, the investor’s investment decision optimization process is to maximize his indirect utility over his terminal wealth with his belief updates and minimum trade size constraint over various investment periods. We then simplify the investor’s investment behavior, and assume that a single investor lives for 3 periods and study his investment decision optimization.

2.3. End-of-Period Investment Strategy Optimization (T=2)

With the above assumptions, the terminal period investment decision optimization problem must be solved first by obtaining the optimal outcomes of the three single investment strategies and then comparing the three results to identify the optimal strategy.

First, we will come to the optimization problem of the investor undertaking real investment. Let the value equation of the investor’s wealth at Period 2 be J2(W2, p2). According the optimization principle, the investor’s maximization of his investment decision outcome is to maximize his indirect utility over his terminal wealth.

Page 4: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

108 Linjie He and Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 Linjie He,Xiaoyong Zhang/ Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

Therefore, the mathematical expression of this optimization process is,

}1

)()ˆ1(1

)(ˆ{)ˆ,(1

222

122

20

222 max2

cxWp

cxWppWJ

x

I

According to Bellman's Principle of Optimality, the solution to this kind of optimization problem is to solve

E[dJ]=0. Therefore, the first order derivative of (3) is the optimal outcome of the real investment decision:

0]

1)()ˆ1(

1)(ˆ[

2

122

2

122

2

dx

cxWp

cxWpd

)()ˆ1(ˆ)ˆ1(ˆ1

2/12

/12

/12

/12

2 cWpp

ppx

Substitute the outcome into the wealth-value equation J12 (W2, p2), we get

0])ˆ1(ˆ[21

)()ˆ,( 2/1

2/1

21

12

222

xppcW

pWJ I

Then, consider the optimization problem when the investor chooses the investment strategy II. Likewise, we can

write the optimization problem of the investor’s wealth-value equation JII2(W2, p2) as

}1

)()ˆ1(1

)(ˆ{)ˆ,(1

22

12

20

222 max2

cWp

cWppWJ

x

II

From the above equation, we can see that, in accordance to Bellman's Principle of Optimality, there does not

exist an optimal solution. Therefore, it suggests that for the investor’s terminal period investment decision it is not the investor’s optimal investment behavior not to undertake real investment but pay the cost to observe the trade outcome.

Lastly, consider the optimization problem when the investor chooses the investment strategy III. If the investor neither undertakes real investment, nor pays the learning cost, but chooses to exit the stock market, his wealth-value equation is

1)ˆ,(

12

222W

pWJ III

After solving the optimization problems for the three investment strategies, we compare the three outcomes to

solve the optimization problem of the investor’s terminal period investment decision in terms of the principle of utility maximization:

)ˆ,(,)ˆ,(maxarg)ˆ,( 222222222 pWJpWJpWJ IIII

Page 5: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

109Linjie He and Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 Linjie He,Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

)If the investor chooses investment strategy I to make real investment, expression (9) becomes

ˆ,()ˆ,( 222222 pWJpWJ IIII

1])ˆ1(ˆ[2

1)( 1

2/12

/12

11

2 Wpp

cW

From e above expressions w c w th

to r t e

th , e an kno at the conditions for the choice of strategy I are (1) p2>1/2 and (2) )]. The conditions show us that the learning cost for the investor

should not be too high, or the investor will choose to give up learning and exit the market. In other words, the conditions mean that the investor will pay the learning cost lea n h investment skills if the cost is low enough in the stock market. We notate the learning cost as c and

1/(1[/12

/12

12 }])ˆ1(ˆ[21{ ppWc

0 2

c

. Hence, the investor’s investment decision equation is

W

}])ˆ1(ˆ[2{1

)( /111

22 ckW

)ˆ,( 2222 pppWJ

/1

In the case that the investor stays out of the market, k2=0, . 1])ˆ1(ˆ[2 /1

2/1

21 pp

For the simplicity of the expressions, we set , and thus the optimal result of the terminal investment decision becomes

])ˆ1(ˆ[2)ˆ(ˆ /12

/12

122 pppB

)ˆ(ˆ1

)()ˆ,( 2

122

22 2 pBckW

pWJ

In the above expression, what is worth emphasizing is that investors are heterogeneous traders in terms of our

assumption, and therefore the belief function ) is indirectly influenced by investors’ wealth W2. ˆ(ˆ

22 pB

2.4. Initial Period Investment Strategy Optimization (T=1)

In this section, we set about solving the optimization problem of the investor’s initial Investment strategy. Here, we continue to use the optimization method discussed in the previous section. We first derive the investor’s maximum indirect utility of his wealth in terms of Bellman’s Principle of Optimality, and then choose among the optimal outcomes.

First, we solve the optimization problem of the investor’s investment strategy I. The investor’s wealth-value optimization equation is

}1

])[()ˆ1(

1])[(ˆ{

)}ˆ,()ˆ1()ˆ,(ˆ{

})ˆ,()ˆ1()ˆ,(ˆ{)ˆ,(

2

1211

12

1211

10

21121211210

222122210

111

max

maxmax

1

1

1

BckcxW

pBckcxW

p

pcxWJppcxWJp

pWJppWJppWJ

x

x

x

I

where 2 ; + signifies that the trading outcome is increasing, and – means that trading outcome is decreasing. Solving the optimization problem through Bellman’s optimization process E[dJ]=0, we get

ˆ(ˆ pB2B̂ )

}]ˆ)ˆ1[(]ˆˆ[]ˆ)ˆ1[(]ˆˆ[

]ˆ)ˆ1[(]ˆˆ[]ˆ)ˆ1[(]ˆˆ[{1

/121

/121

2/1

212/1

211/1

21/1

21

/121

/121

1 cBpBp

kBpkBpW

BpBp

BpBpx

Page 6: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

110 Linjie He and Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 Linjie He,Xiaoyong Zhang/ Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

Substitute the optimal outcome into the wealth-value equation , we obtain )ˆ,( 111 pWJ I

2

2/121

1

11

2

2/122

/121

11

1

111

ˆ of case in the made are

sinvestment and0])ˆˆ[(2

1

)23(

B̂ of cases both thein made

are sinvestment and0}]ˆ)ˆ1[()ˆˆ{(2

1)2(

)ˆ,(

B

xBp

cW

xBpBp

cW

pWJ I

Secondly, we consider the optimiza ion problem of the investor’s investment strategy II. The investor’s wealth-

value optimization equation is t )ˆ,( 112 pWJ II

}ˆ1

])[()ˆ1(ˆ

1])[(ˆ{

)}ˆ,()ˆ1()ˆ,(ˆ pcWJp{)ˆ,(

2

121

12

121

1

21212121112

BckcW

pBckcW

p

pcWJppWJ II

Thirdly, we come to the optimization problem of the investor’s investment strategy III. When the investor choose to stay out of the stock market, his wealth-value equation is

1)ˆ,(

11

111W

pWJ III

Finally, we compare the three investment outcomes in terms of the principle of maximizing the indirect utility, and the investor’s initial period investment strategy optimization problem is

)ˆ,(),ˆ,(,)ˆ,(maxarg)ˆ,( 111111111111 pWJpWJpWJpWJ IIIIII

3. Empirical Study

3.1. Methodology and Data

There doesn’t exist an analytical solution to the investor’s investment decision model in this paper, and the model cannot be directly transformed to estimate the parameter for the learning cost. Therefore, this paper adopts the following empirical research design: first, take discrete parameters (kα, kβ, α1, β1); secondly, list all the possible belief combinations; thirdly, find the solutions to the model with those belief combinations. According to this design, for every investor i and each group of parameters (kα, kβ), we first use the priori belief (αi1, βi1) to estimate the shortest distance between the realized outcome and the forecast by the model; then, we use xαt to represent the real investment size (including trading cost c) and xρt to represent the investment size forecast by the priori belief ρ≡(α1, β1) to solve for yαt,, yρt (yt representing the increment of the investment size ). The formula for yt is:

0,0

0,1

1

11

t

tt

t

t

xif

xifx

xy

Next, we define the distance between the real investment size and the forecast investment size (t>1) as

elseyy

andxifx

andxifx

e

tt

tt

tt

t

001001

Page 7: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

111Linjie He and Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 Linjie He,Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

2

The distance represents the difference in the increments of the real investment size and the forecast investment size for an investor. For a given new parameter group (kα, kβ), we will select the optimal investment belief ρi* for every investor i to solve for minimum squared sum of the distance between the real investment size and the forecast size within the first k trading days, that is,

K

tt

i e2

* )(minarg

In this way, the point estimates of the parameters we need are then changed into the process of solving for the minimum sum of squared residuals for M single investors in the sample space,

M

mm

kkkk

1

*

),(

** minarg),(

At last, we sample the single investors in the sample for Q times to solve for the path estimate with the sample distribution (k*α, k*β). In the estimating process, we have an implicit assumption of the investor’s belief, that is, the belief of an investor, with (kα, kβ) as his choice, conforms to Bayesian rationality.

The empirical study in this section involves the following procedures: first, we generate a network of 1,000 investors’ beliefs, and randomly select 30 different values from 0.5 to 2 for α1 and β1; secondly, we set kα = 1, and select 100 different values ranging from 0 to 2 for kβ. The reason for presetting kα and varying kβ is due to the fact that the investor’s belief and his updating parameter cannot be identified at the same time in the investor’s behavioral decision model. Therefore, the purpose of using this estimation method is to test whether a single investor can update his investment belief symmetrically, or in mathematical language, to see whether there exists kα,= kβ, as the symmetrical updating is supposed to be the information updating of a Bayesian man.

The data used in this paper is from the investors’ trading data bank of Fortune Securities, each piece of datum for a investor consists of: trading time, price, volume, buying/selling, trading cost, stock name, tick, investor code. In addition, in view of the need of data for continuous trading, we eliminate those inactive traders and select high frequency traders (T=480) as the sample for the empirical study. An obvious characteristic of the high frequency traders is that they undertake trade in almost every trading day except for certain time points. The duration of the data for this empirical study is from January 1, 2007 to December 31, 2008, with 185 investors selected for this empirical study.

In this study, we preset the following parameters: T=10 for the horizontal axis, the single investor’s risk aversion coefficient γ=2, and the trading cost c=50. Furthermore, we set that the investment outcome is loss if the average selling price is lower than the average buying price within a trading day, and the contrary is also true. We use every investor’s real investment outcome to predict his investment size within a trading day. Meanwhile, we adopt investor’s trading data for the first 10 trading days (M=10) to assess the adaptability of the model. The sample replacement Q is set to be 20, 000 times, and the size of the path sample is the same as the size of the original sample.

3.2. Analysis of Empirical Evidence

Fig. 2 Sample path distribution of kβ

Page 8: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

112 Linjie He and Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 Linjie He,Xiaoyong Zhang/ Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

Figure 2 depicts the sample path distribution, which shows kβ is significantly less than 1 in our estimation: 98.72% of the estimates for kβ ranges from 0.256 to 0.283 with a mean of 0.285 and a median of 0.275. This result indicates that, compared to the gain, single investors underestimate the loss. But for a Bayesian investor, he tends to symmetrically update his belief in the gain and the loss, i.e., kα,= kβ= 1. Thus, our conclusion is consistent with that of investors’ attribution bias in previous literature on behavioral finance. For example, Daniel, Hirshleifer and Subrahmanyam (1998) modeled the investor’s over-reaction and under-reaction to the stock price change in the process of updating his belief. Gervais and Odean (2001) studied the outcome of non-Bayesian man’s belief updating rule: if the investor relatively overestimates the gain over the loss, then what would happen in the stock market? Based on the above, our estimate kα,≥ kβ will give the similar explanation: even if the investor can learn from the trading outcome, and gain some investment experience, his technique of processing new information, compared to the Bayesian man’s symmetrical updating of information (kα= kβ= 1) , is still partly suboptimal.

There is still a point that must be pointed out is that in our empirical study we have an implicit assumption for every investors—they update their investment belief in the same way. Other studies such as Nicolosi, peng and Zhu (2004) found that single investors are heterogeneous in their investment decision learning behaviors. In Figure 3 the sample distribution shows that there exists “unusual” coarseness when the distribution density approaches to kβ= 1. This result suggests that there exists a possibility that there is a small number of single investors whose learning abilities are superior to most of the investors.

Fig. 3 Single investors’ priori belief distribution

Figure 3 is the distribution of single investors’ priori beliefs. The diagonal represents the set of the break-even points of the investors’ costs before their trading. The result tells us two interesting rules. First, most single investors don’t believe that they would gain at their initial trading in the stock market: 57.9% investors’ beliefs are above the break-even point diagonal, i.e., E1(p)<0.5. This finding is consistent with the theoretical description about ordinary investors’ beliefs in Mahani and Bernhardt (2005). Furthermore, theories like theirs give a strong support to our assumption of learning man. It shows that most of the investors undertake intra-day trading only because they think that security trading may make profit, but not because they have clear investment beliefs that security investment will surely be profitable. In addition, we find that, for most of the investors, their investment behavior at their initial investment trading period is located in the section of “paying learning cost” of the figure. This finding is of great theoretic significance for the study of investors’ learning behavior.

The second rule we find is that single investors beliefs cluster at the area where α1=0, β1=0, which indicates in Figure 3 that investors are not quite sure about the profitability of their trading in their initial period of investment. (Of course, Figure 3 also shows that there exist some investors with obstinate investment belief (for example, those with relatively high value of α1+β1 ), which means that they are confident of their investment decision. )

Page 9: A New Model for Investment Decision Engineering

113Linjie He and Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 2 (2011) 105 – 113 Linjie He,Xiaoyong Zhang / Systems Engineering Procedia 00 (2011) 000–000

4. Conclusion

In this paper, we introduce learning cost into the dynamic investment decision model in Bernnan (1998) to construct an investor’s learning-decision engineering model on the basis of their learning behavior, and calculate the optimal decision for a three-period investment and the optimal investment size. We also find that, if the learning cost is relatively small, investors are willing to make small size investment for the sake of learning, even when they are aware that they face a loss. In our empirical study, we analyze the investment decisions of investors (both with optimistic and pessimistic beliefs) and our calculation results support the model assumption and conclusion that single investors have a demand for learning and their learning costs are real in their process of investment decision. Furthermore, single investors will make small size investments to learn the stock market and their own ability to make investment decisions at the risk of a loss if the learning cost is affordable.

5. Copyright

All authors must sign the Transfer of Copyright agreement before the article can be published. This transfer agreement enables Elsevier to protect the copyrighted material for the authors, but does not relinquish the authors' proprietary rights. The copyright transfer covers the exclusive rights to reproduce and distribute the article, including reprints, photographic reproductions, microfilm or any other reproductions of similar nature and translations. Authors are responsible for obtaining from the copyright holder permission to reproduce any figures for which copyright exists.

Acknowledgements

This paper is funded by Provincial Natural Science foundation of Hunan under grants No. 11JJ5052 and by Provincial Social Science of Hunan under grants No. 2010YBA163.

References

1. Merton R.C., Lifetime Portfolio Selection Under Uncertainty: The Continuous-time Case. Review of Economics and Statistics. 3 (1969) 247-257.

2. Williams J.T., Capital Asset Prices With Heterogeneous Beliefs. Journal of Financial Economics. 2 (1977) 219-239. 3. Bawa V. and Klein R., Estimation Risk and Optimal Portfolio Choice, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1979. 4. F.W and X.Y, Skewness of Return Distribution and Coeffcient of Risk Premium. Journal of Systems Science and Complexity. 1 (2009)

360-371. 5. Brennan M.J., The role of learning in dynamic portfolio decisions. European Economic Review. 3 (1998) 295-306. 6. Xia Y, Learning About Predictability:The Effects of Parameter Uncertainty on Dynamic Asset Allocation. Journal of Finance. 1 (2001)

205-246. 7. Epstein L and Miao J J, A Two-Person Dynamic Equilibrium Under Ambiguity. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 7 (2003)

1253-1288. 8. Barber B M and Odean T, Boys Will be Boys: Gender, Overconfidence, and Common Stock Investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics.

1 (2001a) 261-292. 9. Barber B M and Odean T, The Internet and the Investor. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 1 (2001b) 41-54.